Quotations.ch
  Directory : An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
GUIDE SUPPORT US BLOG
  • The Project Gutenberg EBook of An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
  • the Wealth of Nations, by Adam Smith
  • This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere at no cost and with
  • almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or
  • re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included
  • with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org
  • Title: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
  • Author: Adam Smith
  • Release Date: February 28, 2009 [EBook #3300]
  • Last Updated: September 7, 2019
  • Language: English
  • Character set encoding: UTF-8
  • *** START OF THIS PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK NATURE AND CAUSES OF THE WEALTH OF NATIONS ***
  • Produced by Colin Muir, and David Widger
  • An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
  • by Adam Smith
  • Contents
  • INTRODUCTION AND PLAN OF THE WORK.
  • BOOK I. OF THE CAUSES OF IMPROVEMENT IN THE PRODUCTIVE
  • POWERS OF LABOUR, AND OF THE ORDER ACCORDING TO WHICH ITS PRODUCE IS NATURALLY
  • DISTRIBUTED AMONG THE DIFFERENT RANKS OF THE PEOPLE.
  • CHAPTER I. OF THE DIVISION OF LABOUR.
  • CHAPTER II. OF THE PRINCIPLE WHICH GIVES OCCASION TO THE
  • DIVISION OF LABOUR.
  • CHAPTER III. THAT THE DIVISION OF LABOUR IS LIMITED BY
  • THE EXTENT OF THE MARKET.
  • CHAPTER IV. OF THE ORIGIN AND USE OF MONEY.
  • CHAPTER V. OF THE REAL AND NOMINAL PRICE OF
  • COMMODITIES, OR OF THEIR PRICE IN LABOUR, AND THEIR PRICE IN MONEY.
  • CHAPTER VI. OF THE COMPONENT PART OF THE PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
  • CHAPTER VII. OF THE NATURAL AND MARKET PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
  • CHAPTER VIII. OF THE WAGES OF LABOUR.
  • CHAPTER IX. OF THE PROFITS OF STOCK.
  • CHAPTER X. OF WAGES AND PROFIT IN THE DIFFERENT
  • EMPLOYMENTS OF LABOUR AND STOCK.
  • CHAPTER XI. OF THE RENT OF LAND.
  • BOOK II. OF THE NATURE, ACCUMULATION, AND
  • EMPLOYMENT OF STOCK.
  • CHAPTER I. OF THE DIVISION OF STOCK.
  • CHAPTER II. OF MONEY, CONSIDERED AS A PARTICULAR BRANCH
  • OF THE GENERAL STOCK OF THE SOCIETY, OR OF THE EXPENSE OF MAINTAINING THE
  • NATIONAL CAPITAL.
  • CHAPTER III. OF THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL, OR OF
  • PRODUCTIVE AND UNPRODUCTIVE LABOUR.
  • CHAPTER IV. OF STOCK LENT AT INTEREST.
  • CHAPTER V. OF THE DIFFERENT EMPLOYMENTS OF
  • CAPITALS.
  • BOOK III. OF THE DIFFERENT PROGRESS OF OPULENCE IN
  • DIFFERENT NATIONS
  • CHAPTER I. OF THE NATURAL PROGRESS OF OPULENCE.
  • CHAPTER II. OF THE DISCOURAGEMENT OF AGRICULTURE IN THE
  • ANCIENT STATE OF EUROPE, AFTER THE FALL OF THE ROMAN EMPIRE.
  • CHAPTER III. OF THE RISE AND PROGRESS OF CITIES AND
  • TOWNS, AFTER THE FALL OF THE ROMAN EMPIRE.
  • CHAPTER IV. HOW THE COMMERCE OF TOWNS CONTRIBUTED TO THE
  • IMPROVEMENT OF THE COUNTRY.
  • BOOK IV. OF SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY.
  • CHAPTER I. OF THE PRINCIPLE OF THE COMMERCIAL OR
  • MERCANTILE SYSTEM.
  • CHAPTER II. OF RESTRAINTS UPON IMPORTATION FROM FOREIGN
  • COUNTRIES OF SUCH GOODS AS CAN BE PRODUCED AT HOME.
  • CHAPTER III. OF THE EXTRAORDINARY RESTRAINTS UPON THE
  • IMPORTATION OF GOODS OF ALMOST ALL KINDS, FROM THOSE COUNTRIES WITH WHICH THE
  • BALANCE IS SUPPOSED TO BE DISADVANTAGEOUS.
  • CHAPTER IV. OF DRAWBACKS.
  • CHAPTER V. OF BOUNTIES.
  • CHAPTER VI. OF TREATIES OF COMMERCE.
  • CHAPTER VII. OF COLONIES.
  • CHAPTER VIII. CONCLUSION OF THE MERCANTILE SYSTEM.
  • CHAPTER IX. OF THE AGRICULTURAL SYSTEMS, OR OF THOSE
  • SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY WHICH REPRESENT THE PRODUCE OF LAND, AS EITHER
  • THE SOLE OR THE PRINCIPAL SOURCE OF THE REVENUE AND WEALTH OF EVERY COUNTRY.
  • BOOK V. OF THE REVENUE OF THE SOVEREIGN OR COMMONWEALTH
  • CHAPTER I. OF THE EXPENSES OF THE SOVEREIGN OR COMMONWEALTH.
  • CHAPTER II. OF THE SOURCES OF THE GENERAL OR PUBLIC
  • REVENUE OF THE SOCIETY.
  • CHAPTER III. OF PUBLIC DEBTS.
  • INTRODUCTION AND PLAN OF THE WORK.
  • The annual labour of every nation is the fund which originally supplies it
  • with all the necessaries and conveniencies of life which it annually
  • consumes, and which consist always either in the immediate produce of that
  • labour, or in what is purchased with that produce from other nations.
  • According, therefore, as this produce, or what is purchased with it, bears
  • a greater or smaller proportion to the number of those who are to consume
  • it, the nation will be better or worse supplied with all the necessaries
  • and conveniencies for which it has occasion.
  • But this proportion must in every nation be regulated by two different
  • circumstances: first, by the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which its
  • labour is generally applied; and, secondly, by the proportion between the
  • number of those who are employed in useful labour, and that of those who
  • are not so employed. Whatever be the soil, climate, or extent of territory
  • of any particular nation, the abundance or scantiness of its annual supply
  • must, in that particular situation, depend upon those two circumstances.
  • The abundance or scantiness of this supply, too, seems to depend more upon
  • the former of those two circumstances than upon the latter. Among the
  • savage nations of hunters and fishers, every individual who is able to
  • work is more or less employed in useful labour, and endeavours to provide,
  • as well as he can, the necessaries and conveniencies of life, for himself,
  • and such of his family or tribe as are either too old, or too young, or
  • too infirm, to go a-hunting and fishing. Such nations, however, are so
  • miserably poor, that, from mere want, they are frequently reduced, or at
  • least think themselves reduced, to the necessity sometimes of directly
  • destroying, and sometimes of abandoning their infants, their old people,
  • and those afflicted with lingering diseases, to perish with hunger, or to
  • be devoured by wild beasts. Among civilized and thriving nations, on the
  • contrary, though a great number of people do not labour at all, many of
  • whom consume the produce of ten times, frequently of a hundred times, more
  • labour than the greater part of those who work; yet the produce of the
  • whole labour of the society is so great, that all are often abundantly
  • supplied; and a workman, even of the lowest and poorest order, if he is
  • frugal and industrious, may enjoy a greater share of the necessaries and
  • conveniencies of life than it is possible for any savage to acquire.
  • The causes of this improvement in the productive powers of labour, and the
  • order according to which its produce is naturally distributed among the
  • different ranks and conditions of men in the society, make the subject of
  • the first book of this Inquiry.
  • Whatever be the actual state of the skill, dexterity, and judgment, with
  • which labour is applied in any nation, the abundance or scantiness of its
  • annual supply must depend, during the continuance of that state, upon the
  • proportion between the number of those who are annually employed in useful
  • labour, and that of those who are not so employed. The number of useful
  • and productive labourers, it will hereafter appear, is everywhere in
  • proportion to the quantity of capital stock which is employed in setting
  • them to work, and to the particular way in which it is so employed. The
  • second book, therefore, treats of the nature of capital stock, of the
  • manner in which it is gradually accumulated, and of the different
  • quantities of labour which it puts into motion, according to the different
  • ways in which it is employed.
  • Nations tolerably well advanced as to skill, dexterity, and judgment, in
  • the application of labour, have followed very different plans in the
  • general conduct or direction of it; and those plans have not all been
  • equally favourable to the greatness of its produce. The policy of some
  • nations has given extraordinary encouragement to the industry of the
  • country; that of others to the industry of towns. Scarce any nation has
  • dealt equally and impartially with every sort of industry. Since the
  • down-fall of the Roman empire, the policy of Europe has been more
  • favourable to arts, manufactures, and commerce, the industry of towns,
  • than to agriculture, the Industry of the country. The circumstances which
  • seem to have introduced and established this policy are explained in the
  • third book.
  • Though those different plans were, perhaps, first introduced by the
  • private interests and prejudices of particular orders of men, without any
  • regard to, or foresight of, their consequences upon the general welfare of
  • the society; yet they have given occasion to very different theories of
  • political economy; of which some magnify the importance of that industry
  • which is carried on in towns, others of that which is carried on in the
  • country. Those theories have had a considerable influence, not only upon
  • the opinions of men of learning, but upon the public conduct of princes
  • and sovereign states. I have endeavoured, in the fourth book, to explain
  • as fully and distinctly as I can those different theories, and the
  • principal effects which they have produced in different ages and nations.
  • To explain in what has consisted the revenue of the great body of the
  • people, or what has been the nature of those funds, which, in different
  • ages and nations, have supplied their annual consumption, is the object of
  • these four first books. The fifth and last book treats of the revenue of
  • the sovereign, or commonwealth. In this book I have endeavoured to shew,
  • first, what are the necessary expenses of the sovereign, or commonwealth;
  • which of those expenses ought to be defrayed by the general contribution
  • of the whole society, and which of them, by that of some particular part
  • only, or of some particular members of it: secondly, what are the
  • different methods in which the whole society may be made to contribute
  • towards defraying the expenses incumbent on the whole society, and what
  • are the principal advantages and inconveniencies of each of those methods;
  • and, thirdly and lastly, what are the reasons and causes which have
  • induced almost all modern governments to mortgage some part of this
  • revenue, or to contract debts; and what have been the effects of those
  • debts upon the real wealth, the annual produce of the land and labour of
  • the society.
  • BOOK I.
  • OF THE CAUSES OF IMPROVEMENT IN THE
  • PRODUCTIVE POWERS OF LABOUR, AND OF THE ORDER ACCORDING TO WHICH ITS PRODUCE IS
  • NATURALLY DISTRIBUTED AMONG THE DIFFERENT RANKS OF THE PEOPLE.
  • CHAPTER I.
  • OF THE DIVISION OF LABOUR.
  • The greatest improvements in the productive powers of labour, and the
  • greater part of the skill, dexterity, and judgment, with which it is
  • anywhere directed, or applied, seem to have been the effects of the
  • division of labour. The effects of the division of labour, in the general
  • business of society, will be more easily understood, by considering in
  • what manner it operates in some particular manufactures. It is commonly
  • supposed to be carried furthest in some very trifling ones; not perhaps
  • that it really is carried further in them than in others of more
  • importance: but in those trifling manufactures which are destined to
  • supply the small wants of but a small number of people, the whole number
  • of workmen must necessarily be small; and those employed in every
  • different branch of the work can often be collected into the same
  • workhouse, and placed at once under the view of the spectator.
  • In those great manufactures, on the contrary, which are destined to supply
  • the great wants of the great body of the people, every different branch of
  • the work employs so great a number of workmen, that it is impossible to
  • collect them all into the same workhouse. We can seldom see more, at one
  • time, than those employed in one single branch. Though in such
  • manufactures, therefore, the work may really be divided into a much
  • greater number of parts, than in those of a more trifling nature, the
  • division is not near so obvious, and has accordingly been much less
  • observed.
  • To take an example, therefore, from a very trifling manufacture, but one
  • in which the division of labour has been very often taken notice of, the
  • trade of a pin-maker: a workman not educated to this business (which the
  • division of labour has rendered a distinct trade), nor acquainted with the
  • use of the machinery employed in it (to the invention of which the same
  • division of labour has probably given occasion), could scarce, perhaps,
  • with his utmost industry, make one pin in a day, and certainly could not
  • make twenty. But in the way in which this business is now carried on, not
  • only the whole work is a peculiar trade, but it is divided into a number
  • of branches, of which the greater part are likewise peculiar trades. One
  • man draws out the wire; another straights it; a third cuts it; a fourth
  • points it; a fifth grinds it at the top for receiving the head; to make
  • the head requires two or three distinct operations; to put it on is a
  • peculiar business; to whiten the pins is another; it is even a trade by
  • itself to put them into the paper; and the important business of making a
  • pin is, in this manner, divided into about eighteen distinct operations,
  • which, in some manufactories, are all performed by distinct hands, though
  • in others the same man will sometimes perform two or three of them. I have
  • seen a small manufactory of this kind, where ten men only were employed,
  • and where some of them consequently performed two or three distinct
  • operations. But though they were very poor, and therefore but
  • indifferently accommodated with the necessary machinery, they could, when
  • they exerted themselves, make among them about twelve pounds of pins in a
  • day. There are in a pound upwards of four thousand pins of a middling
  • size. Those ten persons, therefore, could make among them upwards of
  • forty-eight thousand pins in a day. Each person, therefore, making a tenth
  • part of forty-eight thousand pins, might be considered as making four
  • thousand eight hundred pins in a day. But if they had all wrought
  • separately and independently, and without any of them having been educated
  • to this peculiar business, they certainly could not each of them have made
  • twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day; that is, certainly, not the two
  • hundred and fortieth, perhaps not the four thousand eight hundredth, part
  • of what they are at present capable of performing, in consequence of a
  • proper division and combination of their different operations.
  • In every other art and manufacture, the effects of the division of labour
  • are similar to what they are in this very trifling one, though, in many of
  • them, the labour can neither be so much subdivided, nor reduced to so
  • great a simplicity of operation. The division of labour, however, so far
  • as it can be introduced, occasions, in every art, a proportionable
  • increase of the productive powers of labour. The separation of different
  • trades and employments from one another, seems to have taken place in
  • consequence of this advantage. This separation, too, is generally carried
  • furthest in those countries which enjoy the highest degree of industry and
  • improvement; what is the work of one man, in a rude state of society,
  • being generally that of several in an improved one. In every improved
  • society, the farmer is generally nothing but a farmer; the manufacturer,
  • nothing but a manufacturer. The labour, too, which is necessary to produce
  • any one complete manufacture, is almost always divided among a great
  • number of hands. How many different trades are employed in each branch of
  • the linen and woollen manufactures, from the growers of the flax and the
  • wool, to the bleachers and smoothers of the linen, or to the dyers and
  • dressers of the cloth! The nature of agriculture, indeed, does not admit
  • of so many subdivisions of labour, nor of so complete a separation of one
  • business from another, as manufactures. It is impossible to separate so
  • entirely the business of the grazier from that of the corn-farmer, as the
  • trade of the carpenter is commonly separated from that of the smith. The
  • spinner is almost always a distinct person from the weaver; but the
  • ploughman, the harrower, the sower of the seed, and the reaper of the
  • corn, are often the same. The occasions for those different sorts of
  • labour returning with the different seasons of the year, it is impossible
  • that one man should be constantly employed in any one of them. This
  • impossibility of making so complete and entire a separation of all the
  • different branches of labour employed in agriculture, is perhaps the
  • reason why the improvement of the productive powers of labour, in this
  • art, does not always keep pace with their improvement in manufactures. The
  • most opulent nations, indeed, generally excel all their neighbours in
  • agriculture as well as in manufactures; but they are commonly more
  • distinguished by their superiority in the latter than in the former. Their
  • lands are in general better cultivated, and having more labour and expense
  • bestowed upon them, produce more in proportion to the extent and natural
  • fertility of the ground. But this superiority of produce is seldom much
  • more than in proportion to the superiority of labour and expense. In
  • agriculture, the labour of the rich country is not always much more
  • productive than that of the poor; or, at least, it is never so much more
  • productive, as it commonly is in manufactures. The corn of the rich
  • country, therefore, will not always, in the same degree of goodness, come
  • cheaper to market than that of the poor. The corn of Poland, in the same
  • degree of goodness, is as cheap as that of France, notwithstanding the
  • superior opulence and improvement of the latter country. The corn of
  • France is, in the corn-provinces, fully as good, and in most years nearly
  • about the same price with the corn of England, though, in opulence and
  • improvement, France is perhaps inferior to England. The corn-lands of
  • England, however, are better cultivated than those of France, and the
  • corn-lands of France are said to be much better cultivated than those of
  • Poland. But though the poor country, notwithstanding the inferiority of
  • its cultivation, can, in some measure, rival the rich in the cheapness and
  • goodness of its corn, it can pretend to no such competition in its
  • manufactures, at least if those manufactures suit the soil, climate, and
  • situation, of the rich country. The silks of France are better and cheaper
  • than those of England, because the silk manufacture, at least under the
  • present high duties upon the importation of raw silk, does not so well
  • suit the climate of England as that of France. But the hardware and the
  • coarse woollens of England are beyond all comparison superior to those of
  • France, and much cheaper, too, in the same degree of goodness. In Poland
  • there are said to be scarce any manufactures of any kind, a few of those
  • coarser household manufactures excepted, without which no country can well
  • subsist.
  • This great increase in the quantity of work, which, in consequence of the
  • division of labour, the same number of people are capable of performing,
  • is owing to three different circumstances; first, to the increase of
  • dexterity in every particular workman; secondly, to the saving of the time
  • which is commonly lost in passing from one species of work to another;
  • and, lastly, to the invention of a great number of machines which
  • facilitate and abridge labour, and enable one man to do the work of many.
  • First, the improvement of the dexterity of the workmen, necessarily
  • increases the quantity of the work he can perform; and the division of
  • labour, by reducing every man’s business to some one simple operation, and
  • by making this operation the sole employment of his life, necessarily
  • increases very much the dexterity of the workman. A common smith, who,
  • though accustomed to handle the hammer, has never been used to make nails,
  • if, upon some particular occasion, he is obliged to attempt it, will
  • scarce, I am assured, be able to make above two or three hundred nails in
  • a day, and those, too, very bad ones. A smith who has been accustomed to
  • make nails, but whose sole or principal business has not been that of a
  • nailer, can seldom, with his utmost diligence, make more than eight
  • hundred or a thousand nails in a day. I have seen several boys, under
  • twenty years of age, who had never exercised any other trade but that of
  • making nails, and who, when they exerted themselves, could make, each of
  • them, upwards of two thousand three hundred nails in a day. The making of
  • a nail, however, is by no means one of the simplest operations. The same
  • person blows the bellows, stirs or mends the fire as there is occasion,
  • heats the iron, and forges every part of the nail: in forging the head,
  • too, he is obliged to change his tools. The different operations into
  • which the making of a pin, or of a metal button, is subdivided, are all of
  • them much more simple, and the dexterity of the person, of whose life it
  • has been the sole business to perform them, is usually much greater. The
  • rapidity with which some of the operations of those manufactures are
  • performed, exceeds what the human hand could, by those who had never seen
  • them, be supposed capable of acquiring.
  • Secondly, the advantage which is gained by saving the time commonly lost
  • in passing from one sort of work to another, is much greater than we
  • should at first view be apt to imagine it. It is impossible to pass very
  • quickly from one kind of work to another, that is carried on in a
  • different place, and with quite different tools. A country weaver, who
  • cultivates a small farm, must lose a good deal of time in passing from
  • his loom to the field, and from the field to his loom. When the two trades
  • can be carried on in the same workhouse, the loss of time is, no doubt,
  • much less. It is, even in this case, however, very considerable. A man
  • commonly saunters a little in turning his hand from one sort of employment
  • to another. When he first begins the new work, he is seldom very keen and
  • hearty; his mind, as they say, does not go to it, and for some time he
  • rather trifles than applies to good purpose. The habit of sauntering, and
  • of indolent careless application, which is naturally, or rather
  • necessarily, acquired by every country workman who is obliged to change
  • his work and his tools every half hour, and to apply his hand in twenty
  • different ways almost every day of his life, renders him almost always
  • slothful and lazy, and incapable of any vigorous application, even on the
  • most pressing occasions. Independent, therefore, of his deficiency in
  • point of dexterity, this cause alone must always reduce considerably the
  • quantity of work which he is capable of performing.
  • Thirdly, and lastly, everybody must be sensible how much labour is
  • facilitated and abridged by the application of proper machinery. It is
  • unnecessary to give any example. I shall only observe, therefore, that the
  • invention of all those machines by which labour is so much facilitated and
  • abridged, seems to have been originally owing to the division of labour.
  • Men are much more likely to discover easier and readier methods of
  • attaining any object, when the whole attention of their minds is directed
  • towards that single object, than when it is dissipated among a great
  • variety of things. But, in consequence of the division of labour, the
  • whole of every man’s attention comes naturally to be directed towards some
  • one very simple object. It is naturally to be expected, therefore, that
  • some one or other of those who are employed in each particular branch of
  • labour should soon find out easier and readier methods of performing their
  • own particular work, whenever the nature of it admits of such improvement.
  • A great part of the machines made use of in those manufactures in which
  • labour is most subdivided, were originally the invention of common
  • workmen, who, being each of them employed in some very simple operation,
  • naturally turned their thoughts towards finding out easier and readier
  • methods of performing it. Whoever has been much accustomed to visit such
  • manufactures, must frequently have been shewn very pretty machines, which
  • were the inventions of such workmen, in order to facilitate and quicken
  • their own particular part of the work. In the first fire engines {this was
  • the current designation for steam engines}, a boy was constantly employed
  • to open and shut alternately the communication between the boiler and the
  • cylinder, according as the piston either ascended or descended. One of
  • those boys, who loved to play with his companions, observed that, by tying
  • a string from the handle of the valve which opened this communication to
  • another part of the machine, the valve would open and shut without his
  • assistance, and leave him at liberty to divert himself with his
  • play-fellows. One of the greatest improvements that has been made upon
  • this machine, since it was first invented, was in this manner the
  • discovery of a boy who wanted to save his own labour.
  • All the improvements in machinery, however, have by no means been the
  • inventions of those who had occasion to use the machines. Many
  • improvements have been made by the ingenuity of the makers of the
  • machines, when to make them became the business of a peculiar trade; and
  • some by that of those who are called philosophers, or men of speculation,
  • whose trade it is not to do any thing, but to observe every thing, and
  • who, upon that account, are often capable of combining together the powers
  • of the most distant and dissimilar objects in the progress of society,
  • philosophy or speculation becomes, like every other employment, the
  • principal or sole trade and occupation of a particular class of citizens.
  • Like every other employment, too, it is subdivided into a great number of
  • different branches, each of which affords occupation to a peculiar tribe
  • or class of philosophers; and this subdivision of employment in
  • philosophy, as well as in every other business, improves dexterity, and
  • saves time. Each individual becomes more expert in his own peculiar
  • branch, more work is done upon the whole, and the quantity of science is
  • considerably increased by it.
  • It is the great multiplication of the productions of all the different
  • arts, in consequence of the division of labour, which occasions, in a
  • well-governed society, that universal opulence which extends itself to the
  • lowest ranks of the people. Every workman has a great quantity of his own
  • work to dispose of beyond what he himself has occasion for; and every
  • other workman being exactly in the same situation, he is enabled to
  • exchange a great quantity of his own goods for a great quantity or, what
  • comes to the same thing, for the price of a great quantity of theirs. He
  • supplies them abundantly with what they have occasion for, and they
  • accommodate him as amply with what he has occasion for, and a general
  • plenty diffuses itself through all the different ranks of the society.
  • Observe the accommodation of the most common artificer or daylabourer in a
  • civilized and thriving country, and you will perceive that the number of
  • people, of whose industry a part, though but a small part, has been
  • employed in procuring him this accommodation, exceeds all computation. The
  • woollen coat, for example, which covers the day-labourer, as coarse and
  • rough as it may appear, is the produce of the joint labour of a great
  • multitude of workmen. The shepherd, the sorter of the wool, the
  • wool-comber or carder, the dyer, the scribbler, the spinner, the weaver,
  • the fuller, the dresser, with many others, must all join their different
  • arts in order to complete even this homely production. How many merchants
  • and carriers, besides, must have been employed in transporting the
  • materials from some of those workmen to others who often live in a very
  • distant part of the country? How much commerce and navigation in
  • particular, how many ship-builders, sailors, sail-makers, rope-makers,
  • must have been employed in order to bring together the different drugs
  • made use of by the dyer, which often come from the remotest corners of the
  • world? What a variety of labour, too, is necessary in order to produce the
  • tools of the meanest of those workmen! To say nothing of such complicated
  • machines as the ship of the sailor, the mill of the fuller, or even the
  • loom of the weaver, let us consider only what a variety of labour is
  • requisite in order to form that very simple machine, the shears with which
  • the shepherd clips the wool. The miner, the builder of the furnace for
  • smelting the ore, the feller of the timber, the burner of the charcoal to
  • be made use of in the smelting-house, the brickmaker, the bricklayer, the
  • workmen who attend the furnace, the millwright, the forger, the smith,
  • must all of them join their different arts in order to produce them. Were
  • we to examine, in the same manner, all the different parts of his dress
  • and household furniture, the coarse linen shirt which he wears next his
  • skin, the shoes which cover his feet, the bed which he lies on, and all
  • the different parts which compose it, the kitchen-grate at which he
  • prepares his victuals, the coals which he makes use of for that purpose,
  • dug from the bowels of the earth, and brought to him, perhaps, by a long
  • sea and a long land-carriage, all the other utensils of his kitchen, all
  • the furniture of his table, the knives and forks, the earthen or pewter
  • plates upon which he serves up and divides his victuals, the different
  • hands employed in preparing his bread and his beer, the glass window which
  • lets in the heat and the light, and keeps out the wind and the rain, with
  • all the knowledge and art requisite for preparing that beautiful and happy
  • invention, without which these northern parts of the world could scarce
  • have afforded a very comfortable habitation, together with the tools of
  • all the different workmen employed in producing those different
  • conveniencies; if we examine, I say, all these things, and consider what a
  • variety of labour is employed about each of them, we shall be sensible
  • that, without the assistance and co-operation of many thousands, the very
  • meanest person in a civilized country could not be provided, even
  • according to, what we very falsely imagine, the easy and simple manner in
  • which he is commonly accommodated. Compared, indeed, with the more
  • extravagant luxury of the great, his accommodation must no doubt appear
  • extremely simple and easy; and yet it may be true, perhaps, that the
  • accommodation of an European prince does not always so much exceed that of
  • an industrious and frugal peasant, as the accommodation of the latter
  • exceeds that of many an African king, the absolute masters of the lives
  • and liberties of ten thousand naked savages.
  • CHAPTER II.
  • OF THE PRINCIPLE WHICH GIVES OCCASION
  • TO THE DIVISION OF LABOUR.
  • This division of labour, from which so many advantages are derived, is not
  • originally the effect of any human wisdom, which foresees and intends that
  • general opulence to which it gives occasion. It is the necessary, though
  • very slow and gradual, consequence of a certain propensity in human
  • nature, which has in view no such extensive utility; the propensity to
  • truck, barter, and exchange one thing for another.
  • Whether this propensity be one of those original principles in human
  • nature, of which no further account can be given, or whether, as seems
  • more probable, it be the necessary consequence of the faculties of reason
  • and speech, it belongs not to our present subject to inquire. It is common
  • to all men, and to be found in no other race of animals, which seem to
  • know neither this nor any other species of contracts. Two greyhounds, in
  • running down the same hare, have sometimes the appearance of acting in
  • some sort of concert. Each turns her towards his companion, or endeavours
  • to intercept her when his companion turns her towards himself. This,
  • however, is not the effect of any contract, but of the accidental
  • concurrence of their passions in the same object at that particular time.
  • Nobody ever saw a dog make a fair and deliberate exchange of one bone for
  • another with another dog. Nobody ever saw one animal, by its gestures and
  • natural cries signify to another, this is mine, that yours; I am willing
  • to give this for that. When an animal wants to obtain something either of
  • a man, or of another animal, it has no other means of persuasion, but to
  • gain the favour of those whose service it requires. A puppy fawns upon its
  • dam, and a spaniel endeavours, by a thousand attractions, to engage the
  • attention of its master who is at dinner, when it wants to be fed by him.
  • Man sometimes uses the same arts with his brethren, and when he has no
  • other means of engaging them to act according to his inclinations,
  • endeavours by every servile and fawning attention to obtain their good
  • will. He has not time, however, to do this upon every occasion. In
  • civilized society he stands at all times in need of the co-operation and
  • assistance of great multitudes, while his whole life is scarce sufficient
  • to gain the friendship of a few persons. In almost every other race of
  • animals, each individual, when it is grown up to maturity, is entirely
  • independent, and in its natural state has occasion for the assistance of
  • no other living creature. But man has almost constant occasion for the
  • help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from their
  • benevolence only. He will be more likely to prevail if he can interest
  • their self-love in his favour, and shew them that it is for their own
  • advantage to do for him what he requires of them. Whoever offers to
  • another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I
  • want, and you shall have this which you want, is the meaning of every such
  • offer; and it is in this manner that we obtain from one another the far
  • greater part of those good offices which we stand in need of. It is not
  • from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we
  • expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. We address
  • ourselves, not to their humanity, but to their self-love, and never talk
  • to them of our own necessities, but of their advantages. Nobody but a
  • beggar chooses to depend chiefly upon the benevolence of his
  • fellow-citizens. Even a beggar does not depend upon it entirely. The
  • charity of well-disposed people, indeed, supplies him with the whole fund
  • of his subsistence. But though this principle ultimately provides him with
  • all the necessaries of life which he has occasion for, it neither does nor
  • can provide him with them as he has occasion for them. The greater part of
  • his occasional wants are supplied in the same manner as those of other
  • people, by treaty, by barter, and by purchase. With the money which one
  • man gives him he purchases food. The old clothes which another bestows
  • upon him he exchanges for other clothes which suit him better, or for
  • lodging, or for food, or for money, with which he can buy either food,
  • clothes, or lodging, as he has occasion.
  • As it is by treaty, by barter, and by purchase, that we obtain from one
  • another the greater part of those mutual good offices which we stand in
  • need of, so it is this same trucking disposition which originally gives
  • occasion to the division of labour. In a tribe of hunters or shepherds, a
  • particular person makes bows and arrows, for example, with more readiness
  • and dexterity than any other. He frequently exchanges them for cattle or
  • for venison, with his companions; and he finds at last that he can, in
  • this manner, get more cattle and venison, than if he himself went to the
  • field to catch them. From a regard to his own interest, therefore, the
  • making of bows and arrows grows to be his chief business, and he becomes a
  • sort of armourer. Another excels in making the frames and covers of their
  • little huts or moveable houses. He is accustomed to be of use in this way
  • to his neighbours, who reward him in the same manner with cattle and with
  • venison, till at last he finds it his interest to dedicate himself
  • entirely to this employment, and to become a sort of house-carpenter. In
  • the same manner a third becomes a smith or a brazier; a fourth, a tanner
  • or dresser of hides or skins, the principal part of the clothing of
  • savages. And thus the certainty of being able to exchange all that surplus
  • part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own
  • consumption, for such parts of the produce of other men’s labour as he may
  • have occasion for, encourages every man to apply himself to a particular
  • occupation, and to cultivate and bring to perfection whatever talent of
  • genius he may possess for that particular species of business.
  • The difference of natural talents in different men, is, in reality, much
  • less than we are aware of; and the very different genius which appears to
  • distinguish men of different professions, when grown up to maturity, is
  • not upon many occasions so much the cause, as the effect of the division
  • of labour. The difference between the most dissimilar characters, between
  • a philosopher and a common street porter, for example, seems to arise not
  • so much from nature, as from habit, custom, and education. When they came
  • in to the world, and for the first six or eight years of their existence,
  • they were, perhaps, very much alike, and neither their parents nor
  • play-fellows could perceive any remarkable difference. About that age, or
  • soon after, they come to be employed in very different occupations. The
  • difference of talents comes then to be taken notice of, and widens by
  • degrees, till at last the vanity of the philosopher is willing to
  • acknowledge scarce any resemblance. But without the disposition to truck,
  • barter, and exchange, every man must have procured to himself every
  • necessary and conveniency of life which he wanted. All must have had the
  • same duties to perform, and the same work to do, and there could have been
  • no such difference of employment as could alone give occasion to any great
  • difference of talents.
  • As it is this disposition which forms that difference of talents, so
  • remarkable among men of different professions, so it is this same
  • disposition which renders that difference useful. Many tribes of animals,
  • acknowledged to be all of the same species, derive from nature a much more
  • remarkable distinction of genius, than what, antecedent to custom and
  • education, appears to take place among men. By nature a philosopher is not
  • in genius and disposition half so different from a street porter, as a
  • mastiff is from a grey-hound, or a grey-hound from a spaniel, or this last
  • from a shepherd’s dog. Those different tribes of animals, however, though
  • all of the same species are of scarce any use to one another. The strength
  • of the mastiff is not in the least supported either by the swiftness of
  • the greyhound, or by the sagacity of the spaniel, or by the docility of
  • the shepherd’s dog. The effects of those different geniuses and talents,
  • for want of the power or disposition to barter and exchange, cannot be
  • brought into a common stock, and do not in the least contribute to the
  • better accommodation and conveniency of the species. Each animal is still
  • obliged to support and defend itself, separately and independently, and
  • derives no sort of advantage from that variety of talents with which
  • nature has distinguished its fellows. Among men, on the contrary, the most
  • dissimilar geniuses are of use to one another; the different produces of
  • their respective talents, by the general disposition to truck, barter, and
  • exchange, being brought, as it were, into a common stock, where every man
  • may purchase whatever part of the produce of other men’s talents he has
  • occasion for.
  • CHAPTER III.
  • THAT THE DIVISION OF LABOUR IS
  • LIMITED BY THE EXTENT OF THE MARKET.
  • As it is the power of exchanging that gives occasion to the division of
  • labour, so the extent of this division must always be limited by the
  • extent of that power, or, in other words, by the extent of the market.
  • When the market is very small, no person can have any encouragement to
  • dedicate himself entirely to one employment, for want of the power to
  • exchange all that surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is
  • over and above his own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other
  • men’s labour as he has occasion for.
  • There are some sorts of industry, even of the lowest kind, which can be
  • carried on nowhere but in a great town. A porter, for example, can find
  • employment and subsistence in no other place. A village is by much too
  • narrow a sphere for him; even an ordinary market-town is scarce large
  • enough to afford him constant occupation. In the lone houses and very
  • small villages which are scattered about in so desert a country as the
  • highlands of Scotland, every farmer must be butcher, baker, and brewer,
  • for his own family. In such situations we can scarce expect to find even a
  • smith, a carpenter, or a mason, within less than twenty miles of another
  • of the same trade. The scattered families that live at eight or ten miles
  • distance from the nearest of them, must learn to perform themselves a
  • great number of little pieces of work, for which, in more populous
  • countries, they would call in the assistance of those workmen. Country
  • workmen are almost everywhere obliged to apply themselves to all the
  • different branches of industry that have so much affinity to one another
  • as to be employed about the same sort of materials. A country carpenter
  • deals in every sort of work that is made of wood; a country smith in every
  • sort of work that is made of iron. The former is not only a carpenter, but
  • a joiner, a cabinet-maker, and even a carver in wood, as well as a
  • wheel-wright, a plough-wright, a cart and waggon-maker. The employments of
  • the latter are still more various. It is impossible there should be such a
  • trade as even that of a nailer in the remote and inland parts of the
  • highlands of Scotland. Such a workman at the rate of a thousand nails
  • a-day, and three hundred working days in the year, will make three hundred
  • thousand nails in the year. But in such a situation it would be impossible
  • to dispose of one thousand, that is, of one day’s work in the year. As by
  • means of water-carriage, a more extensive market is opened to every sort
  • of industry than what land-carriage alone can afford it, so it is upon the
  • sea-coast, and along the banks of navigable rivers, that industry of every
  • kind naturally begins to subdivide and improve itself, and it is
  • frequently not till a long time after that those improvements extend
  • themselves to the inland parts of the country. A broad-wheeled waggon,
  • attended by two men, and drawn by eight horses, in about six weeks time,
  • carries and brings back between London and Edinburgh near four ton weight
  • of goods. In about the same time a ship navigated by six or eight men, and
  • sailing between the ports of London and Leith, frequently carries and
  • brings back two hundred ton weight of goods. Six or eight men, therefore,
  • by the help of water-carriage, can carry and bring back, in the same time,
  • the same quantity of goods between London and Edinburgh as fifty
  • broad-wheeled waggons, attended by a hundred men, and drawn by four
  • hundred horses. Upon two hundred tons of goods, therefore, carried by the
  • cheapest land-carriage from London to Edinburgh, there must be charged the
  • maintenance of a hundred men for three weeks, and both the maintenance and
  • what is nearly equal to maintenance the wear and tear of four hundred
  • horses, as well as of fifty great waggons. Whereas, upon the same quantity
  • of goods carried by water, there is to be charged only the maintenance of
  • six or eight men, and the wear and tear of a ship of two hundred tons
  • burthen, together with the value of the superior risk, or the difference
  • of the insurance between land and water-carriage. Were there no other
  • communication between those two places, therefore, but by land-carriage,
  • as no goods could be transported from the one to the other, except such
  • whose price was very considerable in proportion to their weight, they
  • could carry on but a small part of that commerce which at present subsists
  • between them, and consequently could give but a small part of that
  • encouragement which they at present mutually afford to each other’s
  • industry. There could be little or no commerce of any kind between the
  • distant parts of the world. What goods could bear the expense of
  • land-carriage between London and Calcutta? Or if there were any so
  • precious as to be able to support this expense, with what safety could
  • they be transported through the territories of so many barbarous nations?
  • Those two cities, however, at present carry on a very considerable
  • commerce with each other, and by mutually affording a market, give a good
  • deal of encouragement to each other’s industry.
  • Since such, therefore, are the advantages of water-carriage, it is natural
  • that the first improvements of art and industry should be made where this
  • conveniency opens the whole world for a market to the produce of every
  • sort of labour, and that they should always be much later in extending
  • themselves into the inland parts of the country. The inland parts of the
  • country can for a long time have no other market for the greater part of
  • their goods, but the country which lies round about them, and separates
  • them from the sea-coast, and the great navigable rivers. The extent of the
  • market, therefore, must for a long time be in proportion to the riches and
  • populousness of that country, and consequently their improvement must
  • always be posterior to the improvement of that country. In our North
  • American colonies, the plantations have constantly followed either the
  • sea-coast or the banks of the navigable rivers, and have scarce anywhere
  • extended themselves to any considerable distance from both.
  • The nations that, according to the best authenticated history, appear to
  • have been first civilized, were those that dwelt round the coast of the
  • Mediterranean sea. That sea, by far the greatest inlet that is known in
  • the world, having no tides, nor consequently any waves, except such as are
  • caused by the wind only, was, by the smoothness of its surface, as well as
  • by the multitude of its islands, and the proximity of its neighbouring
  • shores, extremely favourable to the infant navigation of the world; when,
  • from their ignorance of the compass, men were afraid to quit the view of
  • the coast, and from the imperfection of the art of ship-building, to
  • abandon themselves to the boisterous waves of the ocean. To pass beyond
  • the pillars of Hercules, that is, to sail out of the straits of Gibraltar,
  • was, in the ancient world, long considered as a most wonderful and
  • dangerous exploit of navigation. It was late before even the Phoenicians
  • and Carthaginians, the most skilful navigators and ship-builders of those
  • old times, attempted it; and they were, for a long time, the only nations
  • that did attempt it.
  • Of all the countries on the coast of the Mediterranean sea, Egypt seems to
  • have been the first in which either agriculture or manufactures were
  • cultivated and improved to any considerable degree. Upper Egypt extends
  • itself nowhere above a few miles from the Nile; and in Lower Egypt, that
  • great river breaks itself into many different canals, which, with the
  • assistance of a little art, seem to have afforded a communication by
  • water-carriage, not only between all the great towns, but between all the
  • considerable villages, and even to many farm-houses in the country, nearly
  • in the same manner as the Rhine and the Maese do in Holland at present.
  • The extent and easiness of this inland navigation was probably one of the
  • principal causes of the early improvement of Egypt.
  • The improvements in agriculture and manufactures seem likewise to have
  • been of very great antiquity in the provinces of Bengal, in the East
  • Indies, and in some of the eastern provinces of China, though the great
  • extent of this antiquity is not authenticated by any histories of whose
  • authority we, in this part of the world, are well assured. In Bengal, the
  • Ganges, and several other great rivers, form a great number of navigable
  • canals, in the same manner as the Nile does in Egypt. In the eastern
  • provinces of China, too, several great rivers form, by their different
  • branches, a multitude of canals, and, by communicating with one another,
  • afford an inland navigation much more extensive than that either of the
  • Nile or the Ganges, or, perhaps, than both of them put together. It is
  • remarkable, that neither the ancient Egyptians, nor the Indians, nor the
  • Chinese, encouraged foreign commerce, but seem all to have derived their
  • great opulence from this inland navigation.
  • All the inland parts of Africa, and all that part of Asia which lies any
  • considerable way north of the Euxine and Caspian seas, the ancient
  • Scythia, the modern Tartary and Siberia, seem, in all ages of the world,
  • to have been in the same barbarous and uncivilized state in which we find
  • them at present. The sea of Tartary is the frozen ocean, which admits of
  • no navigation; and though some of the greatest rivers in the world run
  • through that country, they are at too great a distance from one another to
  • carry commerce and communication through the greater part of it. There are
  • in Africa none of those great inlets, such as the Baltic and Adriatic seas
  • in Europe, the Mediterranean and Euxine seas in both Europe and Asia, and
  • the gulfs of Arabia, Persia, India, Bengal, and Siam, in Asia, to carry
  • maritime commerce into the interior parts of that great continent; and the
  • great rivers of Africa are at too great a distance from one another to
  • give occasion to any considerable inland navigation. The commerce,
  • besides, which any nation can carry on by means of a river which does not
  • break itself into any great number of branches or canals, and which runs
  • into another territory before it reaches the sea, can never be very
  • considerable, because it is always in the power of the nations who possess
  • that other territory to obstruct the communication between the upper
  • country and the sea. The navigation of the Danube is of very little use to
  • the different states of Bavaria, Austria, and Hungary, in comparison of
  • what it would be, if any of them possessed the whole of its course, till
  • it falls into the Black sea.
  • CHAPTER IV.
  • OF THE ORIGIN AND USE OF MONEY.
  • When the division of labour has been once thoroughly established, it is
  • but a very small part of a man’s wants which the produce of his own labour
  • can supply. He supplies the far greater part of them by exchanging that
  • surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his
  • own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other men’s labour as he
  • has occasion for. Every man thus lives by exchanging, or becomes, in some
  • measure, a merchant, and the society itself grows to be what is properly a
  • commercial society.
  • But when the division of labour first began to take place, this power of
  • exchanging must frequently have been very much clogged and embarrassed in
  • its operations. One man, we shall suppose, has more of a certain commodity
  • than he himself has occasion for, while another has less. The former,
  • consequently, would be glad to dispose of; and the latter to purchase, a
  • part of this superfluity. But if this latter should chance to have nothing
  • that the former stands in need of, no exchange can be made between them.
  • The butcher has more meat in his shop than he himself can consume, and the
  • brewer and the baker would each of them be willing to purchase a part of
  • it. But they have nothing to offer in exchange, except the different
  • productions of their respective trades, and the butcher is already
  • provided with all the bread and beer which he has immediate occasion for.
  • No exchange can, in this case, be made between them. He cannot be their
  • merchant, nor they his customers; and they are all of them thus mutually
  • less serviceable to one another. In order to avoid the inconveniency of
  • such situations, every prudent man in every period of society, after the
  • first establishment of the division of labour, must naturally have
  • endeavoured to manage his affairs in such a manner, as to have at all
  • times by him, besides the peculiar produce of his own industry, a certain
  • quantity of some one commodity or other, such as he imagined few people
  • would be likely to refuse in exchange for the produce of their industry.
  • Many different commodities, it is probable, were successively both thought
  • of and employed for this purpose. In the rude ages of society, cattle are
  • said to have been the common instrument of commerce; and, though they must
  • have been a most inconvenient one, yet, in old times, we find things were
  • frequently valued according to the number of cattle which had been given
  • in exchange for them. The armour of Diomede, says Homer, cost only nine
  • oxen; but that of Glaucus cost a hundred oxen. Salt is said to be the
  • common instrument of commerce and exchanges in Abyssinia; a species of
  • shells in some parts of the coast of India; dried cod at Newfoundland;
  • tobacco in Virginia; sugar in some of our West India colonies; hides or
  • dressed leather in some other countries; and there is at this day a
  • village in Scotland, where it is not uncommon, I am told, for a workman to
  • carry nails instead of money to the baker’s shop or the ale-house.
  • In all countries, however, men seem at last to have been determined by
  • irresistible reasons to give the preference, for this employment, to
  • metals above every other commodity. Metals can not only be kept with as
  • little loss as any other commodity, scarce any thing being less perishable
  • than they are, but they can likewise, without any loss, be divided into
  • any number of parts, as by fusion those parts can easily be re-united
  • again; a quality which no other equally durable commodities possess, and
  • which, more than any other quality, renders them fit to be the instruments
  • of commerce and circulation. The man who wanted to buy salt, for example,
  • and had nothing but cattle to give in exchange for it, must have been
  • obliged to buy salt to the value of a whole ox, or a whole sheep, at a
  • time. He could seldom buy less than this, because what he was to give for
  • it could seldom be divided without loss; and if he had a mind to buy more,
  • he must, for the same reasons, have been obliged to buy double or triple
  • the quantity, the value, to wit, of two or three oxen, or of two or three
  • sheep. If, on the contrary, instead of sheep or oxen, he had metals to
  • give in exchange for it, he could easily proportion the quantity of the
  • metal to the precise quantity of the commodity which he had immediate
  • occasion for.
  • Different metals have been made use of by different nations for this
  • purpose. Iron was the common instrument of commerce among the ancient
  • Spartans, copper among the ancient Romans, and gold and silver among all
  • rich and commercial nations.
  • Those metals seem originally to have been made use of for this purpose in
  • rude bars, without any stamp or coinage. Thus we are told by Pliny (Plin.
  • Hist Nat. lib. 33, cap. 3), upon the authority of Timaeus, an ancient
  • historian, that, till the time of Servius Tullius, the Romans had no
  • coined money, but made use of unstamped bars of copper, to purchase
  • whatever they had occasion for. These rude bars, therefore, performed at
  • this time the function of money.
  • The use of metals in this rude state was attended with two very
  • considerable inconveniences; first, with the trouble of weighing, and
  • secondly, with that of assaying them. In the precious metals, where a
  • small difference in the quantity makes a great difference in the value,
  • even the business of weighing, with proper exactness, requires at least
  • very accurate weights and scales. The weighing of gold, in particular, is
  • an operation of some nicety in the coarser metals, indeed, where a small
  • error would be of little consequence, less accuracy would, no doubt, be
  • necessary. Yet we should find it excessively troublesome if every time a
  • poor man had occasion either to buy or sell a farthing’s worth of goods,
  • he was obliged to weigh the farthing. The operation of assaying is still
  • more difficult, still more tedious; and, unless a part of the metal is
  • fairly melted in the crucible, with proper dissolvents, any conclusion
  • that can be drawn from it is extremely uncertain. Before the institution
  • of coined money, however, unless they went through this tedious and
  • difficult operation, people must always have been liable to the grossest
  • frauds and impositions; and instead of a pound weight of pure silver, or
  • pure copper, might receive, in exchange for their goods, an adulterated
  • composition of the coarsest and cheapest materials, which had, however, in
  • their outward appearance, been made to resemble those metals. To prevent
  • such abuses, to facilitate exchanges, and thereby to encourage all sorts
  • of industry and commerce, it has been found necessary, in all countries
  • that have made any considerable advances towards improvement, to affix a
  • public stamp upon certain quantities of such particular metals, as were in
  • those countries commonly made use of to purchase goods. Hence the origin
  • of coined money, and of those public offices called mints; institutions
  • exactly of the same nature with those of the aulnagers and stamp-masters
  • of woollen and linen cloth. All of them are equally meant to ascertain, by
  • means of a public stamp, the quantity and uniform goodness of those
  • different commodities when brought to market.
  • The first public stamps of this kind that were affixed to the current
  • metals, seem in many cases to have been intended to ascertain, what it was
  • both most difficult and most important to ascertain, the goodness or
  • fineness of the metal, and to have resembled the sterling mark which is at
  • present affixed to plate and bars of silver, or the Spanish mark which is
  • sometimes affixed to ingots of gold, and which, being struck only upon one
  • side of the piece, and not covering the whole surface, ascertains the
  • fineness, but not the weight of the metal. Abraham weighs to Ephron the
  • four hundred shekels of silver which he had agreed to pay for the field of
  • Machpelah. They are said, however, to be the current money of the
  • merchant, and yet are received by weight, and not by tale, in the same
  • manner as ingots of gold and bars of silver are at present. The revenues
  • of the ancient Saxon kings of England are said to have been paid, not in
  • money, but in kind, that is, in victuals and provisions of all sorts.
  • William the Conqueror introduced the custom of paying them in money. This
  • money, however, was for a long time, received at the exchequer, by weight,
  • and not by tale.
  • The inconveniency and difficulty of weighing those metals with exactness,
  • gave occasion to the institution of coins, of which the stamp, covering
  • entirely both sides of the piece, and sometimes the edges too, was
  • supposed to ascertain not only the fineness, but the weight of the metal.
  • Such coins, therefore, were received by tale, as at present, without the
  • trouble of weighing.
  • The denominations of those coins seem originally to have expressed the
  • weight or quantity of metal contained in them. In the time of Servius
  • Tullius, who first coined money at Rome, the Roman as or pondo contained a
  • Roman pound of good copper. It was divided, in the same manner as our
  • Troyes pound, into twelve ounces, each of which contained a real ounce of
  • good copper. The English pound sterling, in the time of Edward I.
  • contained a pound, Tower weight, of silver of a known fineness. The Tower
  • pound seems to have been something more than the Roman pound, and
  • something less than the Troyes pound. This last was not introduced into
  • the mint of England till the 18th of Henry the VIII. The French livre
  • contained, in the time of Charlemagne, a pound, Troyes weight, of silver
  • of a known fineness. The fair of Troyes in Champaign was at that time
  • frequented by all the nations of Europe, and the weights and measures of
  • so famous a market were generally known and esteemed. The Scots money
  • pound contained, from the time of Alexander the First to that of Robert
  • Bruce, a pound of silver of the same weight and fineness with the English
  • pound sterling. English, French, and Scots pennies, too, contained all of
  • them originally a real penny-weight of silver, the twentieth part of an
  • ounce, and the two hundred-and-fortieth part of a pound. The shilling,
  • too, seems originally to have been the denomination of a weight. “When
  • wheat is at twelve shillings the quarter,” says an ancient statute of
  • Henry III. “then wastel bread of a farthing shall weigh eleven shillings
  • and fourpence”. The proportion, however, between the shilling, and either
  • the penny on the one hand, or the pound on the other, seems not to have
  • been so constant and uniform as that between the penny and the pound.
  • During the first race of the kings of France, the French sou or shilling
  • appears upon different occasions to have contained five, twelve, twenty,
  • and forty pennies. Among the ancient Saxons, a shilling appears at one
  • time to have contained only five pennies, and it is not improbable that it
  • may have been as variable among them as among their neighbours, the
  • ancient Franks. From the time of Charlemagne among the French, and from
  • that of William the Conqueror among the English, the proportion between
  • the pound, the shilling, and the penny, seems to have been uniformly the
  • same as at present, though the value of each has been very different; for
  • in every country of the world, I believe, the avarice and injustice of
  • princes and sovereign states, abusing the confidence of their subjects,
  • have by degrees diminished the real quantity of metal, which had been
  • originally contained in their coins. The Roman as, in the latter ages of
  • the republic, was reduced to the twenty-fourth part of its original value,
  • and, instead of weighing a pound, came to weigh only half an ounce. The
  • English pound and penny contain at present about a third only; the Scots
  • pound and penny about a thirty-sixth; and the French pound and penny about
  • a sixty-sixth part of their original value. By means of those operations,
  • the princes and sovereign states which performed them were enabled, in
  • appearance, to pay their debts and fulfil their engagements with a smaller
  • quantity of silver than would otherwise have been requisite. It was indeed
  • in appearance only; for their creditors were really defrauded of a part of
  • what was due to them. All other debtors in the state were allowed the same
  • privilege, and might pay with the same nominal sum of the new and debased
  • coin whatever they had borrowed in the old. Such operations, therefore,
  • have always proved favourable to the debtor, and ruinous to the creditor,
  • and have sometimes produced a greater and more universal revolution in the
  • fortunes of private persons, than could have been occasioned by a very
  • great public calamity.
  • It is in this manner that money has become, in all civilized nations, the
  • universal instrument of commerce, by the intervention of which goods of
  • all kinds are bought and sold, or exchanged for one another.
  • What are the rules which men naturally observe, in exchanging them either
  • for money, or for one another, I shall now proceed to examine. These rules
  • determine what may be called the relative or exchangeable value of goods.
  • The word VALUE, it is to be observed, has two different meanings, and
  • sometimes expresses the utility of some particular object, and sometimes
  • the power of purchasing other goods which the possession of that object
  • conveys. The one may be called ‘value in use;’ the other, ‘value in
  • exchange.’ The things which have the greatest value in use have frequently
  • little or no value in exchange; and, on the contrary, those which have the
  • greatest value in exchange have frequently little or no value in use.
  • Nothing is more useful than water; but it will purchase scarce any thing;
  • scarce any thing can be had in exchange for it. A diamond, on the
  • contrary, has scarce any value in use; but a very great quantity of other
  • goods may frequently be had in exchange for it.
  • In order to investigate the principles which regulate the exchangeable
  • value of commodities, I shall endeavour to shew,
  • First, what is the real measure of this exchangeable value; or wherein
  • consists the real price of all commodities.
  • Secondly, what are the different parts of which this real price is
  • composed or made up.
  • And, lastly, what are the different circumstances which sometimes raise
  • some or all of these different parts of price above, and sometimes sink
  • them below, their natural or ordinary rate; or, what are the causes which
  • sometimes hinder the market price, that is, the actual price of
  • commodities, from coinciding exactly with what may be called their natural
  • price.
  • I shall endeavour to explain, as fully and distinctly as I can, those
  • three subjects in the three following chapters, for which I must very
  • earnestly entreat both the patience and attention of the reader: his
  • patience, in order to examine a detail which may, perhaps, in some places,
  • appear unnecessarily tedious; and his attention, in order to understand
  • what may perhaps, after the fullest explication which I am capable of
  • giving it, appear still in some degree obscure. I am always willing to run
  • some hazard of being tedious, in order to be sure that I am perspicuous;
  • and, after taking the utmost pains that I can to be perspicuous, some
  • obscurity may still appear to remain upon a subject, in its own nature
  • extremely abstracted.
  • CHAPTER V.
  • OF THE REAL AND NOMINAL PRICE OF
  • COMMODITIES, OR OF THEIR PRICE IN LABOUR, AND THEIR PRICE IN MONEY.
  • Every man is rich or poor according to the degree in which he can afford
  • to enjoy the necessaries, conveniencies, and amusements of human life. But
  • after the division of labour has once thoroughly taken place, it is but a
  • very small part of these with which a man’s own labour can supply him. The
  • far greater part of them he must derive from the labour of other people,
  • and he must be rich or poor according to the quantity of that labour which
  • he can command, or which he can afford to purchase. The value of any
  • commodity, therefore, to the person who possesses it, and who means not to
  • use or consume it himself, but to exchange it for other commodities, is
  • equal to the quantity of labour which it enables him to purchase or
  • command. Labour therefore, is the real measure of the exchangeable value
  • of all commodities.
  • The real price of every thing, what every thing really costs to the man
  • who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. What
  • every thing is really worth to the man who has acquired it and who wants
  • to dispose of it, or exchange it for something else, is the toil and
  • trouble which it can save to himself, and which it can impose upon other
  • people. What is bought with money, or with goods, is purchased by labour,
  • as much as what we acquire by the toil of our own body. That money, or
  • those goods, indeed, save us this toil. They contain the value of a
  • certain quantity of labour, which we exchange for what is supposed at the
  • time to contain the value of an equal quantity. Labour was the first
  • price, the original purchase money that was paid for all things. It was
  • not by gold or by silver, but by labour, that all the wealth of the world
  • was originally purchased; and its value, to those who possess it, and who
  • want to exchange it for some new productions, is precisely equal to the
  • quantity of labour which it can enable them to purchase or command.
  • Wealth, as Mr Hobbes says, is power. But the person who either acquires,
  • or succeeds to a great fortune, does not necessarily acquire or succeed to
  • any political power, either civil or military. His fortune may, perhaps,
  • afford him the means of acquiring both; but the mere possession of that
  • fortune does not necessarily convey to him either. The power which that
  • possession immediately and directly conveys to him, is the power of
  • purchasing a certain command over all the labour, or over all the produce
  • of labour which is then in the market. His fortune is greater or less,
  • precisely in proportion to the extent of this power, or to the quantity
  • either of other men’s labour, or, what is the same thing, of the produce
  • of other men’s labour, which it enables him to purchase or command. The
  • exchangeable value of every thing must always be precisely equal to the
  • extent of this power which it conveys to its owner.
  • But though labour be the real measure of the exchangeable value of all
  • commodities, it is not that by which their value is commonly estimated. It
  • is often difficult to ascertain the proportion between two different
  • quantities of labour. The time spent in two different sorts of work will
  • not always alone determine this proportion. The different degrees of
  • hardship endured, and of ingenuity exercised, must likewise be taken into
  • account. There may be more labour in an hour’s hard work, than in two
  • hours easy business; or in an hour’s application to a trade which it cost
  • ten years labour to learn, than in a month’s industry, at an ordinary and
  • obvious employment. But it is not easy to find any accurate measure either
  • of hardship or ingenuity. In exchanging, indeed, the different productions
  • of different sorts of labour for one another, some allowance is commonly
  • made for both. It is adjusted, however, not by any accurate measure, but
  • by the higgling and bargaining of the market, according to that sort of
  • rough equality which, though not exact, is sufficient for carrying on the
  • business of common life.
  • Every commodity, besides, is more frequently exchanged for, and thereby
  • compared with, other commodities, than with labour. It is more natural,
  • therefore, to estimate its exchangeable value by the quantity of some
  • other commodity, than by that of the labour which it can produce. The
  • greater part of people, too, understand better what is meant by a quantity
  • of a particular commodity, than by a quantity of labour. The one is a
  • plain palpable object; the other an abstract notion, which though it can
  • be made sufficiently intelligible, is not altogether so natural and
  • obvious.
  • But when barter ceases, and money has become the common instrument of
  • commerce, every particular commodity is more frequently exchanged for
  • money than for any other commodity. The butcher seldom carries his beef or
  • his mutton to the baker or the brewer, in order to exchange them for bread
  • or for beer; but he carries them to the market, where he exchanges them
  • for money, and afterwards exchanges that money for bread and for beer. The
  • quantity of money which he gets for them regulates, too, the quantity of
  • bread and beer which he can afterwards purchase. It is more natural and
  • obvious to him, therefore, to estimate their value by the quantity of
  • money, the commodity for which he immediately exchanges them, than by that
  • of bread and beer, the commodities for which he can exchange them only by
  • the intervention of another commodity; and rather to say that his
  • butcher’s meat is worth three-pence or fourpence a-pound, than that it is
  • worth three or four pounds of bread, or three or four quarts of small
  • beer. Hence it comes to pass, that the exchangeable value of every
  • commodity is more frequently estimated by the quantity of money, than by
  • the quantity either of labour or of any other commodity which can be had
  • in exchange for it.
  • Gold and silver, however, like every other commodity, vary in their value;
  • are sometimes cheaper and sometimes dearer, sometimes of easier and
  • sometimes of more difficult purchase. The quantity of labour which any
  • particular quantity of them can purchase or command, or the quantity of
  • other goods which it will exchange for, depends always upon the fertility
  • or barrenness of the mines which happen to be known about the time when
  • such exchanges are made. The discovery of the abundant mines of America,
  • reduced, in the sixteenth century, the value of gold and silver in Europe
  • to about a third of what it had been before. As it cost less labour to
  • bring those metals from the mine to the market, so, when they were brought
  • thither, they could purchase or command less labour; and this revolution
  • in their value, though perhaps the greatest, is by no means the only one
  • of which history gives some account. But as a measure of quantity, such as
  • the natural foot, fathom, or handful, which is continually varying in its
  • own quantity, can never be an accurate measure of the quantity of other
  • things; so a commodity which is itself continually varying in its own
  • value, can never be an accurate measure of the value of other commodities.
  • Equal quantities of labour, at all times and places, may be said to be of
  • equal value to the labourer. In his ordinary state of health, strength,
  • and spirits; in the ordinary degree of his skill and dexterity, he must
  • always lay down the same portion of his ease, his liberty, and his
  • happiness. The price which he pays must always be the same, whatever may
  • be the quantity of goods which he receives in return for it. Of these,
  • indeed, it may sometimes purchase a greater and sometimes a smaller
  • quantity; but it is their value which varies, not that of the labour which
  • purchases them. At all times and places, that is dear which it is
  • difficult to come at, or which it costs much labour to acquire; and that
  • cheap which is to be had easily, or with very little labour. Labour alone,
  • therefore, never varying in its own value, is alone the ultimate and real
  • standard by which the value of all commodities can at all times and places
  • be estimated and compared. It is their real price; money is their nominal
  • price only.
  • But though equal quantities of labour are always of equal value to the
  • labourer, yet to the person who employs him they appear sometimes to be of
  • greater, and sometimes of smaller value. He purchases them sometimes with
  • a greater, and sometimes with a smaller quantity of goods, and to him the
  • price of labour seems to vary like that of all other things. It appears to
  • him dear in the one case, and cheap in the other. In reality, however, it
  • is the goods which are cheap in the one case, and dear in the other.
  • In this popular sense, therefore, labour, like commodities, may be said to
  • have a real and a nominal price. Its real price may be said to consist in
  • the quantity of the necessaries and conveniencies of life which are given
  • for it; its nominal price, in the quantity of money. The labourer is rich
  • or poor, is well or ill rewarded, in proportion to the real, not to the
  • nominal price of his labour.
  • The distinction between the real and the nominal price of commodities and
  • labour is not a matter of mere speculation, but may sometimes be of
  • considerable use in practice. The same real price is always of the same
  • value; but on account of the variations in the value of gold and silver,
  • the same nominal price is sometimes of very different values. When a
  • landed estate, therefore, is sold with a reservation of a perpetual rent,
  • if it is intended that this rent should always be of the same value, it is
  • of importance to the family in whose favour it is reserved, that it should
  • not consist in a particular sum of money. Its value would in this case be
  • liable to variations of two different kinds: first, to those which arise
  • from the different quantities of gold and silver which are contained at
  • different times in coin of the same denomination; and, secondly, to those
  • which arise from the different values of equal quantities of gold and
  • silver at different times.
  • Princes and sovereign states have frequently fancied that they had a
  • temporary interest to diminish the quantity of pure metal contained in
  • their coins; but they seldom have fancied that they had any to augment it.
  • The quantity of metal contained in the coins, I believe of all nations,
  • has accordingly been almost continually diminishing, and hardly ever
  • augmenting. Such variations, therefore, tend almost always to diminish the
  • value of a money rent.
  • The discovery of the mines of America diminished the value of gold and
  • silver in Europe. This diminution, it is commonly supposed, though I
  • apprehend without any certain proof, is still going on gradually, and is
  • likely to continue to do so for a long time. Upon this supposition,
  • therefore, such variations are more likely to diminish than to augment the
  • value of a money rent, even though it should be stipulated to be paid, not
  • in such a quantity of coined money of such a denomination (in so many
  • pounds sterling, for example), but in so many ounces, either of pure
  • silver, or of silver of a certain standard.
  • The rents which have been reserved in corn, have preserved their value
  • much better than those which have been reserved in money, even where the
  • denomination of the coin has not been altered. By the 18th of Elizabeth,
  • it was enacted, that a third of the rent of all college leases should be
  • reserved in corn, to be paid either in kind, or according to the current
  • prices at the nearest public market. The money arising from this corn
  • rent, though originally but a third of the whole, is, in the present
  • times, according to Dr. Blackstone, commonly near double of what arises
  • from the other two-thirds. The old money rents of colleges must, according
  • to this account, have sunk almost to a fourth part of their ancient value,
  • or are worth little more than a fourth part of the corn which they were
  • formerly worth. But since the reign of Philip and Mary, the denomination
  • of the English coin has undergone little or no alteration, and the same
  • number of pounds, shillings, and pence, have contained very nearly the
  • same quantity of pure silver. This degradation, therefore, in the value of
  • the money rents of colleges, has arisen altogether from the degradation in
  • the price of silver.
  • When the degradation in the value of silver is combined with the
  • diminution of the quantity of it contained in the coin of the same
  • denomination, the loss is frequently still greater. In Scotland, where the
  • denomination of the coin has undergone much greater alterations than it
  • ever did in England, and in France, where it has undergone still greater
  • than it ever did in Scotland, some ancient rents, originally of
  • considerable value, have, in this manner, been reduced almost to nothing.
  • Equal quantities of labour will, at distant times, be purchased more
  • nearly with equal quantities of corn, the subsistence of the labourer,
  • than with equal quantities of gold and silver, or, perhaps, of any other
  • commodity. Equal quantities of corn, therefore, will, at distant times, be
  • more nearly of the same real value, or enable the possessor to purchase or
  • command more nearly the same quantity of the labour of other people. They
  • will do this, I say, more nearly than equal quantities of almost any other
  • commodity; for even equal quantities of corn will not do it exactly. The
  • subsistence of the labourer, or the real price of labour, as I shall
  • endeavour to shew hereafter, is very different upon different occasions;
  • more liberal in a society advancing to opulence, than in one that is
  • standing still, and in one that is standing still, than in one that is
  • going backwards. Every other commodity, however, will, at any particular
  • time, purchase a greater or smaller quantity of labour, in proportion to
  • the quantity of subsistence which it can purchase at that time. A rent,
  • therefore, reserved in corn, is liable only to the variations in the
  • quantity of labour which a certain quantity of corn can purchase. But a
  • rent reserved in any other commodity is liable, not only to the variations
  • in the quantity of labour which any particular quantity of corn can
  • purchase, but to the variations in the quantity of corn which can be
  • purchased by any particular quantity of that commodity.
  • Though the real value of a corn rent, it is to be observed, however,
  • varies much less from century to century than that of a money rent, it
  • varies much more from year to year. The money price of labour, as I shall
  • endeavour to shew hereafter, does not fluctuate from year to year with the
  • money price of corn, but seems to be everywhere accommodated, not to the
  • temporary or occasional, but to the average or ordinary price of that
  • necessary of life. The average or ordinary price of corn, again is
  • regulated, as I shall likewise endeavour to shew hereafter, by the value
  • of silver, by the richness or barrenness of the mines which supply the
  • market with that metal, or by the quantity of labour which must be
  • employed, and consequently of corn which must be consumed, in order to
  • bring any particular quantity of silver from the mine to the market. But
  • the value of silver, though it sometimes varies greatly from century to
  • century, seldom varies much from year to year, but frequently continues
  • the same, or very nearly the same, for half a century or a century
  • together. The ordinary or average money price of corn, therefore, may,
  • during so long a period, continue the same, or very nearly the same, too,
  • and along with it the money price of labour, provided, at least, the
  • society continues, in other respects, in the same, or nearly in the same,
  • condition. In the mean time, the temporary and occasional price of corn
  • may frequently be double one year of what it had been the year before, or
  • fluctuate, for example, from five-and-twenty to fifty shillings the
  • quarter. But when corn is at the latter price, not only the nominal, but
  • the real value of a corn rent, will be double of what it is when at the
  • former, or will command double the quantity either of labour, or of the
  • greater part of other commodities; the money price of labour, and along
  • with it that of most other things, continuing the same during all these
  • fluctuations.
  • Labour, therefore, it appears evidently, is the only universal, as well as
  • the only accurate, measure of value, or the only standard by which we can
  • compare the values of different commodities, at all times, and at all
  • places. We cannot estimate, it is allowed, the real value of different
  • commodities from century to century by the quantities of silver which were
  • given for them. We cannot estimate it from year to year by the quantities
  • of corn. By the quantities of labour, we can, with the greatest accuracy,
  • estimate it, both from century to century, and from year to year. From
  • century to century, corn is a better measure than silver, because, from
  • century to century, equal quantities of corn will command the same
  • quantity of labour more nearly than equal quantities of silver. From year
  • to year, on the contrary, silver is a better measure than corn, because
  • equal quantities of it will more nearly command the same quantity of
  • labour.
  • But though, in establishing perpetual rents, or even in letting very long
  • leases, it may be of use to distinguish between real and nominal price; it
  • is of none in buying and selling, the more common and ordinary
  • transactions of human life.
  • At the same time and place, the real and the nominal price of all
  • commodities are exactly in proportion to one another. The more or less
  • money you get for any commodity, in the London market, for example, the
  • more or less labour it will at that time and place enable you to purchase
  • or command. At the same time and place, therefore, money is the exact
  • measure of the real exchangeable value of all commodities. It is so,
  • however, at the same time and place only.
  • Though at distant places there is no regular proportion between the real
  • and the money price of commodities, yet the merchant who carries goods
  • from the one to the other, has nothing to consider but the money price, or
  • the difference between the quantity of silver for which he buys them, and
  • that for which he is likely to sell them. Half an ounce of silver at
  • Canton in China may command a greater quantity both of labour and of the
  • necessaries and conveniencies of life, than an ounce at London. A
  • commodity, therefore, which sells for half an ounce of silver at Canton,
  • may there be really dearer, of more real importance to the man who
  • possesses it there, than a commodity which sells for an ounce at London is
  • to the man who possesses it at London. If a London merchant, however, can
  • buy at Canton, for half an ounce of silver, a commodity which he can
  • afterwards sell at London for an ounce, he gains a hundred per cent. by
  • the bargain, just as much as if an ounce of silver was at London exactly
  • of the same value as at Canton. It is of no importance to him that half an
  • ounce of silver at Canton would have given him the command of more labour,
  • and of a greater quantity of the necessaries and conveniencies of life
  • than an ounce can do at London. An ounce at London will always give him
  • the command of double the quantity of all these, which half an ounce could
  • have done there, and this is precisely what he wants.
  • As it is the nominal or money price of goods, therefore, which finally
  • determines the prudence or imprudence of all purchases and sales, and
  • thereby regulates almost the whole business of common life in which price
  • is concerned, we cannot wonder that it should have been so much more
  • attended to than the real price.
  • In such a work as this, however, it may sometimes be of use to compare the
  • different real values of a particular commodity at different times and
  • places, or the different degrees of power over the labour of other people
  • which it may, upon different occasions, have given to those who possessed
  • it. We must in this case compare, not so much the different quantities of
  • silver for which it was commonly sold, as the different quantities or
  • labour which those different quantities of silver could have purchased.
  • But the current prices of labour, at distant times and places, can scarce
  • ever be known with any degree of exactness. Those of corn, though they
  • have in few places been regularly recorded, are in general better known,
  • and have been more frequently taken notice of by historians and other
  • writers. We must generally, therefore, content ourselves with them, not as
  • being always exactly in the same proportion as the current prices of
  • labour, but as being the nearest approximation which can commonly be had
  • to that proportion. I shall hereafter have occasion to make several
  • comparisons of this kind.
  • In the progress of industry, commercial nations have found it convenient
  • to coin several different metals into money; gold for larger payments,
  • silver for purchases of moderate value, and copper, or some other coarse
  • metal, for those of still smaller consideration, They have always,
  • however, considered one of those metals as more peculiarly the measure of
  • value than any of the other two; and this preference seems generally to
  • have been given to the metal which they happen first to make use of as the
  • instrument of commerce. Having once begun to use it as their standard,
  • which they must have done when they had no other money, they have
  • generally continued to do so even when the necessity was not the same.
  • The Romans are said to have had nothing but copper money till within five
  • years before the first Punic war (Pliny, lib. xxxiii. cap. 3), when they
  • first began to coin silver. Copper, therefore, appears to have continued
  • always the measure of value in that republic. At Rome all accounts appear
  • to have been kept, and the value of all estates to have been computed,
  • either in asses or in sestertii. The as was always the denomination of a
  • copper coin. The word sestertius signifies two asses and a half. Though
  • the sestertius, therefore, was originally a silver coin, its value was
  • estimated in copper. At Rome, one who owed a great deal of money was said
  • to have a great deal of other people’s copper.
  • The northern nations who established themselves upon the ruins of the
  • Roman empire, seem to have had silver money from the first beginning of
  • their settlements, and not to have known either gold or copper coins for
  • several ages thereafter. There were silver coins in England in the time of
  • the Saxons; but there was little gold coined till the time of Edward III
  • nor any copper till that of James I. of Great Britain. In England,
  • therefore, and for the same reason, I believe, in all other modern nations
  • of Europe, all accounts are kept, and the value of all goods and of all
  • estates is generally computed, in silver: and when we mean to express the
  • amount of a person’s fortune, we seldom mention the number of guineas, but
  • the number of pounds sterling which we suppose would be given for it.
  • Originally, in all countries, I believe, a legal tender of payment could
  • be made only in the coin of that metal which was peculiarly considered as
  • the standard or measure of value. In England, gold was not considered as a
  • legal tender for a long time after it was coined into money. The
  • proportion between the values of gold and silver money was not fixed by
  • any public law or proclamation, but was left to be settled by the market.
  • If a debtor offered payment in gold, the creditor might either reject such
  • payment altogether, or accept of it at such a valuation of the gold as he
  • and his debtor could agree upon. Copper is not at present a legal tender,
  • except in the change of the smaller silver coins.
  • In this state of things, the distinction between the metal which was the
  • standard, and that which was not the standard, was something more than a
  • nominal distinction.
  • In process of time, and as people became gradually more familiar with the
  • use of the different metals in coin, and consequently better acquainted
  • with the proportion between their respective values, it has, in most
  • countries, I believe, been found convenient to ascertain this proportion,
  • and to declare by a public law, that a guinea, for example, of such a
  • weight and fineness, should exchange for one-and-twenty shillings, or be a
  • legal tender for a debt of that amount. In this state of things, and
  • during the continuance of any one regulated proportion of this kind, the
  • distinction between the metal, which is the standard, and that which is
  • not the standard, becomes little more than a nominal distinction.
  • In consequence of any change, however, in this regulated proportion, this
  • distinction becomes, or at least seems to become, something more than
  • nominal again. If the regulated value of a guinea, for example, was either
  • reduced to twenty, or raised to two-and-twenty shillings, all accounts
  • being kept, and almost all obligations for debt being expressed, in silver
  • money, the greater part of payments could in either case be made with the
  • same quantity of silver money as before; but would require very different
  • quantities of gold money; a greater in the one case, and a smaller in the
  • other. Silver would appear to be more invariable in its value than gold.
  • Silver would appear to measure the value of gold, and gold would not
  • appear to measure the value of silver. The value of gold would seem to
  • depend upon the quantity of silver which it would exchange for, and the
  • value of silver would not seem to depend upon the quantity of gold which
  • it would exchange for. This difference, however, would be altogether owing
  • to the custom of keeping accounts, and of expressing the amount of all
  • great and small sums rather in silver than in gold money. One of Mr
  • Drummond’s notes for five-and-twenty or fifty guineas would, after an
  • alteration of this kind, be still payable with five-and-twenty or fifty
  • guineas, in the same manner as before. It would, after such an alteration,
  • be payable with the same quantity of gold as before, but with very
  • different quantities of silver. In the payment of such a note, gold would
  • appear to be more invariable in its value than silver. Gold would appear
  • to measure the value of silver, and silver would not appear to measure the
  • value of gold. If the custom of keeping accounts, and of expressing
  • promissory-notes and other obligations for money, in this manner should
  • ever become general, gold, and not silver, would be considered as the
  • metal which was peculiarly the standard or measure of value.
  • In reality, during the continuance of any one regulated proportion between
  • the respective values of the different metals in coin, the value of the
  • most precious metal regulates the value of the whole coin. Twelve copper
  • pence contain half a pound avoirdupois of copper, of not the best quality,
  • which, before it is coined, is seldom worth seven-pence in silver. But as,
  • by the regulation, twelve such pence are ordered to exchange for a
  • shilling, they are in the market considered as worth a shilling, and a
  • shilling can at any time be had for them. Even before the late reformation
  • of the gold coin of Great Britain, the gold, that part of it at least
  • which circulated in London and its neighbourhood, was in general less
  • degraded below its standard weight than the greater part of the silver.
  • One-and-twenty worn and defaced shillings, however, were considered as
  • equivalent to a guinea, which, perhaps, indeed, was worn and defaced too,
  • but seldom so much so. The late regulations have brought the gold coin as
  • near, perhaps, to its standard weight as it is possible to bring the
  • current coin of any nation; and the order to receive no gold at the public
  • offices but by weight, is likely to preserve it so, as long as that order
  • is enforced. The silver coin still continues in the same worn and degraded
  • state as before the reformation of the cold coin. In the market, however,
  • one-and-twenty shillings of this degraded silver coin are still considered
  • as worth a guinea of this excellent gold coin.
  • The reformation of the gold coin has evidently raised the value of the
  • silver coin which can be exchanged for it.
  • In the English mint, a pound weight of gold is coined into forty-four
  • guineas and a half, which at one-and-twenty shillings the guinea, is equal
  • to forty-six pounds fourteen shillings and sixpence. An ounce of such gold
  • coin, therefore, is worth £ 3:17:10½ in silver. In England, no duty or
  • seignorage is paid upon the coinage, and he who carries a pound weight or
  • an ounce weight of standard gold bullion to the mint, gets back a pound
  • weight or an ounce weight of gold in coin, without any deduction. Three
  • pounds seventeen shillings and tenpence halfpenny an ounce, therefore, is
  • said to be the mint price of gold in England, or the quantity of gold coin
  • which the mint gives in return for standard gold bullion.
  • Before the reformation of the gold coin, the price of standard gold
  • bullion in the market had, for many years, been upwards of £3:18s.
  • sometimes £ 3:19s, and very frequently £4 an ounce; that sum, it is
  • probable, in the worn and degraded gold coin, seldom containing more than
  • an ounce of standard gold. Since the reformation of the gold coin, the
  • market price of standard gold bullion seldom exceeds £ 3:17:7 an ounce.
  • Before the reformation of the gold coin, the market price was always more
  • or less above the mint price. Since that reformation, the market price has
  • been constantly below the mint price. But that market price is the same
  • whether it is paid in gold or in silver coin. The late reformation of the
  • gold coin, therefore, has raised not only the value of the gold coin, but
  • likewise that of the silver coin in proportion to gold bullion, and
  • probably, too, in proportion to all other commodities; though the price of
  • the greater part of other commodities being influenced by so many other
  • causes, the rise in the value of either gold or silver coin in proportion
  • to them may not be so distinct and sensible.
  • In the English mint, a pound weight of standard silver bullion is coined
  • into sixty-two shillings, containing, in the same manner, a pound weight
  • of standard silver. Five shillings and twopence an ounce, therefore, is
  • said to be the mint price of silver in England, or the quantity of silver
  • coin which the mint gives in return for standard silver bullion. Before
  • the reformation of the gold coin, the market price of standard silver
  • bullion was, upon different occasions, five shillings and fourpence, five
  • shillings and fivepence, five shillings and sixpence, five shillings and
  • sevenpence, and very often five shillings and eightpence an ounce. Five
  • shillings and sevenpence, however, seems to have been the most common
  • price. Since the reformation of the gold coin, the market price of
  • standard silver bullion has fallen occasionally to five shillings and
  • threepence, five shillings and fourpence, and five shillings and fivepence
  • an ounce, which last price it has scarce ever exceeded. Though the market
  • price of silver bullion has fallen considerably since the reformation of
  • the gold coin, it has not fallen so low as the mint price.
  • In the proportion between the different metals in the English coin, as
  • copper is rated very much above its real value, so silver is rated
  • somewhat below it. In the market of Europe, in the French coin and in the
  • Dutch coin, an ounce of fine gold exchanges for about fourteen ounces of
  • fine silver. In the English coin, it exchanges for about fifteen ounces,
  • that is, for more silver than it is worth, according to the common
  • estimation of Europe. But as the price of copper in bars is not, even in
  • England, raised by the high price of copper in English coin, so the price
  • of silver in bullion is not sunk by the low rate of silver in English
  • coin. Silver in bullion still preserves its proper proportion to gold, for
  • the same reason that copper in bars preserves its proper proportion to
  • silver.
  • Upon the reformation of the silver coin, in the reign of William III., the
  • price of silver bullion still continued to be somewhat above the mint
  • price. Mr Locke imputed this high price to the permission of exporting
  • silver bullion, and to the prohibition of exporting silver coin. This
  • permission of exporting, he said, rendered the demand for silver bullion
  • greater than the demand for silver coin. But the number of people who want
  • silver coin for the common uses of buying and selling at home, is surely
  • much greater than that of those who want silver bullion either for the use
  • of exportation or for any other use. There subsists at present a like
  • permission of exporting gold bullion, and a like prohibition of exporting
  • gold coin; and yet the price of gold bullion has fallen below the mint
  • price. But in the English coin, silver was then, in the same manner as
  • now, under-rated in proportion to gold; and the gold coin (which at that
  • time, too, was not supposed to require any reformation) regulated then, as
  • well as now, the real value of the whole coin. As the reformation of the
  • silver coin did not then reduce the price of silver bullion to the mint
  • price, it is not very probable that a like reformation will do so now.
  • Were the silver coin brought back as near to its standard weight as the
  • gold, a guinea, it is probable, would, according to the present
  • proportion, exchange for more silver in coin than it would purchase in
  • bullion. The silver coin containing its full standard weight, there would
  • in this case, be a profit in melting it down, in order, first to sell the
  • bullion for gold coin, and afterwards to exchange this gold coin for
  • silver coin, to be melted down in the same manner. Some alteration in the
  • present proportion seems to be the only method of preventing this
  • inconveniency.
  • The inconveniency, perhaps, would be less, if silver was rated in the coin
  • as much above its proper proportion to gold as it is at present rated
  • below it, provided it was at the same time enacted, that silver should not
  • be a legal tender for more than the change of a guinea, in the same manner
  • as copper is not a legal tender for more than the change of a shilling. No
  • creditor could, in this case, be cheated in consequence of the high
  • valuation of silver in coin; as no creditor can at present be cheated in
  • consequence of the high valuation of copper. The bankers only would suffer
  • by this regulation. When a run comes upon them, they sometimes endeavour
  • to gain time, by paying in sixpences, and they would be precluded by this
  • regulation from this discreditable method of evading immediate payment.
  • They would be obliged, in consequence, to keep at all times in their
  • coffers a greater quantity of cash than at present; and though this might,
  • no doubt, be a considerable inconveniency to them, it would, at the same
  • time, be a considerable security to their creditors.
  • Three pounds seventeen shillings and tenpence halfpenny (the mint price of
  • gold) certainly does not contain, even in our present excellent gold coin,
  • more than an ounce of standard gold, and it may be thought, therefore,
  • should not purchase more standard bullion. But gold in coin is more
  • convenient than gold in bullion; and though, in England, the coinage is
  • free, yet the gold which is carried in bullion to the mint, can seldom be
  • returned in coin to the owner till after a delay of several weeks. In the
  • present hurry of the mint, it could not be returned till after a delay of
  • several months. This delay is equivalent to a small duty, and renders gold
  • in coin somewhat more valuable than an equal quantity of gold in bullion.
  • If, in the English coin, silver was rated according to its proper
  • proportion to gold, the price of silver bullion would probably fall below
  • the mint price, even without any reformation of the silver coin; the value
  • even of the present worn and defaced silver coin being regulated by the
  • value of the excellent gold coin for which it can be changed.
  • A small seignorage or duty upon the coinage of both gold and silver, would
  • probably increase still more the superiority of those metals in coin above
  • an equal quantity of either of them in bullion. The coinage would, in this
  • case, increase the value of the metal coined in proportion to the extent
  • of this small duty, for the same reason that the fashion increases the
  • value of plate in proportion to the price of that fashion. The superiority
  • of coin above bullion would prevent the melting down of the coin, and
  • would discourage its exportation. If, upon any public exigency, it should
  • become necessary to export the coin, the greater part of it would soon
  • return again, of its own accord. Abroad, it could sell only for its weight
  • in bullion. At home, it would buy more than that weight. There would be a
  • profit, therefore, in bringing it home again. In France, a seignorage of
  • about eight per cent. is imposed upon the coinage, and the French coin,
  • when exported, is said to return home again, of its own accord.
  • The occasional fluctuations in the market price of gold and silver bullion
  • arise from the same causes as the like fluctuations in that of all other
  • commodities. The frequent loss of those metals from various accidents by
  • sea and by land, the continual waste of them in gilding and plating, in
  • lace and embroidery, in the wear and tear of coin, and in that of plate,
  • require, in all countries which possess no mines of their own, a continual
  • importation, in order to repair this loss and this waste. The merchant
  • importers, like all other merchants, we may believe, endeavour, as well as
  • they can, to suit their occasional importations to what they judge is
  • likely to be the immediate demand. With all their attention, however, they
  • sometimes overdo the business, and sometimes underdo it. When they import
  • more bullion than is wanted, rather than incur the risk and trouble of
  • exporting it again, they are sometimes willing to sell a part of it for
  • something less than the ordinary or average price. When, on the other
  • hand, they import less than is wanted, they get something more than this
  • price. But when, under all those occasional fluctuations, the market price
  • either of gold or silver bullion continues for several years together
  • steadily and constantly, either more or less above, or more or less below
  • the mint price, we may be assured that this steady and constant, either
  • superiority or inferiority of price, is the effect of something in the
  • state of the coin, which, at that time, renders a certain quantity of coin
  • either of more value or of less value than the precise quantity of bullion
  • which it ought to contain. The constancy and steadiness of the effect
  • supposes a proportionable constancy and steadiness in the cause.
  • The money of any particular country is, at any particular time and place,
  • more or less an accurate measure or value, according as the current coin
  • is more or less exactly agreeable to its standard, or contains more or
  • less exactly the precise quantity of pure gold or pure silver which it
  • ought to contain. If in England, for example, forty-four guineas and a
  • half contained exactly a pound weight of standard gold, or eleven ounces
  • of fine gold, and one ounce of alloy, the gold coin of England would be as
  • accurate a measure of the actual value of goods at any particular time and
  • place as the nature of the thing would admit. But if, by rubbing and
  • wearing, forty-four guineas and a half generally contain less than a pound
  • weight of standard gold, the diminution, however, being greater in some
  • pieces than in others, the measure of value comes to be liable to the same
  • sort of uncertainty to which all other weights and measures are commonly
  • exposed. As it rarely happens that these are exactly agreeable to their
  • standard, the merchant adjusts the price of his goods as well as he can,
  • not to what those weights and measures ought to be, but to what, upon an
  • average, he finds, by experience, they actually are. In consequence of a
  • like disorder in the coin, the price of goods comes, in the same manner,
  • to be adjusted, not to the quantity of pure gold or silver which the coin
  • ought to contain, but to that which, upon an average, it is found, by
  • experience, it actually does contain.
  • By the money price of goods, it is to be observed, I understand always the
  • quantity of pure gold or silver for which they are sold, without any
  • regard to the denomination of the coin. Six shillings and eight pence, for
  • example, in the time of Edward I., I consider as the same money price with
  • a pound sterling in the present times, because it contained, as nearly as
  • we can judge, the same quantity of pure silver.
  • CHAPTER VI.
  • OF THE COMPONENT PART OF THE PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
  • In that early and rude state of society which precedes both the
  • accumulation of stock and the appropriation of land, the proportion
  • between the quantities of labour necessary for acquiring different
  • objects, seems to be the only circumstance which can afford any rule for
  • exchanging them for one another. If among a nation of hunters, for
  • example, it usually costs twice the labour to kill a beaver which it does
  • to kill a deer, one beaver should naturally exchange for or be worth two
  • deer. It is natural that what is usually the produce of two days or two
  • hours labour, should be worth double of what is usually the produce of one
  • day’s or one hour’s labour.
  • If the one species of labour should be more severe than the other, some
  • allowance will naturally be made for this superior hardship; and the
  • produce of one hour’s labour in the one way may frequently exchange for
  • that of two hour’s labour in the other.
  • Or if the one species of labour requires an uncommon degree of dexterity
  • and ingenuity, the esteem which men have for such talents, will naturally
  • give a value to their produce, superior to what would be due to the time
  • employed about it. Such talents can seldom be acquired but in consequence
  • of long application, and the superior value of their produce may
  • frequently be no more than a reasonable compensation for the time and
  • labour which must be spent in acquiring them. In the advanced state of
  • society, allowances of this kind, for superior hardship and superior
  • skill, are commonly made in the wages of labour; and something of the same
  • kind must probably have taken place in its earliest and rudest period.
  • In this state of things, the whole produce of labour belongs to the
  • labourer; and the quantity of labour commonly employed in acquiring or
  • producing any commodity, is the only circumstance which can regulate the
  • quantity of labour which it ought commonly to purchase, command, or
  • exchange for.
  • As soon as stock has accumulated in the hands of particular persons, some
  • of them will naturally employ it in setting to work industrious people,
  • whom they will supply with materials and subsistence, in order to make a
  • profit by the sale of their work, or by what their labour adds to the
  • value of the materials. In exchanging the complete manufacture either for
  • money, for labour, or for other goods, over and above what may be
  • sufficient to pay the price of the materials, and the wages of the
  • workmen, something must be given for the profits of the undertaker of the
  • work, who hazards his stock in this adventure. The value which the workmen
  • add to the materials, therefore, resolves itself in this case into two
  • parts, of which the one pays their wages, the other the profits of their
  • employer upon the whole stock of materials and wages which he advanced. He
  • could have no interest to employ them, unless he expected from the sale of
  • their work something more than what was sufficient to replace his stock to
  • him; and he could have no interest to employ a great stock rather than a
  • small one, unless his profits were to bear some proportion to the extent
  • of his stock.
  • The profits of stock, it may perhaps be thought, are only a different name
  • for the wages of a particular sort of labour, the labour of inspection and
  • direction. They are, however, altogether different, are regulated by quite
  • different principles, and bear no proportion to the quantity, the
  • hardship, or the ingenuity of this supposed labour of inspection and
  • direction. They are regulated altogether by the value of the stock
  • employed, and are greater or smaller in proportion to the extent of this
  • stock. Let us suppose, for example, that in some particular place, where
  • the common annual profits of manufacturing stock are ten per cent. there
  • are two different manufactures, in each of which twenty workmen are
  • employed, at the rate of fifteen pounds a year each, or at the expense of
  • three hundred a-year in each manufactory. Let us suppose, too, that the
  • coarse materials annually wrought up in the one cost only seven hundred
  • pounds, while the finer materials in the other cost seven thousand. The
  • capital annually employed in the one will, in this case, amount only to
  • one thousand pounds; whereas that employed in the other will amount to
  • seven thousand three hundred pounds. At the rate of ten per cent.
  • therefore, the undertaker of the one will expect a yearly profit of about
  • one hundred pounds only; while that of the other will expect about seven
  • hundred and thirty pounds. But though their profits are so very different,
  • their labour of inspection and direction may be either altogether or very
  • nearly the same. In many great works, almost the whole labour of this kind
  • is committed to some principal clerk. His wages properly express the value
  • of this labour of inspection and direction. Though in settling them some
  • regard is had commonly, not only to his labour and skill, but to the trust
  • which is reposed in him, yet they never bear any regular proportion to the
  • capital of which he oversees the management; and the owner of this
  • capital, though he is thus discharged of almost all labour, still expects
  • that his profit should bear a regular proportion to his capital. In the
  • price of commodities, therefore, the profits of stock constitute a
  • component part altogether different from the wages of labour, and
  • regulated by quite different principles.
  • In this state of things, the whole produce of labour does not always
  • belong to the labourer. He must in most cases share it with the owner of
  • the stock which employs him. Neither is the quantity of labour commonly
  • employed in acquiring or producing any commodity, the only circumstance
  • which can regulate the quantity which it ought commonly to purchase,
  • command or exchange for. An additional quantity, it is evident, must be
  • due for the profits of the stock which advanced the wages and furnished
  • the materials of that labour.
  • As soon as the land of any country has all become private property, the
  • landlords, like all other men, love to reap where they never sowed, and
  • demand a rent even for its natural produce. The wood of the forest, the
  • grass of the field, and all the natural fruits of the earth, which, when
  • land was in common, cost the labourer only the trouble of gathering them,
  • come, even to him, to have an additional price fixed upon them. He must
  • then pay for the licence to gather them, and must give up to the landlord
  • a portion of what his labour either collects or produces. This portion,
  • or, what comes to the same thing, the price of this portion, constitutes
  • the rent of land, and in the price of the greater part of commodities,
  • makes a third component part.
  • The real value of all the different component parts of price, it must be
  • observed, is measured by the quantity of labour which they can, each of
  • them, purchase or command. Labour measures the value, not only of that
  • part of price which resolves itself into labour, but of that which
  • resolves itself into rent, and of that which resolves itself into profit.
  • In every society, the price of every commodity finally resolves itself
  • into some one or other, or all of those three parts; and in every improved
  • society, all the three enter, more or less, as component parts, into the
  • price of the far greater part of commodities.
  • In the price of corn, for example, one part pays the rent of the landlord,
  • another pays the wages or maintenance of the labourers and labouring
  • cattle employed in producing it, and the third pays the profit of the
  • farmer. These three parts seem either immediately or ultimately to make up
  • the whole price of corn. A fourth part, it may perhaps be thought is
  • necessary for replacing the stock of the farmer, or for compensating the
  • wear and tear of his labouring cattle, and other instruments of husbandry.
  • But it must be considered, that the price of any instrument of husbandry,
  • such as a labouring horse, is itself made up of the same time parts; the
  • rent of the land upon which he is reared, the labour of tending and
  • rearing him, and the profits of the farmer, who advances both the rent of
  • this land, and the wages of this labour. Though the price of the corn,
  • therefore, may pay the price as well as the maintenance of the horse, the
  • whole price still resolves itself, either immediately or ultimately, into
  • the same three parts of rent, labour, and profit.
  • In the price of flour or meal, we must add to the price of the corn, the
  • profits of the miller, and the wages of his servants; in the price of
  • bread, the profits of the baker, and the wages of his servants; and in the
  • price of both, the labour of transporting the corn from the house of the
  • farmer to that of the miller, and from that of the miller to that of the
  • baker, together with the profits of those who advance the wages of that
  • labour.
  • The price of flax resolves itself into the same three parts as that of
  • corn. In the price of linen we must add to this price the wages of the
  • flax-dresser, of the spinner, of the weaver, of the bleacher, etc.
  • together with the profits of their respective employers.
  • As any particular commodity comes to be more manufactured, that part of
  • the price which resolves itself into wages and profit, comes to be greater
  • in proportion to that which resolves itself into rent. In the progress of
  • the manufacture, not only the number of profits increase, but every
  • subsequent profit is greater than the foregoing; because the capital from
  • which it is derived must always be greater. The capital which employs the
  • weavers, for example, must be greater than that which employs the
  • spinners; because it not only replaces that capital with its profits, but
  • pays, besides, the wages of the weavers: and the profits must always bear
  • some proportion to the capital.
  • In the most improved societies, however, there are always a few
  • commodities of which the price resolves itself into two parts only: the
  • wages of labour, and the profits of stock; and a still smaller number, in
  • which it consists altogether in the wages of labour. In the price of
  • sea-fish, for example, one part pays the labour of the fisherman, and the
  • other the profits of the capital employed in the fishery. Rent very seldom
  • makes any part of it, though it does sometimes, as I shall shew hereafter.
  • It is otherwise, at least through the greater part of Europe, in river
  • fisheries. A salmon fishery pays a rent; and rent, though it cannot well
  • be called the rent of land, makes a part of the price of a salmon, as well
  • as wares and profit. In some parts of Scotland, a few poor people make a
  • trade of gathering, along the sea-shore, those little variegated stones
  • commonly known by the name of Scotch pebbles. The price which is paid to
  • them by the stone-cutter, is altogether the wages of their labour; neither
  • rent nor profit makes an part of it.
  • But the whole price of any commodity must still finally resolve itself
  • into some one or other or all of those three parts; as whatever part of it
  • remains after paying the rent of the land, and the price of the whole
  • labour employed in raising, manufacturing, and bringing it to market, must
  • necessarily be profit to somebody.
  • As the price or exchangeable value of every particular commodity, taken
  • separately, resolves itself into some one or other, or all of those three
  • parts; so that of all the commodities which compose the whole annual
  • produce of the labour of every country, taken complexly, must resolve
  • itself into the same three parts, and be parcelled out among different
  • inhabitants of the country, either as the wages of their labour, the
  • profits of their stock, or the rent of their land. The whole of what is
  • annually either collected or produced by the labour of every society, or,
  • what comes to the same thing, the whole price of it, is in this manner
  • originally distributed among some of its different members. Wages, profit,
  • and rent, are the three original sources of all revenue, as well as of all
  • exchangeable value. All other revenue is ultimately derived from some one
  • or other of these.
  • Whoever derives his revenue from a fund which is his own, must draw it
  • either from his labour, from his stock, or from his land. The revenue
  • derived from labour is called wages; that derived from stock, by the
  • person who manages or employs it, is called profit; that derived from it
  • by the person who does not employ it himself, but lends it to another, is
  • called the interest or the use of money. It is the compensation which the
  • borrower pays to the lender, for the profit which he has an opportunity of
  • making by the use of the money. Part of that profit naturally belongs to
  • the borrower, who runs the risk and takes the trouble of employing it, and
  • part to the lender, who affords him the opportunity of making this profit.
  • The interest of money is always a derivative revenue, which, if it is not
  • paid from the profit which is made by the use of the money, must be paid
  • from some other source of revenue, unless perhaps the borrower is a
  • spendthrift, who contracts a second debt in order to pay the interest of
  • the first. The revenue which proceeds altogether from land, is called
  • rent, and belongs to the landlord. The revenue of the farmer is derived
  • partly from his labour, and partly from his stock. To him, land is only
  • the instrument which enables him to earn the wages of this labour, and to
  • make the profits of this stock. All taxes, and all the revenue which is
  • founded upon them, all salaries, pensions, and annuities of every kind,
  • are ultimately derived from some one or other of those three original
  • sources of revenue, and are paid either immediately or mediately from the
  • wages of labour, the profits of stock, or the rent of land.
  • When those three different sorts of revenue belong to different persons,
  • they are readily distinguished; but when they belong to the same, they are
  • sometimes confounded with one another, at least in common language.
  • A gentleman who farms a part of his own estate, after paying the expense
  • of cultivation, should gain both the rent of the landlord and the profit
  • of the farmer. He is apt to denominate, however, his whole gain, profit,
  • and thus confounds rent with profit, at least in common language. The
  • greater part of our North American and West Indian planters are in this
  • situation. They farm, the greater part of them, their own estates: and
  • accordingly we seldom hear of the rent of a plantation, but frequently of
  • its profit.
  • Common farmers seldom employ any overseer to direct the general operations
  • of the farm. They generally, too, work a good deal with their own hands,
  • as ploughmen, harrowers, etc. What remains of the crop, after paying the
  • rent, therefore, should not only replace to them their stock employed in
  • cultivation, together with its ordinary profits, but pay them the wages
  • which are due to them, both as labourers and overseers. Whatever remains,
  • however, after paying the rent and keeping up the stock, is called profit.
  • But wages evidently make a part of it. The farmer, by saving these wages,
  • must necessarily gain them. Wages, therefore, are in this case confounded
  • with profit.
  • An independent manufacturer, who has stock enough both to purchase
  • materials, and to maintain himself till he can carry his work to market,
  • should gain both the wages of a journeyman who works under a master, and
  • the profit which that master makes by the sale of that journeyman’s work.
  • His whole gains, however, are commonly called profit, and wages are, in
  • this case, too, confounded with profit.
  • A gardener who cultivates his own garden with his own hands, unites in his
  • own person the three different characters, of landlord, farmer, and
  • labourer. His produce, therefore, should pay him the rent of the first,
  • the profit of the second, and the wages of the third. The whole, however,
  • is commonly considered as the earnings of his labour. Both rent and profit
  • are, in this case, confounded with wages.
  • As in a civilized country there are but few commodities of which the
  • exchangeable value arises from labour only, rent and profit contributing
  • largely to that of the far greater part of them, so the annual produce of
  • its labour will always be sufficient to purchase or command a much greater
  • quantity of labour than what was employed in raising, preparing, and
  • bringing that produce to market. If the society were annually to employ
  • all the labour which it can annually purchase, as the quantity of labour
  • would increase greatly every year, so the produce of every succeeding year
  • would be of vastly greater value than that of the foregoing. But there is
  • no country in which the whole annual produce is employed in maintaining
  • the industrious. The idle everywhere consume a great part of it; and,
  • according to the different proportions in which it is annually divided
  • between those two different orders of people, its ordinary or average
  • value must either annually increase or diminish, or continue the same from
  • one year to another.
  • CHAPTER VII.
  • OF THE NATURAL AND MARKET PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
  • There is in every society or neighbourhood an ordinary or average rate,
  • both of wages and profit, in every different employment of labour and
  • stock. This rate is naturally regulated, as I shall shew hereafter, partly
  • by the general circumstances of the society, their riches or poverty,
  • their advancing, stationary, or declining condition, and partly by the
  • particular nature of each employment.
  • There is likewise in every society or neighbourhood an ordinary or average
  • rate of rent, which is regulated, too, as I shall shew hereafter, partly
  • by the general circumstances of the society or neighbourhood in which the
  • land is situated, and partly by the natural or improved fertility of the
  • land.
  • These ordinary or average rates may be called the natural rates of wages,
  • profit and rent, at the time and place in which they commonly prevail.
  • When the price of any commodity is neither more nor less than what is
  • sufficient to pay the rent of the land, the wages of the labour, and the
  • profits of the stock employed in raising, preparing, and bringing it to
  • market, according to their natural rates, the commodity is then sold for
  • what may be called its natural price.
  • The commodity is then sold precisely for what it is worth, or for what it
  • really costs the person who brings it to market; for though, in common
  • language, what is called the prime cost of any commodity does not
  • comprehend the profit of the person who is to sell it again, yet, if he
  • sells it at a price which does not allow him the ordinary rate of profit
  • in his neighbourhood, he is evidently a loser by the trade; since, by
  • employing his stock in some other way, he might have made that profit. His
  • profit, besides, is his revenue, the proper fund of his subsistence. As,
  • while he is preparing and bringing the goods to market, he advances to his
  • workmen their wages, or their subsistence; so he advances to himself, in
  • the same manner, his own subsistence, which is generally suitable to the
  • profit which he may reasonably expect from the sale of his goods. Unless
  • they yield him this profit, therefore, they do not repay him what they may
  • very properly be said to have really cost him.
  • Though the price, therefore, which leaves him this profit, is not always
  • the lowest at which a dealer may sometimes sell his goods, it is the
  • lowest at which he is likely to sell them for any considerable time; at
  • least where there is perfect liberty, or where he may change his trade as
  • often as he pleases.
  • The actual price at which any commodity is commonly sold, is called its
  • market price. It may either be above, or below, or exactly the same with
  • its natural price.
  • The market price of every particular commodity is regulated by the
  • proportion between the quantity which is actually brought to market, and
  • the demand of those who are willing to pay the natural price of the
  • commodity, or the whole value of the rent, labour, and profit, which must
  • be paid in order to bring it thither. Such people may be called the
  • effectual demanders, and their demand the effectual demand; since it maybe
  • sufficient to effectuate the bringing of the commodity to market. It is
  • different from the absolute demand. A very poor man may be said, in some
  • sense, to have a demand for a coach and six; he might like to have it; but
  • his demand is not an effectual demand, as the commodity can never be
  • brought to market in order to satisfy it.
  • When the quantity of any commodity which is brought to market falls short
  • of the effectual demand, all those who are willing to pay the whole value
  • of the rent, wages, and profit, which must be paid in order to bring it
  • thither, cannot be supplied with the quantity which they want. Rather than
  • want it altogether, some of them will be willing to give more. A
  • competition will immediately begin among them, and the market price will
  • rise more or less above the natural price, according as either the
  • greatness of the deficiency, or the wealth and wanton luxury of the
  • competitors, happen to animate more or less the eagerness of the
  • competition. Among competitors of equal wealth and luxury, the same
  • deficiency will generally occasion a more or less eager competition,
  • according as the acquisition of the commodity happens to be of more or
  • less importance to them. Hence the exorbitant price of the necessaries of
  • life during the blockade of a town, or in a famine.
  • When the quantity brought to market exceeds the effectual demand, it
  • cannot be all sold to those who are willing to pay the whole value of the
  • rent, wages, and profit, which must be paid in order to bring it thither.
  • Some part must be sold to those who are willing to pay less, and the low
  • price which they give for it must reduce the price of the whole. The
  • market price will sink more or less below the natural price, according as
  • the greatness of the excess increases more or less the competition of the
  • sellers, or according as it happens to be more or less important to them
  • to get immediately rid of the commodity. The same excess in the
  • importation of perishable, will occasion a much greater competition than
  • in that of durable commodities; in the importation of oranges, for
  • example, than in that of old iron.
  • When the quantity brought to market is just sufficient to supply the
  • effectual demand, and no more, the market price naturally comes to be
  • either exactly, or as nearly as can be judged of, the same with the
  • natural price. The whole quantity upon hand can be disposed of for this
  • price, and can not be disposed of for more. The competition of the
  • different dealers obliges them all to accept of this price, but does not
  • oblige them to accept of less.
  • The quantity of every commodity brought to market naturally suits itself
  • to the effectual demand. It is the interest of all those who employ their
  • land, labour, or stock, in bringing any commodity to market, that the
  • quantity never should exceed the effectual demand; and it is the interest
  • of all other people that it never should fall short of that demand.
  • If at any time it exceeds the effectual demand, some of the component
  • parts of its price must be paid below their natural rate. If it is rent,
  • the interest of the landlords will immediately prompt them to withdraw a
  • part of their land; and if it is wages or profit, the interest of the
  • labourers in the one case, and of their employers in the other, will
  • prompt them to withdraw a part of their labour or stock, from this
  • employment. The quantity brought to market will soon be no more than
  • sufficient to supply the effectual demand. All the different parts of its
  • price will rise to their natural rate, and the whole price to its natural
  • price.
  • If, on the contrary, the quantity brought to market should at any time
  • fall short of the effectual demand, some of the component parts of its
  • price must rise above their natural rate. If it is rent, the interest of
  • all other landlords will naturally prompt them to prepare more land for
  • the raising of this commodity; if it is wages or profit, the interest of
  • all other labourers and dealers will soon prompt them to employ more
  • labour and stock in preparing and bringing it to market. The quantity
  • brought thither will soon be sufficient to supply the effectual demand.
  • All the different parts of its price will soon sink to their natural rate,
  • and the whole price to its natural price.
  • The natural price, therefore, is, as it were, the central price, to which
  • the prices of all commodities are continually gravitating. Different
  • accidents may sometimes keep them suspended a good deal above it, and
  • sometimes force them down even somewhat below it. But whatever may be the
  • obstacles which hinder them from settling in this centre of repose and
  • continuance, they are constantly tending towards it.
  • The whole quantity of industry annually employed in order to bring any
  • commodity to market, naturally suits itself in this manner to the
  • effectual demand. It naturally aims at bringing always that precise
  • quantity thither which may be sufficient to supply, and no more than
  • supply, that demand.
  • But, in some employments, the same quantity of industry will, in different
  • years, produce very different quantities of commodities; while, in others,
  • it will produce always the same, or very nearly the same. The same number
  • of labourers in husbandry will, in different years, produce very different
  • quantities of corn, wine, oil, hops, etc. But the same number of spinners
  • or weavers will every year produce the same, or very nearly the same,
  • quantity of linen and woollen cloth. It is only the average produce of the
  • one species of industry which can be suited, in any respect, to the
  • effectual demand; and as its actual produce is frequently much greater,
  • and frequently much less, than its average produce, the quantity of the
  • commodities brought to market will sometimes exceed a good deal, and
  • sometimes fall short a good deal, of the effectual demand. Even though
  • that demand, therefore, should continue always the same, their market
  • price will be liable to great fluctuations, will sometimes fall a good
  • deal below, and sometimes rise a good deal above, their natural price. In
  • the other species of industry, the produce of equal quantities of labour
  • being always the same, or very nearly the same, it can be more exactly
  • suited to the effectual demand. While that demand continues the same,
  • therefore, the market price of the commodities is likely to do so too, and
  • to be either altogether, or as nearly as can be judged of, the same with
  • the natural price. That the price of linen and woollen cloth is liable
  • neither to such frequent, nor to such great variations, as the price of
  • corn, every man’s experience will inform him. The price of the one species
  • of commodities varies only with the variations in the demand; that of the
  • other varies not only with the variations in the demand, but with the much
  • greater, and more frequent, variations in the quantity of what is brought
  • to market, in order to supply that demand.
  • The occasional and temporary fluctuations in the market price of any
  • commodity fall chiefly upon those parts of its price which resolve
  • themselves into wages and profit. That part which resolves itself into
  • rent is less affected by them. A rent certain in money is not in the least
  • affected by them, either in its rate or in its value. A rent which
  • consists either in a certain proportion, or in a certain quantity, of the
  • rude produce, is no doubt affected in its yearly value by all the
  • occasional and temporary fluctuations in the market price of that rude
  • produce; but it is seldom affected by them in its yearly rate. In settling
  • the terms of the lease, the landlord and farmer endeavour, according to
  • their best judgment, to adjust that rate, not to the temporary and
  • occasional, but to the average and ordinary price of the produce.
  • Such fluctuations affect both the value and the rate, either of wages or
  • of profit, according as the market happens to be either overstocked or
  • understocked with commodities or with labour, with work done, or with work
  • to be done. A public mourning raises the price of black cloth (with which
  • the market is almost always understocked upon such occasions), and
  • augments the profits of the merchants who possess any considerable
  • quantity of it. It has no effect upon the wages of the weavers. The market
  • is understocked with commodities, not with labour, with work done, not
  • with work to be done. It raises the wages of journeymen tailors. The
  • market is here understocked with labour. There is an effectual demand for
  • more labour, for more work to be done, than can be had. It sinks the price
  • of coloured silks and cloths, and thereby reduces the profits of the
  • merchants who have any considerable quantity of them upon hand. It sinks,
  • too, the wages of the workmen employed in preparing such commodities, for
  • which all demand is stopped for six months, perhaps for a twelvemonth. The
  • market is here overstocked both with commodities and with labour.
  • But though the market price of every particular commodity is in this
  • manner continually gravitating, if one may say so, towards the natural
  • price; yet sometimes particular accidents, sometimes natural causes, and
  • sometimes particular regulations of policy, may, in many commodities, keep
  • up the market price, for a long time together, a good deal above the
  • natural price.
  • When, by an increase in the effectual demand, the market price of some
  • particular commodity happens to rise a good deal above the natural price,
  • those who employ their stocks in supplying that market, are generally
  • careful to conceal this change. If it was commonly known, their great
  • profit would tempt so many new rivals to employ their stocks in the same
  • way, that, the effectual demand being fully supplied, the market price
  • would soon be reduced to the natural price, and, perhaps, for some time
  • even below it. If the market is at a great distance from the residence of
  • those who supply it, they may sometimes be able to keep the secret for
  • several years together, and may so long enjoy their extraordinary profits
  • without any new rivals. Secrets of this kind, however, it must be
  • acknowledged, can seldom be long kept; and the extraordinary profit can
  • last very little longer than they are kept.
  • Secrets in manufactures are capable of being longer kept than secrets in
  • trade. A dyer who has found the means of producing a particular colour
  • with materials which cost only half the price of those commonly made use
  • of, may, with good management, enjoy the advantage of his discovery as
  • long as he lives, and even leave it as a legacy to his posterity. His
  • extraordinary gains arise from the high price which is paid for his
  • private labour. They properly consist in the high wages of that labour.
  • But as they are repeated upon every part of his stock, and as their whole
  • amount bears, upon that account, a regular proportion to it, they are
  • commonly considered as extraordinary profits of stock.
  • Such enhancements of the market price are evidently the effects of
  • particular accidents, of which, however, the operation may sometimes last
  • for many years together.
  • Some natural productions require such a singularity of soil and situation,
  • that all the land in a great country, which is fit for producing them, may
  • not be sufficient to supply the effectual demand. The whole quantity
  • brought to market, therefore, may be disposed of to those who are willing
  • to give more than what is sufficient to pay the rent of the land which
  • produced them, together with the wages of the labour and the profits of
  • the stock which were employed in preparing and bringing them to market,
  • according to their natural rates. Such commodities may continue for whole
  • centuries together to be sold at this high price; and that part of it
  • which resolves itself into the rent of land, is in this case the part
  • which is generally paid above its natural rate. The rent of the land which
  • affords such singular and esteemed productions, like the rent of some
  • vineyards in France of a peculiarly happy soil and situation, bears no
  • regular proportion to the rent of other equally fertile and equally well
  • cultivated land in its neighbourhood. The wages of the labour, and the
  • profits of the stock employed in bringing such commodities to market, on
  • the contrary, are seldom out of their natural proportion to those of the
  • other employments of labour and stock in their neighbourhood.
  • Such enhancements of the market price are evidently the effect of natural
  • causes, which may hinder the effectual demand from ever being fully
  • supplied, and which may continue, therefore, to operate for ever.
  • A monopoly granted either to an individual or to a trading company, has
  • the same effect as a secret in trade or manufactures. The monopolists, by
  • keeping the market constantly understocked by never fully supplying the
  • effectual demand, sell their commodities much above the natural price, and
  • raise their emoluments, whether they consist in wages or profit, greatly
  • above their natural rate.
  • The price of monopoly is upon every occasion the highest which can be got.
  • The natural price, or the price of free competition, on the contrary, is
  • the lowest which can be taken, not upon every occasion indeed, but for any
  • considerable time together. The one is upon every occasion the highest
  • which can be squeezed out of the buyers, or which it is supposed they will
  • consent to give; the other is the lowest which the sellers can commonly
  • afford to take, and at the same time continue their business.
  • The exclusive privileges of corporations, statutes of apprenticeship, and
  • all those laws which restrain in particular employments, the competition
  • to a smaller number than might otherwise go into them, have the same
  • tendency, though in a less degree. They are a sort of enlarged monopolies,
  • and may frequently, for ages together, and in whole classes of
  • employments, keep up the market price of particular commodities above the
  • natural price, and maintain both the wages of the labour and the profits
  • of the stock employed about them somewhat above their natural rate.
  • Such enhancements of the market price may last as long as the regulations
  • of policy which give occasion to them.
  • The market price of any particular commodity, though it may continue long
  • above, can seldom continue long below, its natural price. Whatever part of
  • it was paid below the natural rate, the persons whose interest it affected
  • would immediately feel the loss, and would immediately withdraw either so
  • much land or so much labour, or so much stock, from being employed about
  • it, that the quantity brought to market would soon be no more than
  • sufficient to supply the effectual demand. Its market price, therefore,
  • would soon rise to the natural price; this at least would be the case
  • where there was perfect liberty.
  • The same statutes of apprenticeship and other corporation laws, indeed,
  • which, when a manufacture is in prosperity, enable the workman to raise
  • his wages a good deal above their natural rate, sometimes oblige him, when
  • it decays, to let them down a good deal below it. As in the one case they
  • exclude many people from his employment, so in the other they exclude him
  • from many employments. The effect of such regulations, however, is not
  • near so durable in sinking the workman’s wages below, as in raising them
  • above their natural rate. Their operation in the one way may endure for
  • many centuries, but in the other it can last no longer than the lives of
  • some of the workmen who were bred to the business in the time of its
  • prosperity. When they are gone, the number of those who are afterwards
  • educated to the trade will naturally suit itself to the effectual demand.
  • The policy must be as violent as that of Indostan or ancient Egypt (where
  • every man was bound by a principle of religion to follow the occupation of
  • his father, and was supposed to commit the most horrid sacrilege if he
  • changed it for another), which can in any particular employment, and for
  • several generations together, sink either the wages of labour or the
  • profits of stock below their natural rate.
  • This is all that I think necessary to be observed at present concerning
  • the deviations, whether occasional or permanent, of the market price of
  • commodities from the natural price.
  • The natural price itself varies with the natural rate of each of its
  • component parts, of wages, profit, and rent; and in every society this
  • rate varies according to their circumstances, according to their riches or
  • poverty, their advancing, stationary, or declining condition. I shall, in
  • the four following chapters, endeavour to explain, as fully and distinctly
  • as I can, the causes of those different variations.
  • First, I shall endeavour to explain what are the circumstances which
  • naturally determine the rate of wages, and in what manner those
  • circumstances are affected by the riches or poverty, by the advancing,
  • stationary, or declining state of the society.
  • Secondly, I shall endeavour to shew what are the circumstances which
  • naturally determine the rate of profit; and in what manner, too, those
  • circumstances are affected by the like variations in the state of the
  • society.
  • Though pecuniary wages and profit are very different in the different
  • employments of labour and stock; yet a certain proportion seems commonly
  • to take place between both the pecuniary wages in all the different
  • employments of labour, and the pecuniary profits in all the different
  • employments of stock. This proportion, it will appear hereafter, depends
  • partly upon the nature of the different employments, and partly upon the
  • different laws and policy of the society in which they are carried on. But
  • though in many respects dependent upon the laws and policy, this
  • proportion seems to be little affected by the riches or poverty of that
  • society, by its advancing, stationary, or declining condition, but to
  • remain the same, or very nearly the same, in all those different states. I
  • shall, in the third place, endeavour to explain all the different
  • circumstances which regulate this proportion.
  • In the fourth and last place, I shall endeavour to shew what are the
  • circumstances which regulate the rent of land, and which either raise or
  • lower the real price of all the different substances which it produces.
  • CHAPTER VIII.
  • OF THE WAGES OF LABOUR.
  • The produce of labour constitutes the natural recompence or wages of
  • labour. In that original state of things which precedes both the
  • appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock, the whole produce of
  • labour belongs to the labourer. He has neither landlord nor master to
  • share with him.
  • Had this state continued, the wages of labour would have augmented with
  • all those improvements in its productive powers, to which the division of
  • labour gives occasion. All things would gradually have become cheaper.
  • They would have been produced by a smaller quantity of labour; and as the
  • commodities produced by equal quantities of labour would naturally in this
  • state of things be exchanged for one another, they would have been
  • purchased likewise with the produce of a smaller quantity.
  • But though all things would have become cheaper in reality, in appearance
  • many things might have become dearer, than before, or have been exchanged
  • for a greater quantity of other goods. Let us suppose, for example, that
  • in the greater part of employments the productive powers of labour had
  • been improved to tenfold, or that a day’s labour could produce ten times
  • the quantity of work which it had done originally; but that in a
  • particular employment they had been improved only to double, or that a
  • day’s labour could produce only twice the quantity of work which it had
  • done before. In exchanging the produce of a day’s labour in the greater
  • part of employments for that of a day’s labour in this particular one, ten
  • times the original quantity of work in them would purchase only twice the
  • original quantity in it. Any particular quantity in it, therefore, a pound
  • weight, for example, would appear to be five times dearer than before. In
  • reality, however, it would be twice as cheap. Though it required five
  • times the quantity of other goods to purchase it, it would require only
  • half the quantity of labour either to purchase or to produce it. The
  • acquisition, therefore, would be twice as easy as before.
  • But this original state of things, in which the labourer enjoyed the whole
  • produce of his own labour, could not last beyond the first introduction of
  • the appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock. It was at an end,
  • therefore, long before the most considerable improvements were made in the
  • productive powers of labour; and it would be to no purpose to trace
  • further what might have been its effects upon the recompence or wages of
  • labour.
  • As soon as land becomes private property, the landlord demands a share of
  • almost all the produce which the labourer can either raise or collect from
  • it. His rent makes the first deduction from the produce of the labour
  • which is employed upon land.
  • It seldom happens that the person who tills the ground has wherewithal to
  • maintain himself till he reaps the harvest. His maintenance is generally
  • advanced to him from the stock of a master, the farmer who employs him,
  • and who would have no interest to employ him, unless he was to share in
  • the produce of his labour, or unless his stock was to be replaced to him
  • with a profit. This profit makes a second deduction from the produce of
  • the labour which is employed upon land.
  • The produce of almost all other labour is liable to the like deduction of
  • profit. In all arts and manufactures, the greater part of the workmen
  • stand in need of a master, to advance them the materials of their work,
  • and their wages and maintenance, till it be completed. He shares in the
  • produce of their labour, or in the value which it adds to the materials
  • upon which it is bestowed; and in this share consists his profit.
  • It sometimes happens, indeed, that a single independent workman has stock
  • sufficient both to purchase the materials of his work, and to maintain
  • himself till it be completed. He is both master and workman, and enjoys
  • the whole produce of his own labour, or the whole value which it adds to
  • the materials upon which it is bestowed. It includes what are usually two
  • distinct revenues, belonging to two distinct persons, the profits of
  • stock, and the wages of labour.
  • Such cases, however, are not very frequent; and in every part of Europe
  • twenty workmen serve under a master for one that is independent, and the
  • wages of labour are everywhere understood to be, what they usually are,
  • when the labourer is one person, and the owner of the stock which employs
  • him another.
  • What are the common wages of labour, depends everywhere upon the contract
  • usually made between those two parties, whose interests are by no means
  • the same. The workmen desire to get as much, the masters to give as
  • little, as possible. The former are disposed to combine in order to raise,
  • the latter in order to lower, the wages of labour.
  • It is not, however, difficult to foresee which of the two parties must,
  • upon all ordinary occasions, have the advantage in the dispute, and force
  • the other into a compliance with their terms. The masters, being fewer in
  • number, can combine much more easily: and the law, besides, authorises, or
  • at least does not prohibit, their combinations, while it prohibits those
  • of the workmen. We have no acts of parliament against combining to lower
  • the price of work, but many against combining to raise it. In all such
  • disputes, the masters can hold out much longer. A landlord, a farmer, a
  • master manufacturer, or merchant, though they did not employ a single
  • workman, could generally live a year or two upon the stocks, which they
  • have already acquired. Many workmen could not subsist a week, few could
  • subsist a month, and scarce any a year, without employment. In the long
  • run, the workman may be as necessary to his master as his master is to
  • him; but the necessity is not so immediate.
  • We rarely hear, it has been said, of the combinations of masters, though
  • frequently of those of workmen. But whoever imagines, upon this account,
  • that masters rarely combine, is as ignorant of the world as of the
  • subject. Masters are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but
  • constant and uniform, combination, not to raise the wages of labour above
  • their actual rate. To violate this combination is everywhere a most
  • unpopular action, and a sort of reproach to a master among his neighbours
  • and equals. We seldom, indeed, hear of this combination, because it is the
  • usual, and, one may say, the natural state of things, which nobody ever
  • hears of. Masters, too, sometimes enter into particular combinations to
  • sink the wages of labour even below this rate. These are always conducted
  • with the utmost silence and secrecy till the moment of execution; and when
  • the workmen yield, as they sometimes do without resistance, though
  • severely felt by them, they are never heard of by other people. Such
  • combinations, however, are frequently resisted by a contrary defensive
  • combination of the workmen, who sometimes, too, without any provocation of
  • this kind, combine, of their own accord, to raise the price of their
  • labour. Their usual pretences are, sometimes the high price of provisions,
  • sometimes the great profit which their masters make by their work. But
  • whether their combinations be offensive or defensive, they are always
  • abundantly heard of. In order to bring the point to a speedy decision,
  • they have always recourse to the loudest clamour, and sometimes to the
  • most shocking violence and outrage. They are desperate, and act with the
  • folly and extravagance of desperate men, who must either starve, or
  • frighten their masters into an immediate compliance with their demands.
  • The masters, upon these occasions, are just as clamorous upon the other
  • side, and never cease to call aloud for the assistance of the civil
  • magistrate, and the rigorous execution of those laws which have been
  • enacted with so much severity against the combination of servants,
  • labourers, and journeymen. The workmen, accordingly, very seldom derive
  • any advantage from the violence of those tumultuous combinations, which,
  • partly from the interposition of the civil magistrate, partly from the
  • superior steadiness of the masters, partly from the necessity which the
  • greater part of the workmen are under of submitting for the sake of
  • present subsistence, generally end in nothing but the punishment or ruin
  • of the ringleaders.
  • But though, in disputes with their workmen, masters must generally have
  • the advantage, there is, however, a certain rate, below which it seems
  • impossible to reduce, for any considerable time, the ordinary wages even
  • of the lowest species of labour.
  • A man must always live by his work, and his wages must at least be
  • sufficient to maintain him. They must even upon most occasions be somewhat
  • more, otherwise it would be impossible for him to bring up a family, and
  • the race of such workmen could not last beyond the first generation. Mr
  • Cantillon seems, upon this account, to suppose that the lowest species of
  • common labourers must everywhere earn at least double their own
  • maintenance, in order that, one with another, they may be enabled to bring
  • up two children; the labour of the wife, on account of her necessary
  • attendance on the children, being supposed no more than sufficient to
  • provide for herself: But one half the children born, it is computed, die
  • before the age of manhood. The poorest labourers, therefore, according to
  • this account, must, one with another, attempt to rear at least four
  • children, in order that two may have an equal chance of living to that
  • age. But the necessary maintenance of four children, it is supposed, may
  • be nearly equal to that of one man. The labour of an able-bodied slave,
  • the same author adds, is computed to be worth double his maintenance; and
  • that of the meanest labourer, he thinks, cannot be worth less than that of
  • an able-bodied slave. Thus far at least seems certain, that, in order to
  • bring up a family, the labour of the husband and wife together must, even
  • in the lowest species of common labour, be able to earn something more
  • than what is precisely necessary for their own maintenance; but in what
  • proportion, whether in that above-mentioned, or many other, I shall not
  • take upon me to determine.
  • There are certain circumstances, however, which sometimes give the
  • labourers an advantage, and enable them to raise their wages considerably
  • above this rate, evidently the lowest which is consistent with common
  • humanity.
  • When in any country the demand for those who live by wages, labourers,
  • journeymen, servants of every kind, is continually increasing; when every
  • year furnishes employment for a greater number than had been employed the
  • year before, the workmen have no occasion to combine in order to raise
  • their wages. The scarcity of hands occasions a competition among masters,
  • who bid against one another in order to get workmen, and thus voluntarily
  • break through the natural combination of masters not to raise wages. The
  • demand for those who live by wages, it is evident, cannot increase but in
  • proportion to the increase of the funds which are destined to the payment
  • of wages. These funds are of two kinds, first, the revenue which is over
  • and above what is necessary for the maintenance; and, secondly, the stock
  • which is over and above what is necessary for the employment of their
  • masters.
  • When the landlord, annuitant, or monied man, has a greater revenue than
  • what he judges sufficient to maintain his own family, he employs either
  • the whole or a part of the surplus in maintaining one or more menial
  • servants. Increase this surplus, and he will naturally increase the number
  • of those servants.
  • When an independent workman, such as a weaver or shoemaker, has got more
  • stock than what is sufficient to purchase the materials of his own work,
  • and to maintain himself till he can dispose of it, he naturally employs
  • one or more journeymen with the surplus, in order to make a profit by
  • their work. Increase this surplus, and he will naturally increase the
  • number of his journeymen.
  • The demand for those who live by wages, therefore, necessarily increases
  • with the increase of the revenue and stock of every country, and cannot
  • possibly increase without it. The increase of revenue and stock is the
  • increase of national wealth. The demand for those who live by wages,
  • therefore, naturally increases with the increase of national wealth, and
  • cannot possibly increase without it.
  • It is not the actual greatness of national wealth, but its continual
  • increase, which occasions a rise in the wages of labour. It is not,
  • accordingly, in the richest countries, but in the most thriving, or in
  • those which are growing rich the fastest, that the wages of labour are
  • highest. England is certainly, in the present times, a much richer country
  • than any part of North America. The wages of labour, however, are much
  • higher in North America than in any part of England. In the province of
  • New York, common labourers earned in 1773, before the commencement of the
  • late disturbances, three shillings and sixpence currency, equal to two
  • shillings sterling, a-day; ship-carpenters, ten shillings and sixpence
  • currency, with a pint of rum, worth sixpence sterling, equal in all to six
  • shillings and sixpence sterling; house-carpenters and bricklayers, eight
  • shillings currency, equal to four shillings and sixpence sterling;
  • journeymen tailors, five shillings currency, equal to about two shillings
  • and tenpence sterling. These prices are all above the London price; and
  • wages are said to be as high in the other colonies as in New York. The
  • price of provisions is everywhere in North America much lower than in
  • England. A dearth has never been known there. In the worst seasons they
  • have always had a sufficiency for themselves, though less for exportation.
  • If the money price of labour, therefore, be higher than it is anywhere in
  • the mother-country, its real price, the real command of the necessaries
  • and conveniencies of life which it conveys to the labourer, must be higher
  • in a still greater proportion.
  • But though North America is not yet so rich as England, it is much more
  • thriving, and advancing with much greater rapidity to the further
  • acquisition of riches. The most decisive mark of the prosperity of any
  • country is the increase of the number of its inhabitants. In Great
  • Britain, and most other European countries, they are not supposed to
  • double in less than five hundred years. In the British colonies in North
  • America, it has been found that they double in twenty or five-and-twenty
  • years. Nor in the present times is this increase principally owing to the
  • continual importation of new inhabitants, but to the great multiplication
  • of the species. Those who live to old age, it is said, frequently see
  • there from fifty to a hundred, and sometimes many more, descendants from
  • their own body. Labour is there so well rewarded, that a numerous family
  • of children, instead of being a burden, is a source of opulence and
  • prosperity to the parents. The labour of each child, before it can leave
  • their house, is computed to be worth a hundred pounds clear gain to them.
  • A young widow with four or five young children, who, among the middling or
  • inferior ranks of people in Europe, would have so little chance for a
  • second husband, is there frequently courted as a sort of fortune. The
  • value of children is the greatest of all encouragements to marriage. We
  • cannot, therefore, wonder that the people in North America should
  • generally marry very young. Notwithstanding the great increase occasioned
  • by such early marriages, there is a continual complaint of the scarcity of
  • hands in North America. The demand for labourers, the funds destined for
  • maintaining them increase, it seems, still faster than they can find
  • labourers to employ.
  • Though the wealth of a country should be very great, yet if it has been
  • long stationary, we must not expect to find the wages of labour very high
  • in it. The funds destined for the payment of wages, the revenue and stock
  • of its inhabitants, may be of the greatest extent; but if they have
  • continued for several centuries of the same, or very nearly of the same
  • extent, the number of labourers employed every year could easily supply,
  • and even more than supply, the number wanted the following year. There
  • could seldom be any scarcity of hands, nor could the masters be obliged to
  • bid against one another in order to get them. The hands, on the contrary,
  • would, in this case, naturally multiply beyond their employment. There
  • would be a constant scarcity of employment, and the labourers would be
  • obliged to bid against one another in order to get it. If in such a
  • country the wages of labour had ever been more than sufficient to
  • maintain the labourer, and to enable him to bring up a family, the
  • competition of the labourers and the interest of the masters would soon
  • reduce them to the lowest rate which is consistent with common humanity.
  • China has been long one of the richest, that is, one of the most fertile,
  • best cultivated, most industrious, and most populous, countries in the
  • world. It seems, however, to have been long stationary. Marco Polo, who
  • visited it more than five hundred years ago, describes its cultivation,
  • industry, and populousness, almost in the same terms in which they are
  • described by travellers in the present times. It had, perhaps, even long
  • before his time, acquired that full complement of riches which the nature
  • of its laws and institutions permits it to acquire. The accounts of all
  • travellers, inconsistent in many other respects, agree in the low wages of
  • labour, and in the difficulty which a labourer finds in bringing up a
  • family in China. If by digging the ground a whole day he can get what will
  • purchase a small quantity of rice in the evening, he is contented. The
  • condition of artificers is, if possible, still worse. Instead of waiting
  • indolently in their work-houses for the calls of their customers, as in
  • Europe, they are continually running about the streets with the tools of
  • their respective trades, offering their services, and, as it were, begging
  • employment. The poverty of the lower ranks of people in China far
  • surpasses that of the most beggarly nations in Europe. In the
  • neighbourhood of Canton, many hundred, it is commonly said, many thousand
  • families have no habitation on the land, but live constantly in little
  • fishing-boats upon the rivers and canals. The subsistence which they find
  • there is so scanty, that they are eager to fish up the nastiest garbage
  • thrown overboard from any European ship. Any carrion, the carcase of a
  • dead dog or cat, for example, though half putrid and stinking, is as
  • welcome to them as the most wholesome food to the people of other
  • countries. Marriage is encouraged in China, not by the profitableness of
  • children, but by the liberty of destroying them. In all great towns,
  • several are every night exposed in the street, or drowned like puppies in
  • the water. The performance of this horrid office is even said to be the
  • avowed business by which some people earn their subsistence.
  • China, however, though it may, perhaps, stand still, does not seem to go
  • backwards. Its towns are nowhere deserted by their inhabitants. The lands
  • which had once been cultivated, are nowhere neglected. The same, or very
  • nearly the same, annual labour, must, therefore, continue to be performed,
  • and the funds destined for maintaining it must not, consequently, be
  • sensibly diminished. The lowest class of labourers, therefore,
  • notwithstanding their scanty subsistence, must some way or another make
  • shift to continue their race so far as to keep up their usual numbers.
  • But it would be otherwise in a country where the funds destined for the
  • maintenance of labour were sensibly decaying. Every year the demand for
  • servants and labourers would, in all the different classes of employments,
  • be less than it had been the year before. Many who had been bred in the
  • superior classes, not being able to find employment in their own business,
  • would be glad to seek it in the lowest. The lowest class being not only
  • overstocked with its own workmen, but with the overflowings of all the
  • other classes, the competition for employment would be so great in it, as
  • to reduce the wages of labour to the most miserable and scanty subsistence
  • of the labourer. Many would not be able to find employment even upon these
  • hard terms, but would either starve, or be driven to seek a subsistence,
  • either by begging, or by the perpetration perhaps, of the greatest
  • enormities. Want, famine, and mortality, would immediately prevail in that
  • class, and from thence extend themselves to all the superior classes, till
  • the number of inhabitants in the country was reduced to what could easily
  • be maintained by the revenue and stock which remained in it, and which had
  • escaped either the tyranny or calamity which had destroyed the rest. This,
  • perhaps, is nearly the present state of Bengal, and of some other of the
  • English settlements in the East Indies. In a fertile country, which had
  • before been much depopulated, where subsistence, consequently, should not
  • be very difficult, and where, notwithstanding, three or four hundred
  • thousand people die of hunger in one year, we may be assured that the funds
  • destined for the maintenance of the labouring poor are fast decaying. The
  • difference between the genius of the British constitution, which protects
  • and governs North America, and that of the mercantile company which
  • oppresses and domineers in the East Indies, cannot, perhaps, be better
  • illustrated than by the different state of those countries.
  • The liberal reward of labour, therefore, as it is the necessary effect, so
  • it is the natural symptom of increasing national wealth. The scanty
  • maintenance of the labouring poor, on the other hand, is the natural
  • symptom that things are at a stand, and their starving condition, that
  • they are going fast backwards.
  • In Great Britain, the wages of labour seem, in the present times, to be
  • evidently more than what is precisely necessary to enable the labourer to
  • bring up a family. In order to satisfy ourselves upon this point, it will
  • not be necessary to enter into any tedious or doubtful calculation of what
  • may be the lowest sum upon which it is possible to do this. There are many
  • plain symptoms, that the wages of labour are nowhere in this country
  • regulated by this lowest rate, which is consistent with common humanity.
  • First, in almost every part of Great Britain there is a distinction, even
  • in the lowest species of labour, between summer and winter wages. Summer
  • wages are always highest. But, on account of the extraordinary expense of
  • fuel, the maintenance of a family is most expensive in winter. Wages,
  • therefore, being highest when this expense is lowest, it seems evident
  • that they are not regulated by what is necessary for this expense, but by
  • the quantity and supposed value of the work. A labourer, it may be said,
  • indeed, ought to save part of his summer wages, in order to defray his
  • winter expense; and that, through the whole year, they do not exceed what
  • is necessary to maintain his family through the whole year. A slave,
  • however, or one absolutely dependent on us for immediate subsistence,
  • would not be treated in this manner. His daily subsistence would be
  • proportioned to his daily necessities.
  • Secondly, the wages of labour do not, in Great Britain, fluctuate with the
  • price of provisions. These vary everywhere from year to year, frequently
  • from month to month. But in many places, the money price of labour remains
  • uniformly the same, sometimes for half a century together. If, in these
  • places, therefore, the labouring poor can maintain their families in dear
  • years, they must be at their ease in times of moderate plenty, and in
  • affluence in those of extraordinary cheapness. The high price of
  • provisions during these ten years past, has not, in many parts of the
  • kingdom, been accompanied with any sensible rise in the money price of
  • labour. It has, indeed, in some; owing, probably, more to the increase of
  • the demand for labour, than to that of the price of provisions.
  • Thirdly, as the price of provisions varies more from year to year than the
  • wages of labour, so, on the other hand, the wages of labour vary more from
  • place to place than the price of provisions. The prices of bread and
  • butchers’ meat are generally the same, or very nearly the same, through
  • the greater part of the united kingdom. These, and most other things which
  • are sold by retail, the way in which the labouring poor buy all things,
  • are generally fully as cheap, or cheaper, in great towns than in the
  • remoter parts of the country, for reasons which I shall have occasion to
  • explain hereafter. But the wages of labour in a great town and its
  • neighbourhood are frequently a fourth or a fifth part, twenty or five-and—twenty
  • per cent. higher than at a few miles distance. Eighteen pence a day may be
  • reckoned the common price of labour in London and its neighbourhood. At a
  • few miles distance, it falls to fourteen and fifteen pence. Tenpence may
  • be reckoned its price in Edinburgh and its neighbourhood. At a few miles
  • distance, it falls to eightpence, the usual price of common labour through
  • the greater part of the low country of Scotland, where it varies a good
  • deal less than in England. Such a difference of prices, which, it seems,
  • is not always sufficient to transport a man from one parish to another,
  • would necessarily occasion so great a transportation of the most bulky
  • commodities, not only from one parish to another, but from one end of the
  • kingdom, almost from one end of the world to the other, as would soon
  • reduce them more nearly to a level. After all that has been said of the
  • levity and inconstancy of human nature, it appears evidently from
  • experience, that man is, of all sorts of luggage, the most difficult to be
  • transported. If the labouring poor, therefore, can maintain their families
  • in those parts of the kingdom where the price of labour is lowest, they
  • must be in affluence where it is highest.
  • Fourthly, the variations in the price of labour not only do not
  • correspond, either in place or time, with those in the price of
  • provisions, but they are frequently quite opposite.
  • Grain, the food of the common people, is dearer in Scotland than in
  • England, whence Scotland receives almost every year very large supplies.
  • But English corn must be sold dearer in Scotland, the country to which it
  • is brought, than in England, the country from which it comes; and in
  • proportion to its quality it cannot be sold dearer in Scotland than the
  • Scotch corn that comes to the same market in competition with it. The
  • quality of grain depends chiefly upon the quantity of flour or meal which
  • it yields at the mill; and, in this respect, English grain is so much
  • superior to the Scotch, that though often dearer in appearance, or in
  • proportion to the measure of its bulk, it is generally cheaper in reality,
  • or in proportion to its quality, or even to the measure of its weight. The
  • price of labour, on the contrary, is dearer in England than in Scotland.
  • If the labouring poor, therefore, can maintain their families in the one
  • part of the united kingdom, they must be in affluence in the other.
  • Oatmeal, indeed, supplies the common people in Scotland with the greatest
  • and the best part of their food, which is, in general, much inferior to
  • that of their neighbours of the same rank in England. This difference,
  • however, in the mode of their subsistence, is not the cause, but the
  • effect, of the difference in their wages; though, by a strange
  • misapprehension, I have frequently heard it represented as the cause. It
  • is not because one man keeps a coach, while his neighbour walks a-foot,
  • that the one is rich, and the other poor; but because the one is rich, he
  • keeps a coach, and because the other is poor, he walks a-foot.
  • During the course of the last century, taking one year with another, grain
  • was dearer in both parts of the united kingdom than during that of the
  • present. This is a matter of fact which cannot now admit of any reasonable
  • doubt; and the proof of it is, if possible, still more decisive with
  • regard to Scotland than with regard to England. It is in Scotland
  • supported by the evidence of the public fiars, annual valuations made upon
  • oath, according to the actual state of the markets, of all the different
  • sorts of grain in every different county of Scotland. If such direct proof
  • could require any collateral evidence to confirm it, I would observe, that
  • this has likewise been the case in France, and probably in most other
  • parts of Europe. With regard to France, there is the clearest proof. But
  • though it is certain, that in both parts of the united kingdom grain was
  • somewhat dearer in the last century than in the present, it is equally
  • certain that labour was much cheaper. If the labouring poor, therefore,
  • could bring up their families then, they must be much more at their ease
  • now. In the last century, the most usual day-wages of common labour
  • through the greater part of Scotland were sixpence in summer, and
  • fivepence in winter. Three shillings a-week, the same price, very nearly
  • still continues to be paid in some parts of the Highlands and Western
  • islands. Through the greater part of the Low country, the most usual wages
  • of common labour are now eight pence a-day; tenpence, sometimes a
  • shilling, about Edinburgh, in the counties which border upon England,
  • probably on account of that neighbourhood, and in a few other places where
  • there has lately been a considerable rise in the demand for labour, about
  • Glasgow, Carron, Ayrshire, etc. In England, the improvements of
  • agriculture, manufactures, and commerce, began much earlier than in
  • Scotland. The demand for labour, and consequently its price, must
  • necessarily have increased with those improvements. In the last century,
  • accordingly, as well as in the present, the wages of labour were higher in
  • England than in Scotland. They have risen, too, considerably since that
  • time, though, on account of the greater variety of wages paid there in
  • different places, it is more difficult to ascertain how much. In 1614, the
  • pay of a foot soldier was the same as in the present times, eightpence
  • a-day. When it was first established, it would naturally be regulated by
  • the usual wages of common labourers, the rank of people from which foot
  • soldiers are commonly drawn. Lord-chief-justice Hales, who wrote in the
  • time of Charles II. computes the necessary expense of a labourer’s family,
  • consisting of six persons, the father and mother, two children able to do
  • something, and two not able, at ten shillings a-week, or twenty-six pounds
  • a-year. If they cannot earn this by their labour, they must make it up, he
  • supposes, either by begging or stealing. He appears to have enquired very
  • carefully into this subject {See his scheme for the maintenance of the
  • poor, in Burn’s History of the Poor Laws.}. In 1688, Mr Gregory King,
  • whose skill in political arithmetic is so much extolled by Dr Davenant,
  • computed the ordinary income of labourers and out-servants to be fifteen
  • pounds a-year to a family, which he supposed to consist, one with another,
  • of three and a half persons. His calculation, therefore, though different
  • in appearance, corresponds very nearly at bottom with that of Judge Hales.
  • Both suppose the weekly expense of such families to be about twenty-pence
  • a-head. Both the pecuniary income and expense of such families have
  • increased considerably since that time through the greater part of the
  • kingdom, in some places more, and in some less, though perhaps scarce
  • anywhere so much as some exaggerated accounts of the present wages of
  • labour have lately represented them to the public. The price of labour, it
  • must be observed, cannot be ascertained very accurately anywhere,
  • different prices being often paid at the same place and for the same sort
  • of labour, not only according to the different abilities of the workman,
  • but according to the easiness or hardness of the masters. Where wages are
  • not regulated by law, all that we can pretend to determine is, what are
  • the most usual; and experience seems to shew that law can never regulate
  • them properly, though it has often pretended to do so.
  • The real recompence of labour, the real quantity of the necessaries and
  • conveniencies of life which it can procure to the labourer, has, during
  • the course of the present century, increased perhaps in a still greater
  • proportion than its money price. Not only grain has become somewhat
  • cheaper, but many other things, from which the industrious poor derive an
  • agreeable and wholesome variety of food, have become a great deal cheaper.
  • Potatoes, for example, do not at present, through the greater part of the
  • kingdom, cost half the price which they used to do thirty or forty years
  • ago. The same thing may be said of turnips, carrots, cabbages; things
  • which were formerly never raised but by the spade, but which are now
  • commonly raised by the plough. All sort of garden stuff, too, has become
  • cheaper. The greater part of the apples, and even of the onions, consumed
  • in Great Britain, were, in the last century, imported from Flanders. The
  • great improvements in the coarser manufactories of both linen and woollen
  • cloth furnish the labourers with cheaper and better clothing; and those in
  • the manufactories of the coarser metals, with cheaper and better
  • instruments of trade, as well as with many agreeable and convenient pieces
  • of household furniture. Soap, salt, candles, leather, and fermented
  • liquors, have, indeed, become a good deal dearer, chiefly from the taxes
  • which have been laid upon them. The quantity of these, however, which the
  • labouring poor are under any necessity of consuming, is so very small, that
  • the increase in their price does not compensate the diminution in that of
  • so many other things. The common complaint, that luxury extends itself
  • even to the lowest ranks of the people, and that the labouring poor will
  • not now be contented with the same food, clothing, and lodging, which
  • satisfied them in former times, may convince us that it is not the money
  • price of labour only, but its real recompence, which has augmented.
  • Is this improvement in the circumstances of the lower ranks of the people
  • to be regarded as an advantage, or as an inconveniency, to the society?
  • The answer seems at first abundantly plain. Servants, labourers, and
  • workmen of different kinds, make up the far greater part of every great
  • political society. But what improves the circumstances of the greater
  • part, can never be regarded as any inconveniency to the whole. No society
  • can surely be flourishing and happy, of which the far greater part of the
  • members are poor and miserable. It is but equity, besides, that they who
  • feed, clothe, and lodge the whole body of the people, should have such a
  • share of the produce of their own labour as to be themselves tolerably
  • well fed, clothed, and lodged.
  • Poverty, though it no doubt discourages, does not always prevent,
  • marriage. It seems even to be favourable to generation. A half-starved
  • Highland woman frequently bears more than twenty children, while a
  • pampered fine lady is often incapable of bearing any, and is generally
  • exhausted by two or three. Barrenness, so frequent among women of fashion,
  • is very rare among those of inferior station. Luxury, in the fair sex,
  • while it inflames, perhaps, the passion for enjoyment, seems always to
  • weaken, and frequently to destroy altogether, the powers of generation.
  • But poverty, though it does not prevent the generation, is extremely
  • unfavourable to the rearing of children. The tender plant is produced; but
  • in so cold a soil, and so severe a climate, soon withers and dies. It is
  • not uncommon, I have been frequently told, in the Highlands of Scotland,
  • for a mother who has born twenty children not to have two alive. Several
  • officers of great experience have assured me, that, so far from recruiting
  • their regiment, they have never been able to supply it with drums and
  • fifes, from all the soldiers’ children that were born in it. A greater
  • number of fine children, however, is seldom seen anywhere than about a
  • barrack of soldiers. Very few of them, it seems, arrive at the age of
  • thirteen or fourteen. In some places, one half the children die before
  • they are four years of age, in many places before they are seven, and in
  • almost all places before they are nine or ten. This great mortality,
  • however will everywhere be found chiefly among the children of the common
  • people, who cannot afford to tend them with the same care as those of
  • better station. Though their marriages are generally more fruitful than
  • those of people of fashion, a smaller proportion of their children arrive
  • at maturity. In foundling hospitals, and among the children brought up by
  • parish charities, the mortality is still greater than among those of the
  • common people.
  • Every species of animals naturally multiplies in proportion to the means
  • of their subsistence, and no species can ever multiply beyond it. But in
  • civilized society, it is only among the inferior ranks of people that the
  • scantiness of subsistence can set limits to the further multiplication of
  • the human species; and it can do so in no other way than by destroying a
  • great part of the children which their fruitful marriages produce.
  • The liberal reward of labour, by enabling them to provide better for their
  • children, and consequently to bring up a greater number, naturally tends
  • to widen and extend those limits. It deserves to be remarked, too, that it
  • necessarily does this as nearly as possible in the proportion which the
  • demand for labour requires. If this demand is continually increasing, the
  • reward of labour must necessarily encourage in such a manner the marriage
  • and multiplication of labourers, as may enable them to supply that
  • continually increasing demand by a continually increasing population. If
  • the reward should at any time be less than what was requisite for this
  • purpose, the deficiency of hands would soon raise it; and if it should at
  • any time be more, their excessive multiplication would soon lower it to
  • this necessary rate. The market would be so much understocked with labour
  • in the one case, and so much overstocked in the other, as would soon force
  • back its price to that proper rate which the circumstances of the society
  • required. It is in this manner that the demand for men, like that for any
  • other commodity, necessarily regulates the production of men, quickens it
  • when it goes on too slowly, and stops it when it advances too fast. It is
  • this demand which regulates and determines the state of propagation in all
  • the different countries of the world; in North America, in Europe, and in
  • China; which renders it rapidly progressive in the first, slow and gradual
  • in the second, and altogether stationary in the last.
  • The wear and tear of a slave, it has been said, is at the expense of his
  • master; but that of a free servant is at his own expense. The wear and
  • tear of the latter, however, is, in reality, as much at the expense of his
  • master as that of the former. The wages paid to journeymen and servants of
  • every kind must be such as may enable them, one with another to continue
  • the race of journeymen and servants, according as the increasing,
  • diminishing, or stationary demand of the society, may happen to require.
  • But though the wear and tear of a free servant be equally at the expense
  • of his master, it generally costs him much less than that of a slave. The
  • fund destined for replacing or repairing, if I may say so, the wear and
  • tear of the slave, is commonly managed by a negligent master or careless
  • overseer. That destined for performing the same office with regard to the
  • freeman is managed by the freeman himself. The disorders which generally
  • prevail in the economy of the rich, naturally introduce themselves into
  • the management of the former; the strict frugality and parsimonious
  • attention of the poor as naturally establish themselves in that of the
  • latter. Under such different management, the same purpose must require
  • very different degrees of expense to execute it. It appears, accordingly,
  • from the experience of all ages and nations, I believe, that the work done
  • by freemen comes cheaper in the end than that performed by slaves. It is
  • found to do so even at Boston, New-York, and Philadelphia, where the wages
  • of common labour are so very high.
  • The liberal reward of labour, therefore, as it is the effect of increasing
  • wealth, so it is the cause of increasing population. To complain of it, is
  • to lament over the necessary cause and effect of the greatest public
  • prosperity.
  • It deserves to be remarked, perhaps, that it is in the progressive state,
  • while the society is advancing to the further acquisition, rather than
  • when it has acquired its full complement of riches, that the condition of
  • the labouring poor, of the great body of the people, seems to be the
  • happiest and the most comfortable. It is hard in the stationary, and
  • miserable in the declining state. The progressive state is, in reality,
  • the cheerful and the hearty state to all the different orders of the
  • society; the stationary is dull; the declining melancholy.
  • The liberal reward of labour, as it encourages the propagation, so it
  • increases the industry of the common people. The wages of labour are the
  • encouragement of industry, which, like every other human quality, improves
  • in proportion to the encouragement it receives. A plentiful subsistence
  • increases the bodily strength of the labourer, and the comfortable hope of
  • bettering his condition, and of ending his days, perhaps, in ease and
  • plenty, animates him to exert that strength to the utmost. Where wages are
  • high, accordingly, we shall always find the workmen more active, diligent,
  • and expeditious, than where they are low; in England, for example, than in
  • Scotland; in the neighbourhood of great towns, than in remote country
  • places. Some workmen, indeed, when they can earn in four days what will
  • maintain them through the week, will be idle the other three. This,
  • however, is by no means the case with the greater part. Workmen, on the
  • contrary, when they are liberally paid by the piece, are very apt to
  • overwork themselves, and to ruin their health and constitution in a few
  • years. A carpenter in London, and in some other places, is not supposed to
  • last in his utmost vigour above eight years. Something of the same kind
  • happens in many other trades, in which the workmen are paid by the piece;
  • as they generally are in manufactures, and even in country labour,
  • wherever wages are higher than ordinary. Almost every class of artificers
  • is subject to some peculiar infirmity occasioned by excessive application
  • to their peculiar species of work. Ramuzzini, an eminent Italian
  • physician, has written a particular book concerning such diseases. We do
  • not reckon our soldiers the most industrious set of people among us; yet
  • when soldiers have been employed in some particular sorts of work, and
  • liberally paid by the piece, their officers have frequently been obliged
  • to stipulate with the undertaker, that they should not be allowed to earn
  • above a certain sum every day, according to the rate at which they were
  • paid. Till this stipulation was made, mutual emulation, and the desire of
  • greater gain, frequently prompted them to overwork themselves, and to hurt
  • their health by excessive labour. Excessive application, during four days
  • of the week, is frequently the real cause of the idleness of the other
  • three, so much and so loudly complained of. Great labour, either of mind
  • or body, continued for several days together is, in most men, naturally
  • followed by a great desire of relaxation, which, if not restrained by
  • force, or by some strong necessity, is almost irresistible. It is the call
  • of nature, which requires to be relieved by some indulgence, sometimes of
  • ease only, but sometimes too of dissipation and diversion. If it is not
  • complied with, the consequences are often dangerous and sometimes fatal,
  • and such as almost always, sooner or later, bring on the peculiar
  • infirmity of the trade. If masters would always listen to the dictates of
  • reason and humanity, they have frequently occasion rather to moderate,
  • than to animate the application of many of their workmen. It will be
  • found, I believe, in every sort of trade, that the man who works so
  • moderately, as to be able to work constantly, not only preserves his
  • health the longest, but, in the course of the year, executes the greatest
  • quantity of work.
  • In cheap years it is pretended, workmen are generally more idle, and in
  • dear times more industrious than ordinary. A plentiful subsistence,
  • therefore, it has been concluded, relaxes, and a scanty one quickens their
  • industry. That a little more plenty than ordinary may render some workmen
  • idle, cannot be well doubted; but that it should have this effect upon the
  • greater part, or that men in general should work better when they are ill
  • fed, than when they are well fed, when they are disheartened than when
  • they are in good spirits, when they are frequently sick than when they are
  • generally in good health, seems not very probable. Years of dearth, it is
  • to be observed, are generally among the common people years of sickness
  • and mortality, which cannot fail to diminish the produce of their
  • industry.
  • In years of plenty, servants frequently leave their masters, and trust
  • their subsistence to what they can make by their own industry. But the
  • same cheapness of provisions, by increasing the fund which is destined for
  • the maintenance of servants, encourages masters, farmers especially, to
  • employ a greater number. Farmers, upon such occasions, expect more profit
  • from their corn by maintaining a few more labouring servants, than by
  • selling it at a low price in the market. The demand for servants
  • increases, while the number of those who offer to supply that demand
  • diminishes. The price of labour, therefore, frequently rises in cheap
  • years.
  • In years of scarcity, the difficulty and uncertainty of subsistence make
  • all such people eager to return to service. But the high price of
  • provisions, by diminishing the funds destined for the maintenance of
  • servants, disposes masters rather to diminish than to increase the number
  • of those they have. In dear years, too, poor independent workmen
  • frequently consume the little stock with which they had used to supply
  • themselves with the materials of their work, and are obliged to become
  • journeymen for subsistence. More people want employment than easily get
  • it; many are willing to take it upon lower terms than ordinary; and the
  • wages of both servants and journeymen frequently sink in dear years.
  • Masters of all sorts, therefore, frequently make better bargains with
  • their servants in dear than in cheap years, and find them more humble and
  • dependent in the former than in the latter. They naturally, therefore,
  • commend the former as more favourable to industry. Landlords and farmers,
  • besides, two of the largest classes of masters, have another reason for
  • being pleased with dear years. The rents of the one, and the profits of
  • the other, depend very much upon the price of provisions. Nothing can be
  • more absurd, however, than to imagine that men in general should work less
  • when they work for themselves, than when they work for other people. A
  • poor independent workman will generally be more industrious than even a
  • journeyman who works by the piece. The one enjoys the whole produce of his
  • own industry, the other shares it with his master. The one, in his
  • separate independent state, is less liable to the temptations of bad
  • company, which, in large manufactories, so frequently ruin the morals of
  • the other. The superiority of the independent workman over those servants
  • who are hired by the month or by the year, and whose wages and maintenance
  • are the same, whether they do much or do little, is likely to be still
  • greater. Cheap years tend to increase the proportion of independent
  • workmen to journeymen and servants of all kinds, and dear years to
  • diminish it.
  • A French author of great knowledge and ingenuity, Mr Messance, receiver of
  • the tallies in the election of St Etienne, endeavours to shew that the
  • poor do more work in cheap than in dear years, by comparing the quantity
  • and value of the goods made upon those different occasions in three
  • different manufactures; one of coarse woollens, carried on at Elbeuf; one
  • of linen, and another of silk, both which extend through the whole
  • generality of Rouen. It appears from his account, which is copied from the
  • registers of the public offices, that the quantity and value of the goods
  • made in all those three manufactories has generally been greater in cheap
  • than in dear years, and that it has always been greatest in the cheapest,
  • and least in the dearest years. All the three seem to be stationary
  • manufactures, or which, though their produce may vary somewhat from year
  • to year, are, upon the whole, neither going backwards nor forwards.
  • The manufacture of linen in Scotland, and that of coarse woollens in the
  • West Riding of Yorkshire, are growing manufactures, of which the produce
  • is generally, though with some variations, increasing both in quantity and
  • value. Upon examining, however, the accounts which have been published of
  • their annual produce, I have not been able to observe that its variations
  • have had any sensible connection with the dearness or cheapness of the
  • seasons. In 1740, a year of great scarcity, both manufactures, indeed,
  • appear to have declined very considerably. But in 1756, another year of
  • great scarcity, the Scotch manufactures made more than ordinary advances.
  • The Yorkshire manufacture, indeed, declined, and its produce did not rise
  • to what it had been in 1755, till 1766, after the repeal of the American
  • stamp act. In that and the following year, it greatly exceeded what it had
  • ever been before, and it has continued to advance ever since.
  • The produce of all great manufactures for distant sale must necessarily
  • depend, not so much upon the dearness or cheapness of the seasons in the
  • countries where they are carried on, as upon the circumstances which
  • affect the demand in the countries where they are consumed; upon peace or
  • war, upon the prosperity or declension of other rival manufactures and
  • upon the good or bad humour of their principal customers. A great part of
  • the extraordinary work, besides, which is probably done in cheap years,
  • never enters the public registers of manufactures. The men-servants, who
  • leave their masters, become independent labourers. The women return to
  • their parents, and commonly spin, in order to make clothes for themselves
  • and their families. Even the independent workmen do not always, work for
  • public sale, but are employed by some of their neighbours in manufactures
  • for family use. The produce of their labour, therefore, frequently makes
  • no figure in those public registers, of which the records are sometimes
  • published with so much parade, and from which our merchants and
  • manufacturers would often vainly pretend to announce the prosperity or
  • declension of the greatest empires.
  • Though the variations in the price of labour not only do not always
  • correspond with those in the price of provisions, but are frequently quite
  • opposite, we must not, upon this account, imagine that the price of
  • provisions has no influence upon that of labour. The money price of labour
  • is necessarily regulated by two circumstances; the demand for labour, and
  • the price of the necessaries and conveniencies of life. The demand for
  • labour, according as it happens to be increasing, stationary, or
  • declining, or to require an increasing, stationary, or declining
  • population, determines the quantities of the necessaries and conveniencies
  • of life which must be given to the labourer; and the money price of labour
  • is determined by what is requisite for purchasing this quantity. Though
  • the money price of labour, therefore, is sometimes high where the price of
  • provisions is low, it would be still higher, the demand continuing the
  • same, if the price of provisions was high.
  • It is because the demand for labour increases in years of sudden and
  • extraordinary plenty, and diminishes in those of sudden and extraordinary
  • scarcity, that the money price of labour sometimes rises in the one, and
  • sinks in the other.
  • In a year of sudden and extraordinary plenty, there are funds in the hands
  • of many of the employers of industry, sufficient to maintain and employ a
  • greater number of industrious people than had been employed the year
  • before; and this extraordinary number cannot always be had. Those masters,
  • therefore, who want more workmen, bid against one another, in order to get
  • them, which sometimes raises both the real and the money price of their
  • labour.
  • The contrary of this happens in a year of sudden and extraordinary
  • scarcity. The funds destined for employing industry are less than they had
  • been the year before. A considerable number of people are thrown out of
  • employment, who bid one against another, in order to get it, which
  • sometimes lowers both the real and the money price of labour. In 1740, a
  • year of extraordinary scarcity, many people were willing to work for bare
  • subsistence. In the succeeding years of plenty, it was more difficult to
  • get labourers and servants. The scarcity of a dear year, by diminishing
  • the demand for labour, tends to lower its price, as the high price of
  • provisions tends to raise it. The plenty of a cheap year, on the contrary,
  • by increasing the demand, tends to raise the price of labour, as the
  • cheapness of provisions tends to lower it. In the ordinary variations of
  • the prices of provisions, those two opposite causes seem to counterbalance
  • one another, which is probably, in part, the reason why the wages of
  • labour are everywhere so much more steady and permanent than the price of
  • provisions.
  • The increase in the wages of labour necessarily increases the price of
  • many commodities, by increasing that part of it which resolves itself into
  • wages, and so far tends to diminish their consumption, both at home and
  • abroad. The same cause, however, which raises the wages of labour, the
  • increase of stock, tends to increase its productive powers, and to make a
  • smaller quantity of labour produce a greater quantity of work. The owner
  • of the stock which employs a great number of labourers necessarily
  • endeavours, for his own advantage, to make such a proper division and
  • distribution of employment, that they may be enabled to produce the
  • greatest quantity of work possible. For the same reason, he endeavours to
  • supply them with the best machinery which either he or they can think of.
  • What takes place among the labourers in a particular workhouse, takes
  • place, for the same reason, among those of a great society. The greater
  • their number, the more they naturally divide themselves into different
  • classes and subdivisions of employments. More heads are occupied in
  • inventing the most proper machinery for executing the work of each, and it
  • is, therefore, more likely to be invented. There are many commodities,
  • therefore, which, in consequence of these improvements, come to be
  • produced by so much less labour than before, that the increase of its
  • price is more than compensated by the diminution of its quantity.
  • CHAPTER IX.
  • OF THE PROFITS OF STOCK.
  • The rise and fall in the profits of stock depend upon the same causes with
  • the rise and fall in the wages of labour, the increasing or declining
  • state of the wealth of the society; but those causes affect the one and
  • the other very differently.
  • The increase of stock, which raises wages, tends to lower profit. When the
  • stocks of many rich merchants are turned into the same trade, their mutual
  • competition naturally tends to lower its profit; and when there is a like
  • increase of stock in all the different trades carried on in the same
  • society, the same competition must produce the same effect in them all.
  • It is not easy, it has already been observed, to ascertain what are the
  • average wages of labour, even in a particular place, and at a particular
  • time. We can, even in this case, seldom determine more than what are the
  • most usual wages. But even this can seldom be done with regard to the
  • profits of stock. Profit is so very fluctuating, that the person who
  • carries on a particular trade, cannot always tell you himself what is the
  • average of his annual profit. It is affected, not only by every variation
  • of price in the commodities which he deals in, but by the good or bad
  • fortune both of his rivals and of his customers, and by a thousand other
  • accidents, to which goods, when carried either by sea or by land, or even
  • when stored in a warehouse, are liable. It varies, therefore, not only
  • from year to year, but from day to day, and almost from hour to hour. To
  • ascertain what is the average profit of all the different trades carried
  • on in a great kingdom, must be much more difficult; and to judge of what
  • it may have been formerly, or in remote periods of time, with any degree
  • of precision, must be altogether impossible.
  • But though it may be impossible to determine, with any degree of
  • precision, what are or were the average profits of stock, either in the
  • present or in ancient times, some notion may be formed of them from the
  • interest of money. It may be laid down as a maxim, that wherever a great
  • deal can be made by the use of money, a great deal will commonly be given
  • for the use of it; and that, wherever little can be made by it, less will
  • commonly he given for it. Accordingly, therefore, as the usual market rate
  • of interest varies in any country, we may be assured that the ordinary
  • profits of stock must vary with it, must sink as it sinks, and rise as it
  • rises. The progress of interest, therefore, may lead us to form some
  • notion of the progress of profit.
  • By the 37th of Henry VIII. all interest above ten per cent. was declared
  • unlawful. More, it seems, had sometimes been taken before that. In the
  • reign of Edward VI. religious zeal prohibited all interest. This
  • prohibition, however, like all others of the same kind, is said to have
  • produced no effect, and probably rather increased than diminished the evil
  • of usury. The statute of Henry VIII. was revived by the 13th of Elizabeth,
  • cap. 8. and ten per cent. continued to be the legal rate of interest till
  • the 21st of James I. when it was restricted to eight per cent. It was
  • reduced to six per cent. soon after the Restoration, and by the 12th of
  • Queen Anne, to five per cent. All these different statutory regulations
  • seem to have been made with great propriety. They seem to have followed,
  • and not to have gone before, the market rate of interest, or the rate at
  • which people of good credit usually borrowed. Since the time of Queen
  • Anne, five per cent. seems to have been rather above than below the market
  • rate. Before the late war, the government borrowed at three per cent.; and
  • people of good credit in the capital, and in many other parts of the
  • kingdom, at three and a-half, four, and four and a-half per cent.
  • Since the time of Henry VIII. the wealth and revenue of the country have
  • been continually advancing, and in the course of their progress, their
  • pace seems rather to have been gradually accelerated than retarded. They
  • seem not only to have been going on, but to have been going on faster and
  • faster. The wages of labour have been continually increasing during the
  • same period, and, in the greater part of the different branches of trade
  • and manufactures, the profits of stock have been diminishing.
  • It generally requires a greater stock to carry on any sort of trade in a
  • great town than in a country village. The great stocks employed in every
  • branch of trade, and the number of rich competitors, generally reduce the
  • rate of profit in the former below what it is in the latter. But the wages
  • of labour are generally higher in a great town than in a country village.
  • In a thriving town, the people who have great stocks to employ, frequently
  • cannot get the number of workmen they want, and therefore bid against one
  • another, in order to get as many as they can, which raises the wages of
  • labour, and lowers the profits of stock. In the remote parts of the
  • country, there is frequently not stock sufficient to employ all the
  • people, who therefore bid against one another, in order to get employment,
  • which lowers the wages of labour, and raises the profits of stock.
  • In Scotland, though the legal rate of interest is the same as in England,
  • the market rate is rather higher. People of the best credit there seldom
  • borrow under five per cent. Even private bankers in Edinburgh give four
  • per cent. upon their promissory-notes, of which payment, either in whole
  • or in part may be demanded at pleasure. Private bankers in London give no
  • interest for the money which is deposited with them. There are few trades
  • which cannot be carried on with a smaller stock in Scotland than in
  • England. The common rate of profit, therefore, must be somewhat greater.
  • The wages of labour, it has already been observed, are lower in Scotland
  • than in England. The country, too, is not only much poorer, but the steps
  • by which it advances to a better condition, for it is evidently advancing,
  • seem to be much slower and more tardy. The legal rate of interest in
  • France has not during the course of the present century, been always
  • regulated by the market rate {See Denisart, Article Taux des Interests,
  • tom. iii, p.13}. In 1720, interest was reduced from the twentieth to the
  • fiftieth penny, or from five to two per cent. In 1724, it was raised to
  • the thirtieth penny, or to three and a third per cent. In 1725, it was
  • again raised to the twentieth penny, or to five per cent. In 1766, during
  • the administration of Mr Laverdy, it was reduced to the twenty-fifth
  • penny, or to four per cent. The Abbé Terray raised it afterwards to the
  • old rate of five per cent. The supposed purpose of many of those violent
  • reductions of interest was to prepare the way for reducing that of the
  • public debts; a purpose which has sometimes been executed. France is,
  • perhaps, in the present times, not so rich a country as England; and
  • though the legal rate of interest has in France frequently been lower than
  • in England, the market rate has generally been higher; for there, as in
  • other countries, they have several very safe and easy methods of evading
  • the law. The profits of trade, I have been assured by British merchants
  • who had traded in both countries, are higher in France than in England;
  • and it is no doubt upon this account, that many British subjects chuse
  • rather to employ their capitals in a country where trade is in disgrace,
  • than in one where it is highly respected. The wages of labour are lower in
  • France than in England. When you go from Scotland to England, the
  • difference which you may remark between the dress and countenance of the
  • common people in the one country and in the other, sufficiently indicates
  • the difference in their condition. The contrast is still greater when you
  • return from France. France, though no doubt a richer country than
  • Scotland, seems not to be going forward so fast. It is a common and even a
  • popular opinion in the country, that it is going backwards; an opinion
  • which I apprehend, is ill-founded, even with regard to France, but which
  • nobody can possibly entertain with regard to Scotland, who sees the
  • country now, and who saw it twenty or thirty years ago.
  • The province of Holland, on the other hand, in proportion to the extent of
  • its territory and the number of its people, is a richer country than
  • England. The government there borrow at two per cent. and private people
  • of good credit at three. The wages of labour are said to be higher in
  • Holland than in England, and the Dutch, it is well known, trade upon lower
  • profits than any people in Europe. The trade of Holland, it has been
  • pretended by some people, is decaying, and it may perhaps be true that
  • some particular branches of it are so; but these symptoms seem to indicate
  • sufficiently that there is no general decay. When profit diminishes,
  • merchants are very apt to complain that trade decays, though the
  • diminution of profit is the natural effect of its prosperity, or of a
  • greater stock being employed in it than before. During the late war, the
  • Dutch gained the whole carrying trade of France, of which they still
  • retain a very large share. The great property which they possess both in
  • French and English funds, about forty millions, it is said in the latter
  • (in which, I suspect, however, there is a considerable exaggeration ), the
  • great sums which they lend to private people, in countries where the rate
  • of interest is higher than in their own, are circumstances which no doubt
  • demonstrate the redundancy of their stock, or that it has increased beyond
  • what they can employ with tolerable profit in the proper business of their
  • own country; but they do not demonstrate that that business has decreased.
  • As the capital of a private man, though acquired by a particular trade,
  • may increase beyond what he can employ in it, and yet that trade continue
  • to increase too, so may likewise the capital of a great nation.
  • In our North American and West Indian colonies, not only the wages of
  • labour, but the interest of money, and consequently the profits of stock,
  • are higher than in England. In the different colonies, both the legal and
  • the market rate of interest run from six to eight percent. High wages of
  • labour and high profits of stock, however, are things, perhaps, which
  • scarce ever go together, except in the peculiar circumstances of new
  • colonies. A new colony must always, for some time, be more understocked in
  • proportion to the extent of its territory, and more underpeopled in
  • proportion to the extent of its stock, than the greater part of other
  • countries. They have more land than they have stock to cultivate. What
  • they have, therefore, is applied to the cultivation only of what is most
  • fertile and most favourably situated, the land near the sea-shore, and
  • along the banks of navigable rivers. Such land, too, is frequently
  • purchased at a price below the value even of its natural produce. Stock
  • employed in the purchase and improvement of such lands, must yield a very
  • large profit, and, consequently, afford to pay a very large interest. Its
  • rapid accumulation in so profitable an employment enables the planter to
  • increase the number of his hands faster than he can find them in a new
  • settlement. Those whom he can find, therefore, are very liberally
  • rewarded. As the colony increases, the profits of stock gradually
  • diminish. When the most fertile and best situated lands have been all
  • occupied, less profit can be made by the cultivation of what is inferior
  • both in soil and situation, and less interest can be afforded for the
  • stock which is so employed. In the greater part of our colonies,
  • accordingly, both the legal and the market rate of interest have been
  • considerably reduced during the course of the present century. As riches,
  • improvement, and population, have increased, interest has declined. The
  • wages of labour do not sink with the profits of stock. The demand for
  • labour increases with the increase of stock, whatever be its profits; and
  • after these are diminished, stock may not only continue to increase, but
  • to increase much faster than before. It is with industrious nations, who
  • are advancing in the acquisition of riches, as with industrious
  • individuals. A great stock, though with small profits, generally increases
  • faster than a small stock with great profits. Money, says the proverb,
  • makes money. When you have got a little, it is often easy to get more. The
  • great difficulty is to get that little. The connection between the
  • increase of stock and that of industry, or of the demand for useful
  • labour, has partly been explained already, but will be explained more
  • fully hereafter, in treating of the accumulation of stock.
  • The acquisition of new territory, or of new branches of trade, may
  • sometimes raise the profits of stock, and with them the interest of money,
  • even in a country which is fast advancing in the acquisition of riches.
  • The stock of the country, not being sufficient for the whole accession of
  • business which such acquisitions present to the different people among
  • whom it is divided, is applied to those particular branches only which
  • afford the greatest profit. Part of what had before been employed in other
  • trades, is necessarily withdrawn from them, and turned into some of the
  • new and more profitable ones. In all those old trades, therefore, the
  • competition comes to be less than before. The market comes to be less
  • fully supplied with many different sorts of goods. Their price necessarily
  • rises more or less, and yields a greater profit to those who deal in them,
  • who can, therefore, afford to borrow at a higher interest. For some time
  • after the conclusion of the late war, not only private people of the best
  • credit, but some of the greatest companies in London, commonly borrowed at
  • five per cent. who, before that, had not been used to pay more than four,
  • and four and a half per cent. The great accession both of territory and
  • trade by our acquisitions in North America and the West Indies, will
  • sufficiently account for this, without supposing any diminution in the
  • capital stock of the society. So great an accession of new business to be
  • carried on by the old stock, must necessarily have diminished the quantity
  • employed in a great number of particular branches, in which the
  • competition being less, the profits must have been greater. I shall
  • hereafter have occasion to mention the reasons which dispose me to believe
  • that the capital stock of Great Britain was not diminished, even by the
  • enormous expense of the late war.
  • The diminution of the capital stock of the society, or of the funds
  • destined for the maintenance of industry, however, as it lowers the wages
  • of labour, so it raises the profits of stock, and consequently the
  • interest of money. By the wages of labour being lowered, the owners of
  • what stock remains in the society can bring their goods at less expense to
  • market than before; and less stock being employed in supplying the market
  • than before, they can sell them dearer. Their goods cost them less, and
  • they get more for them. Their profits, therefore, being augmented at both
  • ends, can well afford a large interest. The great fortunes so suddenly and
  • so easily acquired in Bengal and the other British settlements in the East
  • Indies, may satisfy us, that as the wages of labour are very low, so the
  • profits of stock are very high in those ruined countries. The interest of
  • money is proportionably so. In Bengal, money is frequently lent to the
  • farmers at forty, fifty, and sixty per cent. and the succeeding crop is
  • mortgaged for the payment. As the profits which can afford such an
  • interest must eat up almost the whole rent of the landlord, so such
  • enormous usury must in its turn eat up the greater part of those profits.
  • Before the fall of the Roman republic, a usury of the same kind seems to
  • have been common in the provinces, under the ruinous administration of
  • their proconsuls. The virtuous Brutus lent money in Cyprus at
  • eight-and-forty per cent. as we learn from the letters of Cicero.
  • In a country which had acquired that full complement of riches which the
  • nature of its soil and climate, and its situation with respect to other
  • countries, allowed it to acquire, which could, therefore, advance no
  • further, and which was not going backwards, both the wages of labour and
  • the profits of stock would probably be very low. In a country fully
  • peopled in proportion to what either its territory could maintain, or its
  • stock employ, the competition for employment would necessarily be so great
  • as to reduce the wages of labour to what was barely sufficient to keep up
  • the number of labourers, and the country being already fully peopled, that
  • number could never be augmented. In a country fully stocked in proportion
  • to all the business it had to transact, as great a quantity of stock would
  • be employed in every particular branch as the nature and extent of the
  • trade would admit. The competition, therefore, would everywhere be as
  • great, and, consequently, the ordinary profit as low as possible.
  • But, perhaps, no country has ever yet arrived at this degree of opulence.
  • China seems to have been long stationary, and had, probably, long ago
  • acquired that full complement of riches which is consistent with the
  • nature of its laws and institutions. But this complement may be much
  • inferior to what, with other laws and institutions, the nature of its
  • soil, climate, and situation, might admit of. A country which neglects or
  • despises foreign commerce, and which admits the vessel of foreign nations
  • into one or two of its ports only, cannot transact the same quantity of
  • business which it might do with different laws and institutions. In a
  • country, too, where, though the rich, or the owners of large capitals,
  • enjoy a good deal of security, the poor, or the owners of small capitals,
  • enjoy scarce any, but are liable, under the pretence of justice, to be
  • pillaged and plundered at any time by the inferior mandarins, the quantity
  • of stock employed in all the different branches of business transacted
  • within it, can never be equal to what the nature and extent of that
  • business might admit. In every different branch, the oppression of the
  • poor must establish the monopoly of the rich, who, by engrossing the whole
  • trade to themselves, will be able to make very large profits. Twelve per
  • cent. accordingly, is said to be the common interest of money in China,
  • and the ordinary profits of stock must be sufficient to afford this large
  • interest.
  • A defect in the law may sometimes raise the rate of interest considerably
  • above what the condition of the country, as to wealth or poverty, would
  • require. When the law does not enforce the performance of contracts, it
  • puts all borrowers nearly upon the same footing with bankrupts, or people
  • of doubtful credit, in better regulated countries. The uncertainty of
  • recovering his money makes the lender exact the same usurious interest
  • which is usually required from bankrupts. Among the barbarous nations who
  • overran the western provinces of the Roman empire, the performance of
  • contracts was left for many ages to the faith of the contracting parties.
  • The courts of justice of their kings seldom intermeddled in it. The high
  • rate of interest which took place in those ancient times, may, perhaps, be
  • partly accounted for from this cause.
  • When the law prohibits interest altogether, it does not prevent it. Many
  • people must borrow, and nobody will lend without such a consideration for
  • the use of their money as is suitable, not only to what can be made by the
  • use of it, but to the difficulty and danger of evading the law. The high
  • rate of interest among all Mahometan nations is accounted for by M.
  • Montesquieu, not from their poverty, but partly from this, and partly from
  • the difficulty of recovering the money.
  • The lowest ordinary rate of profit must always be something more than what
  • is sufficient to compensate the occasional losses to which every
  • employment of stock is exposed. It is this surplus only which is neat or
  • clear profit. What is called gross profit, comprehends frequently not only
  • this surplus, but what is retained for compensating such extraordinary
  • losses. The interest which the borrower can afford to pay is in proportion
  • to the clear profit only. The lowest ordinary rate of interest must, in
  • the same manner, be something more than sufficient to compensate the
  • occasional losses to which lending, even with tolerable prudence, is
  • exposed. Were it not, mere charity or friendship could be the only motives
  • for lending.
  • In a country which had acquired its full complement of riches, where, in
  • every particular branch of business, there was the greatest quantity of
  • stock that could be employed in it, as the ordinary rate of clear profit
  • would be very small, so the usual market rate of interest which could be
  • afforded out of it would be so low as to render it impossible for any but
  • the very wealthiest people to live upon the interest of their money. All
  • people of small or middling fortunes would be obliged to superintend
  • themselves the employment of their own stocks. It would be necessary that
  • almost every man should be a man of business, or engage in some sort of
  • trade. The province of Holland seems to be approaching near to this state.
  • It is there unfashionable not to be a man of business. Necessity makes it
  • usual for almost every man to be so, and custom everywhere regulates
  • fashion. As it is ridiculous not to dress, so is it, in some measure, not
  • to be employed like other people. As a man of a civil profession seems
  • awkward in a camp or a garrison, and is even in some danger of being
  • despised there, so does an idle man among men of business.
  • The highest ordinary rate of profit may be such as, in the price of the
  • greater part of commodities, eats up the whole of what should go to the
  • rent of the land, and leaves only what is sufficient to pay the labour of
  • preparing and bringing them to market, according to the lowest rate at
  • which labour can anywhere be paid, the bare subsistence of the labourer.
  • The workman must always have been fed in some way or other while he was
  • about the work, but the landlord may not always have been paid. The
  • profits of the trade which the servants of the East India Company carry on
  • in Bengal may not, perhaps, be very far from this rate.
  • The proportion which the usual market rate of interest ought to bear to
  • the ordinary rate of clear profit, necessarily varies as profit rises or
  • falls. Double interest is in Great Britain reckoned what the merchants
  • call a good, moderate, reasonable profit; terms which, I apprehend, mean
  • no more than a common and usual profit. In a country where the ordinary
  • rate of clear profit is eight or ten per cent. it may be reasonable that
  • one half of it should go to interest, wherever business is carried on with
  • borrowed money. The stock is at the risk of the borrower, who, as it were,
  • insures it to the lender; and four or five per cent. may, in the greater
  • part of trades, be both a sufficient profit upon the risk of this
  • insurance, and a sufficient recompence for the trouble of employing the
  • stock. But the proportion between interest and clear profit might not be
  • the same in countries where the ordinary rate of profit was either a good
  • deal lower, or a good deal higher. If it were a good deal lower, one half
  • of it, perhaps, could not be afforded for interest; and more might be
  • afforded if it were a good deal higher.
  • In countries which are fast advancing to riches, the low rate of profit
  • may, in the price of many commodities, compensate the high wages of
  • labour, and enable those countries to sell as cheap as their less thriving
  • neighbours, among whom the wages of labour may be lower.
  • In reality, high profits tend much more to raise the price of work than
  • high wages. If, in the linen manufacture, for example, the wages of the
  • different working people, the flax-dressers, the spinners, the weavers,
  • etc. should all of them be advanced twopence a-day, it would be necessary
  • to heighten the price of a piece of linen only by a number of twopences
  • equal to the number of people that had been employed about it, multiplied
  • by the number of days during which they had been so employed. That part of
  • the price of the commodity which resolved itself into the wages, would,
  • through all the different stages of the manufacture, rise only in
  • arithmetical proportion to this rise of wages. But if the profits of all
  • the different employers of those working people should be raised five per
  • cent. that part of the price of the commodity which resolved itself into
  • profit would, through all the different stages of the manufacture, rise in
  • geometrical proportion to this rise of profit. The employer of the flax
  • dressers would, in selling his flax, require an additional five per cent.
  • upon the whole value of the materials and wages which he advanced to his
  • workmen. The employer of the spinners would require an additional five per
  • cent. both upon the advanced price of the flax, and upon the wages of the
  • spinners. And the employer of the weavers would require alike five per
  • cent. both upon the advanced price of the linen-yarn, and upon the wages
  • of the weavers. In raising the price of commodities, the rise of wages
  • operates in the same manner as simple interest does in the accumulation of
  • debt. The rise of profit operates like compound interest. Our merchants
  • and master manufacturers complain much of the bad effects of high wages in
  • raising the price, and thereby lessening the sale of their goods, both at
  • home and abroad. They say nothing concerning the bad effects of high
  • profits; they are silent with regard to the pernicious effects of their
  • own gains; they complain only of those of other people.
  • CHAPTER X.
  • OF WAGES AND PROFIT IN THE DIFFERENT
  • EMPLOYMENTS OF LABOUR AND STOCK.
  • The whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different employments
  • of labour and stock, must, in the same neighbourhood, be either perfectly
  • equal, or continually tending to equality. If, in the same neighbourhood,
  • there was any employment evidently either more or less advantageous than
  • the rest, so many people would crowd into it in the one case, and so many
  • would desert it in the other, that its advantages would soon return to the
  • level of other employments. This, at least, would be the case in a society
  • where things were left to follow their natural course, where there was
  • perfect liberty, and where every man was perfectly free both to choose
  • what occupation he thought proper, and to change it as often as he thought
  • proper. Every man’s interest would prompt him to seek the advantageous,
  • and to shun the disadvantageous employment.
  • Pecuniary wages and profit, indeed, are everywhere in Europe extremely
  • different, according to the different employments of labour and stock. But
  • this difference arises, partly from certain circumstances in the
  • employments themselves, which, either really, or at least in the
  • imagination of men, make up for a small pecuniary gain in some, and
  • counterbalance a great one in others, and partly from the policy of
  • Europe, which nowhere leaves things at perfect liberty.
  • The particular consideration of those circumstances, and of that policy,
  • will divide this Chapter into two parts.
  • PART I. Inequalities arising from the nature of the employments
  • themselves.
  • The five following are the principal circumstances which, so far as I have
  • been able to observe, make up for a small pecuniary gain in some
  • employments, and counterbalance a great one in others. First, the
  • agreeableness or disagreeableness of the employments themselves; secondly,
  • the easiness and cheapness, or the difficulty and expense of learning
  • them; thirdly, the constancy or inconstancy of employment in them;
  • fourthly, the small or great trust which must be reposed in those who
  • exercise them; and, fifthly, the probability or improbability of success
  • in them.
  • First, the wages of labour vary with the ease or hardship, the cleanliness
  • or dirtiness, the honourableness or dishonourableness, of the employment.
  • Thus in most places, take the year round, a journeyman tailor earns less
  • than a journeyman weaver. His work is much easier. A journeyman weaver
  • earns less than a journeyman smith. His work is not always easier, but it
  • is much cleanlier. A journeyman blacksmith, though an artificer, seldom
  • earns so much in twelve hours, as a collier, who is only a labourer, does
  • in eight. His work is not quite so dirty, is less dangerous, and is
  • carried on in day-light, and above ground. Honour makes a great part of
  • the reward of all honourable professions. In point of pecuniary gain, all
  • things considered, they are generally under-recompensed, as I shall
  • endeavour to shew by and by. Disgrace has the contrary effect. The trade
  • of a butcher is a brutal and an odious business; but it is in most places
  • more profitable than the greater part of common trades. The most
  • detestable of all employments, that of public executioner, is, in
  • proportion to the quantity of work done, better paid than any common trade
  • whatever.
  • Hunting and fishing, the most important employments of mankind in the rude
  • state of society, become, in its advanced state, their most agreeable
  • amusements, and they pursue for pleasure what they once followed from
  • necessity. In the advanced state of society, therefore, they are all very
  • poor people who follow as a trade, what other people pursue as a pastime.
  • Fishermen have been so since the time of Theocritus. {See Idyllium xxi.}.
  • A poacher is everywhere a very poor man in Great Britain. In countries
  • where the rigour of the law suffers no poachers, the licensed hunter is
  • not in a much better condition. The natural taste for those employments
  • makes more people follow them, than can live comfortably by them; and the
  • produce of their labour, in proportion to its quantity, comes always too
  • cheap to market, to afford any thing but the most scanty subsistence to
  • the labourers.
  • Disagreeableness and disgrace affect the profits of stock in the same
  • manner as the wages of labour. The keeper of an inn or tavern, who is
  • never master of his own house, and who is exposed to the brutality of
  • every drunkard, exercises neither a very agreeable nor a very creditable
  • business. But there is scarce any common trade in which a small stock
  • yields so great a profit.
  • Secondly, the wages of labour vary with the easiness and cheapness, or the
  • difficulty and expense, of learning the business.
  • When any expensive machine is erected, the extraordinary work to be
  • performed by it before it is worn out, it must be expected, will replace
  • the capital laid out upon it, with at least the ordinary profits. A man
  • educated at the expense of much labour and time to any of those
  • employments which require extraordinary dexterity and skill, may be
  • compared to one of those expensive machines. The work which he learns to
  • perform, it must be expected, over and above the usual wages of common
  • labour, will replace to him the whole expense of his education, with at
  • least the ordinary profits of an equally valuable capital. It must do this
  • too in a reasonable time, regard being had to the very uncertain duration
  • of human life, in the same manner as to the more certain duration of the
  • machine.
  • The difference between the wages of skilled labour and those of common
  • labour, is founded upon this principle.
  • The policy of Europe considers the labour of all mechanics, artificers,
  • and manufacturers, as skilled labour; and that of all country labourers as
  • common labour. It seems to suppose that of the former to be of a more nice
  • and delicate nature than that of the latter. It is so perhaps in some
  • cases; but in the greater part it is quite otherwise, as I shall endeavour
  • to shew by and by. The laws and customs of Europe, therefore, in order to
  • qualify any person for exercising the one species of labour, impose the
  • necessity of an apprenticeship, though with different degrees of rigour in
  • different places. They leave the other free and open to every body. During
  • the continuance of the apprenticeship, the whole labour of the apprentice
  • belongs to his master. In the meantime he must, in many cases, be
  • maintained by his parents or relations, and, in almost all cases, must be
  • clothed by them. Some money, too, is commonly given to the master for
  • teaching him his trade. They who cannot give money, give time, or become
  • bound for more than the usual number of years; a consideration which,
  • though it is not always advantageous to the master, on account of the
  • usual idleness of apprentices, is always disadvantageous to the
  • apprentice. In country labour, on the contrary, the labourer, while he is
  • employed about the easier, learns the more difficult parts of his
  • business, and his own labour maintains him through all the different
  • stages of his employment. It is reasonable, therefore, that in Europe the
  • wages of mechanics, artificers, and manufacturers, should be somewhat
  • higher than those of common labourers. They are so accordingly, and their
  • superior gains make them, in most places, be considered as a superior rank
  • of people. This superiority, however, is generally very small: the daily
  • or weekly earnings of journeymen in the more common sorts of manufactures,
  • such as those of plain linen and woollen cloth, computed at an average,
  • are, in most places, very little more than the day-wages of common
  • labourers. Their employment, indeed, is more steady and uniform, and the
  • superiority of their earnings, taking the whole year together, may be
  • somewhat greater. It seems evidently, however, to be no greater than what
  • is sufficient to compensate the superior expense of their education.
  • Education in the ingenious arts, and in the liberal professions, is still
  • more tedious and expensive. The pecuniary recompence, therefore, of
  • painters and sculptors, of lawyers and physicians, ought to be much more
  • liberal; and it is so accordingly.
  • The profits of stock seem to be very little affected by the easiness or
  • difficulty of learning the trade in which it is employed. All the
  • different ways in which stock is commonly employed in great towns seem, in
  • reality, to be almost equally easy and equally difficult to learn. One
  • branch, either of foreign or domestic trade, cannot well be a much more
  • intricate business than another.
  • Thirdly, the wages of labour in different occupations vary with the
  • constancy or inconstancy of employment.
  • Employment is much more constant in some trades than in others. In the
  • greater part of manufactures, a journeyman maybe pretty sure of employment
  • almost every day in the year that he is able to work. A mason or
  • bricklayer, on the contrary, can work neither in hard frost nor in foul
  • weather, and his employment at all other times depends upon the occasional
  • calls of his customers. He is liable, in consequence, to be frequently
  • without any. What he earns, therefore, while he is employed, must not only
  • maintain him while he is idle, but make him some compensation for those
  • anxious and desponding moments which the thought of so precarious a
  • situation must sometimes occasion. Where the computed earnings of the
  • greater part of manufacturers, accordingly, are nearly upon a level with
  • the day-wages of common labourers, those of masons and bricklayers are
  • generally from one-half more to double those wages. Where common labourers
  • earn four or five shillings a-week, masons and bricklayers frequently earn
  • seven and eight; where the former earn six, the latter often earn nine and
  • ten; and where the former earn nine and ten, as in London, the latter
  • commonly earn fifteen and eighteen. No species of skilled labour, however,
  • seems more easy to learn than that of masons and bricklayers. Chairmen in
  • London, during the summer season, are said sometimes to be employed as
  • bricklayers. The high wages of those workmen, therefore, are not so much
  • the recompence of their skill, as the compensation for the inconstancy of
  • their employment.
  • A house-carpenter seems to exercise rather a nicer and a more ingenious
  • trade than a mason. In most places, however, for it is not universally so,
  • his day-wages are somewhat lower. His employment, though it depends much,
  • does not depend so entirely upon the occasional calls of his customers;
  • and it is not liable to be interrupted by the weather.
  • When the trades which generally afford constant employment, happen in a
  • particular place not to do so, the wages of the workmen always rise a good
  • deal above their ordinary proportion to those of common labour. In London,
  • almost all journeymen artificers are liable to be called upon and
  • dismissed by their masters from day to day, and from week to week, in the
  • same manner as day-labourers in other places. The lowest order of
  • artificers, journeymen tailors, accordingly, earn their half-a-crown
  • a-day, though eighteen pence may be reckoned the wages of common labour.
  • In small towns and country villages, the wages of journeymen tailors
  • frequently scarce equal those of common labour; but in London they are
  • often many weeks without employment, particularly during the summer.
  • When the inconstancy of employment is combined with the hardship,
  • disagreeableness, and dirtiness of the work, it sometimes raises the wages
  • of the most common labour above those of the most skilful artificers. A
  • collier working by the piece is supposed, at Newcastle, to earn commonly
  • about double, and, in many parts of Scotland, about three times, the wages
  • of common labour. His high wages arise altogether from the hardship,
  • disagreeableness, and dirtiness of his work. His employment may, upon most
  • occasions, be as constant as he pleases. The coal-heavers in London
  • exercise a trade which, in hardship, dirtiness, and disagreeableness,
  • almost equals that of colliers; and, from the unavoidable irregularity in
  • the arrivals of coal-ships, the employment of the greater part of them is
  • necessarily very inconstant. If colliers, therefore, commonly earn double
  • and triple the wages of common labour, it ought not to seem unreasonable
  • that coal-heavers should sometimes earn four and five times those wages.
  • In the inquiry made into their condition a few years ago, it was found
  • that, at the rate at which they were then paid, they could earn from six
  • to ten shillings a-day. Six shillings are about four times the wages of
  • common labour in London; and, in every particular trade, the lowest common
  • earnings may always be considered as those of the far greater number. How
  • extravagant soever those earnings may appear, if they were more than
  • sufficient to compensate all the disagreeable circumstances of the
  • business, there would soon be so great a number of competitors, as, in a
  • trade which has no exclusive privilege, would quickly reduce them to a
  • lower rate.
  • The constancy or inconstancy of employment cannot affect the ordinary
  • profits of stock in any particular trade. Whether the stock is or is not
  • constantly employed, depends, not upon the trade, but the trader.
  • Fourthly, the wages of labour vary according to the small or great trust
  • which must be reposed in the workmen.
  • The wages of goldsmiths and jewellers are everywhere superior to those of
  • many other workmen, not only of equal, but of much superior ingenuity, on
  • account of the precious materials with which they are entrusted. We trust
  • our health to the physician, our fortune, and sometimes our life and
  • reputation, to the lawyer and attorney. Such confidence could not safely
  • be reposed in people of a very mean or low condition. Their reward must be
  • such, therefore, as may give them that rank in the society which so
  • important a trust requires. The long time and the great expense which must
  • be laid out in their education, when combined with this circumstance,
  • necessarily enhance still further the price of their labour.
  • When a person employs only his own stock in trade, there is no trust; and
  • the credit which he may get from other people, depends, not upon the
  • nature of the trade, but upon their opinion of his fortune, probity and
  • prudence. The different rates of profit, therefore, in the different
  • branches of trade, cannot arise from the different degrees of trust
  • reposed in the traders.
  • Fifthly, the wages of labour in different employments vary according to
  • the probability or improbability of success in them.
  • The probability that any particular person shall ever be qualified for the
  • employments to which he is educated, is very different in different
  • occupations. In the greatest part of mechanic trades success is almost
  • certain; but very uncertain in the liberal professions. Put your son
  • apprentice to a shoemaker, there is little doubt of his learning to make a
  • pair of shoes; but send him to study the law, it as at least twenty to one
  • if he ever makes such proficiency as will enable him to live by the
  • business. In a perfectly fair lottery, those who draw the prizes ought to
  • gain all that is lost by those who draw the blanks. In a profession, where
  • twenty fail for one that succeeds, that one ought to gain all that should
  • have been gained by the unsuccessful twenty. The counsellor at law, who,
  • perhaps, at near forty years of age, begins to make something by his
  • profession, ought to receive the retribution, not only of his own so
  • tedious and expensive education, but of that of more than twenty others,
  • who are never likely to make any thing by it. How extravagant soever the
  • fees of counsellors at law may sometimes appear, their real retribution is
  • never equal to this. Compute, in any particular place, what is likely to
  • be annually gained, and what is likely to be annually spent, by all the
  • different workmen in any common trade, such as that of shoemakers or
  • weavers, and you will find that the former sum will generally exceed the
  • latter. But make the same computation with regard to all the counsellors
  • and students of law, in all the different Inns of Court, and you will find
  • that their annual gains bear but a very small proportion to their annual
  • expense, even though you rate the former as high, and the latter as low,
  • as can well be done. The lottery of the law, therefore, is very far from
  • being a perfectly fair lottery; and that as well as many other liberal and
  • honourable professions, is, in point of pecuniary gain, evidently
  • under-recompensed.
  • Those professions keep their level, however, with other occupations; and,
  • notwithstanding these discouragements, all the most generous and liberal
  • spirits are eager to crowd into them. Two different causes contribute to
  • recommend them. First, the desire of the reputation which attends upon
  • superior excellence in any of them; and, secondly, the natural confidence
  • which every man has, more or less, not only in his own abilities, but in
  • his own good fortune.
  • To excel in any profession, in which but few arrive at mediocrity, is the
  • most decisive mark of what is called genius, or superior talents. The
  • public admiration which attends upon such distinguished abilities makes
  • always a part of their reward; a greater or smaller, in proportion as it
  • is higher or lower in degree. It makes a considerable part of that reward
  • in the profession of physic; a still greater, perhaps, in that of law; in
  • poetry and philosophy it makes almost the whole.
  • There are some very agreeable and beautiful talents, of which the
  • possession commands a certain sort of admiration, but of which the
  • exercise, for the sake of gain, is considered, whether from reason or
  • prejudice, as a sort of public prostitution. The pecuniary recompence,
  • therefore, of those who exercise them in this manner, must be sufficient,
  • not only to pay for the time, labour, and expense of acquiring the
  • talents, but for the discredit which attends the employment of them as the
  • means of subsistence. The exorbitant rewards of players, opera-singers,
  • opera-dancers, etc. are founded upon those two principles; the rarity and
  • beauty of the talents, and the discredit of employing them in this manner.
  • It seems absurd at first sight, that we should despise their persons, and
  • yet reward their talents with the most profuse liberality. While we do the
  • one, however, we must of necessity do the other, Should the public opinion
  • or prejudice ever alter with regard to such occupations, their pecuniary
  • recompence would quickly diminish. More people would apply to them, and
  • the competition would quickly reduce the price of their labour. Such
  • talents, though far from being common, are by no means so rare as
  • imagined. Many people possess them in great perfection, who disdain to
  • make this use of them; and many more are capable of acquiring them, if any
  • thing could be made honourably by them.
  • The over-weening conceit which the greater part of men have of their own
  • abilities, is an ancient evil remarked by the philosophers and moralists
  • of all ages. Their absurd presumption in their own good fortune has been
  • less taken notice of. It is, however, if possible, still more universal.
  • There is no man living, who, when in tolerable health and spirits, has not
  • some share of it. The chance of gain is by every man more or less
  • over-valued, and the chance of loss is by most men under-valued, and by
  • scarce any man, who is in tolerable health and spirits, valued more than
  • it is worth.
  • That the chance of gain is naturally overvalued, we may learn from the
  • universal success of lotteries. The world neither ever saw, nor ever will
  • see, a perfectly fair lottery, or one in which the whole gain compensated
  • the whole loss; because the undertaker could make nothing by it. In the
  • state lotteries, the tickets are really not worth the price which is paid
  • by the original subscribers, and yet commonly sell in the market for
  • twenty, thirty, and sometimes forty per cent. advance. The vain hopes of
  • gaining some of the great prizes is the sole cause of this demand. The
  • soberest people scarce look upon it as a folly to pay a small sum for the
  • chance of gaining ten or twenty thousand pounds, though they know that
  • even that small sum is perhaps twenty or thirty per cent. more than the
  • chance is worth. In a lottery in which no prize exceeded twenty pounds,
  • though in other respects it approached much nearer to a perfectly fair one
  • than the common state lotteries, there would not be the same demand for
  • tickets. In order to have a better chance for some of the great prizes,
  • some people purchase several tickets; and others, small shares in a still
  • greater number. There is not, however, a more certain proposition in
  • mathematics, than that the more tickets you adventure upon, the more
  • likely you are to be a loser. Adventure upon all the tickets in the
  • lottery, and you lose for certain; and the greater the number of your
  • tickets, the nearer you approach to this certainty.
  • That the chance of loss is frequently undervalued, and scarce ever valued
  • more than it is worth, we may learn from the very moderate profit of
  • insurers. In order to make insurance, either from fire or sea-risk, a
  • trade at all, the common premium must be sufficient to compensate the
  • common losses, to pay the expense of management, and to afford such a
  • profit as might have been drawn from an equal capital employed in any
  • common trade. The person who pays no more than this, evidently pays no
  • more than the real value of the risk, or the lowest price at which he can
  • reasonably expect to insure it. But though many people have made a little
  • money by insurance, very few have made a great fortune; and, from this
  • consideration alone, it seems evident enough that the ordinary balance of
  • profit and loss is not more advantageous in this than in other common
  • trades, by which so many people make fortunes. Moderate, however, as the
  • premium of insurance commonly is, many people despise the risk too much to
  • care to pay it. Taking the whole kingdom at an average, nineteen houses in
  • twenty, or rather, perhaps, ninety-nine in a hundred, are not insured from
  • fire. Sea-risk is more alarming to the greater part of people; and the
  • proportion of ships insured to those not insured is much greater. Many
  • sail, however, at all seasons, and even in time of war, without any
  • insurance. This may sometimes, perhaps, be done without any imprudence.
  • When a great company, or even a great merchant, has twenty or thirty ships
  • at sea, they may, as it were, insure one another. The premium saved up on
  • them all may more than compensate such losses as they are likely to meet
  • with in the common course of chances. The neglect of insurance upon
  • shipping, however, in the same manner as upon houses, is, in most cases,
  • the effect of no such nice calculation, but of mere thoughtless rashness,
  • and presumptuous contempt of the risk.
  • The contempt of risk, and the presumptuous hope of success, are in no
  • period of life more active than at the age at which young people choose
  • their professions. How little the fear of misfortune is then capable of
  • balancing the hope of good luck, appears still more evidently in the
  • readiness of the common people to enlist as soldiers, or to go to sea,
  • than in the eagerness of those of better fashion to enter into what are
  • called the liberal professions.
  • What a common soldier may lose is obvious enough. Without regarding the
  • danger, however, young volunteers never enlist so readily as at the
  • beginning of a new war; and though they have scarce any chance of
  • preferment, they figure to themselves, in their youthful fancies, a
  • thousand occasions of acquiring honour and distinction which never occur.
  • These romantic hopes make the whole price of their blood. Their pay is
  • less than that of common labourers, and, in actual service, their fatigues
  • are much greater.
  • The lottery of the sea is not altogether so disadvantageous as that of the
  • army. The son of a creditable labourer or artificer may frequently go to
  • sea with his father’s consent; but if he enlists as a soldier, it is
  • always without it. Other people see some chance of his making something by
  • the one trade; nobody but himself sees any of his making any thing by the
  • other. The great admiral is less the object of public admiration than the
  • great general; and the highest success in the sea service promises a less
  • brilliant fortune and reputation than equal success in the land. The same
  • difference runs through all the inferior degrees of preferment in both. By
  • the rules of precedency, a captain in the navy ranks with a colonel in the
  • army; but he does not rank with him in the common estimation. As the great
  • prizes in the lottery are less, the smaller ones must be more numerous.
  • Common sailors, therefore, more frequently get some fortune and preferment
  • than common soldiers; and the hope of those prizes is what principally
  • recommends the trade. Though their skill and dexterity are much superior
  • to that of almost any artificers; and though their whole life is one
  • continual scene of hardship and danger; yet for all this dexterity and
  • skill, for all those hardships and dangers, while they remain in the
  • condition of common sailors, they receive scarce any other recompence but
  • the pleasure of exercising the one and of surmounting the other. Their
  • wages are not greater than those of common labourers at the port which
  • regulates the rate of seamen’s wages. As they are continually going from
  • port to port, the monthly pay of those who sail from all the different
  • ports of Great Britain, is more nearly upon a level than that of any other
  • workmen in those different places; and the rate of the port to and from
  • which the greatest number sail, that is, the port of London, regulates
  • that of all the rest. At London, the wages of the greater part of the
  • different classes of workmen are about double those of the same classes at
  • Edinburgh. But the sailors who sail from the port of London, seldom earn
  • above three or four shillings a month more than those who sail from the
  • port of Leith, and the difference is frequently not so great. In time of
  • peace, and in the merchant-service, the London price is from a guinea to
  • about seven-and-twenty shillings the calendar month. A common labourer in
  • London, at the rate of nine or ten shillings a week, may earn in the
  • calendar month from forty to five-and-forty shillings. The sailor, indeed,
  • over and above his pay, is supplied with provisions. Their value, however,
  • may not perhaps always exceed the difference between his pay and that of
  • the common labourer; and though it sometimes should, the excess will not
  • be clear gain to the sailor, because he cannot share it with his wife and
  • family, whom he must maintain out of his wages at home.
  • The dangers and hair-breadth escapes of a life of adventures, instead of
  • disheartening young people, seem frequently to recommend a trade to them.
  • A tender mother, among the inferior ranks of people, is often afraid to
  • send her son to school at a sea-port town, lest the sight of the ships,
  • and the conversation and adventures of the sailors, should entice him to
  • go to sea. The distant prospect of hazards, from which we can hope to
  • extricate ourselves by courage and address, is not disagreeable to us, and
  • does not raise the wages of labour in any employment. It is otherwise with
  • those in which courage and address can be of no avail. In trades which are
  • known to be very unwholesome, the wages of labour are always remarkably
  • high. Unwholesomeness is a species of disagreeableness, and its effects
  • upon the wages of labour are to be ranked under that general head.
  • In all the different employments of stock, the ordinary rate of profit
  • varies more or less with the certainty or uncertainty of the returns.
  • These are, in general, less uncertain in the inland than in the foreign
  • trade, and in some branches of foreign trade than in others; in the trade
  • to North America, for example, than in that to Jamaica. The ordinary rate
  • of profit always rises more or less with the risk. It does not, however,
  • seem to rise in proportion to it, or so as to compensate it completely.
  • Bankruptcies are most frequent in the most hazardous trades. The most
  • hazardous of all trades, that of a smuggler, though, when the adventure
  • succeeds, it is likewise the most profitable, is the infallible road to
  • bankruptcy. The presumptuous hope of success seems to act here as upon all
  • other occasions, and to entice so many adventurers into those hazardous
  • trades, that their competition reduces the profit below what is sufficient
  • to compensate the risk. To compensate it completely, the common returns
  • ought, over and above the ordinary profits of stock, not only to make up
  • for all occasional losses, but to afford a surplus profit to the
  • adventurers, of the same nature with the profit of insurers. But if the
  • common returns were sufficient for all this, bankruptcies would not be
  • more frequent in these than in other trades.
  • Of the five circumstances, therefore, which vary the wages of labour, two
  • only affect the profits of stock; the agreeableness or disagreeableness of
  • the business, and the risk or security with which it is attended. In point
  • of agreeableness or disagreeableness, there is little or no difference in
  • the far greater part of the different employments of stock, but a great
  • deal in those of labour; and the ordinary profit of stock, though it rises
  • with the risk, does not always seem to rise in proportion to it. It should
  • follow from all this, that, in the same society or neighbourhood, the
  • average and ordinary rates of profit in the different employments of stock
  • should be more nearly upon a level than the pecuniary wages of the
  • different sorts of labour.
  • They are so accordingly. The difference between the earnings of a common
  • labourer and those of a well employed lawyer or physician, is evidently
  • much greater than that between the ordinary profits in any two different
  • branches of trade. The apparent difference, besides, in the profits of
  • different trades, is generally a deception arising from our not always
  • distinguishing what ought to be considered as wages, from what ought to be
  • considered as profit.
  • Apothecaries’ profit is become a bye-word, denoting something uncommonly
  • extravagant. This great apparent profit, however, is frequently no more
  • than the reasonable wages of labour. The skill of an apothecary is a much
  • nicer and more delicate matter than that of any artificer whatever; and
  • the trust which is reposed in him is of much greater importance. He is the
  • physician of the poor in all cases, and of the rich when the distress or
  • danger is not very great. His reward, therefore, ought to be suitable to
  • his skill and his trust; and it arises generally from the price at which
  • he sells his drugs. But the whole drugs which the best employed apothecary
  • in a large market-town, will sell in a year, may not perhaps cost him
  • above thirty or forty pounds. Though he should sell them, therefore, for
  • three or four hundred, or at a thousand per cent. profit, this may
  • frequently be no more than the reasonable wages of his labour, charged, in
  • the only way in which he can charge them, upon the price of his drugs. The
  • greater part of the apparent profit is real wages disguised in the garb of
  • profit.
  • In a small sea-port town, a little grocer will make forty or fifty per
  • cent. upon a stock of a single hundred pounds, while a considerable
  • wholesale merchant in the same place will scarce make eight or ten per
  • cent. upon a stock of ten thousand. The trade of the grocer may be
  • necessary for the conveniency of the inhabitants, and the narrowness of
  • the market may not admit the employment of a larger capital in the
  • business. The man, however, must not only live by his trade, but live by
  • it suitably to the qualifications which it requires. Besides possessing a
  • little capital, he must be able to read, write, and account and must be a
  • tolerable judge, too, of perhaps fifty or sixty different sorts of goods,
  • their prices, qualities, and the markets where they are to be had
  • cheapest. He must have all the knowledge, in short, that is necessary for
  • a great merchant, which nothing hinders him from becoming but the want of
  • a sufficient capital. Thirty or forty pounds a year cannot be considered
  • as too great a recompence for the labour of a person so accomplished.
  • Deduct this from the seemingly great profits of his capital, and little
  • more will remain, perhaps, than the ordinary profits of stock. The greater
  • part of the apparent profit is, in this case too, real wages.
  • The difference between the apparent profit of the retail and that of the
  • wholesale trade, is much less in the capital than in small towns and
  • country villages. Where ten thousand pounds can be employed in the grocery
  • trade, the wages of the grocer’s labour must be a very trifling addition
  • to the real profits of so great a stock. The apparent profits of the
  • wealthy retailer, therefore, are there more nearly upon a level with those
  • of the wholesale merchant. It is upon this account that goods sold by
  • retail are generally as cheap, and frequently much cheaper, in the capital
  • than in small towns and country villages. Grocery goods, for example, are
  • generally much cheaper; bread and butchers’ meat frequently as cheap. It
  • costs no more to bring grocery goods to the great town than to the country
  • village; but it costs a great deal more to bring corn and cattle, as the
  • greater part of them must be brought from a much greater distance. The
  • prime cost of grocery goods, therefore, being the same in both places,
  • they are cheapest where the least profit is charged upon them. The prime
  • cost of bread and butchers’ meat is greater in the great town than in the
  • country village; and though the profit is less, therefore they are not
  • always cheaper there, but often equally cheap. In such articles as bread
  • and butchers’ meat, the same cause which diminishes apparent profit,
  • increases prime cost. The extent of the market, by giving employment to
  • greater stocks, diminishes apparent profit; but by requiring supplies from
  • a greater distance, it increases prime cost. This diminution of the one
  • and increase of the other, seem, in most cases, nearly to counterbalance
  • one another; which is probably the reason that, though the prices of corn
  • and cattle are commonly very different in different parts of the kingdom,
  • those of bread and butchers’ meat are generally very nearly the same
  • through the greater part of it.
  • Though the profits of stock, both in the wholesale and retail trade, are
  • generally less in the capital than in small towns and country villages,
  • yet great fortunes are frequently acquired from small beginnings in the
  • former, and scarce ever in the latter. In small towns and country
  • villages, on account of the narrowness of the market, trade cannot always
  • be extended as stock extends. In such places, therefore, though the rate
  • of a particular person’s profits may be very high, the sum or amount of
  • them can never be very great, nor consequently that of his annual
  • accumulation. In great towns, on the contrary, trade can be extended as
  • stock increases, and the credit of a frugal and thriving man increases
  • much faster than his stock. His trade is extended in proportion to the
  • amount of both; and the sum or amount of his profits is in proportion to
  • the extent of his trade, and his annual accumulation in proportion to the
  • amount of his profits. It seldom happens, however, that great fortunes are
  • made, even in great towns, by any one regular, established, and well-known
  • branch of business, but in consequence of a long life of industry,
  • frugality, and attention. Sudden fortunes, indeed, are sometimes made in
  • such places, by what is called the trade of speculation. The speculative
  • merchant exercises no one regular, established, or well-known branch of
  • business. He is a corn merchant this year, and a wine merchant the next,
  • and a sugar, tobacco, or tea merchant the year after. He enters into every
  • trade, when he foresees that it is likely to be more than commonly
  • profitable, and he quits it when he foresees that its profits are likely
  • to return to the level of other trades. His profits and losses, therefore,
  • can bear no regular proportion to those of any one established and
  • well-known branch of business. A bold adventurer may sometimes acquire a
  • considerable fortune by two or three successful speculations, but is just
  • as likely to lose one by two or three unsuccessful ones. This trade can be
  • carried on nowhere but in great towns. It is only in places of the most
  • extensive commerce and correspondence that the intelligence requisite for
  • it can be had.
  • The five circumstances above mentioned, though they occasion considerable
  • inequalities in the wages of labour and profits of stock, occasion none in
  • the whole of the advantages and disadvantages, real or imaginary, of the
  • different employments of either. The nature of those circumstances is
  • such, that they make up for a small pecuniary gain in some, and
  • counterbalance a great one in others.
  • In order, however, that this equality may take place in the whole of their
  • advantages or disadvantages, three things are requisite, even where there
  • is the most perfect freedom. First the employments must be well known and
  • long established in the neighbourhood; secondly, they must be in their
  • ordinary, or what may be called their natural state; and, thirdly, they
  • must be the sole or principal employments of those who occupy them.
  • First, this equality can take place only in those employments which are
  • well known, and have been long established in the neighbourhood.
  • Where all other circumstances are equal, wages are generally higher in new
  • than in old trades. When a projector attempts to establish a new
  • manufacture, he must at first entice his workmen from other employments,
  • by higher wages than they can either earn in their own trades, or than the
  • nature of his work would otherwise require; and a considerable time must
  • pass away before he can venture to reduce them to the common level.
  • Manufactures for which the demand arises altogether from fashion and
  • fancy, are continually changing, and seldom last long enough to be
  • considered as old established manufactures. Those, on the contrary, for
  • which the demand arises chiefly from use or necessity, are less liable to
  • change, and the same form or fabric may continue in demand for whole
  • centuries together. The wages of labour, therefore, are likely to be
  • higher in manufactures of the former, than in those of the latter kind.
  • Birmingham deals chiefly in manufactures of the former kind; Sheffield in
  • those of the latter; and the wages of labour in those two different places
  • are said to be suitable to this difference in the nature of their
  • manufactures.
  • The establishment of any new manufacture, of any new branch of commerce,
  • or of any new practice in agriculture, is always a speculation from which
  • the projector promises himself extraordinary profits. These profits
  • sometimes are very great, and sometimes, more frequently, perhaps, they
  • are quite otherwise; but, in general, they bear no regular proportion to
  • those of other old trades in the neighbourhood. If the project succeeds,
  • they are commonly at first very high. When the trade or practice becomes
  • thoroughly established and well known, the competition reduces them to the
  • level of other trades.
  • Secondly, this equality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages
  • of the different employments of labour and stock, can take place only in
  • the ordinary, or what may be called the natural state of those
  • employments.
  • The demand for almost every different species of labour is sometimes
  • greater, and sometimes less than usual. In the one case, the advantages of
  • the employment rise above, in the other they fall below the common level.
  • The demand for country labour is greater at hay-time and harvest than
  • during the greater part of the year; and wages rise with the demand. In
  • time of war, when forty or fifty thousand sailors are forced from the
  • merchant service into that of the king, the demand for sailors to merchant
  • ships necessarily rises with their scarcity; and their wages, upon such
  • occasions, commonly rise from a guinea and seven-and-twenty shillings to
  • forty shillings and three pounds a-month. In a decaying manufacture, on
  • the contrary, many workmen, rather than quit their own trade, are
  • contented with smaller wages than would otherwise be suitable to the
  • nature of their employment.
  • The profits of stock vary with the price of the commodities in which it is
  • employed. As the price of any commodity rises above the ordinary or
  • average rate, the profits of at least some part of the stock that is
  • employed in bringing it to market, rise above their proper level, and as
  • it falls they sink below it. All commodities are more or less liable to
  • variations of price, but some are much more so than others. In all
  • commodities which are produced by human industry, the quantity of industry
  • annually employed is necessarily regulated by the annual demand, in such a
  • manner that the average annual produce may, as nearly as possible, be
  • equal to the average annual consumption. In some employments, it has
  • already been observed, the same quantity of industry will always produce
  • the same, or very nearly the same quantity of commodities. In the linen or
  • woollen manufactures, for example, the same number of hands will annually
  • work up very nearly the same quantity of linen and woollen cloth. The
  • variations in the market price of such commodities, therefore, can arise
  • only from some accidental variation in the demand. A public mourning
  • raises the price of black cloth. But as the demand for most sorts of plain
  • linen and woollen cloth is pretty uniform, so is likewise the price. But
  • there are other employments in which the same quantity of industry will
  • not always produce the same quantity of commodities. The same quantity of
  • industry, for example, will, in different years, produce very different
  • quantities of corn, wine, hops, sugar tobacco, etc. The price of such
  • commodities, therefore, varies not only with the variations of demand, but
  • with the much greater and more frequent variations of quantity, and is
  • consequently extremely fluctuating; but the profit of some of the dealers
  • must necessarily fluctuate with the price of the commodities. The
  • operations of the speculative merchant are principally employed about such
  • commodities. He endeavours to buy them up when he foresees that their
  • price is likely to rise, and to sell them when it is likely to fall.
  • Thirdly, this equality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of
  • the different employments of labour and stock, can take place only in such
  • as are the sole or principal employments of those who occupy them.
  • When a person derives his subsistence from one employment, which does not
  • occupy the greater part of his time, in the intervals of his leisure he is
  • often willing to work at another for less wages than would otherwise suit
  • the nature of the employment.
  • There still subsists, in many parts of Scotland, a set of people called
  • cottars or cottagers, though they were more frequent some years ago than
  • they are now. They are a sort of out-servants of the landlords and
  • farmers. The usual reward which they receive from their master is a house,
  • a small garden for pot-herbs, as much grass as will feed a cow, and,
  • perhaps, an acre or two of bad arable land. When their master has occasion
  • for their labour, he gives them, besides, two pecks of oatmeal a-week,
  • worth about sixteen pence sterling. During a great part of the year, he
  • has little or no occasion for their labour, and the cultivation of their
  • own little possession is not sufficient to occupy the time which is left
  • at their own disposal. When such occupiers were more numerous than they
  • are at present, they are said to have been willing to give their spare
  • time for a very small recompence to any body, and to have wrought for less
  • wages than other labourers. In ancient times, they seem to have been
  • common all over Europe. In countries ill cultivated, and worse inhabited,
  • the greater part of landlords and farmers could not otherwise provide
  • themselves with the extraordinary number of hands which country labour
  • requires at certain seasons. The daily or weekly recompence which such
  • labourers occasionally received from their masters, was evidently not the
  • whole price of their labour. Their small tenement made a considerable part
  • of it. This daily or weekly recompence, however, seems to have been
  • considered as the whole of it, by many writers who have collected the
  • prices of labour and provisions in ancient times, and who have taken
  • pleasure in representing both as wonderfully low.
  • The produce of such labour comes frequently cheaper to market than would
  • otherwise be suitable to its nature. Stockings, in many parts of Scotland,
  • are knit much cheaper than they can anywhere be wrought upon the loom.
  • They are the work of servants and labourers who derive the principal part
  • of their subsistence from some other employment. More than a thousand pair
  • of Shetland stockings are annually imported into Leith, of which the price
  • is from fivepence to seven-pence a pair. At Lerwick, the small capital of
  • the Shetland islands, tenpence a-day, I have been assured, is a common
  • price of common labour. In the same islands, they knit worsted stockings
  • to the value of a guinea a pair and upwards.
  • The spinning of linen yarn is carried on in Scotland nearly in the same
  • way as the knitting of stockings, by servants, who are chiefly hired for
  • other purposes. They earn but a very scanty subsistence, who endeavour to
  • get their livelihood by either of those trades. In most parts of Scotland,
  • she is a good spinner who can earn twentypence a-week.
  • In opulent countries, the market is generally so extensive, that any one
  • trade is sufficient to employ the whole labour and stock of those who
  • occupy it. Instances of people living by one employment, and, at the same
  • time, deriving some little advantage from another, occur chiefly in poor
  • countries. The following instance, however, of something of the same kind,
  • is to be found in the capital of a very rich one. There is no city in
  • Europe, I believe, in which house-rent is dearer than in London, and yet I
  • know no capital in which a furnished apartment can be hired so cheap.
  • Lodging is not only much cheaper in London than in Paris; it is much
  • cheaper than in Edinburgh, of the same degree of goodness; and, what may
  • seem extraordinary, the dearness of house-rent is the cause of the
  • cheapness of lodging. The dearness of house-rent in London arises, not
  • only from those causes which render it dear in all great capitals, the
  • dearness of labour, the dearness of all the materials of building, which
  • must generally be brought from a great distance, and, above all, the
  • dearness of ground-rent, every landlord acting the part of a monopolist,
  • and frequently exacting a higher rent for a single acre of bad land in a
  • town, than can be had for a hundred of the best in the country; but it
  • arises in part from the peculiar manners and customs of the people, which
  • oblige every master of a family to hire a whole house from top to bottom.
  • A dwelling-house in England means every thing that is contained under the
  • same roof. In France, Scotland, and many other parts of Europe, it
  • frequently means no more than a single storey. A tradesman in London is
  • obliged to hire a whole house in that part of the town where his customers
  • live. His shop is upon the ground floor, and he and his family sleep in
  • the garret; and he endeavours to pay a part of his house-rent by letting
  • the two middle storeys to lodgers. He expects to maintain his family by
  • his trade, and not by his lodgers. Whereas at Paris and Edinburgh, people
  • who let lodgings have commonly no other means of subsistence; and the
  • price of the lodging must pay, not only the rent of the house, but the
  • whole expense of the family.
  • PART II.—Inequalities occasioned by the Policy of Europe.
  • Such are the inequalities in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages
  • of the different employments of labour and stock, which the defect of any
  • of the three requisites above mentioned must occasion, even where there is
  • the most perfect liberty. But the policy of Europe, by not leaving things
  • at perfect liberty, occasions other inequalities of much greater
  • importance.
  • It does this chiefly in the three following ways. First, by restraining
  • the competition in some employments to a smaller number than would
  • otherwise be disposed to enter into them; secondly, by increasing it in
  • others beyond what it naturally would be; and, thirdly, by obstructing the
  • free circulation of labour and stock, both from employment to employment,
  • and from place to place.
  • First, The policy of Europe occasions a very important inequality in the
  • whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different employments of
  • labour and stock, by restraining the competition in some employments to a
  • smaller number than might otherwise be disposed to enter into them.
  • The exclusive privileges of corporations are the principal means it makes
  • use of for this purpose.
  • The exclusive privilege of an incorporated trade necessarily restrains the
  • competition, in the town where it is established, to those who are free of
  • the trade. To have served an apprenticeship in the town, under a master
  • properly qualified, is commonly the necessary requisite for obtaining this
  • freedom. The bye-laws of the corporation regulate sometimes the number of
  • apprentices which any master is allowed to have, and almost always the
  • number of years which each apprentice is obliged to serve. The intention
  • of both regulations is to restrain the competition to a much smaller
  • number than might otherwise be disposed to enter into the trade. The
  • limitation of the number of apprentices restrains it directly. A long term
  • of apprenticeship restrains it more indirectly, but as effectually, by
  • increasing the expense of education.
  • In Sheffield, no master cutler can have more than one apprentice at a
  • time, by a bye-law of the corporation. In Norfolk and Norwich, no master
  • weaver can have more than two apprentices, under pain of forfeiting five
  • pounds a-month to the king. No master hatter can have more than two
  • apprentices anywhere in England, or in the English plantations, under pain
  • of forfeiting; five pounds a-month, half to the king, and half to him who
  • shall sue in any court of record. Both these regulations, though they have
  • been confirmed by a public law of the kingdom, are evidently dictated by
  • the same corporation-spirit which enacted the bye-law of Sheffield. The
  • silk-weavers in London had scarce been incorporated a year, when they
  • enacted a bye-law, restraining any master from having more than two
  • apprentices at a time. It required a particular act of parliament to
  • rescind this bye-law.
  • Seven years seem anciently to have been, all over Europe, the usual term
  • established for the duration of apprenticeships in the greater part of
  • incorporated trades. All such incorporations were anciently called
  • universities, which, indeed, is the proper Latin name for any
  • incorporation whatever. The university of smiths, the university of
  • tailors, etc. are expressions which we commonly meet with in the old
  • charters of ancient towns. When those particular incorporations, which are
  • now peculiarly called universities, were first established, the term of
  • years which it was necessary to study, in order to obtain the degree of
  • master of arts, appears evidently to have been copied from the term of
  • apprenticeship in common trades, of which the incorporations were much
  • more ancient. As to have wrought seven years under a master properly
  • qualified, was necessary, in order to entitle any person to become a
  • master, and to have himself apprentices in a common trade; so to have
  • studied seven years under a master properly qualified, was necessary to
  • entitle him to become a master, teacher, or doctor (words anciently
  • synonymous), in the liberal arts, and to have scholars or apprentices
  • (words likewise originally synonymous) to study under him.
  • By the 5th of Elizabeth, commonly called the Statute of Apprenticeship, it
  • was enacted, that no person should, for the future, exercise any trade,
  • craft, or mystery, at that time exercised in England, unless he had
  • previously served to it an apprenticeship of seven years at least; and
  • what before had been the bye-law of many particular corporations, became
  • in England the general and public law of all trades carried on in market
  • towns. For though the words of the statute are very general, and seem
  • plainly to include the whole kingdom, by interpretation its operation has
  • been limited to market towns; it having been held that, in country
  • villages, a person may exercise several different trades, though he has
  • not served a seven years apprenticeship to each, they being necessary for
  • the conveniency of the inhabitants, and the number of people frequently
  • not being sufficient to supply each with a particular set of hands. By a
  • strict interpretation of the words, too, the operation of this statute has
  • been limited to those trades which were established in England before the
  • 5th of Elizabeth, and has never been extended to such as have been
  • introduced since that time. This limitation has given occasion to several
  • distinctions, which, considered as rules of police, appear as foolish as
  • can well be imagined. It has been adjudged, for example, that a
  • coach-maker can neither himself make nor employ journeymen to make his
  • coach-wheels, but must buy them of a master wheel-wright; this latter
  • trade having been exercised in England before the 5th of Elizabeth. But a
  • wheel-wright, though he has never served an apprenticeship to a
  • coachmaker, may either himself make or employ journeymen to make coaches;
  • the trade of a coachmaker not being within the statute, because not
  • exercised in England at the time when it was made. The manufactures of
  • Manchester, Birmingham, and Wolverhampton, are many of them, upon this
  • account, not within the statute, not having been exercised in England
  • before the 5th of Elizabeth.
  • In France, the duration of apprenticeships is different in different towns
  • and in different trades. In Paris, five years is the term required in a
  • great number; but, before any person can be qualified to exercise the
  • trade as a master, he must, in many of them, serve five years more as a
  • journeyman. During this latter term, he is called the companion of his
  • master, and the term itself is called his companionship.
  • In Scotland, there is no general law which regulates universally the
  • duration of apprenticeships. The term is different in different
  • corporations. Where it is long, a part of it may generally be redeemed by
  • paying a small fine. In most towns, too, a very small fine is sufficient
  • to purchase the freedom of any corporation. The weavers of linen and
  • hempen cloth, the principal manufactures of the country, as well as all
  • other artificers subservient to them, wheel-makers, reel-makers, etc. may
  • exercise their trades in any town-corporate without paying any fine. In
  • all towns-corporate, all persons are free to sell butchers’ meat upon any
  • lawful day of the week. Three years is, in Scotland, a common term of
  • apprenticeship, even in some very nice trades; and, in general, I know of
  • no country in Europe, in which corporation laws are so little oppressive.
  • The property which every man has in his own labour, as it is the original
  • foundation of all other property, so it is the most sacred and inviolable.
  • The patrimony of a poor man lies in the strength and dexterity of his
  • hands; and to hinder him from employing this strength and dexterity in
  • what manner he thinks proper, without injury to his neighbour, is a plain
  • violation of this most sacred property. It is a manifest encroachment upon
  • the just liberty, both of the workman, and of those who might be disposed
  • to employ him. As it hinders the one from working at what he thinks
  • proper, so it hinders the others from employing whom they think proper. To
  • judge whether he is fit to be employed, may surely be trusted to the
  • discretion of the employers, whose interest it so much concerns. The
  • affected anxiety of the lawgiver, lest they should employ an improper
  • person, is evidently as impertinent as it is oppressive.
  • The institution of long apprenticeships can give no security that
  • insufficient workmanship shall not frequently be exposed to public sale.
  • When this is done, it is generally the effect of fraud, and not of
  • inability; and the longest apprenticeship can give no security against
  • fraud. Quite different regulations are necessary to prevent this abuse.
  • The sterling mark upon plate, and the stamps upon linen and woollen cloth,
  • give the purchaser much greater security than any statute of
  • apprenticeship. He generally looks at these, but never thinks it worth
  • while to enquire whether the workman had served a seven years
  • apprenticeship.
  • The institution of long apprenticeships has no tendency to form young
  • people to industry. A journeyman who works by the piece is likely to be
  • industrious, because he derives a benefit from every exertion of his
  • industry. An apprentice is likely to be idle, and almost always is so,
  • because he has no immediate interest to be otherwise. In the inferior
  • employments, the sweets of labour consist altogether in the recompence of
  • labour. They who are soonest in a condition to enjoy the sweets of it, are
  • likely soonest to conceive a relish for it, and to acquire the early habit
  • of industry. A young man naturally conceives an aversion to labour, when
  • for a long time he receives no benefit from it. The boys who are put out
  • apprentices from public charities are generally bound for more than the
  • usual number of years, and they generally turn out very idle and
  • worthless.
  • Apprenticeships were altogether unknown to the ancients. The reciprocal
  • duties of master and apprentice make a considerable article in every
  • modern code. The Roman law is perfectly silent with regard to them. I know
  • no Greek or Latin word (I might venture, I believe, to assert that there
  • is none) which expresses the idea we now annex to the word apprentice, a
  • servant bound to work at a particular trade for the benefit of a master,
  • during a term of years, upon condition that the master shall teach him
  • that trade.
  • Long apprenticeships are altogether unnecessary. The arts, which are much
  • superior to common trades, such as those of making clocks and watches,
  • contain no such mystery as to require a long course of instruction. The
  • first invention of such beautiful machines, indeed, and even that of some
  • of the instruments employed in making them, must no doubt have been the
  • work of deep thought and long time, and may justly be considered as among
  • the happiest efforts of human ingenuity. But when both have been fairly
  • invented, and are well understood, to explain to any young man, in the
  • completest manner, how to apply the instruments, and how to construct the
  • machines, cannot well require more than the lessons of a few weeks;
  • perhaps those of a few days might be sufficient. In the common mechanic
  • trades, those of a few days might certainly be sufficient. The dexterity
  • of hand, indeed, even in common trades, cannot be acquired without much
  • practice and experience. But a young man would practice with much more
  • diligence and attention, if from the beginning he wrought as a journeyman,
  • being paid in proportion to the little work which he could execute, and
  • paying in his turn for the materials which he might sometimes spoil
  • through awkwardness and inexperience. His education would generally in
  • this way be more effectual, and always less tedious and expensive. The
  • master, indeed, would be a loser. He would lose all the wages of the
  • apprentice, which he now saves, for seven years together. In the end,
  • perhaps, the apprentice himself would be a loser. In a trade so easily
  • learnt he would have more competitors, and his wages, when he came to be a
  • complete workman, would be much less than at present. The same increase of
  • competition would reduce the profits of the masters, as well as the wages
  • of workmen. The trades, the crafts, the mysteries, would all be losers.
  • But the public would be a gainer, the work of all artificers coming in
  • this way much cheaper to market.
  • It is to prevent his reduction of price, and consequently of wages and
  • profit, by restraining that free competition which would most certainly
  • occasion it, that all corporations, and the greater part of corporation
  • laws have been established. In order to erect a corporation, no other
  • authority in ancient times was requisite, in many parts of Europe, but
  • that of the town-corporate in which it was established. In England,
  • indeed, a charter from the king was likewise necessary. But this
  • prerogative of the crown seems to have been reserved rather for extorting
  • money from the subject, than for the defence of the common liberty against
  • such oppressive monopolies. Upon paying a fine to the king, the charter
  • seems generally to have been readily granted; and when any particular
  • class of artificers or traders thought proper to act as a corporation,
  • without a charter, such adulterine guilds, as they were called, were not
  • always disfranchised upon that account, but obliged to fine annually to
  • the king, for permission to exercise their usurped privileges {See Madox
  • Firma Burgi p. 26 etc.}. The immediate inspection of all corporations, and
  • of the bye-laws which they might think proper to enact for their own
  • government, belonged to the town-corporate in which they were established;
  • and whatever discipline was exercised over them, proceeded commonly, not
  • from the king, but from that greater incorporation of which those
  • subordinate ones were only parts or members.
  • The government of towns-corporate was altogether in the hands of traders
  • and artificers, and it was the manifest interest of every particular class
  • of them, to prevent the market from being overstocked, as they commonly
  • express it, with their own particular species of industry; which is in
  • reality to keep it always understocked. Each class was eager to establish
  • regulations proper for this purpose, and, provided it was allowed to do
  • so, was willing to consent that every other class should do the same. In
  • consequence of such regulations, indeed, each class was obliged to buy the
  • goods they had occasion for from every other within the town, somewhat
  • dearer than they otherwise might have done. But, in recompence, they were
  • enabled to sell their own just as much dearer; so that, so far it was as
  • broad as long, as they say; and in the dealings of the different classes
  • within the town with one another, none of them were losers by these
  • regulations. But in their dealings with the country they were all great
  • gainers; and in these latter dealings consist the whole trade which
  • supports and enriches every town.
  • Every town draws its whole subsistence, and all the materials of its
  • industry, from the: country. It pays for these chiefly in two ways. First,
  • by sending back to the country a part of those materials wrought up and
  • manufactured; in which case, their price is augmented by the wages of the
  • workmen, and the profits of their masters or immediate employers;
  • secondly, by sending to it a part both of the rude and manufactured
  • produce, either of other countries, or of distant parts of the same
  • country, imported into the town; in which case, too, the original price of
  • those goods is augmented by the wages of the carriers or sailors, and by
  • the profits of the merchants who employ them. In what is gained upon the
  • first of those branches of commerce, consists the advantage which the town
  • makes by its manufactures; in what is gained upon the second, the
  • advantage of its inland and foreign trade. The wages of the workmen, and
  • the profits of their different employers, make up the whole of what is
  • gained upon both. Whatever regulations, therefore, tend to increase those
  • wages and profits beyond what they otherwise: would be, tend to enable the
  • town to purchase, with a smaller quantity of its labour, the produce of a
  • greater quantity of the labour of the country. They give the traders and
  • artificers in the town an advantage over the landlords, farmers, and
  • labourers, in the country, and break down that natural equality which
  • would otherwise take place in the commerce which is carried on between
  • them. The whole annual produce of the labour of the society is annually
  • divided between those two different sets of people. By means of those
  • regulations, a greater share of it is given to the inhabitants of the town
  • than would otherwise fall to them, and a less to those of the country.
  • The price which the town really pays for the provisions and materials
  • annually imported into it, is the quantity of manufactures and other goods
  • annually exported from it. The dearer the latter are sold, the cheaper the
  • former are bought. The industry of the town becomes more, and that of the
  • country less advantageous.
  • That the industry which is carried on in towns is, everywhere in Europe,
  • more advantageous than that which is carried on in the country, without
  • entering into any very nice computations, we may satisfy ourselves by one
  • very simple and obvious observation. In every country of Europe, we find
  • at least a hundred people who have acquired great fortunes, from small
  • beginnings, by trade and manufactures, the industry which properly belongs
  • to towns, for one who has done so by that which properly belongs to the
  • country, the raising of rude produce by the improvement and cultivation of
  • land. Industry, therefore, must be better rewarded, the wages of labour
  • and the profits of stock must evidently be greater, in the one situation
  • than in the other. But stock and labour naturally seek the most
  • advantageous employment. They naturally, therefore, resort as much as they
  • can to the town, and desert the country.
  • The inhabitants of a town being collected into one place, can easily
  • combine together. The most insignificant trades carried on in towns have,
  • accordingly, in some place or other, been incorporated; and even where
  • they have never been incorporated, yet the corporation-spirit, the
  • jealousy of strangers, the aversion to take apprentices, or to communicate
  • the secret of their trade, generally prevail in them, and often teach
  • them, by voluntary associations and agreements, to prevent that free
  • competition which they cannot prohibit by bye-laws. The trades which
  • employ but a small number of hands, run most easily into such
  • combinations. Half-a-dozen wool-combers, perhaps, are necessary to keep a
  • thousand spinners and weavers at work. By combining not to take
  • apprentices, they can not only engross the employment, but reduce the
  • whole manufacture into a sort of slavery to themselves, and raise the
  • price of their labour much above what is due to the nature of their work.
  • The inhabitants of the country, dispersed in distant places, cannot easily
  • combine together. They have not only never been incorporated, but the
  • incorporation spirit never has prevailed among them. No apprenticeship has
  • ever been thought necessary to qualify for husbandry, the great trade of
  • the country. After what are called the fine arts, and the liberal
  • professions, however, there is perhaps no trade which requires so great a
  • variety of knowledge and experience. The innumerable volumes which have
  • been written upon it in all languages, may satisfy us, that among the
  • wisest and most learned nations, it has never been regarded as a matter
  • very easily understood. And from all those volumes we shall in vain
  • attempt to collect that knowledge of its various and complicated
  • operations which is commonly possessed even by the common farmer; how
  • contemptuously soever the very contemptible authors of some of them may
  • sometimes affect to speak of him. There is scarce any common mechanic
  • trade, on the contrary, of which all the operations may not be as
  • completely and distinctly explained in a pamphlet of a very few pages, as
  • it is possible for words illustrated by figures to explain them. In the
  • history of the arts, now publishing by the French Academy of Sciences,
  • several of them are actually explained in this manner. The direction of
  • operations, besides, which must be varied with every change of the
  • weather, as well as with many other accidents, requires much more judgment
  • and discretion, than that of those which are always the same, or very
  • nearly the same.
  • Not only the art of the farmer, the general direction of the operations of
  • husbandry, but many inferior branches of country labour require much more
  • skill and experience than the greater part of mechanic trades. The man who
  • works upon brass and iron, works with instruments, and upon materials of
  • which the temper is always the same, or very nearly the same. But the man
  • who ploughs the ground with a team of horses or oxen, works with
  • instruments of which the health, strength, and temper, are very different
  • upon different occasions. The condition of the materials which he works
  • upon, too, is as variable as that of the instruments which he works with,
  • and both require to be managed with much judgment and discretion. The
  • common ploughman, though generally regarded as the pattern of stupidity
  • and ignorance, is seldom defective in this judgment and discretion. He is
  • less accustomed, indeed, to social intercourse, than the mechanic who
  • lives in a town. His voice and language are more uncouth, and more
  • difficult to be understood by those who are not used to them. His
  • understanding, however, being accustomed to consider a greater variety of
  • objects, is generally much superior to that of the other, whose whole
  • attention, from morning till night, is commonly occupied in performing one
  • or two very simple operations. How much the lower ranks of people in the
  • country are really superior to those of the town, is well known to every
  • man whom either business or curiosity has led to converse much with both.
  • In China and Indostan, accordingly, both the rank and the wages of country
  • labourers are said to be superior to those of the greater part of
  • artificers and manufacturers. They would probably be so everywhere, if
  • corporation laws and the corporation spirit did not prevent it.
  • The superiority which the industry of the towns has everywhere in Europe
  • over that of the country, is not altogether owing to corporations and
  • corporation laws. It is supported by many other regulations. The high
  • duties upon foreign manufactures, and upon all goods imported by alien
  • merchants, all tend to the same purpose. Corporation laws enable the
  • inhabitants of towns to raise their prices, without fearing to be
  • undersold by the free competition of their own countrymen. Those other
  • regulations secure them equally against that of foreigners. The
  • enhancement of price occasioned by both is everywhere finally paid by the
  • landlords, farmers, and labourers, of the country, who have seldom opposed
  • the establishment of such monopolies. They have commonly neither
  • inclination nor fitness to enter into combinations; and the clamour and
  • sophistry of merchants and manufacturers easily persuade them, that the
  • private interest of a part, and of a subordinate part, of the society, is
  • the general interest of the whole.
  • In Great Britain, the superiority of the industry of the towns over that
  • of the country seems to have been greater formerly than in the present
  • times. The wages of country labour approach nearer to those of
  • manufacturing labour, and the profits of stock employed in agriculture to
  • those of trading and manufacturing stock, than they are said to have done
  • in the last century, or in the beginning of the present. This change may
  • be regarded as the necessary, though very late consequence of the
  • extraordinary encouragement given to the industry of the towns. The stocks
  • accumulated in them come in time to be so great, that it can no longer be
  • employed with the ancient profit in that species of industry which is
  • peculiar to them. That industry has its limits like every other; and the
  • increase of stock, by increasing the competition, necessarily reduces the
  • profit. The lowering of profit in the town forces out stock to the
  • country, where, by creating a new demand for country labour, it
  • necessarily raises its wages. It then spreads itself, if I my say so, over
  • the face of the land, and, by being employed in agriculture, is in part
  • restored to the country, at the expense of which, in a great measure, it
  • had originally been accumulated in the town. That everywhere in Europe the
  • greatest improvements of the country have been owing to such over flowings
  • of the stock originally accumulated in the towns, I shall endeavour to
  • shew hereafter, and at the same time to demonstrate, that though some
  • countries have, by this course, attained to a considerable degree of
  • opulence, it is in itself necessarily slow, uncertain, liable to be
  • disturbed and interrupted by innumerable accidents, and, in every respect,
  • contrary to the order of nature and of reason. The interests, prejudices,
  • laws, and customs, which have given occasion to it, I shall endeavour to
  • explain as fully and distinctly as I can in the third and fourth books of
  • this Inquiry.
  • People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and
  • diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public,
  • or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is impossible, indeed, to
  • prevent such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would
  • be consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder
  • people of the same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to
  • do nothing to facilitate such assemblies, much less to render them
  • necessary.
  • A regulation which obliges all those of the same trade in a particular
  • town to enter their names and places of abode in a public register,
  • facilitates such assemblies. It connects individuals who might never
  • otherwise be known to one another, and gives every man of the trade a
  • direction where to find every other man of it.
  • A regulation which enables those of the same trade to tax themselves, in
  • order to provide for their poor, their sick, their widows and orphans, by
  • giving them a common interest to manage, renders such assemblies
  • necessary.
  • An incorporation not only renders them necessary, but makes the act of the
  • majority binding upon the whole. In a free trade, an effectual combination
  • cannot be established but by the unanimous consent of every single trader,
  • and it cannot last longer than every single trader continues of the same
  • mind. The majority of a corporation can enact a bye-law, with proper
  • penalties, which will limit the competition more effectually and more
  • durably than any voluntary combination whatever.
  • The pretence that corporations are necessary for the better government of
  • the trade, is without any foundation. The real and effectual discipline
  • which is exercised over a workman, is not that of his corporation, but
  • that of his customers. It is the fear of losing their employment which
  • restrains his frauds and corrects his negligence. An exclusive corporation
  • necessarily weakens the force of this discipline. A particular set of
  • workmen must then be employed, let them behave well or ill. It is upon
  • this account that, in many large incorporated towns, no tolerable workmen
  • are to be found, even in some of the most necessary trades. If you would
  • have your work tolerably executed, it must be done in the suburbs, where
  • the workmen, having no exclusive privilege, have nothing but their
  • character to depend upon, and you must then smuggle it into the town as
  • well as you can.
  • It is in this manner that the policy of Europe, by restraining the
  • competition in some employments to a smaller number than would otherwise
  • be disposed to enter into them, occasions a very important inequality in
  • the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different employments
  • of labour and stock.
  • Secondly, the policy of Europe, by increasing the competition in some
  • employments beyond what it naturally would be, occasions another
  • inequality, of an opposite kind, in the whole of the advantages and
  • disadvantages of the different employments of labour and stock.
  • It has been considered as of so much importance that a proper number of
  • young people should be educated for certain professions, that sometimes
  • the public, and sometimes the piety of private founders, have established
  • many pensions, scholarships, exhibitions, bursaries, etc. for this
  • purpose, which draw many more people into those trades than could
  • otherwise pretend to follow them. In all Christian countries, I believe,
  • the education of the greater part of churchmen is paid for in this
  • manner. Very few of them are educated altogether at their own expense.
  • The long, tedious, and expensive education, therefore, of those who are,
  • will not always procure them a suitable reward, the church being crowded
  • with people, who, in order to get employment, are willing to accept of a
  • much smaller recompence than what such an education would otherwise have
  • entitled them to; and in this manner the competition of the poor takes
  • away the reward of the rich. It would be indecent, no doubt, to compare
  • either a curate or a chaplain with a journeyman in any common trade. The
  • pay of a curate or chaplain, however, may very properly be considered as
  • of the same nature with the wages of a journeyman. They are all three
  • paid for their work according to the contract which they may happen to
  • make with their respective superiors. Till after the middle of the
  • fourteenth century, five merks, containing about as much silver as ten
  • pounds of our present money, was in England the usual pay of a curate or
  • a stipendiary parish priest, as we find it regulated by the decrees of
  • several different national councils. At the same period, fourpence a-day,
  • containing the same quantity of silver as a shilling of our present
  • money, was declared to be the pay of a master mason; and threepence
  • a-day, equal to ninepence of our present money, that of a journeyman
  • mason. {See the Statute of Labourers, 25, Ed. III.} The wages of both
  • these labourers, therefore, supposing them to have been constantly
  • employed, were much superior to those of the curate. The wages of the
  • master mason, supposing him to have been without employment one-third of
  • the year, would have fully equalled them. By the 12th of Queen Anne, c.
  • 12. it is declared, “That whereas, for want of sufficient
  • maintenance and encouragement to curates, the cures have, in several
  • places, been meanly supplied, the bishop is, therefore, empowered to
  • appoint, by writing under his hand and seal, a sufficient certain stipend
  • or allowance, not exceeding fifty, and not less than twenty pounds
  • a-year”. Forty pounds a-year is reckoned at present very good pay
  • for a curate; and, notwithstanding this act of parliament, there are many
  • curacies under twenty pounds a-year. There are journeymen shoemakers in
  • London who earn forty pounds a-year, and there is scarce an industrious
  • workman of any kind in that metropolis who does not earn more than
  • twenty. This last sum, indeed, does not exceed what is frequently earned
  • by common labourers in many country parishes. Whenever the law has
  • attempted to regulate the wages of workmen, it has always been rather to
  • lower them than to raise them. But the law has, upon many occasions,
  • attempted to raise the wages of curates, and, for the dignity of the
  • church, to oblige the rectors of parishes to give them more than the
  • wretched maintenance which they themselves might be willing to accept of.
  • And, in both cases, the law seems to have been equally ineffectual, and
  • has never either been able to raise the wages of curates, or to sink
  • those of labourers to the degree that was intended; because it has never
  • been able to hinder either the one from being willing to accept of less
  • than the legal allowance, on account of the indigence of their situation
  • and the multitude of their competitors, or the other from receiving more,
  • on account of the contrary competition of those who expected to derive
  • either profit or pleasure from employing them.
  • The great benefices and other ecclesiastical dignities support the honour
  • of the church, notwithstanding the mean circumstances of some of its
  • inferior members. The respect paid to the profession, too, makes some
  • compensation even to them for the meanness of their pecuniary recompence.
  • In England, and in all Roman catholic countries, the lottery of the church
  • is in reality much more advantageous than is necessary. The example of the
  • churches of Scotland, of Geneva, and of several other protestant churches,
  • may satisfy us, that in so creditable a profession, in which education is
  • so easily procured, the hopes of much more moderate benefices will draw a
  • sufficient number of learned, decent, and respectable men into holy
  • orders.
  • In professions in which there are no benefices, such as law and physic, if
  • an equal proportion of people were educated at the public expense, the
  • competition would soon be so great as to sink very much their pecuniary
  • reward. It might then not be worth any man’s while to educate his son to
  • either of those professions at his own expense. They would be entirely
  • abandoned to such as had been educated by those public charities, whose
  • numbers and necessities would oblige them in general to content themselves
  • with a very miserable recompence, to the entire degradation of the now
  • respectable professions of law and physic.
  • That unprosperous race of men, commonly called men of letters, are pretty
  • much in the situation which lawyers and physicians probably would be in,
  • upon the foregoing supposition. In every part of Europe, the greater part
  • of them have been educated for the church, but have been hindered by
  • different reasons from entering into holy orders. They have generally,
  • therefore, been educated at the public expense; and their numbers are
  • everywhere so great, as commonly to reduce the price of their labour to a
  • very paltry recompence.
  • Before the invention of the art of printing, the only employment by which
  • a man of letters could make any thing by his talents, was that of a public
  • or private teacher, or by communicating to other people the curious and
  • useful knowledge which he had acquired himself; and this is still surely a
  • more honourable, a more useful, and, in general, even a more profitable
  • employment than that other of writing for a bookseller, to which the art
  • of printing has given occasion. The time and study, the genius, knowledge,
  • and application requisite to qualify an eminent teacher of the sciences,
  • are at least equal to what is necessary for the greatest practitioners in
  • law and physic. But the usual reward of the eminent teacher bears no
  • proportion to that of the lawyer or physician, because the trade of the
  • one is crowded with indigent people, who have been brought up to it at the
  • public expense; whereas those of the other two are encumbered with very
  • few who have not been educated at their own. The usual recompence,
  • however, of public and private teachers, small as it may appear, would
  • undoubtedly be less than it is, if the competition of those yet more
  • indigent men of letters, who write for bread, was not taken out of the
  • market. Before the invention of the art of printing, a scholar and a
  • beggar seem to have been terms very nearly synonymous. The different
  • governors of the universities, before that time, appear to have often
  • granted licences to their scholars to beg.
  • In ancient times, before any charities of this kind had been established
  • for the education of indigent people to the learned professions, the
  • rewards of eminent teachers appear to have been much more considerable.
  • Isocrates, in what is called his discourse against the sophists,
  • reproaches the teachers of his own times with inconsistency. “They make
  • the most magnificent promises to their scholars,” says he, “and undertake
  • to teach them to be wise, to be happy, and to be just; and, in return for
  • so important a service, they stipulate the paltry reward of four or five
  • minae.” “They who teach wisdom,” continues he, “ought certainly to be wise
  • themselves; but if any man were to sell such a bargain for such a price,
  • he would be convicted of the most evident folly.” He certainly does not
  • mean here to exaggerate the reward, and we may be assured that it was not
  • less than he represents it. Four minae were equal to thirteen pounds six
  • shillings and eightpence; five minae to sixteen pounds thirteen shillings
  • and fourpence. Something not less than the largest of those two sums,
  • therefore, must at that time have been usually paid to the most eminent
  • teachers at Athens. Isocrates himself demanded ten minae, or £ 33:6:8 from
  • each scholar. When he taught at Athens, he is said to have had a hundred
  • scholars. I understand this to be the number whom he taught at one time,
  • or who attended what we would call one course of lectures; a number which
  • will not appear extraordinary from so great a city to so famous a teacher,
  • who taught, too, what was at that time the most fashionable of all
  • sciences, rhetoric. He must have made, therefore, by each course of
  • lectures, a thousand minae, or £ 3335:6:8. A thousand minae, accordingly,
  • is said by Plutarch, in another place, to have been his didactron, or
  • usual price of teaching. Many other eminent teachers in those times appear
  • to have acquired great fortunes. Georgias made a present to the temple of
  • Delphi of his own statue in solid gold. We must not, I presume, suppose
  • that it was as large as the life. His way of living, as well as that of
  • Hippias and Protagoras, two other eminent teachers of those times, is
  • represented by Plato as splendid, even to ostentation. Plato himself is
  • said to have lived with a good deal of magnificence. Aristotle, after
  • having been tutor to Alexander, and most munificently rewarded, as it is
  • universally agreed, both by him and his father, Philip, thought it worth
  • while, notwithstanding, to return to Athens, in order to resume the
  • teaching of his school. Teachers of the sciences were probably in those
  • times less common than they came to be in an age or two afterwards, when
  • the competition had probably somewhat reduced both the price of their
  • labour and the admiration for their persons. The most eminent of them,
  • however, appear always to have enjoyed a degree of consideration much
  • superior to any of the like profession in the present times. The Athenians
  • sent Carneades the academic, and Diogenes the stoic, upon a solemn embassy
  • to Rome; and though their city had then declined from its former grandeur,
  • it was still an independent and considerable republic.
  • Carneades, too, was a Babylonian by birth; and as there never was a people
  • more jealous of admitting foreigners to public offices than the Athenians,
  • their consideration for him must have been very great.
  • This inequality is, upon the whole, perhaps rather advantageous than
  • hurtful to the public. It may somewhat degrade the profession of a public
  • teacher; but the cheapness of literary education is surely an advantage
  • which greatly overbalances this trifling inconveniency. The public, too,
  • might derive still greater benefit from it, if the constitution of those
  • schools and colleges, in which education is carried on, was more
  • reasonable than it is at present through the greater part of Europe.
  • Thirdly, the policy of Europe, by obstructing the free circulation of
  • labour and stock, both from employment to employment, and from place to
  • place, occasions, in some cases, a very inconvenient inequality in the
  • whole of the advantages and disadvantages of their different employments.
  • The statute of apprenticeship obstructs the free circulation of labour
  • from one employment to another, even in the same place. The exclusive
  • privileges of corporations obstruct it from one place to another, even in
  • the same employment.
  • It frequently happens, that while high wages are given to the workmen in
  • one manufacture, those in another are obliged to content themselves with
  • bare subsistence. The one is in an advancing state, and has therefore a
  • continual demand for new hands; the other is in a declining state, and the
  • superabundance of hands is continually increasing. Those two manufactures
  • may sometimes be in the same town, and sometimes in the same
  • neighbourhood, without being able to lend the least assistance to one
  • another. The statute of apprenticeship may oppose it in the one case, and
  • both that and an exclusive corporation in the other. In many different
  • manufactures, however, the operations are so much alike, that the workmen
  • could easily change trades with one another, if those absurd laws did not
  • hinder them. The arts of weaving plain linen and plain silk, for example,
  • are almost entirely the same. That of weaving plain woollen is somewhat
  • different; but the difference is so insignificant, that either a linen or
  • a silk weaver might become a tolerable workman in a very few days. If any
  • of those three capital manufactures, therefore, were decaying, the workmen
  • might find a resource in one of the other two which was in a more
  • prosperous condition; and their wages would neither rise too high in the
  • thriving, nor sink too low in the decaying manufacture. The linen
  • manufacture, indeed, is in England, by a particular statute, open to every
  • body; but as it is not much cultivated through the greater part of the
  • country, it can afford no general resource to the work men of other
  • decaying manufactures, who, wherever the statute of apprenticeship takes
  • place, have no other choice, but either to come upon the parish, or to
  • work as common labourers; for which, by their habits, they are much worse
  • qualified than for any sort of manufacture that bears any resemblance to
  • their own. They generally, therefore, chuse to come upon the parish.
  • Whatever obstructs the free circulation of labour from one employment to
  • another, obstructs that of stock likewise; the quantity of stock which can
  • be employed in any branch of business depending very much upon that of the
  • labour which can be employed in it. Corporation laws, however, give less
  • obstruction to the free circulation of stock from one place to another,
  • than to that of labour. It is everywhere much easier for a wealthy
  • merchant to obtain the privilege of trading in a town-corporate, than for
  • a poor artificer to obtain that of working in it.
  • The obstruction which corporation laws give to the free circulation of
  • labour is common, I believe, to every part of Europe. That which is given
  • to it by the poor laws is, so far as I know, peculiar to England. It
  • consists in the difficulty which a poor man finds in obtaining a
  • settlement, or even in being allowed to exercise his industry in any
  • parish but that to which he belongs. It is the labour of artificers and
  • manufacturers only of which the free circulation is obstructed by
  • corporation laws. The difficulty of obtaining settlements obstructs even
  • that of common labour. It may be worth while to give some account of the
  • rise, progress, and present state of this disorder, the greatest, perhaps,
  • of any in the police of England.
  • When, by the destruction of monasteries, the poor had been deprived of the
  • charity of those religious houses, after some other ineffectual attempts
  • for their relief, it was enacted, by the 43d of Elizabeth, c. 2. that
  • every parish should be bound to provide for its own poor, and that
  • overseers of the poor should be annually appointed, who, with the
  • church-wardens, should raise, by a parish rate, competent sums for this
  • purpose.
  • By this statute, the necessity of providing for their own poor was
  • indispensably imposed upon every parish. Who were to be considered as the
  • poor of each parish became, therefore, a question of some importance. This
  • question, after some variation, was at last determined by the 13th and
  • 14th of Charles II. when it was enacted, that forty days undisturbed
  • residence should gain any person a settlement in any parish; but that
  • within that time it should be lawful for two justices of the peace, upon
  • complaint made by the church-wardens or overseers of the poor, to remove
  • any new inhabitant to the parish where he was last legally settled; unless
  • he either rented a tenement of ten pounds a-year, or could give such
  • security for the discharge of the parish where he was then living, as
  • those justices should judge sufficient.
  • Some frauds, it is said, were committed in consequence of this statute;
  • parish officers sometimes bribing their own poor to go clandestinely to
  • another parish, and, by keeping themselves concealed for forty days, to
  • gain a settlement there, to the discharge of that to which they properly
  • belonged. It was enacted, therefore, by the 1st of James II. that the
  • forty days undisturbed residence of any person necessary to gain a
  • settlement, should be accounted only from the time of his delivering
  • notice, in writing, of the place of his abode and the number of his
  • family, to one of the church-wardens or overseers of the parish where he
  • came to dwell.
  • But parish officers, it seems, were not always more honest with regard to
  • their own than they had been with regard to other parishes, and sometimes
  • connived at such intrusions, receiving the notice, and taking no proper
  • steps in consequence of it. As every person in a parish, therefore, was
  • supposed to have an interest to prevent as much as possible their being
  • burdened by such intruders, it was further enacted by the 3rd of William
  • III. that the forty days residence should be accounted only from the
  • publication of such notice in writing on Sunday in the church, immediately
  • after divine service.
  • “After all,” says Doctor Burn, “this kind of settlement, by continuing
  • forty days after publication of notice in writing, is very seldom
  • obtained; and the design of the acts is not so much for gaining of
  • settlements, as for the avoiding of them by persons coming into a parish
  • clandestinely, for the giving of notice is only putting a force upon the
  • parish to remove. But if a person’s situation is such, that it is doubtful
  • whether he is actually removable or not, he shall, by giving of notice,
  • compel the parish either to allow him a settlement uncontested, by
  • suffering him to continue forty days, or by removing him to try the
  • right.”
  • This statute, therefore, rendered it almost impracticable for a poor man
  • to gain a new settlement in the old way, by forty days inhabitancy. But
  • that it might not appear to preclude altogether the common people of one
  • parish from ever establishing themselves with security in another, it
  • appointed four other ways by which a settlement might be gained without
  • any notice delivered or published. The first was, by being taxed to parish
  • rates and paying them; the second, by being elected into an annual parish
  • office, and serving in it a year; the third, by serving an apprenticeship
  • in the parish; the fourth, by being hired into service there for a year,
  • and continuing in the same service during the whole of it. Nobody can gain
  • a settlement by either of the two first ways, but by the public deed of
  • the whole parish, who are too well aware of the consequences to adopt any
  • new-comer, who has nothing but his labour to support him, either by taxing
  • him to parish rates, or by electing him into a parish office.
  • No married man can well gain any settlement in either of the two last
  • ways. An apprentice is scarce ever married; and it is expressly enacted,
  • that no married servant shall gain any settlement by being hired for a
  • year. The principal effect of introducing settlement by service, has been
  • to put out in a great measure the old fashion of hiring for a year; which
  • before had been so customary in England, that even at this day, if no
  • particular term is agreed upon, the law intends that every servant is
  • hired for a year. But masters are not always willing to give their
  • servants a settlement by hiring them in this manner; and servants are not
  • always willing to be so hired, because, as every last settlement
  • discharges all the foregoing, they might thereby lose their original
  • settlement in the places of their nativity, the habitation of their
  • parents and relations.
  • No independent workman, it is evident, whether labourer or artificer, is
  • likely to gain any new settlement, either by apprenticeship or by service.
  • When such a person, therefore, carried his industry to a new parish, he
  • was liable to be removed, how healthy and industrious soever, at the
  • caprice of any churchwarden or overseer, unless he either rented a
  • tenement of ten pounds a-year, a thing impossible for one who has nothing
  • but his labour to live by, or could give such security for the discharge
  • of the parish as two justices of the peace should judge sufficient.
  • What security they shall require, indeed, is left altogether to their
  • discretion; but they cannot well require less than thirty pounds, it
  • having been enacted, that the purchase even of a freehold estate of less
  • than thirty pounds value, shall not gain any person a settlement, as not
  • being sufficient for the discharge of the parish. But this is a security
  • which scarce any man who lives by labour can give; and much greater
  • security is frequently demanded.
  • In order to restore, in some measure, that free circulation of labour
  • which those different statutes had almost entirely taken away, the
  • invention of certificates was fallen upon. By the 8th and 9th of William
  • III. it was enacted that if any person should bring a certificate from the
  • parish where he was last legally settled, subscribed by the church-wardens
  • and overseers of the poor, and allowed by two justices of the peace, that
  • every other parish should be obliged to receive him; that he should not be
  • removable merely upon account of his being likely to become chargeable,
  • but only upon his becoming actually chargeable; and that then the parish
  • which granted the certificate should be obliged to pay the expense both of
  • his maintenance and of his removal. And in order to give the most perfect
  • security to the parish where such certificated man should come to reside,
  • it was further enacted by the same statute, that he should gain no
  • settlement there by any means whatever, except either by renting a
  • tenement of ten pounds a-year, or by serving upon his own account in an
  • annual parish office for one whole year; and consequently neither by
  • notice nor by service, nor by apprenticeship, nor by paying parish rates.
  • By the 12th of Queen Anne, too, stat. 1, c.18, it was further enacted,
  • that neither the servants nor apprentices of such certificated man should
  • gain any settlement in the parish where he resided under such certificate.
  • How far this invention has restored that free circulation of labour, which
  • the preceding statutes had almost entirely taken away, we may learn from
  • the following very judicious observation of Doctor Burn. “It is obvious,”
  • says he, “that there are divers good reasons for requiring certificates
  • with persons coming to settle in any place; namely, that persons residing
  • under them can gain no settlement, neither by apprenticeship, nor by
  • service, nor by giving notice, nor by paying parish rates; that they can
  • settle neither apprentices nor servants; that if they become chargeable,
  • it is certainly known whither to remove them, and the parish shall be paid
  • for the removal, and for their maintenance in the mean time; and that, if
  • they fall sick, and cannot be removed, the parish which gave the
  • certificate must maintain them; none of all which can be without a
  • certificate. Which reasons will hold proportionably for parishes not
  • granting certificates in ordinary cases; for it is far more than an equal
  • chance, but that they will have the certificated persons again, and in a
  • worse condition.” The moral of this observation seems to be, that
  • certificates ought always to be required by the parish where any poor man
  • comes to reside, and that they ought very seldom to be granted by that
  • which he purposes to leave. “There is somewhat of hardship in this matter
  • of certificates,” says the same very intelligent author, in his History of
  • the Poor Laws, “by putting it in the power of a parish officer to imprison
  • a man as it were for life, however inconvenient it may be for him to
  • continue at that place where he has had the misfortune to acquire what is
  • called a settlement, or whatever advantage he may propose himself by
  • living elsewhere.”
  • Though a certificate carries along with it no testimonial of good
  • behaviour, and certifies nothing but that the person belongs to the parish
  • to which he really does belong, it is altogether discretionary in the
  • parish officers either to grant or to refuse it. A mandamus was once moved
  • for, says Doctor Burn, to compel the church-wardens and overseers to sign
  • a certificate; but the Court of King’s Bench rejected the motion as a very
  • strange attempt.
  • The very unequal price of labour which we frequently find in England, in
  • places at no great distance from one another, is probably owing to the
  • obstruction which the law of settlements gives to a poor man who would
  • carry his industry from one parish to another without a certificate. A
  • single man, indeed who is healthy and industrious, may sometimes reside by
  • sufferance without one; but a man with a wife and family who should
  • attempt to do so, would, in most parishes, be sure of being removed; and,
  • if the single man should afterwards marry, he would generally be removed
  • likewise. The scarcity of hands in one parish, therefore, cannot always be
  • relieved by their superabundance in another, as it is constantly in
  • Scotland, and I believe, in all other countries where there is no
  • difficulty of settlement. In such countries, though wages may sometimes
  • rise a little in the neighbourhood of a great town, or wherever else there
  • is an extraordinary demand for labour, and sink gradually as the distance
  • from such places increases, till they fall back to the common rate of the
  • country; yet we never meet with those sudden and unaccountable differences
  • in the wages of neighbouring places which we sometimes find in England,
  • where it is often more difficult for a poor man to pass the artificial
  • boundary of a parish, than an arm of the sea, or a ridge of high
  • mountains, natural boundaries which sometimes separate very distinctly
  • different rates of wages in other countries.
  • To remove a man who has committed no misdemeanour, from the parish where
  • he chooses to reside, is an evident violation of natural liberty and
  • justice. The common people of England, however, so jealous of their
  • liberty, but like the common people of most other countries, never rightly
  • understanding wherein it consists, have now, for more than a century
  • together, suffered themselves to be exposed to this oppression without a
  • remedy. Though men of reflection, too, have sometimes complained of the
  • law of settlements as a public grievance; yet it has never been the object
  • of any general popular clamour, such as that against general warrants, an
  • abusive practice undoubtedly, but such a one as was not likely to occasion
  • any general oppression. There is scarce a poor man in England, of forty
  • years of age, I will venture to say, who has not, in some part of his
  • life, felt himself most cruelly oppressed by this ill-contrived law of
  • settlements.
  • I shall conclude this long chapter with observing, that though anciently
  • it was usual to rate wages, first by general laws extending over the whole
  • kingdom, and afterwards by particular orders of the justices of peace in
  • every particular county, both these practices have now gone entirely into
  • disuse. “By the experience of above four hundred years,” says Doctor Burn,
  • “it seems time to lay aside all endeavours to bring under strict
  • regulations, what in its own nature seems incapable of minute limitation;
  • for if all persons in the same kind of work were to receive equal wages,
  • there would be no emulation, and no room left for industry or ingenuity.”
  • Particular acts of parliament, however, still attempt sometimes to
  • regulate wages in particular trades, and in particular places. Thus the
  • 8th of George III. prohibits, under heavy penalties, all master tailors in
  • London, and five miles round it, from giving, and their workmen from
  • accepting, more than two shillings and sevenpence halfpenny a-day, except
  • in the case of a general mourning. Whenever the legislature attempts to
  • regulate the differences between masters and their workmen, its
  • counsellors are always the masters. When the regulation, therefore, is in
  • favour of the workmen, it is always just and equitable; but it is
  • sometimes otherwise when in favour of the masters. Thus the law which
  • obliges the masters in several different trades to pay their workmen in
  • money, and not in goods, is quite just and equitable. It imposes no real
  • hardship upon the masters. It only obliges them to pay that value in
  • money, which they pretended to pay, but did not always really pay, in
  • goods. This law is in favour of the workmen; but the 8th of George III. is
  • in favour of the masters. When masters combine together, in order to
  • reduce the wages of their workmen, they commonly enter into a private bond
  • or agreement, not to give more than a certain wage, under a certain
  • penalty. Were the workmen to enter into a contrary combination of the same
  • kind, not to accept of a certain wage, under a certain penalty, the law
  • would punish them very severely; and, if it dealt impartially, it would
  • treat the masters in the same manner. But the 8th of George III. enforces
  • by law that very regulation which masters sometimes attempt to establish
  • by such combinations. The complaint of the workmen, that it puts the
  • ablest and most industrious upon the same footing with an ordinary
  • workman, seems perfectly well founded.
  • In ancient times, too, it was usual to attempt to regulate the profits of
  • merchants and other dealers, by regulating the price of provisions and
  • ether goods. The assize of bread is, so far as I know, the only remnant of
  • this ancient usage. Where there is an exclusive corporation, it may,
  • perhaps, be proper to regulate the price of the first necessary of life;
  • but, where there is none, the competition will regulate it much better
  • than any assize. The method of fixing the assize of bread, established by
  • the 31st of George II. could not be put in practice in Scotland, on
  • account of a defect in the law, its execution depending upon the office of
  • clerk of the market, which does not exist there. This defect was not
  • remedied till the third of George III. The want of an assize occasioned no
  • sensible inconveniency; and the establishment of one in the few places
  • where it has yet taken place has produced no sensible advantage. In the
  • greater part of the towns in Scotland, however, there is an incorporation
  • of bakers, who claim exclusive privileges, though they are not very
  • strictly guarded. The proportion between the different rates, both of
  • wages and profit, in the different employments of labour and stock, seems
  • not to be much affected, as has already been observed, by the riches or
  • poverty, the advancing, stationary, or declining state of the society.
  • Such revolutions in the public welfare, though they affect the general
  • rates both of wages and profit, must, in the end, affect them equally in
  • all different employments. The proportion between them, therefore, must
  • remain the same, and cannot well be altered, at least for any considerable
  • time, by any such revolutions.
  • CHAPTER XI.
  • OF THE RENT OF LAND.
  • Rent, considered as the price paid for the use of land, is naturally the
  • highest which the tenant can afford to pay in the actual circumstances of
  • the land. In adjusting the terms of the lease, the landlord endeavours to
  • leave him no greater share of the produce than what is sufficient to keep
  • up the stock from which he furnishes the seed, pays the labour, and
  • purchases and maintains the cattle and other instruments of husbandry,
  • together with the ordinary profits of farming stock in the neighbourhood.
  • This is evidently the smallest share with which the tenant can content
  • himself, without being a loser, and the landlord seldom means to leave him
  • any more. Whatever part of the produce, or, what is the same thing,
  • whatever part of its price, is over and above this share, he naturally
  • endeavours to reserve to himself as the rent of his land, which is
  • evidently the highest the tenant can afford to pay in the actual
  • circumstances of the land. Sometimes, indeed, the liberality, more
  • frequently the ignorance, of the landlord, makes him accept of somewhat
  • less than this portion; and sometimes, too, though more rarely, the
  • ignorance of the tenant makes him undertake to pay somewhat more, or to
  • content himself with somewhat less, than the ordinary profits of farming
  • stock in the neighbourhood. This portion, however, may still be considered
  • as the natural rent of land, or the rent at which it is naturally meant
  • that land should, for the most part, be let.
  • The rent of land, it may be thought, is frequently no more than a
  • reasonable profit or interest for the stock laid out by the landlord upon
  • its improvement. This, no doubt, may be partly the case upon some
  • occasions; for it can scarce ever be more than partly the case. The
  • landlord demands a rent even for unimproved land, and the supposed
  • interest or profit upon the expense of improvement is generally an
  • addition to this original rent. Those improvements, besides, are not
  • always made by the stock of the landlord, but sometimes by that of the
  • tenant. When the lease comes to be renewed, however, the landlord commonly
  • demands the same augmentation of rent as if they had been all made by his
  • own.
  • He sometimes demands rent for what is altogether incapable of human
  • improvements. Kelp is a species of sea-weed, which, when burnt, yields an
  • alkaline salt, useful for making glass, soap, and for several other
  • purposes. It grows in several parts of Great Britain, particularly in
  • Scotland, upon such rocks only as lie within the high-water mark, which
  • are twice every day covered with the sea, and of which the produce,
  • therefore, was never augmented by human industry. The landlord, however,
  • whose estate is bounded by a kelp shore of this kind, demands a rent for
  • it as much as for his corn-fields.
  • The sea in the neighbourhood of the islands of Shetland is more than
  • commonly abundant in fish, which makes a great part of the subsistence of
  • their inhabitants. But, in order to profit by the produce of the water,
  • they must have a habitation upon the neighbouring land. The rent of the
  • landlord is in proportion, not to what the farmer can make by the land,
  • but to what he can make both by the land and the water. It is partly paid
  • in sea-fish; and one of the very few instances in which rent makes a part
  • of the price of that commodity, is to be found in that country.
  • The rent of land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use of
  • the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to
  • what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or
  • to what he can afford to take, but to what the farmer can afford to give.
  • Such parts only of the produce of land can commonly be brought to market,
  • of which the ordinary price is sufficient to replace the stock which must
  • be employed in bringing them thither, together with its ordinary profits.
  • If the ordinary price is more than this, the surplus part of it will
  • naturally go to the rent of the land. If it is not more, though the
  • commodity may be brought to market, it can afford no rent to the landlord.
  • Whether the price is, or is not more, depends upon the demand.
  • There are some parts of the produce of land, for which the demand must
  • always be such as to afford a greater price than what is sufficient to
  • bring them to market; and there are others for which it either may or may
  • not be such as to afford this greater price. The former must always afford
  • a rent to the landlord. The latter sometimes may and sometimes may not,
  • according to different circumstances.
  • Rent, it is to be observed, therefore, enters into the composition of the
  • price of commodities in a different way from wages and profit. High or low
  • wages and profit are the causes of high or low price; high or low rent is
  • the effect of it. It is because high or low wages and profit must be paid,
  • in order to bring a particular commodity to market, that its price is high
  • or low. But it is because its price is high or low, a great deal more, or
  • very little more, or no more, than what is sufficient to pay those wages
  • and profit, that it affords a high rent, or a low rent, or no rent at all.
  • The particular consideration, first, of those parts of the produce of land
  • which always afford some rent; secondly, of those which sometimes may and
  • sometimes may not afford rent; and, thirdly, of the variations which, in
  • the different periods of improvement, naturally take place in the relative
  • value of those two different sorts of rude produce, when compared both
  • with one another and with manufactured commodities, will divide this
  • chapter into three parts.
  • PART I.—Of the Produce of Land which always affords Rent.
  • As men, like all other animals, naturally multiply in proportion to the
  • means of their subsistence, food is always more or less in demand. It can
  • always purchase or command a greater or smaller quantity of labour, and
  • somebody can always be found who is willing to do something in order to
  • obtain it. The quantity of labour, indeed, which it can purchase, is not
  • always equal to what it could maintain, if managed in the most economical
  • manner, on account of the high wages which are sometimes given to labour;
  • but it can always purchase such a quantity of labour as it can maintain,
  • according to the rate at which that sort of labour is commonly maintained
  • in the neighbourhood.
  • But land, in almost any situation, produces a greater quantity of food
  • than what is sufficient to maintain all the labour necessary for bringing
  • it to market, in the most liberal way in which that labour is ever
  • maintained. The surplus, too, is always more than sufficient to replace
  • the stock which employed that labour, together with its profits.
  • Something, therefore, always remains for a rent to the landlord.
  • The most desert moors in Norway and Scotland produce some sort of pasture
  • for cattle, of which the milk and the increase are always more than
  • sufficient, not only to maintain all the labour necessary for tending
  • them, and to pay the ordinary profit to the farmer or the owner of the
  • herd or flock, but to afford some small rent to the landlord. The rent
  • increases in proportion to the goodness of the pasture. The same extent of
  • ground not only maintains a greater number of cattle, but as they are
  • brought within a smaller compass, less labour becomes requisite to tend
  • them, and to collect their produce. The landlord gains both ways; by the
  • increase of the produce, and by the diminution of the labour which must be
  • maintained out of it.
  • The rent of land not only varies with its fertility, whatever be its
  • produce, but with its situation, whatever be its fertility. Land in the
  • neighbourhood of a town gives a greater rent than land equally fertile in
  • a distant part of the country. Though it may cost no more labour to
  • cultivate the one than the other, it must always cost more to bring the
  • produce of the distant land to market. A greater quantity of labour,
  • therefore, must be maintained out of it; and the surplus, from which are
  • drawn both the profit of the farmer and the rent of the landlord, must be
  • diminished. But in remote parts of the country, the rate of profit, as has
  • already been shewn, is generally higher than in the neighbourhood of a
  • large town. A smaller proportion of this diminished surplus, therefore,
  • must belong to the landlord.
  • Good roads, canals, and navigable rivers, by diminishing the expense of
  • carriage, put the remote parts of the country more nearly upon a level
  • with those in the neighbourhood of the town. They are upon that account
  • the greatest of all improvements. They encourage the cultivation of the
  • remote, which must always be the most extensive circle of the country.
  • They are advantageous to the town by breaking down the monopoly of the
  • country in its neighbourhood. They are advantageous even to that part of
  • the country. Though they introduce some rival commodities into the old
  • market, they open many new markets to its produce. Monopoly, besides, is a
  • great enemy to good management, which can never be universally
  • established, but in consequence of that free and universal competition
  • which forces every body to have recourse to it for the sake of self
  • defence. It is not more than fifty years ago, that some of the counties in
  • the neighbourhood of London petitioned the parliament against the
  • extension of the turnpike roads into the remoter counties. Those remoter
  • counties, they pretended, from the cheapness of labour, would be able to
  • sell their grass and corn cheaper in the London market than themselves,
  • and would thereby reduce their rents, and ruin their cultivation. Their
  • rents, however, have risen, and their cultivation has been improved since
  • that time.
  • A corn field of moderate fertility produces a much greater quantity of
  • food for man, than the best pasture of equal extent. Though its
  • cultivation requires much more labour, yet the surplus which remains after
  • replacing the seed and maintaining all that labour, is likewise much
  • greater. If a pound of butcher’s meat, therefore, was never supposed to be
  • worth more than a pound of bread, this greater surplus would everywhere be
  • of greater value and constitute a greater fund, both for the profit of the
  • farmer and the rent of the landlord. It seems to have done so universally
  • in the rude beginnings of agriculture.
  • But the relative values of those two different species of food, bread and
  • butcher’s meat, are very different in the different periods of
  • agriculture. In its rude beginnings, the unimproved wilds, which then
  • occupy the far greater part of the country, are all abandoned to cattle.
  • There is more butcher’s meat than bread; and bread, therefore, is the food
  • for which there is the greatest competition, and which consequently brings
  • the greatest price. At Buenos Ayres, we are told by Ulloa, four reals,
  • one-and-twenty pence halfpenny sterling, was, forty or fifty years ago,
  • the ordinary price of an ox, chosen from a herd of two or three hundred.
  • He says nothing of the price of bread, probably because he found nothing
  • remarkable about it. An ox there, he says, costs little more than the
  • labour of catching him. But corn can nowhere be raised without a great
  • deal of labour; and in a country which lies upon the river Plate, at that
  • time the direct road from Europe to the silver mines of Potosi, the
  • money-price of labour could be very cheap. It is otherwise when
  • cultivation is extended over the greater part of the country. There is
  • then more bread than butcher’s meat. The competition changes its
  • direction, and the price of butcher’s meat becomes greater than the price
  • of bread.
  • By the extension, besides, of cultivation, the unimproved wilds become
  • insufficient to supply the demand for butcher’s meat. A great part of the
  • cultivated lands must be employed in rearing and fattening cattle; of
  • which the price, therefore, must be sufficient to pay, not only the labour
  • necessary for tending them, but the rent which the landlord, and the
  • profit which the farmer, could have drawn from such land employed in
  • tillage. The cattle bred upon the most uncultivated moors, when brought to
  • the same market, are, in proportion to their weight or goodness, sold at
  • the same price as those which are reared upon the most improved land. The
  • proprietors of those moors profit by it, and raise the rent of their land
  • in proportion to the price of their cattle. It is not more than a century
  • ago, that in many parts of the Highlands of Scotland, butcher’s meat was
  • as cheap or cheaper than even bread made of oatmeal. The Union opened the
  • market of England to the Highland cattle. Their ordinary price, at
  • present, is about three times greater than at the beginning of the
  • century, and the rents of many Highland estates have been tripled and
  • quadrupled in the same time. In almost every part of Great Britain, a
  • pound of the best butcher’s meat is, in the present times, generally worth
  • more than two pounds of the best white bread; and in plentiful years it is
  • sometimes worth three or four pounds.
  • It is thus that, in the progress of improvement, the rent and profit of
  • unimproved pasture come to be regulated in some measure by the rent and
  • profit of what is improved, and these again by the rent and profit of
  • corn. Corn is an annual crop; butcher’s meat, a crop which requires four
  • or five years to grow. As an acre of land, therefore, will produce a much
  • smaller quantity of the one species of food than of the other, the
  • inferiority of the quantity must be compensated by the superiority of the
  • price. If it was more than compensated, more corn-land would be turned
  • into pasture; and if it was not compensated, part of what was in pasture
  • would be brought back into corn.
  • This equality, however, between the rent and profit of grass and those of
  • corn; of the land of which the immediate produce is food for cattle, and
  • of that of which the immediate produce is food for men, must be understood
  • to take place only through the greater part of the improved lands of a
  • great country. In some particular local situations it is quite otherwise,
  • and the rent and profit of grass are much superior to what can be made by
  • corn.
  • Thus, in the neighbourhood of a great town, the demand for milk, and for
  • forage to horses, frequently contribute, together with the high price of
  • butcher’s meat, to raise the value of grass above what may be called its
  • natural proportion to that of corn. This local advantage, it is evident,
  • cannot be communicated to the lands at a distance.
  • Particular circumstances have sometimes rendered some countries so
  • populous, that the whole territory, like the lands in the neighbourhood of
  • a great town, has not been sufficient to produce both the grass and the
  • corn necessary for the subsistence of their inhabitants. Their lands,
  • therefore, have been principally employed in the production of grass, the
  • more bulky commodity, and which cannot be so easily brought from a great
  • distance; and corn, the food of the great body of the people, has been
  • chiefly imported from foreign countries. Holland is at present in this
  • situation; and a considerable part of ancient Italy seems to have been so
  • during the prosperity of the Romans. To feed well, old Cato said, as we
  • are told by Cicero, was the first and most profitable thing in the
  • management of a private estate; to feed tolerably well, the second; and to
  • feed ill, the third. To plough, he ranked only in the fourth place of
  • profit and advantage. Tillage, indeed, in that part of ancient Italy which
  • lay in the neighbour hood of Rome, must have been very much discouraged by
  • the distributions of corn which were frequently made to the people, either
  • gratuitously, or at a very low price. This corn was brought from the
  • conquered provinces, of which several, instead of taxes, were obliged to
  • furnish a tenth part of their produce at a stated price, about sixpence
  • a-peck, to the republic. The low price at which this corn was distributed
  • to the people, must necessarily have sunk the price of what could be
  • brought to the Roman market from Latium, or the ancient territory of Rome,
  • and must have discouraged its cultivation in that country.
  • In an open country, too, of which the principal produce is corn, a
  • well-inclosed piece of grass will frequently rent higher than any corn
  • field in its neighbourhood. It is convenient for the maintenance of the
  • cattle employed in the cultivation of the corn; and its high rent is, in
  • this case, not so properly paid from the value of its own produce, as from
  • that of the corn lands which are cultivated by means of it. It is likely
  • to fall, if ever the neighbouring lands are completely inclosed. The
  • present high rent of inclosed land in Scotland seems owing to the scarcity
  • of inclosure, and will probably last no longer than that scarcity. The
  • advantage of inclosure is greater for pasture than for corn. It saves the
  • labour of guarding the cattle, which feed better, too, when they are not
  • liable to be disturbed by their keeper or his dog.
  • But where there is no local advantage of this kind, the rent and profit of
  • corn, or whatever else is the common vegetable food of the people, must
  • naturally regulate upon the land which is fit for producing it, the rent
  • and profit of pasture.
  • The use of the artificial grasses, of turnips, carrots, cabbages, and the
  • other expedients which have been fallen upon to make an equal quantity of
  • land feed a greater number of cattle than when in natural grass, should
  • somewhat reduce, it might be expected, the superiority which, in an
  • improved country, the price of butcher’s meat naturally has over that of
  • bread. It seems accordingly to have done so; and there is some reason for
  • believing that, at least in the London market, the price of butcher’s
  • meat, in proportion to the price of bread, is a good deal lower in the
  • present times than it was in the beginning of the last century.
  • In the Appendix to the life of Prince Henry, Doctor Birch has given us an
  • account of the prices of butcher’s meat as commonly paid by that prince.
  • It is there said, that the four quarters of an ox, weighing six hundred
  • pounds, usually cost him nine pounds ten shillings, or thereabouts; that
  • is thirty-one shillings and eight-pence per hundred pounds weight. Prince
  • Henry died on the 6th of November 1612, in the nineteenth year of his age.
  • In March 1764, there was a parliamentary inquiry into the causes of the
  • high price of provisions at that time. It was then, among other proof to
  • the same purpose, given in evidence by a Virginia merchant, that in March
  • 1763, he had victualled his ships for twentyfour or twenty-five shillings
  • the hundred weight of beef, which he considered as the ordinary price;
  • whereas, in that dear year, he had paid twenty-seven shillings for the
  • same weight and sort. This high price in 1764 is, however, four shillings
  • and eight-pence cheaper than the ordinary price paid by Prince Henry; and
  • it is the best beef only, it must be observed, which is fit to be salted
  • for those distant voyages.
  • The price paid by Prince Henry amounts to 3d. 4/5ths per pound weight of
  • the whole carcase, coarse and choice pieces taken together; and at that
  • rate the choice pieces could not have been sold by retail for less than
  • 4½d. or 5d. the pound.
  • In the parliamentary inquiry in 1764, the witnesses stated the price of
  • the choice pieces of the best beef to be to the consumer 4d. and 4½d. the
  • pound; and the coarse pieces in general to be from seven farthings to 2½d.
  • and 2¾d.; and this, they said, was in general one halfpenny dearer than
  • the same sort of pieces had usually been sold in the month of March. But
  • even this high price is still a good deal cheaper than what we can well
  • suppose the ordinary retail price to have been in the time of Prince
  • Henry.
  • During the first twelve years of the last century, the average price of
  • the best wheat at the Windsor market was £ 1:18:3½d. the quarter of nine
  • Winchester bushels.
  • But in the twelve years preceding 1764 including that year, the average
  • price of the same measure of the best wheat at the same market was £
  • 2:1:9½d.
  • In the first twelve years of the last century, therefore, wheat appears to
  • have been a good deal cheaper, and butcher’s meat a good deal dearer, than
  • in the twelve years preceding 1764, including that year.
  • In all great countries, the greater part of the cultivated lands are
  • employed in producing either food for men or food for cattle. The rent and
  • profit of these regulate the rent and profit of all other cultivated land.
  • If any particular produce afforded less, the land would soon be turned
  • into corn or pasture; and if any afforded more, some part of the lands in
  • corn or pasture would soon be turned to that produce.
  • Those productions, indeed, which require either a greater original expense
  • of improvement, or a greater annual expense of cultivation in order to fit
  • the land for them, appear commonly to afford, the one a greater rent, the
  • other a greater profit, than corn or pasture. This superiority, however,
  • will seldom be found to amount to more than a reasonable interest or
  • compensation for this superior expense.
  • In a hop garden, a fruit garden, a kitchen garden, both the rent of the
  • landlord, and the profit of the farmer, are generally greater than in
  • acorn or grass field. But to bring the ground into this condition requires
  • more expense. Hence a greater rent becomes due to the landlord. It
  • requires, too, a more attentive and skilful management. Hence a greater
  • profit becomes due to the farmer. The crop, too, at least in the hop and
  • fruit garden, is more precarious. Its price, therefore, besides
  • compensating all occasional losses, must afford something like the profit
  • of insurance. The circumstances of gardeners, generally mean, and always
  • moderate, may satisfy us that their great ingenuity is not commonly
  • over-recompensed. Their delightful art is practised by so many rich people
  • for amusement, that little advantage is to be made by those who practise
  • it for profit; because the persons who should naturally be their best
  • customers, supply themselves with all their most precious productions.
  • The advantage which the landlord derives from such improvements, seems at
  • no time to have been greater than what was sufficient to compensate the
  • original expense of making them. In the ancient husbandry, after the
  • vineyard, a well-watered kitchen garden seems to have been the part of the
  • farm which was supposed to yield the most valuable produce. But
  • Democritus, who wrote upon husbandry about two thousand years ago, and who
  • was regarded by the ancients as one of the fathers of the art, thought
  • they did not act wisely who inclosed a kitchen garden. The profit, he
  • said, would not compensate the expense of a stone-wall: and bricks (he
  • meant, I suppose, bricks baked in the sun) mouldered with the rain and the
  • winter-storm, and required continual repairs. Columella, who reports this
  • judgment of Democritus, does not controvert it, but proposes a very frugal
  • method of inclosing with a hedge of brambles and briars, which he says he
  • had found by experience to be both a lasting and an impenetrable fence;
  • but which, it seems, was not commonly known in the time of Democritus.
  • Palladius adopts the opinion of Columella, which had before been
  • recommended by Varro. In the judgment of those ancient improvers, the
  • produce of a kitchen garden had, it seems, been little more than
  • sufficient to pay the extraordinary culture and the expense of watering;
  • for in countries so near the sun, it was thought proper, in those times as
  • in the present, to have the command of a stream of water, which could be
  • conducted to every bed in the garden. Through the greater part of Europe,
  • a kitchen garden is not at present supposed to deserve a better inclosure
  • than that recommended by Columella. In Great Britain, and some other
  • northern countries, the finer fruits cannot be brought to perfection but
  • by the assistance of a wall. Their price, therefore, in such countries,
  • must be sufficient to pay the expense of building and maintaining what
  • they cannot be had without. The fruit-wall frequently surrounds the
  • kitchen garden, which thus enjoys the benefit of an inclosure which its
  • own produce could seldom pay for.
  • That the vineyard, when properly planted and brought to perfection, was
  • the most valuable part of the farm, seems to have been an undoubted maxim
  • in the ancient agriculture, as it is in the modern, through all the wine
  • countries. But whether it was advantageous to plant a new vineyard, was a
  • matter of dispute among the ancient Italian husbandmen, as we learn from
  • Columella. He decides, like a true lover of all curious cultivation, in
  • favour of the vineyard; and endeavours to shew, by a comparison of the
  • profit and expense, that it was a most advantageous improvement. Such
  • comparisons, however, between the profit and expense of new projects are
  • commonly very fallacious; and in nothing more so than in agriculture. Had
  • the gain actually made by such plantations been commonly as great as he
  • imagined it might have been, there could have been no dispute about it.
  • The same point is frequently at this day a matter of controversy in the
  • wine countries. Their writers on agriculture, indeed, the lovers and
  • promoters of high cultivation, seem generally disposed to decide with
  • Columella in favour of the vineyard. In France, the anxiety of the
  • proprietors of the old vineyards to prevent the planting of any new ones,
  • seems to favour their opinion, and to indicate a consciousness in those
  • who must have the experience, that this species of cultivation is at
  • present in that country more profitable than any other. It seems, at the
  • same time, however, to indicate another opinion, that this superior profit
  • can last no longer than the laws which at present restrain the free
  • cultivation of the vine. In 1731, they obtained an order of council,
  • prohibiting both the planting of new vineyards, and the renewal of these
  • old ones, of which the cultivation had been interrupted for two years,
  • without a particular permission from the king, to be granted only in
  • consequence of an information from the intendant of the province,
  • certifying that he had examined the land, and that it was incapable of any
  • other culture. The pretence of this order was the scarcity of corn and
  • pasture, and the superabundance of wine. But had this superabundance been
  • real, it would, without any order of council, have effectually prevented
  • the plantation of new vineyards, by reducing the profits of this species
  • of cultivation below their natural proportion to those of corn and
  • pasture. With regard to the supposed scarcity of corn occasioned by the
  • multiplication of vineyards, corn is nowhere in France more carefully
  • cultivated than in the wine provinces, where the land is fit for producing
  • it: as in Burgundy, Guienne, and the Upper Languedoc. The numerous hands
  • employed in the one species of cultivation necessarily encourage the
  • other, by affording a ready market for its produce. To diminish the number
  • of those who are capable of paying it, is surely a most unpromising
  • expedient for encouraging the cultivation of corn. It is like the policy
  • which would promote agriculture, by discouraging manufactures.
  • The rent and profit of those productions, therefore, which require either
  • a greater original expense of improvement in order to fit the land for
  • them, or a greater annual expense of cultivation, though often much
  • superior to those of corn and pasture, yet when they do no more than
  • compensate such extraordinary expense, are in reality regulated by the
  • rent and profit of those common crops.
  • It sometimes happens, indeed, that the quantity of land which can be
  • fitted for some particular produce, is too small to supply the effectual
  • demand. The whole produce can be disposed of to those who are willing to
  • give somewhat more than what is sufficient to pay the whole rent, wages,
  • and profit, necessary for raising and bringing it to market, according to
  • their natural rates, or according to the rates at which they are paid in
  • the greater part of other cultivated land. The surplus part of the price
  • which remains after defraying the whole expense of improvement and
  • cultivation, may commonly, in this case, and in this case only, bear no
  • regular proportion to the like surplus in corn or pasture, but may exceed
  • it in almost any degree; and the greater part of this excess naturally
  • goes to the rent of the landlord.
  • The usual and natural proportion, for example, between the rent and profit
  • of wine, and those of corn and pasture, must be understood to take place
  • only with regard to those vineyards which produce nothing but good common
  • wine, such as can be raised almost anywhere, upon any light, gravelly, or
  • sandy soil, and which has nothing to recommend it but its strength and
  • wholesomeness. It is with such vineyards only, that the common land of the
  • country can be brought into competition; for with those of a peculiar
  • quality it is evident that it cannot.
  • The vine is more affected by the difference of soils than any other
  • fruit-tree. From some it derives a flavour which no culture or management
  • can equal, it is supposed, upon any other. This flavour, real or
  • imaginary, is sometimes peculiar to the produce of a few vineyards;
  • sometimes it extends through the greater part of a small district, and
  • sometimes through a considerable part of a large province. The whole
  • quantity of such wines that is brought to market falls short of the
  • effectual demand, or the demand of those who would be willing to pay the
  • whole rent, profit, and wages, necessary for preparing and bringing them
  • thither, according to the ordinary rate, or according to the rate at which
  • they are paid in common vineyards. The whole quantity, therefore, can be
  • disposed of to those who are willing to pay more, which necessarily raises
  • their price above that of common wine. The difference is greater or less,
  • according as the fashionableness and scarcity of the wine render the
  • competition of the buyers more or less eager. Whatever it be, the greater
  • part of it goes to the rent of the landlord. For though such vineyards are
  • in general more carefully cultivated than most others, the high price of
  • the wine seems to be, not so much the effect, as the cause of this careful
  • cultivation. In so valuable a produce, the loss occasioned by negligence
  • is so great, as to force even the most careless to attention. A small part
  • of this high price, therefore, is sufficient to pay the wages of the
  • extraordinary labour bestowed upon their cultivation, and the profits of
  • the extraordinary stock which puts that labour into motion.
  • The sugar colonies possessed by the European nations in the West Indies
  • may be compared to those precious vineyards. Their whole produce falls
  • short of the effectual demand of Europe, and can be disposed of to those
  • who are willing to give more than what is sufficient to pay the whole
  • rent, profit, and wages, necessary for preparing and bringing it to
  • market, according to the rate at which they are commonly paid by any other
  • produce. In Cochin China, the finest white sugar generally sells for three
  • piastres the quintal, about thirteen shillings and sixpence of our money,
  • as we are told by Mr Poivre {Voyages d’un Philosophe.}, a very careful
  • observer of the agriculture of that country. What is there called the
  • quintal, weighs from a hundred and fifty to two hundred Paris pounds, or a
  • hundred and seventy-five Paris pounds at a medium, which reduces the price
  • of the hundred weight English to about eight shillings sterling; not a
  • fourth part of what is commonly paid for the brown or muscovada sugars
  • imported from our colonies, and not a sixth part of what is paid for the
  • finest white sugar. The greater part of the cultivated lands in Cochin
  • China are employed in producing corn and rice, the food of the great body
  • of the people. The respective prices of corn, rice, and sugar, are there
  • probably in the natural proportion, or in that which naturally takes place
  • in the different crops of the greater part of cultivated land, and which
  • recompenses the landlord and farmer, as nearly as can be computed,
  • according to what is usually the original expense of improvement, and the
  • annual expense of cultivation. But in our sugar colonies, the price of
  • sugar bears no such proportion to that of the produce of a rice or corn
  • field either in Europe or America. It is commonly said that a sugar
  • planter expects that the rum and the molasses should defray the whole
  • expense of his cultivation, and that his sugar should be all clear profit.
  • If this be true, for I pretend not to affirm it, it is as if a corn farmer
  • expected to defray the expense of his cultivation with the chaff and the
  • straw, and that the grain should be all clear profit. We see frequently
  • societies of merchants in London, and other trading towns, purchase waste
  • lands in our sugar colonies, which they expect to improve and cultivate
  • with profit, by means of factors and agents, notwithstanding the great
  • distance and the uncertain returns, from the defective administration of
  • justice in those countries. Nobody will attempt to improve and cultivate
  • in the same manner the most fertile lands of Scotland, Ireland, or the
  • corn provinces of North America, though, from the more exact
  • administration of justice in these countries, more regular returns might
  • be expected.
  • In Virginia and Maryland, the cultivation of tobacco is preferred, as most
  • profitable, to that of corn. Tobacco might be cultivated with advantage
  • through the greater part of Europe; but, in almost every part of Europe,
  • it has become a principal subject of taxation; and to collect a tax from
  • every different farm in the country where this plant might happen to be
  • cultivated, would be more difficult, it has been supposed, than to levy
  • one upon its importation at the custom-house. The cultivation of tobacco
  • has, upon this account, been most absurdly prohibited through the greater
  • part of Europe, which necessarily gives a sort of monopoly to the
  • countries where it is allowed; and as Virginia and Maryland produce the
  • greatest quantity of it, they share largely, though with some competitors,
  • in the advantage of this monopoly. The cultivation of tobacco, however,
  • seems not to be so advantageous as that of sugar. I have never even heard
  • of any tobacco plantation that was improved and cultivated by the capital
  • of merchants who resided in Great Britain; and our tobacco colonies send
  • us home no such wealthy planters as we see frequently arrive from our
  • sugar islands. Though, from the preference given in those colonies to the
  • cultivation of tobacco above that of corn, it would appear that the
  • effectual demand of Europe for tobacco is not completely supplied, it
  • probably is more nearly so than that for sugar; and though the present
  • price of tobacco is probably more than sufficient to pay the whole rent,
  • wages, and profit, necessary for preparing and bringing it to market,
  • according to the rate at which they are commonly paid in corn land, it
  • must not be so much more as the present price of sugar. Our tobacco
  • planters, accordingly, have shewn the same fear of the superabundance of
  • tobacco, which the proprietors of the old vineyards in France have of the
  • superabundance of wine. By act of assembly, they have restrained its
  • cultivation to six thousand plants, supposed to yield a thousand weight of
  • tobacco, for every negro between sixteen and sixty years of age. Such a
  • negro, over and above this quantity of tobacco, can manage, they reckon,
  • four acres of Indian corn. To prevent the market from being overstocked,
  • too, they have sometimes, in plentiful years, we are told by Dr Douglas
  • {Douglas’s Summary, vol. ii. p. 379, 373.} (I suspect he has been ill
  • informed), burnt a certain quantity of tobacco for every negro, in the
  • same manner as the Dutch are said to do of spices. If such violent methods
  • are necessary to keep up the present price of tobacco, the superior
  • advantage of its culture over that of corn, if it still has any, will not
  • probably be of long continuance.
  • It is in this manner that the rent of the cultivated land, of which the
  • produce is human food, regulates the rent of the greater part of other
  • cultivated land. No particular produce can long afford less, because the
  • land would immediately be turned to another use; and if any particular
  • produce commonly affords more, it is because the quantity of land which
  • can be fitted for it is too small to supply the effectual demand.
  • In Europe, corn is the principal produce of land, which serves immediately
  • for human food. Except in particular situations, therefore, the rent of
  • corn land regulates in Europe that of all other cultivated land. Britain
  • need envy neither the vineyards of France, nor the olive plantations of
  • Italy. Except in particular situations, the value of these is regulated by
  • that of corn, in which the fertility of Britain is not much inferior to
  • that of either of those two countries.
  • If, in any country, the common and favourite vegetable food of the people
  • should be drawn from a plant of which the most common land, with the same,
  • or nearly the same culture, produced a much greater quantity than the most
  • fertile does of corn; the rent of the landlord, or the surplus quantity of
  • food which would remain to him, after paying the labour, and replacing the
  • stock of the farmer, together with its ordinary profits, would necessarily
  • be much greater. Whatever was the rate at which labour was commonly
  • maintained in that country, this greater surplus could always maintain a
  • greater quantity of it, and, consequently, enable the landlord to purchase
  • or command a greater quantity of it. The real value of his rent, his real
  • power and authority, his command of the necessaries and conveniencies of
  • life with which the labour of other people could supply him, would
  • necessarily be much greater.
  • A rice field produces a much greater quantity of food than the most
  • fertile corn field. Two crops in the year, from thirty to sixty bushels
  • each, are said to be the ordinary produce of an acre. Though its
  • cultivation, therefore, requires more labour, a much greater surplus
  • remains after maintaining all that labour. In those rice countries,
  • therefore, where rice is the common and favourite vegetable food of the
  • people, and where the cultivators are chiefly maintained with it, a
  • greater share of this greater surplus should belong to the landlord than
  • in corn countries. In Carolina, where the planters, as in other British
  • colonies, are generally both farmers and landlords, and where rent,
  • consequently, is confounded with profit, the cultivation of rice is found
  • to be more profitable than that of corn, though their fields produce only
  • one crop in the year, and though, from the prevalence of the customs of
  • Europe, rice is not there the common and favourite vegetable food of the
  • people.
  • A good rice field is a bog at all seasons, and at one season a bog covered
  • with water. It is unfit either for corn, or pasture, or vineyard, or,
  • indeed, for any other vegetable produce that is very useful to men; and
  • the lands which are fit for those purposes are not fit for rice. Even in
  • the rice countries, therefore, the rent of rice lands cannot regulate the
  • rent of the other cultivated land which can never be turned to that
  • produce.
  • The food produced by a field of potatoes is not inferior in quantity to
  • that produced by a field of rice, and much superior to what is produced by
  • a field of wheat. Twelve thousand weight of potatoes from an acre of land
  • is not a greater produce than two thousand weight of wheat. The food or
  • solid nourishment, indeed, which can be drawn from each of those two
  • plants, is not altogether in proportion to their weight, on account of the
  • watery nature of potatoes. Allowing, however, half the weight of this root
  • to go to water, a very large allowance, such an acre of potatoes will
  • still produce six thousand weight of solid nourishment, three times the
  • quantity produced by the acre of wheat. An acre of potatoes is cultivated
  • with less expense than an acre of wheat; the fallow, which generally
  • precedes the sowing of wheat, more than compensating the hoeing and other
  • extraordinary culture which is always given to potatoes. Should this root
  • ever become in any part of Europe, like rice in some rice countries, the
  • common and favourite vegetable food of the people, so as to occupy the
  • same proportion of the lands in tillage, which wheat and other sorts of
  • grain for human food do at present, the same quantity of cultivated land
  • would maintain a much greater number of people; and the labourers being
  • generally fed with potatoes, a greater surplus would remain after
  • replacing all the stock, and maintaining all the labour employed in
  • cultivation. A greater share of this surplus, too, would belong to the
  • landlord. Population would increase, and rents would rise much beyond what
  • they are at present.
  • The land which is fit for potatoes, is fit for almost every other useful
  • vegetable. If they occupied the same proportion of cultivated land which
  • corn does at present, they would regulate, in the same manner, the rent of
  • the greater part of other cultivated land.
  • In some parts of Lancashire, it is pretended, I have been told, that bread
  • of oatmeal is a heartier food for labouring people than wheaten bread, and
  • I have frequently heard the same doctrine held in Scotland. I am, however,
  • somewhat doubtful of the truth of it. The common people in Scotland, who
  • are fed with oatmeal, are in general neither so strong nor so handsome as
  • the same rank of people in England, who are fed with wheaten bread. They
  • neither work so well, nor look so well; and as there is not the same
  • difference between the people of fashion in the two countries, experience
  • would seem to shew, that the food of the common people in Scotland is not
  • so suitable to the human constitution as that of their neighbours of the
  • same rank in England. But it seems to be otherwise with potatoes. The
  • chairmen, porters, and coal-heavers in London, and those unfortunate women
  • who live by prostitution, the strongest men and the most beautiful women
  • perhaps in the British dominions, are said to be, the greater part of
  • them, from the lowest rank of people in Ireland, who are generally fed
  • with this root. No food can afford a more decisive proof of its nourishing
  • quality, or of its being peculiarly suitable to the health of the human
  • constitution.
  • It is difficult to preserve potatoes through the year, and impossible to
  • store them like corn, for two or three years together. The fear of not
  • being able to sell them before they rot, discourages their cultivation,
  • and is, perhaps, the chief obstacle to their ever becoming in any great
  • country, like bread, the principal vegetable food of all the different
  • ranks of the people.
  • PART II.—Of the Produce of Land, which sometimes does, and sometimes
  • does not, afford Rent.
  • Human food seems to be the only produce of land, which always and
  • necessarily affords some rent to the landlord. Other sorts of produce
  • sometimes may, and sometimes may not, according to different
  • circumstances.
  • After food, clothing and lodging are the two great wants of mankind.
  • Land, in its original rude state, can afford the materials of clothing and
  • lodging to a much greater number of people than it can feed. In its
  • improved state, it can sometimes feed a greater number of people than it
  • can supply with those materials; at least in the way in which they require
  • them, and are willing to pay for them. In the one state, therefore, there
  • is always a superabundance of these materials, which are frequently, upon
  • that account, of little or no value. In the other, there is often a
  • scarcity, which necessarily augments their value. In the one state, a
  • great part of them is thrown away as useless and the price of what is used
  • is considered as equal only to the labour and expense of fitting it for
  • use, and can, therefore, afford no rent to the landlord. In the other,
  • they are all made use of, and there is frequently a demand for more than
  • can be had. Somebody is always willing to give more for every part of
  • them, than what is sufficient to pay the expense of bringing them to
  • market. Their price, therefore, can always afford some rent to the
  • landlord.
  • The skins of the larger animals were the original materials of clothing.
  • Among nations of hunters and shepherds, therefore, whose food consists
  • chiefly in the flesh of those animals, everyman, by providing himself with
  • food, provides himself with the materials of more clothing than he can
  • wear. If there was no foreign commerce, the greater part of them would be
  • thrown away as things of no value. This was probably the case among the
  • hunting nations of North America, before their country was discovered by
  • the Europeans, with whom they now exchange their surplus peltry, for
  • blankets, fire-arms, and brandy, which gives it some value. In the present
  • commercial state of the known world, the most barbarous nations, I
  • believe, among whom land property is established, have some foreign
  • commerce of this kind, and find among their wealthier neighbours such a
  • demand for all the materials of clothing, which their land produces, and
  • which can neither be wrought up nor consumed at home, as raises their
  • price above what it costs to send them to those wealthier neighbours. It
  • affords, therefore, some rent to the landlord. When the greater part of
  • the Highland cattle were consumed on their own hills, the exportation of
  • their hides made the most considerable article of the commerce of that
  • country, and what they were exchanged for afforded some addition to the
  • rent of the Highland estates. The wool of England, which in old times,
  • could neither be consumed nor wrought up at home, found a market in the
  • then wealthier and more industrious country of Flanders, and its price
  • afforded something to the rent of the land which produced it. In countries
  • not better cultivated than England was then, or than the Highlands of
  • Scotland are now, and which had no foreign commerce, the materials of
  • clothing would evidently be so superabundant, that a great part of them
  • would be thrown away as useless, and no part could afford any rent to the
  • landlord.
  • The materials of lodging cannot always be transported to so great a
  • distance as those of clothing, and do not so readily become an object of
  • foreign commerce. When they are superabundant in the country which
  • produces them, it frequently happens, even in the present commercial state
  • of the world, that they are of no value to the landlord. A good stone
  • quarry in the neighbourhood of London would afford a considerable rent. In
  • many parts of Scotland and Wales it affords none. Barren timber for
  • building is of great value in a populous and well-cultivated country, and
  • the land which produces it affords a considerable rent. But in many parts
  • of North America, the landlord would be much obliged to any body who would
  • carry away the greater part of his large trees. In some parts of the
  • Highlands of Scotland, the bark is the only part of the wood which, for
  • want of roads and water-carriage, can be sent to market; the timber is
  • left to rot upon the ground. When the materials of lodging are so
  • superabundant, the part made use of is worth only the labour and expense
  • of fitting it for that use. It affords no rent to the landlord, who
  • generally grants the use of it to whoever takes the trouble of asking it.
  • The demand of wealthier nations, however, sometimes enables him to get a
  • rent for it. The paving of the streets of London has enabled the owners of
  • some barren rocks on the coast of Scotland to draw a rent from what never
  • afforded any before. The woods of Norway, and of the coasts of the Baltic,
  • find a market in many parts of Great Britain, which they could not find at
  • home, and thereby afford some rent to their proprietors.
  • Countries are populous, not in proportion to the number of people whom
  • their produce can clothe and lodge, but in proportion to that of those
  • whom it can feed. When food is provided, it is easy to find the necessary
  • clothing and lodging. But though these are at hand, it may often be
  • difficult to find food. In some parts of the British dominions, what is
  • called a house may be built by one day’s labour of one man. The simplest
  • species of clothing, the skins of animals, require somewhat more labour to
  • dress and prepare them for use. They do not, however, require a great
  • deal. Among savage or barbarous nations, a hundredth, or little more than
  • a hundredth part of the labour of the whole year, will be sufficient to
  • provide them with such clothing and lodging as satisfy the greater part of
  • the people. All the other ninety-nine parts are frequently no more than
  • enough to provide them with food.
  • But when, by the improvement and cultivation of land, the labour of one
  • family can provide food for two, the labour of half the society becomes
  • sufficient to provide food for the whole. The other half, therefore, or at
  • least the greater part of them, can be employed in providing other things,
  • or in satisfying the other wants and fancies of mankind. Clothing and
  • lodging, household furniture, and what is called equipage, are the
  • principal objects of the greater part of those wants and fancies. The rich
  • man consumes no more food than his poor neighbour. In quality it may be
  • very different, and to select and prepare it may require more labour and
  • art; but in quantity it is very nearly the same. But compare the spacious
  • palace and great wardrobe of the one, with the hovel and the few rags of
  • the other, and you will be sensible that the difference between their
  • clothing, lodging, and household furniture, is almost as great in quantity
  • as it is in quality. The desire of food is limited in every man by the
  • narrow capacity of the human stomach; but the desire of the conveniencies
  • and ornaments of building, dress, equipage, and household furniture, seems
  • to have no limit or certain boundary. Those, therefore, who have the
  • command of more food than they themselves can consume, are always willing
  • to exchange the surplus, or, what is the same thing, the price of it, for
  • gratifications of this other kind. What is over and above satisfying the
  • limited desire, is given for the amusement of those desires which cannot
  • be satisfied, but seem to be altogether endless. The poor, in order to
  • obtain food, exert themselves to gratify those fancies of the rich; and to
  • obtain it more certainly, they vie with one another in the cheapness and
  • perfection of their work. The number of workmen increases with the
  • increasing quantity of food, or with the growing improvement and
  • cultivation of the lands; and as the nature of their business admits of
  • the utmost subdivisions of labour, the quantity of materials which they
  • can work up, increases in a much greater proportion than their numbers.
  • Hence arises a demand for every sort of material which human invention can
  • employ, either usefully or ornamentally, in building, dress, equipage, or
  • household furniture; for the fossils and minerals contained in the bowels
  • of the earth, the precious metals, and the precious stones.
  • Food is, in this manner, not only the original source of rent, but every
  • other part of the produce of land which afterwards affords rent, derives
  • that part of its value from the improvement of the powers of labour in
  • producing food, by means of the improvement and cultivation of land.
  • Those other parts of the produce of land, however, which afterwards afford
  • rent, do not afford it always. Even in improved and cultivated countries,
  • the demand for them is not always such as to afford a greater price than
  • what is sufficient to pay the labour, and replace, together with its
  • ordinary profits, the stock which must be employed in bringing them to
  • market. Whether it is or is not such, depends upon different
  • circumstances.
  • Whether a coal mine, for example, can afford any rent, depends partly upon
  • its fertility, and partly upon its situation.
  • A mine of any kind may be said to be either fertile or barren, according
  • as the quantity of mineral which can be brought from it by a certain
  • quantity of labour, is greater or less than what can be brought by an
  • equal quantity from the greater part of other mines of the same kind.
  • Some coal mines, advantageously situated, cannot be wrought on account of
  • their barrenness. The produce does not pay the expense. They can afford
  • neither profit nor rent.
  • There are some, of which the produce is barely sufficient to pay the
  • labour, and replace, together with its ordinary profits, the stock
  • employed in working them. They afford some profit to the undertaker of the
  • work, but no rent to the landlord. They can be wrought advantageously by
  • nobody but the landlord, who, being himself the undertaker of the work,
  • gets the ordinary profit of the capital which he employs in it. Many coal
  • mines in Scotland are wrought in this manner, and can be wrought in no
  • other. The landlord will allow nobody else to work them without paying
  • some rent, and nobody can afford to pay any.
  • Other coal mines in the same country, sufficiently fertile, cannot be
  • wrought on account of their situation. A quantity of mineral, sufficient
  • to defray the expense of working, could be brought from the mine by the
  • ordinary, or even less than the ordinary quantity of labour: but in an
  • inland country, thinly inhabited, and without either good roads or
  • water-carriage, this quantity could not be sold.
  • Coals are a less agreeable fuel than wood: they are said too to be less
  • wholesome. The expense of coals, therefore, at the place where they are
  • consumed, must generally be somewhat less than that of wood.
  • The price of wood, again, varies with the state of agriculture, nearly in
  • the same manner, and exactly for the same reason, as the price of cattle.
  • In its rude beginnings, the greater part of every country is covered with
  • wood, which is then a mere incumbrance, of no value to the landlord, who
  • would gladly give it to any body for the cutting. As agriculture advances,
  • the woods are partly cleared by the progress of tillage, and partly go to
  • decay in consequence of the increased number of cattle. These, though they
  • do not increase in the same proportion as corn, which is altogether the
  • acquisition of human industry, yet multiply under the care and protection
  • of men, who store up in the season of plenty what may maintain them in
  • that of scarcity; who, through the whole year, furnish them with a greater
  • quantity of food than uncultivated nature provides for them; and who, by
  • destroying and extirpating their enemies, secure them in the free
  • enjoyment of all that she provides. Numerous herds of cattle, when allowed
  • to wander through the woods, though they do not destroy the old trees,
  • hinder any young ones from coming up; so that, in the course of a century
  • or two, the whole forest goes to ruin. The scarcity of wood then raises
  • its price. It affords a good rent; and the landlord sometimes finds that
  • he can scarce employ his best lands more advantageously than in growing
  • barren timber, of which the greatness of the profit often compensates the
  • lateness of the returns. This seems, in the present times, to be nearly
  • the state of things in several parts of Great Britain, where the profit of
  • planting is found to be equal to that of either corn or pasture. The
  • advantage which the landlord derives from planting can nowhere exceed, at
  • least for any considerable time, the rent which these could afford him;
  • and in an inland country, which is highly cultivated, it will frequently
  • not fall much short of this rent. Upon the sea-coast of a well-improved
  • country, indeed, if coals can conveniently be had for fuel, it may
  • sometimes be cheaper to bring barren timber for building from less
  • cultivated foreign countries than to raise it at home. In the new town of
  • Edinburgh, built within these few years, there is not, perhaps, a single
  • stick of Scotch timber.
  • Whatever may be the price of wood, if that of coals is such that the
  • expense of a coal fire is nearly equal to that of a wood one we may be
  • assured, that at that place, and in these circumstances, the price of
  • coals is as high as it can be. It seems to be so in some of the inland
  • parts of England, particularly in Oxfordshire, where it is usual, even in
  • the fires of the common people, to mix coals and wood together, and where
  • the difference in the expense of those two sorts of fuel cannot,
  • therefore, be very great. Coals, in the coal countries, are everywhere
  • much below this highest price. If they were not, they could not bear the
  • expense of a distant carriage, either by land or by water. A small
  • quantity only could be sold; and the coal masters and the coal proprietors
  • find it more for their interest to sell a great quantity at a price
  • somewhat above the lowest, than a small quantity at the highest. The most
  • fertile coal mine, too, regulates the price of coals at all the other
  • mines in its neighbourhood. Both the proprietor and the undertaker of the
  • work find, the one that he can get a greater rent, the other that he can
  • get a greater profit, by somewhat underselling all their neighbours. Their
  • neighbours are soon obliged to sell at the same price, though they cannot
  • so well afford it, and though it always diminishes, and sometimes takes
  • away altogether, both their rent and their profit. Some works are
  • abandoned altogether; others can afford no rent, and can be wrought only
  • by the proprietor.
  • The lowest price at which coals can be sold for any considerable time, is,
  • like that of all other commodities, the price which is barely sufficient
  • to replace, together with its ordinary profits, the stock which must be
  • employed in bringing them to market. At a coal mine for which the landlord
  • can get no rent, but, which he must either work himself or let it alone
  • altogether, the price of coals must generally be nearly about this price.
  • Rent, even where coals afford one, has generally a smaller share in their
  • price than in that of most other parts of the rude produce of land. The
  • rent of an estate above ground, commonly amounts to what is supposed to be
  • a third of the gross produce; and it is generally a rent certain and
  • independent of the occasional variations in the crop. In coal mines, a
  • fifth of the gross produce is a very great rent, a tenth the common rent;
  • and it is seldom a rent certain, but depends upon the occasional
  • variations in the produce. These are so great, that in a country where
  • thirty years purchase is considered as a moderate price for the property
  • of a landed estate, ten years purchase is regarded as a good price for
  • that of a coal mine.
  • The value of a coal mine to the proprietor, frequently depends as much
  • upon its situation as upon its fertility. That of a metallic mine depends
  • more upon its fertility, and less upon its situation. The coarse, and
  • still more the precious metals, when separated from the ore, are so
  • valuable, that they can generally bear the expense of a very long land,
  • and of the most distant sea carriage. Their market is not confined to the
  • countries in the neighbourhood of the mine, but extends to the whole
  • world. The copper of Japan makes an article of commerce in Europe; the
  • iron of Spain in that of Chili and Peru. The silver of Peru finds its way,
  • not only to Europe, but from Europe to China.
  • The price of coals in Westmoreland or Shropshire can have little effect on
  • their price at Newcastle; and their price in the Lionnois can have none at
  • all. The productions of such distant coal mines can never be brought into
  • competition with one another. But the productions of the most distant
  • metallic mines frequently may, and in fact commonly are.
  • The price, therefore, of the coarse, and still more that of the precious
  • metals, at the most fertile mines in the world, must necessarily more or
  • less affect their price at every other in it. The price of copper in Japan
  • must have some influence upon its price at the copper mines in Europe. The
  • price of silver in Peru, or the quantity either of labour or of other
  • goods which it will purchase there, must have some influence on its price,
  • not only at the silver mines of Europe, but at those of China. After the
  • discovery of the mines of Peru, the silver mines of Europe were, the
  • greater part of them, abandoned. The value of silver was so much reduced,
  • that their produce could no longer pay the expense of working them, or
  • replace, with a profit, the food, clothes, lodging, and other necessaries
  • which were consumed in that operation. This was the case, too, with the
  • mines of Cuba and St. Domingo, and even with the ancient mines of Peru,
  • after the discovery of those of Potosi. The price of every metal, at every
  • mine, therefore, being regulated in some measure by its price at the most
  • fertile mine in the world that is actually wrought, it can, at the greater
  • part of mines, do very little more than pay the expense of working, and
  • can seldom afford a very high rent to the landlord. Rent accordingly,
  • seems at the greater part of mines to have but a small share in the price
  • of the coarse, and a still smaller in that of the precious metals. Labour
  • and profit make up the greater part of both.
  • A sixth part of the gross produce may be reckoned the average rent of the
  • tin mines of Cornwall, the most fertile that are known in the world, as we
  • are told by the Rev. Mr. Borlace, vice-warden of the stannaries. Some, he
  • says, afford more, and some do not afford so much. A sixth part of the
  • gross produce is the rent, too, of several very fertile lead mines in
  • Scotland.
  • In the silver mines of Peru, we are told by Frezier and Ulloa, the
  • proprietor frequently exacts no other acknowledgment from the undertaker
  • of the mine, but that he will grind the ore at his mill, paying him the
  • ordinary multure or price of grinding. Till 1736, indeed, the tax of the
  • king of Spain amounted to one fifth of the standard silver, which till
  • then might be considered as the real rent of the greater part of the
  • silver mines of Peru, the richest which have been known in the world. If
  • there had been no tax, this fifth would naturally have belonged to the
  • landlord, and many mines might have been wrought which could not then be
  • wrought, because they could not afford this tax. The tax of the duke of
  • Cornwall upon tin is supposed to amount to more than five per cent. or one
  • twentieth part of the value; and whatever may be his proportion, it would
  • naturally, too, belong to the proprietor of the mine, if tin was duty
  • free. But if you add one twentieth to one sixth, you will find that the
  • whole average rent of the tin mines of Cornwall, was to the whole average
  • rent of the silver mines of Peru, as thirteen to twelve. But the silver
  • mines of Peru are not now able to pay even this low rent; and the tax upon
  • silver was, in 1736, reduced from one fifth to one tenth. Even this tax
  • upon silver, too, gives more temptation to smuggling than the tax of one
  • twentieth upon tin; and smuggling must be much easier in the precious than
  • in the bulky commodity. The tax of the king of Spain, accordingly, is said
  • to be very ill paid, and that of the duke of Cornwall very well. Rent,
  • therefore, it is probable, makes a greater part of the price of tin at the
  • most fertile tin mines than it does of silver at the most fertile silver
  • mines in the world. After replacing the stock employed in working those
  • different mines, together with its ordinary profits, the residue which
  • remains to the proprietor is greater, it seems, in the coarse, than in the
  • precious metal.
  • Neither are the profits of the undertakers of silver mines commonly very
  • great in Peru. The same most respectable and well-informed authors
  • acquaint us, that when any person undertakes to work a new mine in Peru,
  • he is universally looked upon as a man destined to bankruptcy and ruin,
  • and is upon that account shunned and avoided by every body. Mining, it
  • seems, is considered there in the same light as here, as a lottery, in
  • which the prizes do not compensate the blanks, though the greatness of
  • some tempts many adventurers to throw away their fortunes in such
  • unprosperous projects.
  • As the sovereign, however, derives a considerable part of his revenue from
  • the produce of silver mines, the law in Peru gives every possible
  • encouragement to the discovery and working of new ones. Whoever discovers
  • a new mine, is entitled to measure off two hundred and forty-six feet in
  • length, according to what he supposes to be the direction of the vein, and
  • half as much in breadth. He becomes proprietor of this portion of the
  • mine, and can work it without paving any acknowledgment to the landlord.
  • The interest of the duke of Cornwall has given occasion to a regulation
  • nearly of the same kind in that ancient dutchy. In waste and uninclosed
  • lands, any person who discovers a tin mine may mark out its limits to a
  • certain extent, which is called bounding a mine. The bounder becomes the
  • real proprietor of the mine, and may either work it himself, or give it in
  • lease to another, without the consent of the owner of the land, to whom,
  • however, a very small acknowledgment must be paid upon working it. In both
  • regulations, the sacred rights of private property are sacrificed to the
  • supposed interests of public revenue.
  • The same encouragement is given in Peru to the discovery and working of
  • new gold mines; and in gold the king’s tax amounts only to a twentieth
  • part of the standard rental. It was once a fifth, and afterwards a tenth,
  • as in silver; but it was found that the work could not bear even the
  • lowest of these two taxes. If it is rare, however, say the same authors,
  • Frezier and Ulloa, to find a person who has made his fortune by a silver,
  • it is still much rarer to find one who has done so by a gold mine. This
  • twentieth part seems to be the whole rent which is paid by the greater
  • part of the gold mines of Chili and Peru. Gold, too, is much more liable
  • to be smuggled than even silver; not only on account of the superior value
  • of the metal in proportion to its bulk, but on account of the peculiar way
  • in which nature produces it. Silver is very seldom found virgin, but, like
  • most other metals, is generally mineralized with some other body, from
  • which it is impossible to separate it in such quantities as will pay for
  • the expense, but by a very laborious and tedious operation, which cannot
  • well be carried on but in work-houses erected for the purpose, and,
  • therefore, exposed to the inspection of the king’s officers. Gold, on the
  • contrary, is almost always found virgin. It is sometimes found in pieces
  • of some bulk; and, even when mixed, in small and almost insensible
  • particles, with sand, earth, and other extraneous bodies, it can be
  • separated from them by a very short and simple operation, which can be
  • carried on in any private house by any body who is possessed of a small
  • quantity of mercury. If the king’s tax, therefore, is but ill paid upon
  • silver, it is likely to be much worse paid upon gold; and rent must make a
  • much smaller part of the price of gold than that of silver.
  • The lowest price at which the precious metals can be sold, or the smallest
  • quantity of other goods for which they can be exchanged, during any
  • considerable time, is regulated by the same principles which fix the
  • lowest ordinary price of all other goods. The stock which must commonly be
  • employed, the food, clothes, and lodging, which must commonly be consumed
  • in bringing them from the mine to the market, determine it. It must at
  • least be sufficient to replace that stock, with the ordinary profits.
  • Their highest price, however, seems not to be necessarily determined by
  • any thing but the actual scarcity or plenty of these metals themselves. It
  • is not determined by that of any other commodity, in the same manner as
  • the price of coals is by that of wood, beyond which no scarcity can ever
  • raise it. Increase the scarcity of gold to a certain degree, and the
  • smallest bit of it may become more precious than a diamond, and exchange
  • for a greater quantity of other goods.
  • The demand for those metals arises partly from their utility, and partly
  • from their beauty. If you except iron, they are more useful than, perhaps,
  • any other metal. As they are less liable to rust and impurity, they can
  • more easily be kept clean; and the utensils, either of the table or the
  • kitchen, are often, upon that account, more agreeable when made of them. A
  • silver boiler is more cleanly than a lead, copper, or tin one; and the
  • same quality would render a gold boiler still better than a silver one.
  • Their principal merit, however, arises from their beauty, which renders
  • them peculiarly fit for the ornaments of dress and furniture. No paint or
  • dye can give so splendid a colour as gilding. The merit of their beauty is
  • greatly enhanced by their scarcity. With the greater part of rich people,
  • the chief enjoyment of riches consists in the parade of riches; which, in
  • their eye, is never so complete as when they appear to possess those
  • decisive marks of opulence which nobody can possess but themselves. In
  • their eyes, the merit of an object, which is in any degree either useful
  • or beautiful, is greatly enhanced by its scarcity, or by the great labour
  • which it requires to collect any considerable quantity of it; a labour
  • which nobody can afford to pay but themselves. Such objects they are
  • willing to purchase at a higher price than things much more beautiful and
  • useful, but more common. These qualities of utility, beauty, and scarcity,
  • are the original foundation of the high price of those metals, or of the
  • great quantity of other goods for which they can everywhere be exchanged.
  • This value was antecedent to, and independent of their being employed as
  • coin, and was the quality which fitted them for that employment. That
  • employment, however, by occasioning a new demand, and by diminishing the
  • quantity which could be employed in any other way, may have afterwards
  • contributed to keep up or increase their value.
  • The demand for the precious stones arises altogether from their beauty.
  • They are of no use but as ornaments; and the merit of their beauty is
  • greatly enhanced by their scarcity, or by the difficulty and expense of
  • getting them from the mine. Wages and profit accordingly make up, upon
  • most occasions, almost the whole of the high price. Rent comes in but for
  • a very small share, frequently for no share; and the most fertile mines
  • only afford any considerable rent. When Tavernier, a jeweller, visited the
  • diamond mines of Golconda and Visiapour, he was informed that the
  • sovereign of the country, for whose benefit they were wrought, had ordered
  • all of them to be shut up except those which yielded the largest and
  • finest stones. The other, it seems, were to the proprietor not worth the
  • working.
  • As the prices, both of the precious metals and of the precious stones, is
  • regulated all over the world by their price at the most fertile mine in
  • it, the rent which a mine of either can afford to its proprietor is in
  • proportion, not to its absolute, but to what may be called its relative
  • fertility, or to its superiority over other mines of the same kind. If new
  • mines were discovered, as much superior to those of Potosi, as they were
  • superior to those of Europe, the value of silver might be so much degraded
  • as to render even the mines of Potosi not worth the working. Before the
  • discovery of the Spanish West Indies, the most fertile mines in Europe may
  • have afforded as great a rent to their proprietors as the richest mines in
  • Peru do at present. Though the quantity of silver was much less, it might
  • have exchanged for an equal quantity of other goods, and the proprietor’s
  • share might have enabled him to purchase or command an equal quantity
  • either of labour or of commodities.
  • The value, both of the produce and of the rent, the real revenue which
  • they afforded, both to the public and to the proprietor, might have been
  • the same.
  • The most abundant mines, either of the precious metals, or of the precious
  • stones, could add little to the wealth of the world. A produce, of which
  • the value is principally derived from its scarcity, is necessarily
  • degraded by its abundance. A service of plate, and the other frivolous
  • ornaments of dress and furniture, could be purchased for a smaller
  • quantity of commodities; and in this would consist the sole advantage
  • which the world could derive from that abundance.
  • It is otherwise in estates above ground. The value, both of their produce
  • and of their rent, is in proportion to their absolute, and not to their
  • relative fertility. The land which produces a certain quantity of food,
  • clothes, and lodging, can always feed, clothe, and lodge, a certain number
  • of people; and whatever may be the proportion of the landlord, it will
  • always give him a proportionable command of the labour of those people,
  • and of the commodities with which that labour can supply him. The value of
  • the most barren land is not diminished by the neighbourhood of the most
  • fertile. On the contrary, it is generally increased by it. The great
  • number of people maintained by the fertile lands afford a market to many
  • parts of the produce of the barren, which they could never have found
  • among those whom their own produce could maintain.
  • Whatever increases the fertility of land in producing food, increases not
  • only the value of the lands upon which the improvement is bestowed, but
  • contributes likewise to increase that of many other lands, by creating a
  • new demand for their produce. That abundance of food, of which, in
  • consequence of the improvement of land, many people have the disposal
  • beyond what they themselves can consume, is the great cause of the demand,
  • both for the precious metals and the precious stones, as well as for every
  • other conveniency and ornament of dress, lodging, household furniture, and
  • equipage. Food not only constitutes the principal part of the riches of
  • the world, but it is the abundance of food which gives the principal part
  • of their value to many other sorts of riches. The poor inhabitants of Cuba
  • and St. Domingo, when they were first discovered by the Spaniards, used to
  • wear little bits of gold as ornaments in their hair and other parts of
  • their dress. They seemed to value them as we would do any little pebbles
  • of somewhat more than ordinary beauty, and to consider them as just worth
  • the picking up, but not worth the refusing to any body who asked them,
  • They gave them to their new guests at the first request, without seeming
  • to think that they had made them any very valuable present. They were
  • astonished to observe the rage of the Spaniards to obtain them; and had no
  • notion that there could anywhere be a country in which many people had the
  • disposal of so great a superfluity of food; so scanty always among
  • themselves, that, for a very small quantity of those glittering baubles,
  • they would willingly give as much as might maintain a whole family for
  • many years. Could they have been made to understand this, the passion of
  • the Spaniards would not have surprised them.
  • PART III.—Of the variations in the Proportion between the respective
  • Values of that sort of Produce which always affords Rent, and of that
  • which sometimes does, and sometimes does not, afford Rent.
  • The increasing abundance of food, in consequence of the increasing
  • improvement and cultivation, must necessarily increase the demand for
  • every part of the produce of land which is not food, and which can be
  • applied either to use or to ornament. In the whole progress of
  • improvement, it might, therefore, be expected there should be only one
  • variation in the comparative values of those two different sorts of
  • produce. The value of that sort which sometimes does, and sometimes does
  • not afford rent, should constantly rise in proportion to that which always
  • affords some rent. As art and industry advance, the materials of clothing
  • and lodging, the useful fossils and materials of the earth, the precious
  • metals and the precious stones, should gradually come to be more and more
  • in demand, should gradually exchange for a greater and a greater quantity
  • of food; or, in other words, should gradually become dearer and dearer.
  • This, accordingly, has been the case with most of these things upon most
  • occasions, and would have been the case with all of them upon all
  • occasions, if particular accidents had not, upon some occasions, increased
  • the supply of some of them in a still greater proportion than the demand.
  • The value of a free-stone quarry, for example, will necessarily increase
  • with the increasing improvement and population of the country round about
  • it, especially if it should be the only one in the neighbourhood. But the
  • value of a silver mine, even though there should not be another within a
  • thousand miles of it, will not necessarily increase with the improvement
  • of the country in which it is situated. The market for the produce of a
  • free-stone quarry can seldom extend more than a few miles round about it,
  • and the demand must generally be in proportion to the improvement and
  • population of that small district; but the market for the produce of a
  • silver mine may extend over the whole known world. Unless the world in
  • general, therefore, be advancing in improvement and population, the demand
  • for silver might not be at all increased by the improvement even of a
  • large country in the neighbourhood of the mine. Even though the world in
  • general were improving, yet if, in the course of its improvements, new
  • mines should be discovered, much more fertile than any which had been
  • known before, though the demand for silver would necessarily increase, yet
  • the supply might increase in so much a greater proportion, that the real
  • price of that metal might gradually fall; that is, any given quantity, a
  • pound weight of it, for example, might gradually purchase or command a
  • smaller and a smaller quantity of labour, or exchange for a smaller and a
  • smaller quantity of corn, the principal part of the subsistence of the
  • labourer.
  • The great market for silver is the commercial and civilized part of the
  • world.
  • If, by the general progress of improvement, the demand of this market
  • should increase, while, at the same time, the supply did not increase in
  • the same proportion, the value of silver would gradually rise in
  • proportion to that of corn. Any given quantity of silver would exchange
  • for a greater and a greater quantity of corn; or, in other words, the
  • average money price of corn would gradually become cheaper and cheaper.
  • If, on the contrary, the supply, by some accident, should increase, for
  • many years together, in a greater proportion than the demand, that metal
  • would gradually become cheaper and cheaper; or, in other words, the
  • average money price of corn would, in spite of all improvements, gradually
  • become dearer and dearer.
  • But if, on the other hand, the supply of that metal should increase nearly
  • in the same proportion as the demand, it would continue to purchase or
  • exchange for nearly the same quantity of corn; and the average money price
  • of corn would, in spite of all improvements. continue very nearly the
  • same.
  • These three seem to exhaust all the possible combinations of events which
  • can happen in the progress of improvement; and during the course of the
  • four centuries preceding the present, if we may judge by what has happened
  • both in France and Great Britain, each of those three different
  • combinations seems to have taken place in the European market, and nearly
  • in the same order, too, in which I have here set them down.
  • _Digression concerning the Variations in the value of Silver during the
  • Course of the Four last Centuries._
  • First Period.—In 1350, and for some time before, the average price
  • of the quarter of wheat in England seems not to have been estimated lower
  • than four ounces of silver, Tower weight, equal to about twenty shillings
  • of our present money. From this price it seems to have fallen gradually to
  • two ounces of silver, equal to about ten shillings of our present money,
  • the price at which we find it estimated in the beginning of the sixteenth
  • century, and at which it seems to have continued to be estimated till
  • about 1570.
  • In 1350, being the 25th of Edward III. was enacted what is called the
  • Statute of Labourers. In the preamble, it complains much of the insolence
  • of servants, who endeavoured to raise their wages upon their masters. It
  • therefore ordains, that all servants and labourers should, for the future,
  • be contented with the same wages and liveries (liveries in those times
  • signified not only clothes, but provisions) which they had been accustomed
  • to receive in the 20th year of the king, and the four preceding years;
  • that, upon this account, their livery-wheat should nowhere be estimated
  • higher than tenpence a-bushel, and that it should always be in the option
  • of the master to deliver them either the wheat or the money. Tenpence:
  • a-bushel, therefore, had, in the 25th of Edward III. been reckoned a very
  • moderate price of wheat, since it required a particular statute to oblige
  • servants to accept of it in exchange for their usual livery of provisions;
  • and it had been reckoned a reasonable price ten years before that, or in
  • the 16th year of the king, the term to which the statute refers. But in
  • the 16th year of Edward III. tenpence contained about half an ounce of
  • silver, Tower weight, and was nearly equal to half-a-crown of our present
  • money. Four ounces of silver, Tower weight, therefore, equal to six
  • shillings and eightpence of the money of those times, and to near twenty
  • shillings of that of the present, must have been reckoned a moderate price
  • for the quarter of eight bushels.
  • This statute is surely a better evidence of what was reckoned, in those
  • times, a moderate price of grain, than the prices of some particular
  • years, which have generally been recorded by historians and other writers,
  • on account of their extraordinary dearness or cheapness, and from which,
  • therefore, it is difficult to form any judgment concerning what may have
  • been the ordinary price. There are, besides, other reasons for believing
  • that, in the beginning of the fourteenth century, and for some time
  • before, the common price of wheat was not less than four ounces of silver
  • the quarter, and that of other grain in proportion.
  • In 1309, Ralph de Born, prior of St Augustine’s, Canterbury, gave a feast
  • upon his installation-day, of which William Thorn has preserved, not only
  • the bill of fare, but the prices of many particulars. In that feast were
  • consumed, 1st, fifty-three quarters of wheat, which cost nineteen pounds,
  • or seven shillings, and twopence a-quarter, equal to about one-and-twenty
  • shillings and sixpence of our present money; 2dly, fifty-eight quarters of
  • malt, which cost seventeen pounds ten shillings, or six shillings
  • a-quarter, equal to about eighteen shillings of our present money; 3dly,
  • twenty quarters of oats, which cost four pounds, or four shillings
  • a-quarter, equal to about twelve shillings of our present money. The
  • prices of malt and oats seem here to lie higher than their ordinary
  • proportion to the price of wheat.
  • These prices are not recorded, on account of their extraordinary dearness
  • or cheapness, but are mentioned accidentally, as the prices actually paid
  • for large quantities of grain consumed at a feast, which was famous for
  • its magnificence.
  • In 1262, being the 51st of Henry III. was revived an ancient statute,
  • called the assize of bread and ale, which, the king says in the preamble,
  • had been made in the times of his progenitors, some time kings of England.
  • It is probably, therefore, as old at least as the time of his grandfather,
  • Henry II. and may have been as old as the Conquest. It regulates the price
  • of bread according as the prices of wheat may happen to be, from one
  • shilling to twenty shillings the quarter of the money of those times. But
  • statutes of this kind are generally presumed to provide with equal care
  • for all deviations from the middle price, for those below it, as well as
  • for those above it. Ten shillings, therefore, containing six ounces of
  • silver, Tower weight, and equal to about thirty shillings of our present
  • money, must, upon this supposition, have been reckoned the middle price of
  • the quarter of wheat when this statute was first enacted, and must have
  • continued to be so in the 51st of Henry III. We cannot, therefore, be very
  • wrong in supposing that the middle price was not less than one-third of
  • the highest price at which this statute regulates the price of bread, or
  • than six shillings and eightpence of the money of those times, containing
  • four ounces of silver, Tower weight.
  • From these different facts, therefore, we seem to have some reason to
  • conclude that, about the middle of the fourteenth century, and for a
  • considerable time before, the average or ordinary price of the quarter of
  • wheat was not supposed to be less than four ounces of silver, Tower
  • weight.
  • From about the middle of the fourteenth to the beginning of the sixteenth
  • century, what was reckoned the reasonable and moderate, that is, the
  • ordinary or average price of wheat, seems to have sunk gradually to about
  • one half of this price; so as at last to have fallen to about two ounces
  • of silver, Tower weight, equal to about ten shillings of our present
  • money. It continued to be estimated at this price till about 1570.
  • In the household book of Henry, the fifth earl of Northumberland, drawn up
  • in 1512 there are two different estimations of wheat. In one of them it is
  • computed at six shilling and eightpence the quarter, in the other at five
  • shillings and eightpence only. In 1512, six shillings and eightpence
  • contained only two ounces of silver, Tower weight, and were equal to about
  • ten shillings of our present money.
  • From the 25th of Edward III. to the beginning of the reign of Elizabeth,
  • during the space of more than two hundred years, six shillings and
  • eightpence, it appears from several different statutes, had continued to
  • be considered as what is called the moderate and reasonable, that is, the
  • ordinary or average price of wheat. The quantity of silver, however,
  • contained in that nominal sum was, during the course of this period,
  • continually diminishing in consequence of some alterations which were made
  • in the coin. But the increase of the value of silver had, it seems, so far
  • compensated the diminution of the quantity of it contained in the same
  • nominal sum, that the legislature did not think it worth while to attend
  • to this circumstance.
  • Thus, in 1436, it was enacted, that wheat might be exported without a
  • licence when the price was so low as six shillings and eightpence: and in
  • 1463, it was enacted, that no wheat should be imported if the price was
  • not above six shillings and eightpence the quarter: The legislature had
  • imagined, that when the price was so low, there could be no inconveniency
  • in exportation, but that when it rose higher, it became prudent to allow
  • of importation. Six shillings and eightpence, therefore, containing about
  • the same quantity of silver as thirteen shillings and fourpence of our
  • present money (one-third part less than the same nominal sum contained in
  • the time of Edward III), had, in those times, been considered as what is
  • called the moderate and reasonable price of wheat.
  • In 1554, by the 1st and 2nd of Philip and Mary, and in 1558, by the 1st of
  • Elizabeth, the exportation of wheat was in the same manner prohibited,
  • whenever the price of the quarter should exceed six shillings and
  • eightpence, which did not then contain two penny worth more silver than
  • the same nominal sum does at present. But it had soon been found, that to
  • restrain the exportation of wheat till the price was so very low, was, in
  • reality, to prohibit it altogether. In 1562, therefore, by the 5th of
  • Elizabeth, the exportation of wheat was allowed from certain ports,
  • whenever the price of the quarter should not exceed ten shillings,
  • containing nearly the same quantity of silver as the like nominal sum does
  • at present. This price had at this time, therefore, been considered as
  • what is called the moderate and reasonable price of wheat. It agrees
  • nearly with the estimation of the Northumberland book in 1512.
  • That in France the average price of grain was, in the same manner, much
  • lower in the end of the fifteenth and beginning of the sixteenth century,
  • than in the two centuries preceding, has been observed both by Mr Dupré de
  • St Maur, and by the elegant author of the Essay on the Policy of Grain.
  • Its price, during the same period, had probably sunk in the same manner
  • through the greater part of Europe.
  • This rise in the value of silver, in proportion to that of corn, may
  • either have been owing altogether to the increase of the demand for that
  • metal, in consequence of increasing improvement and cultivation, the
  • supply, in the mean time, continuing the same as before; or, the demand
  • continuing the same as before, it may have been owing altogether to the
  • gradual diminution of the supply: the greater part of the mines which were
  • then known in the world being much exhausted, and, consequently, the
  • expense of working them much increased; or it may have been owing partly
  • to the one, and partly to the other of those two circumstances. In the end
  • of the fifteenth and beginning of the sixteenth centuries, the greater
  • part of Europe was approaching towards a more settled form of government
  • than it had enjoyed for several ages before. The increase of security
  • would naturally increase industry and improvement; and the demand for the
  • precious metals, as well as for every other luxury and ornament, would
  • naturally increase with the increase of riches. A greater annual produce
  • would require a greater quantity of coin to circulate it; and a greater
  • number of rich people would require a greater quantity of plate and other
  • ornaments of silver. It is natural to suppose, too, that the greater part
  • of the mines which then supplied the European market with silver might be
  • a good deal exhausted, and have become more expensive in the working. They
  • had been wrought, many of them, from the time of the Romans.
  • It has been the opinion, however, of the greater part of those who have
  • written upon the prices of commodities in ancient times, that, from the
  • Conquest, perhaps from the invasion of Julius Caesar, till the discovery
  • of the mines of America, the value of silver was continually diminishing.
  • This opinion they seem to have been led into, partly by the observations
  • which they had occasion to make upon the prices both of corn and of some
  • other parts of the rude produce of land, and partly by the popular notion,
  • that as the quantity of silver naturally increases in every country with
  • the increase of wealth, so its value diminishes as it quantity increases.
  • In their observations upon the prices of corn, three different
  • circumstances seem frequently to have misled them.
  • First, in ancient times, almost all rents were paid in kind; in a certain
  • quantity of corn, cattle, poultry, etc. It sometimes happened, however,
  • that the landlord would stipulate, that he should be at liberty to demand
  • of the tenant, either the annual payment in kind or a certain sum of money
  • instead of it. The price at which the payment in kind was in this manner
  • exchanged for a certain sum of money, is in Scotland called the conversion
  • price. As the option is always in the landlord to take either the
  • substance or the price, it is necessary, for the safety of the tenant,
  • that the conversion price should rather be below than above the average
  • market price. In many places, accordingly, it is not much above one half
  • of this price. Through the greater part of Scotland this custom still
  • continues with regard to poultry, and in some places with regard to
  • cattle. It might probably have continued to take place, too, with regard
  • to corn, had not the institution of the public fiars put an end to it.
  • These are annual valuations, according to the judgment of an assize, of
  • the average price of all the different sorts of grain, and of all the
  • different qualities of each, according to the actual market price in every
  • different county. This institution rendered it sufficiently safe for the
  • tenant, and much more convenient for the landlord, to convert, as they
  • call it, the corn rent, rather at what should happen to be the price of
  • the fiars of each year, than at any certain fixed price. But the writers
  • who have collected the prices of corn in ancient times seem frequently to
  • have mistaken what is called in Scotland the conversion price for the
  • actual market price. Fleetwood acknowledges, upon one occasion, that he
  • had made this mistake. As he wrote his book, however, for a particular
  • purpose, he does not think proper to make this acknowledgment till after
  • transcribing this conversion price fifteen times. The price is eight
  • shillings the quarter of wheat. This sum in 1423, the year at which he
  • begins with it, contained the same quantity of silver as sixteen shillings
  • of our present money. But in 1562, the year at which he ends with it, it
  • contained no more than the same nominal sum does at present.
  • Secondly, they have been misled by the slovenly manner in which some
  • ancient statutes of assize had been sometimes transcribed by lazy copiers,
  • and sometimes, perhaps, actually composed by the legislature.
  • The ancient statutes of assize seem to have begun always with determining
  • what ought to be the price of bread and ale when the price of wheat and
  • barley were at the lowest; and to have proceeded gradually to determine
  • what it ought to be, according as the prices of those two sorts of grain
  • should gradually rise above this lowest price. But the transcribers of
  • those statutes seem frequently to have thought it sufficient to copy the
  • regulation as far as the three or four first and lowest prices; saving in
  • this manner their own labour, and judging, I suppose, that this was enough
  • to show what proportion ought to be observed in all higher prices.
  • Thus, in the assize of bread and ale, of the 51st of Henry III. the price
  • of bread was regulated according to the different prices of wheat, from
  • one shilling to twenty shillings the quarter of the money of those times.
  • But in the manuscripts from which all the different editions of the
  • statutes, preceding that of Mr Ruffhead, were printed, the copiers had
  • never transcribed this regulation beyond the price of twelve shillings.
  • Several writers, therefore, being misled by this faulty transcription,
  • very naturally conclude that the middle price, or six shillings the
  • quarter, equal to about eighteen shillings of our present money, was the
  • ordinary or average price of wheat at that time.
  • In the statute of Tumbrel and Pillory, enacted nearly about the same time,
  • the price of ale is regulated according to every sixpence rise in the
  • price of barley, from two shillings, to four shillings the quarter. That
  • four shillings, however, was not considered as the highest price to which
  • barley might frequently rise in those times, and that these prices were
  • only given as an example of the proportion which ought to be observed in
  • all other prices, whether higher or lower, we may infer from the last
  • words of the statute: “Et sic deinceps crescetur vel diminuetur per sex
  • denarios.” The expression is very slovenly, but the meaning is plain
  • enough, “that the price of ale is in this manner to be increased or
  • diminished according to every sixpence rise or fall in the price of
  • barley.” In the composition of this statute, the legislature itself seems
  • to have been as negligent as the copiers were in the transcription of the
  • other.
  • In an ancient manuscript of the Regiam Majestatem, an old Scotch law book,
  • there is a statute of assize, in which the price of bread is regulated
  • according to all the different prices of wheat, from tenpence to three
  • shillings the Scotch boll, equal to about half an English quarter. Three
  • shillings Scotch, at the time when this assize is supposed to have been
  • enacted, were equal to about nine shillings sterling of our present money.
  • Mr Ruddiman seems {See his Preface to Anderson’s Diplomata Scotiae.} to
  • conclude from this, that three shillings was the highest price to which
  • wheat ever rose in those times, and that tenpence, a shilling, or at most
  • two shillings, were the ordinary prices. Upon consulting the manuscript,
  • however, it appears evidently, that all these prices are only set down as
  • examples of the proportion which ought to be observed between the
  • respective prices of wheat and bread. The last words of the statute are
  • “reliqua judicabis secundum praescripta, habendo respectum ad pretium
  • bladi.”—“You shall judge of the remaining cases, according to what
  • is above written, having respect to the price of corn.”
  • Thirdly, they seem to have been misled too, by the very low price at which
  • wheat was sometimes sold in very ancient times; and to have imagined, that
  • as its lowest price was then much lower than in later times its ordinary
  • price must likewise have been much lower. They might have found, however,
  • that in those ancient times its highest price was fully as much above, as
  • its lowest price was below any thing that had ever been known in later
  • times. Thus, in 1270, Fleetwood gives us two prices of the quarter of
  • wheat. The one is four pounds sixteen shillings of the money of those
  • times, equal to fourteen pounds eight shillings of that of the present;
  • the other is six pounds eight shillings, equal to nineteen pounds four
  • shillings of our present money. No price can be found in the end of the
  • fifteenth, or beginning of the sixteenth century, which approaches to the
  • extravagance of these. The price of corn, though at all times liable to
  • variation varies most in those turbulent and disorderly societies, in
  • which the interruption of all commerce and communication hinders the
  • plenty of one part of the country from relieving the scarcity of another.
  • In the disorderly state of England under the Plantagenets, who governed it
  • from about the middle of the twelfth till towards the end of the fifteenth
  • century, one district might be in plenty, while another, at no great
  • distance, by having its crop destroyed, either by some accident of the
  • seasons, or by the incursion of some neighbouring baron, might be
  • suffering all the horrors of a famine; and yet if the lands of some
  • hostile lord were interposed between them, the one might not be able to
  • give the least assistance to the other. Under the vigorous administration
  • of the Tudors, who governed England during the latter part of the
  • fifteenth, and through the whole of the sixteenth century, no baron was
  • powerful enough to dare to disturb the public security.
  • The reader will find at the end of this chapter all the prices of wheat
  • which have been collected by Fleetwood, from 1202 to 1597, both inclusive,
  • reduced to the money of the present times, and digested, according to the
  • order of time, into seven divisions of twelve years each. At the end of
  • each division, too, he will find the average price of the twelve years of
  • which it consists. In that long period of time, Fleetwood has been able to
  • collect the prices of no more than eighty years; so that four years are
  • wanting to make out the last twelve years. I have added, therefore, from
  • the accounts of Eton college, the prices of 1598, 1599, 1600, and 1601. It
  • is the only addition which I have made. The reader will see, that from the
  • beginning of the thirteenth till after the middle of the sixteenth
  • century, the average price of each twelve years grows gradually lower and
  • lower; and that towards the end of the sixteenth century it begins to rise
  • again. The prices, indeed, which Fleetwood has been able to collect, seem
  • to have been those chiefly which were remarkable for extraordinary
  • dearness or cheapness; and I do not pretend that any very certain
  • conclusion can be drawn from them. So far, however, as they prove any
  • thing at all, they confirm the account which I have been endeavouring to
  • give. Fleetwood himself, however, seems, with most other writers, to have
  • believed, that, during all this period, the value of silver, in
  • consequence of its increasing abundance, was continually diminishing. The
  • prices of corn, which he himself has collected, certainly do not agree
  • with this opinion. They agree perfectly with that of Mr Dupré de St Maur,
  • and with that which I have been endeavouring to explain. Bishop Fleetwood
  • and Mr Dupré de St Maur are the two authors who seem to have collected,
  • with the greatest diligence and fidelity, the prices of things in ancient
  • times. It is somewhat curious that, though their opinions are so very
  • different, their facts, so far as they relate to the price of corn at
  • least, should coincide so very exactly.
  • It is not, however, so much from the low price of corn, as from that of
  • some other parts of the rude produce of land, that the most judicious
  • writers have inferred the great value of silver in those very ancient
  • times. Corn, it has been said, being a sort of manufacture, was, in those
  • rude ages, much dearer in proportion than the greater part of other
  • commodities; it is meant, I suppose, than the greater part of
  • unmanufactured commodities, such as cattle, poultry, game of all kinds,
  • etc. That in those times of poverty and barbarism these were
  • proportionably much cheaper than corn, is undoubtedly true. But this
  • cheapness was not the effect of the high value of silver, but of the low
  • value of those commodities. It was not because silver would in such times
  • purchase or represent a greater quantity of labour, but because such
  • commodities would purchase or represent a much smaller quantity than in
  • times of more opulence and improvement. Silver must certainly be cheaper
  • in Spanish America than in Europe; in the country where it is produced,
  • than in the country to which it is brought, at the expense of a long
  • carriage both by land and by sea, of a freight, and an insurance.
  • One-and-twenty pence halfpenny sterling, however, we are told by Ulloa,
  • was, not many years ago, at Buenos Ayres, the price of an ox chosen from a
  • herd of three or four hundred. Sixteen shillings sterling, we are told by
  • Mr Byron, was the price of a good horse in the capital of Chili. In a
  • country naturally fertile, but of which the far greater part is altogether
  • uncultivated, cattle, poultry, game of all kinds, etc. as they can be
  • acquired with a very small quantity of labour, so they will purchase or
  • command but a very small quantity. The low money price for which they may
  • be sold, is no proof that the real value of silver is there very high, but
  • that the real value of those commodities is very low.
  • Labour, it must always be remembered, and not any particular commodity, or
  • set of commodities, is the real measure of the value both of silver and of
  • all other commodities.
  • But in countries almost waste, or but thinly inhabited, cattle, poultry,
  • game of all kinds, etc. as they are the spontaneous productions of Nature,
  • so she frequently produces them in much greater quantities than the
  • consumption of the inhabitants requires. In such a state of things, the
  • supply commonly exceeds the demand. In different states of society, in
  • different states of improvement, therefore, such commodities will
  • represent, or be equivalent, to very different quantities of labour.
  • In every state of society, in every stage of improvement, corn is the
  • production of human industry. But the average produce of every sort of
  • industry is always suited, more or less exactly, to the average
  • consumption; the average supply to the average demand. In every different
  • stage of improvement, besides, the raising of equal quantities of corn in
  • the same soil and climate, will, at an average, require nearly equal
  • quantities of labour; or, what comes to the same thing, the price of
  • nearly equal quantities; the continual increase of the productive powers
  • of labour, in an improved state of cultivation, being more or less
  • counterbalanced by the continual increasing price of cattle, the principal
  • instruments of agriculture. Upon all these accounts, therefore, we may
  • rest assured, that equal quantities of corn will, in every state of
  • society, in every stage of improvement, more nearly represent, or be
  • equivalent to, equal quantities of labour, than equal quantities of any
  • other part of the rude produce of land. Corn, accordingly, it has already
  • been observed, is, in all the different stages of wealth and improvement,
  • a more accurate measure of value than any other commodity or set of
  • commodities. In all those different stages, therefore, we can judge better
  • of the real value of silver, by comparing it with corn, than by comparing
  • it with any other commodity or set of commodities.
  • Corn, besides, or whatever else is the common and favourite vegetable food
  • of the people, constitutes, in every civilized country, the principal part
  • of the subsistence of the labourer. In consequence of the extension of
  • agriculture, the land of every country produces a much greater quantity of
  • vegetable than of animal food, and the labourer everywhere lives chiefly
  • upon the wholesome food that is cheapest and most abundant. Butcher’s
  • meat, except in the most thriving countries, or where labour is most
  • highly rewarded, makes but an insignificant part of his subsistence;
  • poultry makes a still smaller part of it, and game no part of it. In
  • France, and even in Scotland, where labour is somewhat better rewarded
  • than in France, the labouring poor seldom eat butcher’s meat, except upon
  • holidays, and other extraordinary occasions. The money price of labour,
  • therefore, depends much more upon the average money price of corn, the
  • subsistence of the labourer, than upon that of butcher’s meat, or of any
  • other part of the rude produce of land. The real value of gold and silver,
  • therefore, the real quantity of labour which they can purchase or command,
  • depends much more upon the quantity of corn which they can purchase or
  • command, than upon that of butcher’s meat, or any other part of the rude
  • produce of land.
  • Such slight observations, however, upon the prices either of corn or of
  • other commodities, would not probably have misled so many intelligent
  • authors, had they not been influenced at the same time by the popular
  • notion, that as the quantity of silver naturally increases in every
  • country with the increase of wealth, so its value diminishes as its
  • quantity increases. This notion, however, seems to be altogether
  • groundless.
  • The quantity of the precious metals may increase in any country from two
  • different causes; either, first, from the increased abundance of the mines
  • which supply it; or, secondly, from the increased wealth of the people,
  • from the increased produce of their annual labour. The first of these
  • causes is no doubt necessarily connected with the diminution of the value
  • of the precious metals; but the second is not.
  • When more abundant mines are discovered, a greater quantity of the
  • precious metals is brought to market; and the quantity of the necessaries
  • and conveniencies of life for which they must be exchanged being the same
  • as before, equal quantities of the metals must be exchanged for smaller
  • quantities of commodities. So far, therefore, as the increase of the
  • quantity of the precious metals in any country arises from the increased
  • abundance of the mines, it is necessarily connected with some diminution
  • of their value.
  • When, on the contrary, the wealth of any country increases, when the
  • annual produce of its labour becomes gradually greater and greater, a
  • greater quantity of coin becomes necessary in order to circulate a greater
  • quantity of commodities: and the people, as they can afford it, as they
  • have more commodities to give for it, will naturally purchase a greater
  • and a greater quantity of plate. The quantity of their coin will increase
  • from necessity; the quantity of their plate from vanity and ostentation,
  • or from the same reason that the quantity of fine statues, pictures, and
  • of every other luxury and curiosity, is likely to increase among them. But
  • as statuaries and painters are not likely to be worse rewarded in times of
  • wealth and prosperity, than in times of poverty and depression, so gold
  • and silver are not likely to be worse paid for.
  • The price of gold and silver, when the accidental discovery of more
  • abundant mines does not keep it down, as it naturally rises with the
  • wealth of every country, so, whatever be the state of the mines, it is at
  • all times naturally higher in a rich than in a poor country. Gold and
  • silver, like all other commodities, naturally seek the market where the
  • best price is given for them, and the best price is commonly given for
  • every thing in the country which can best afford it. Labour, it must be
  • remembered, is the ultimate price which is paid for every thing; and in
  • countries where labour is equally well rewarded, the money price of labour
  • will be in proportion to that of the subsistence of the labourer. But gold
  • and silver will naturally exchange for a greater quantity of subsistence
  • in a rich than in a poor country; in a country which abounds with
  • subsistence, than in one which is but indifferently supplied with it. If
  • the two countries are at a great distance, the difference may be very
  • great; because, though the metals naturally fly from the worse to the
  • better market, yet it may be difficult to transport them in such
  • quantities as to bring their price nearly to a level in both. If the
  • countries are near, the difference will be smaller, and may sometimes be
  • scarce perceptible; because in this case the transportation will be easy.
  • China is a much richer country than any part of Europe, and the difference
  • between the price of subsistence in China and in Europe is very great.
  • Rice in China is much cheaper than wheat is any where in Europe. England
  • is a much richer country than Scotland, but the difference between the
  • money price of corn in those two countries is much smaller, and is but
  • just perceptible. In proportion to the quantity or measure, Scotch corn
  • generally appears to be a good deal cheaper than English; but, in
  • proportion to its quality, it is certainly somewhat dearer. Scotland
  • receives almost every year very large supplies from England, and every
  • commodity must commonly be somewhat dearer in the country to which it is
  • brought than in that from which it comes. English corn, therefore, must be
  • dearer in Scotland than in England; and yet in proportion to its quality,
  • or to the quantity and goodness of the flour or meal which can be made
  • from it, it cannot commonly be sold higher there than the Scotch corn
  • which comes to market in competition with it.
  • The difference between the money price of labour in China and in Europe,
  • is still greater than that between the money price of subsistence; because
  • the real recompence of labour is higher in Europe than in China, the
  • greater part of Europe being in an improving state, while China seems to
  • be standing still. The money price of labour is lower in Scotland than in
  • England, because the real recompence of labour is much lower: Scotland,
  • though advancing to greater wealth, advances much more slowly than
  • England. The frequency of emigration from Scotland, and the rarity of it
  • from England, sufficiently prove that the demand for labour is very
  • different in the two countries. The proportion between the real recompence
  • of labour in different countries, it must be remembered, is naturally
  • regulated, not by their actual wealth or poverty, but by their advancing,
  • stationary, or declining condition.
  • Gold and silver, as they are naturally of the greatest value among the
  • richest, so they are naturally of the least value among the poorest
  • nations. Among savages, the poorest of all nations, they are scarce of any
  • value.
  • In great towns, corn is always dearer than in remote parts of the country.
  • This, however, is the effect, not of the real cheapness of silver, but of
  • the real dearness of corn. It does not cost less labour to bring silver to
  • the great town than to the remote parts of the country; but it costs a
  • great deal more to bring corn.
  • In some very rich and commercial countries, such as Holland and the
  • territory of Genoa, corn is dear for the same reason that it is dear in
  • great towns. They do not produce enough to maintain their inhabitants.
  • They are rich in the industry and skill of their artificers and
  • manufacturers, in every sort of machinery which can facilitate and abridge
  • labour; in shipping, and in all the other instruments and means of
  • carriage and commerce: but they are poor in corn, which, as it must be
  • brought to them from distant countries, must, by an addition to its price,
  • pay for the carriage from those countries. It does not cost less labour to
  • bring silver to Amsterdam than to Dantzic; but it costs a great deal more
  • to bring corn. The real cost of silver must be nearly the same in both
  • places; but that of corn must be very different. Diminish the real
  • opulence either of Holland or of the territory of Genoa, while the number
  • of their inhabitants remains the same; diminish their power of supplying
  • themselves from distant countries; and the price of corn, instead of
  • sinking with that diminution in the quantity of their silver, which must
  • necessarily accompany this declension, either as its cause or as its
  • effect, will rise to the price of a famine. When we are in want of
  • necessaries, we must part with all superfluities, of which the value, as
  • it rises in times of opulence and prosperity, so it sinks in times of
  • poverty and distress. It is otherwise with necessaries. Their real price,
  • the quantity of labour which they can purchase or command, rises in times
  • of poverty and distress, and sinks in times of opulence and prosperity,
  • which are always times of great abundance; for they could not otherwise be
  • times of opulence and prosperity. Corn is a necessary, silver is only a
  • superfluity.
  • Whatever, therefore, may have been the increase in the quantity of the
  • precious metals, which, during the period between the middle of the
  • fourteenth and that of the sixteenth century, arose from the increase of
  • wealth and improvement, it could have no tendency to diminish their value,
  • either in Great Britain, or in my other part of Europe. If those who have
  • collected the prices of things in ancient times, therefore, had, during
  • this period, no reason to infer the diminution of the value of silver from
  • any observations which they had made upon the prices either of corn, or of
  • other commodities, they had still less reason to infer it from any
  • supposed increase of wealth and improvement.
  • Second Period.—But how various soever may have been the opinions of
  • the learned concerning the progress of the value of silver during the
  • first period, they are unanimous concerning it during the second.
  • From about 1570 to about 1640, during a period of about seventy years, the
  • variation in the proportion between the value of silver and that of corn
  • held a quite opposite course. Silver sunk in its real value, or would
  • exchange for a smaller quantity of labour than before; and corn rose in
  • its nominal price, and, instead of being commonly sold for about two
  • ounces of silver the quarter, or about ten shillings of our present money,
  • came to be sold for six and eight ounces of silver the quarter, or about
  • thirty and forty shillings of our present money.
  • The discovery of the abundant mines of America seems to have been the sole
  • cause of this diminution in the value of silver, in proportion to that of
  • corn. It is accounted for, accordingly, in the same manner by every body;
  • and there never has been any dispute, either about the fact, or about the
  • cause of it. The greater part of Europe was, during this period, advancing
  • in industry and improvement, and the demand for silver must consequently
  • have been increasing; but the increase of the supply had, it seems, so far
  • exceeded that of the demand, that the value of that metal sunk
  • considerably. The discovery of the mines of America, it is to be observed,
  • does not seem to have had any very sensible effect upon the prices of
  • things in England till after 1570; though even the mines of Potosi had
  • been discovered more than twenty years before.
  • From 1595 to 1620, both inclusive, the average price of the quarter of
  • nine bushels of the best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from the
  • accounts of Eton college, to have been £ 2:1:6 9/13. From which sum,
  • neglecting the fraction, and deducting a ninth, or 4s. 7 1/3d., the price
  • of the quarter of eight bushels comes out to have been £ 1:16:10 2/3. And
  • from this sum, neglecting likewise the fraction, and deducting a ninth, or
  • 4s. 1 1/9d., for the difference between the price of the best wheat and
  • that of the middle wheat, the price of the middle wheat comes out to have
  • been about £ 1:12:8 8/9, or about six ounces and one-third of an ounce of
  • silver.
  • From 1621 to 1636, both inclusive, the average price of the same measure
  • of the best wheat, at the same market, appears, from the same accounts, to
  • have been £ 2:10s.; from which, making the like deductions as in the
  • foregoing case, the average price of the quarter of eight bushels of
  • middle wheat comes out to have been £ 1:19:6, or about seven ounces and
  • two-thirds of an ounce of silver.
  • Third Period.—Between 1630 and 1640, or about 1636, the effect of
  • the discovery of the mines of America, in reducing the value of silver,
  • appears to have been completed, and the value of that metal seems never to
  • have sunk lower in proportion to that of corn than it was about that time.
  • It seems to have risen somewhat in the course of the present century, and
  • it had probably begun to do so, even some time before the end of the last.
  • From 1637 to 1700, both inclusive, being the sixty-four last years of the
  • last century the average price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best
  • wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from the same accounts, to have been £
  • 2:11:0 1/3, which is only 1s. 0 1/3d. dearer than it had been during the
  • sixteen years before. But, in the course of these sixty-four years, there
  • happened two events, which must have produced a much greater scarcity of
  • corn than what the course of the seasons would otherwise have occasioned,
  • and which, therefore, without supposing any further reduction in the
  • value of silver, will much more than account for this very small
  • enhancement of price.
  • The first of these events was the civil war, which, by discouraging
  • tillage and interrupting commerce, must have raised the price of corn much
  • above what the course of the seasons would otherwise have occasioned. It
  • must have had this effect, more or less, at all the different markets in
  • the kingdom, but particularly at those in the neighbourhood of London,
  • which require to be supplied from the greatest distance. In 1648,
  • accordingly, the price of the best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, from
  • the same accounts, to have been £ 4:5s., and, in 1649, to have been £ 4,
  • the quarter of nine bushels. The excess of those two years above £ 2:10s.
  • (the average price of the sixteen years preceding 1637) is £ 3:5s., which,
  • divided among the sixty four last years of the last century, will alone
  • very nearly account for that small enhancement of price which seems to
  • have taken place in them. These, however, though the highest, are by no
  • means the only high prices which seem to have been occasioned by the civil
  • wars.
  • The second event was the bounty upon the exportation of corn, granted in
  • 1688. The bounty, it has been thought by many people, by encouraging
  • tillage, may, in a long course of years, have occasioned a greater
  • abundance, and, consequently, a greater cheapness of corn in the home
  • market, than what would otherwise have taken place there. How far the
  • bounty could produce this effect at any time I shall examine hereafter: I
  • shall only observe at present, that between 1688 and 1700, it had not time
  • to produce any such effect. During this short period, its only effect must
  • have been, by encouraging the exportation of the surplus produce of every
  • year, and thereby hindering the abundance of one year from compensating
  • the scarcity of another, to raise the price in the home market. The
  • scarcity which prevailed in England, from 1693 to 1699, both inclusive,
  • though no doubt principally owing to the badness of the seasons, and,
  • therefore, extending through a considerable part of Europe, must have been
  • somewhat enhanced by the bounty. In 1699, accordingly, the further
  • exportation of corn was prohibited for nine months.
  • There was a third event which occurred in the course of the same period,
  • and which, though it could not occasion any scarcity of corn, nor,
  • perhaps, any augmentation in the real quantity of silver which was usually
  • paid for it, must necessarily have occasioned some augmentation in the
  • nominal sum. This event was the great debasement of the silver coin, by
  • clipping and wearing. This evil had begun in the reign of Charles II. and
  • had gone on continually increasing till 1695; at which time, as we may
  • learn from Mr Lowndes, the current silver coin was, at an average, near
  • five-and-twenty per cent. below its standard value. But the nominal sum
  • which constitutes the market price of every commodity is necessarily
  • regulated, not so much by the quantity of silver, which, according to the
  • standard, ought to be contained in it, as by that which, it is found by
  • experience, actually is contained in it. This nominal sum, therefore, is
  • necessarily higher when the coin is much debased by clipping and wearing,
  • than when near to its standard value.
  • In the course of the present century, the silver coin has not at any time
  • been more below its standard weight than it is at present. But though very
  • much defaced, its value has been kept up by that of the gold coin, for
  • which it is exchanged. For though, before the late recoinage, the gold
  • coin was a good deal defaced too, it was less so than the silver. In 1695,
  • on the contrary, the value of the silver coin was not kept up by the gold
  • coin; a guinea then commonly exchanging for thirty shillings of the worn
  • and clipt silver. Before the late recoinage of the gold, the price of
  • silver bullion was seldom higher than five shillings and sevenpence an
  • ounce, which is but fivepence above the mint price. But in 1695, the
  • common price of silver bullion was six shillings and fivepence an ounce,
  • {Lowndes’s Essay on the Silver Coin, 68.} which is fifteen pence above the
  • mint price. Even before the late recoinage of the gold, therefore, the
  • coin, gold and silver together, when compared with silver bullion, was not
  • supposed to be more than eight per cent. below its standard value, In
  • 1695, on the contrary, it had been supposed to be near five-and-twenty per
  • cent. below that value. But in the beginning of the present century, that
  • is, immediately after the great recoinage in King William’s time, the
  • greater part of the current silver coin must have been still nearer to its
  • standard weight than it is at present. In the course of the present
  • century, too, there has been no great public calamity, such as a civil
  • war, which could either discourage tillage, or interrupt the interior
  • commerce of the country. And though the bounty which has taken place
  • through the greater part of this century, must always raise the price of
  • corn somewhat higher than it otherwise would be in the actual state of
  • tillage; yet, as in the course of this century, the bounty has had full
  • time to produce all the good effects commonly imputed to it to encourage
  • tillage, and thereby to increase the quantity of corn in the home market,
  • it may, upon the principles of a system which I shall explain and examine
  • hereafter, be supposed to have done something to lower the price of that
  • commodity the one way, as well as to raise it the other. It is by many
  • people supposed to have done more. In the sixty-four years of the present
  • century, accordingly, the average price of the quarter of nine bushels of
  • the best wheat, at Windsor market, appears, by the accounts of Eton
  • college, to have been £ 2:0:6 10/32, which is about ten shillings and
  • sixpence, or more than five-and-twenty percent. cheaper than it had been
  • during the sixty-four last years of the last century; and about nine
  • shillings and sixpence cheaper than it had been during the sixteen years
  • preceding 1636, when the discovery of the abundant mines of America may be
  • supposed to have produced its full effect; and about one shilling cheaper
  • than it had been in the twenty-six years preceding 1620, before that
  • discovery can well be supposed to have produced its full effect. According
  • to this account, the average price of middle wheat, during these
  • sixty-four first years of the present century, comes out to have been
  • about thirty-two shillings the quarter of eight bushels.
  • The value of silver, therefore, seems to have risen somewhat in proportion
  • to that of corn during the course of the present century, and it had
  • probably begun to do so even some time before the end of the last.
  • In 1687, the price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best wheat, at
  • Windsor market, was £ 1:5:2, the lowest price at which it had ever been
  • from 1595.
  • In 1688, Mr Gregory King, a man famous for his knowledge in matters of
  • this kind, estimated the average price of wheat, in years of moderate
  • plenty, to be to the grower 3s. 6d. the bushel, or eight-and-twenty
  • shillings the quarter. The grower’s price I understand to be the same with
  • what is sometimes called the contract price, or the price at which a
  • farmer contracts for a certain number of years to deliver a certain
  • quantity of corn to a dealer. As a contract of this kind saves the farmer
  • the expense and trouble of marketing, the contract price is generally
  • lower than what is supposed to be the average market price. Mr King had
  • judged eight-and-twenty shillings the quarter to be at that time the
  • ordinary contract price in years of moderate plenty. Before the scarcity
  • occasioned by the late extraordinary course of bad seasons, it was, I have
  • been assured, the ordinary contract price in all common years.
  • In 1688 was granted the parliamentary bounty upon the exportation of corn.
  • The country gentlemen, who then composed a still greater proportion of the
  • legislature than they do at present, had felt that the money price of corn
  • was falling. The bounty was an expedient to raise it artificially to the
  • high price at which it had frequently been sold in the times of Charles I.
  • and II. It was to take place, therefore, till wheat was so high as
  • fortyeight shillings the quarter; that is, twenty shillings, or 5-7ths
  • dearer than Mr King had, in that very year, estimated the grower’s price
  • to be in times of moderate plenty. If his calculations deserve any part of
  • the reputation which they have obtained very universally, eight-and-forty
  • shillings the quarter was a price which, without some such expedient as
  • the bounty, could not at that time be expected, except in years of
  • extraordinary scarcity. But the government of King William was not then
  • fully settled. It was in no condition to refuse anything to the country
  • gentlemen, from whom it was, at that very time, soliciting the first
  • establishment of the annual land-tax.
  • The value of silver, therefore, in proportion to that of corn, had
  • probably risen somewhat before the end of the last century; and it seems
  • to have continued to do so during the course of the greater part of the
  • present, though the necessary operation of the bounty must have hindered
  • that rise from being so sensible as it otherwise would have been in the
  • actual state of tillage.
  • In plentiful years, the bounty, by occasioning an extraordinary
  • exportation, necessarily raises the price of corn above what it otherwise
  • would be in those years. To encourage tillage, by keeping up the price of
  • corn, even in the most plentiful years, was the avowed end of the
  • institution.
  • In years of great scarcity, indeed, the bounty has generally been
  • suspended. It must, however, have had some effect upon the prices of many
  • of those years. By the extraordinary exportation which it occasions in
  • years of plenty, it must frequently hinder the plenty of one year from
  • compensating the scarcity of another.
  • Both in years of plenty and in years of scarcity, therefore, the bounty
  • raises the price of corn above what it naturally would be in the actual
  • state of tillage. If during the sixty-four first years of the present
  • century, therefore, the average price has been lower than during the
  • sixty-four last years of the last century, it must, in the same state of
  • tillage, have been much more so, had it not been for this operation of the
  • bounty.
  • But, without the bounty, it may be said the state of tillage would not
  • have been the same. What may have been the effects of this institution
  • upon the agriculture of the country, I shall endeavour to explain
  • hereafter, when I come to treat particularly of bounties. I shall only
  • observe at present, that this rise in the value of silver, in proportion
  • to that of corn, has not been peculiar to England. It has been observed to
  • have taken place in France during the same period, and nearly in the same
  • proportion, too, by three very faithful, diligent, and laborious
  • collectors of the prices of corn, Mr Dupré de St Maur, Mr Messance, and
  • the author of the Essay on the Police of Grain. But in France, till 1764,
  • the exportation of grain was by law prohibited; and it is somewhat
  • difficult to suppose, that nearly the same diminution of price which took
  • place in one country, notwithstanding this prohibition, should, in
  • another, be owing to the extraordinary encouragement given to exportation.
  • It would be more proper, perhaps, to consider this variation in the
  • average money price of corn as the effect rather of some gradual rise in
  • the real value of silver in the European market, than of any fall in the
  • real average value of corn. Corn, it has already been observed, is, at
  • distant periods of time, a more accurate measure of value than either
  • silver or, perhaps, any other commodity. When, after the discovery of the
  • abundant mines of America, corn rose to three and four times its former
  • money price, this change was universally ascribed, not to any rise in the
  • real value of corn, but to a fall in the real value of silver. If, during
  • the sixty-four first years of the present century, therefore, the average
  • money price of corn has fallen somewhat below what it had been during the
  • greater part of the last century, we should, in the same manner, impute
  • this change, not to any fall in the real value of corn, but to some rise
  • in the real value of silver in the European market.
  • The high price of corn during these ten or twelve years past, indeed, has
  • occasioned a suspicion that the real value of silver still continues to
  • fall in the European market. This high price of corn, however, seems
  • evidently to have been the effect of the extraordinary unfavourableness of
  • the seasons, and ought, therefore, to be regarded, not as a permanent, but
  • as a transitory and occasional event. The seasons, for these ten or twelve
  • years past, have been unfavourable through the greater part of Europe; and
  • the disorders of Poland have very much increased the scarcity in all those
  • countries, which, in dear years, used to be supplied from that market. So
  • long a course of bad seasons, though not a very common event, is by no
  • means a singular one; and whoever has inquired much into the history of
  • the prices of corn in former times, will be at no loss to recollect
  • several other examples of the same kind. Ten years of extraordinary
  • scarcity, besides, are not more wonderful than ten years of extraordinary
  • plenty. The low price of corn, from 1741 to 1750, both inclusive, may very
  • well be set in opposition to its high price during these last eight or ten
  • years. From 1741 to 1750, the average price of the quarter of nine bushels
  • of the best wheat, at Windsor market, it appears from the accounts of Eton
  • college, was only £ 1:13:9 4/5, which is nearly 6s.3d. below the average
  • price of the sixty-four first years of the present century. The average
  • price of the quarter of eight bushels of middle wheat comes out, according
  • to this account, to have been, during these ten years, only £ 1:6:8.
  • Between 1741 and 1750, however, the bounty must have hindered the price of
  • corn from falling so low in the home market as it naturally would have
  • done. During these ten years, the quantity of all sorts of grain exported,
  • it appears from the custom-house books, amounted to no less than 8,029,156
  • quarters, one bushel. The bounty paid for this amounted to £
  • 1,514,962:17:4 1/2. In 1749, accordingly, Mr Pelham, at that time prime
  • minister, observed to the house of commons, that, for the three years
  • preceding, a very extraordinary sum had been paid as bounty for the
  • exportation of corn. He had good reason to make this observation, and in
  • the following year he might have had still better. In that single year,
  • the bounty paid amounted to no less than £ 324,176:10:6. {See Tracts on
  • the Corn Trade, Tract 3,} It is unnecessary to observe how much this
  • forced exportation must have raised the price of corn above what it
  • otherwise would have been in the home market.
  • At the end of the accounts annexed to this chapter the reader will find
  • the particular account of those ten years separated from the rest. He will
  • find there, too, the particular account of the preceding ten years, of
  • which the average is likewise below, though not so much below, the general
  • average of the sixty-four first years of the century. The year 1740,
  • however, was a year of extraordinary scarcity. These twenty years
  • preceding 1750 may very well be set in opposition to the twenty preceding
  • 1770. As the former were a good deal below the general average of the
  • century, notwithstanding the intervention of one or two dear years; so the
  • latter have been a good deal above it, notwithstanding the intervention of
  • one or two cheap ones, of 1759, for example. If the former have not been
  • as much below the general average as the latter have been above it, we
  • ought probably to impute it to the bounty. The change has evidently been
  • too sudden to be ascribed to any change in the value of silver, which is
  • always slow and gradual. The suddenness of the effect can be accounted for
  • only by a cause which can operate suddenly, the accidental variations of
  • the seasons.
  • The money price of labour in Great Britain has, indeed, risen during the
  • course of the present century. This, however, seems to be the effect, not
  • so much of any diminution in the value of silver in the European market,
  • as of an increase in the demand for labour in Great Britain, arising from
  • the great, and almost universal prosperity of the country. In France, a
  • country not altogether so prosperous, the money price of labour has, since
  • the middle of the last century, been observed to sink gradually with the
  • average money price of corn. Both in the last century and in the present,
  • the day wages of common labour are there said to have been pretty
  • uniformly about the twentieth part of the average price of the septier of
  • wheat; a measure which contains a little more than four Winchester
  • bushels. In Great Britain, the real recompence of labour, it has already
  • been shewn, the real quantities of the necessaries and conveniencies of
  • life which are given to the labourer, has increased considerably during
  • the course of the present century. The rise in its money price seems to
  • have been the effect, not of any diminution of the value of silver in the
  • general market of Europe, but of a rise in the real price of labour, in
  • the particular market of Great Britain, owing to the peculiarly happy
  • circumstances of the country.
  • For some time after the first discovery of America, silver would continue
  • to sell at its former, or not much below its former price. The profits of
  • mining would for some time be very great, and much above their natural
  • rate. Those who imported that metal into Europe, however, would soon find
  • that the whole annual importation could not be disposed of at this high
  • price. Silver would gradually exchange for a smaller and a smaller
  • quantity of goods. Its price would sink gradually lower and lower, till it
  • fell to its natural price; or to what was just sufficient to pay,
  • according to their natural rates, the wages of the labour, the profits of
  • the stock, and the rent of the land, which must be paid in order to bring
  • it from the mine to the market. In the greater part of the silver mines of
  • Peru, the tax of the king of Spain, amounting to a tenth of the gross
  • produce, eats up, it has already been observed, the whole rent of the
  • land. This tax was originally a half; it soon afterwards fell to a third,
  • then to a fifth, and at last to a tenth, at which late it still continues.
  • In the greater part of the silver mines of Peru, this, it seems, is all
  • that remains, after replacing the stock of the undertaker of the work,
  • together with its ordinary profits; and it seems to be universally
  • acknowledged that these profits, which were once very high, are now as low
  • as they can well be, consistently with carrying on the works.
  • The tax of the king of Spain was reduced to a fifth of the registered
  • silver in 1504 {Solorzano, vol, ii.}, one-and-forty years before 1545, the
  • date of the discovery of the mines of Potosi. In the course of ninety
  • years, or before 1636, these mines, the most fertile in all America, had
  • time sufficient to produce their full effect, or to reduce the value of
  • silver in the European market as low as it could well fall, while it
  • continued to pay this tax to the king of Spain. Ninety years is time
  • sufficient to reduce any commodity, of which there is no monopoly, to its
  • natural price, or to the lowest price at which, while it pays a particular
  • tax, it can continue to be sold for any considerable time together.
  • The price of silver in the European market might, perhaps, have fallen
  • still lower, and it might have become necessary either to reduce the tax
  • upon it, not only to one-tenth, as in 1736, but to one twentieth, in the
  • same manner as that upon gold, or to give up working the greater part of
  • the American mines which are now wrought. The gradual increase of the
  • demand for silver, or the gradual enlargement of the market for the
  • produce of the silver mines of America, is probably the cause which has
  • prevented this from happening, and which has not only kept up the value of
  • silver in the European market, but has perhaps even raised it somewhat
  • higher than it was about the middle of the last century.
  • Since the first discovery of America, the market for the produce of its
  • silver mines has been growing gradually more and more extensive.
  • First, the market of Europe has become gradually more and more extensive.
  • Since the discovery of America, the greater part of Europe has been much
  • improved. England, Holland, France, and Germany; even Sweden, Denmark, and
  • Russia, have all advanced considerably, both in agriculture and in
  • manufactures. Italy seems not to have gone backwards. The fall of Italy
  • preceded the conquest of Peru. Since that time it seems rather to have
  • recovered a little. Spain and Portugal, indeed, are supposed to have gone
  • backwards. Portugal, however, is but a very small part of Europe, and the
  • declension of Spain is not, perhaps, so great as is commonly imagined. In
  • the beginning of the sixteenth century, Spain was a very poor country,
  • even in comparison with France, which has been so much improved since that
  • time. It was the well known remark of the emperor Charles V. who had
  • travelled so frequently through both countries, that every thing abounded
  • in France, but that every thing was wanting in Spain. The increasing
  • produce of the agriculture and manufactures of Europe must necessarily
  • have required a gradual increase in the quantity of silver coin to
  • circulate it; and the increasing number of wealthy individuals must have
  • required the like increase in the quantity of their plate and other
  • ornaments of silver.
  • Secondly, America is itself a new market, for the produce of its own
  • silver mines; and as its advances in agriculture, industry, and
  • population, are much more rapid than those of the most thriving countries
  • in Europe, its demand must increase much more rapidly. The English
  • colonies are altogether a new market, which, partly for coin, and partly
  • for plate, requires a continual augmenting supply of silver through a
  • great continent where there never was any demand before. The greater part,
  • too, of the Spanish and Portuguese colonies, are altogether new markets.
  • New Granada, the Yucatan, Paraguay, and the Brazils, were, before
  • discovered by the Europeans, inhabited by savage nations, who had neither
  • arts nor agriculture. A considerable degree of both has now been
  • introduced into all of them. Even Mexico and Peru, though they cannot be
  • considered as altogether new markets, are certainly much more extensive
  • ones than they ever were before. After all the wonderful tales which have
  • been published concerning the splendid state of those countries in ancient
  • times, whoever reads, with any degree of sober judgment, the history of
  • their first discovery and conquest, will evidently discern that, in arts,
  • agriculture, and commerce, their inhabitants were much more ignorant than
  • the Tartars of the Ukraine are at present. Even the Peruvians, the more
  • civilized nation of the two, though they made use of gold and silver as
  • ornaments, had no coined money of any kind. Their whole commerce was
  • carried on by barter, and there was accordingly scarce any division of
  • labour among them. Those who cultivated the ground, were obliged to build
  • their own houses, to make their own household furniture, their own
  • clothes, shoes, and instruments of agriculture. The few artificers among
  • them are said to have been all maintained by the sovereign, the nobles,
  • and the priests, and were probably their servants or slaves. All the
  • ancient arts of Mexico and Peru have never furnished one single
  • manufacture to Europe. The Spanish armies, though they scarce ever
  • exceeded five hundred men, and frequently did not amount to half that
  • number, found almost everywhere great difficulty in procuring subsistence.
  • The famines which they are said to have occasioned almost wherever they
  • went, in countries, too, which at the same time are represented as very
  • populous and well cultivated, sufficiently demonstrate that the story of
  • this populousness and high cultivation is in a great measure fabulous. The
  • Spanish colonies are under a government in many respects less favourable
  • to agriculture, improvement, and population, than that of the English
  • colonies. They seem, however, to be advancing in all those much more
  • rapidly than any country in Europe. In a fertile soil and happy climate,
  • the great abundance and cheapness of land, a circumstance common to all
  • new colonies, is, it seems, so great an advantage, as to compensate many
  • defects in civil government. Frezier, who visited Peru in 1713, represents
  • Lima as containing between twenty-five and twenty-eight thousand
  • inhabitants. Ulloa, who resided in the same country between 1740 and 1746,
  • represents it as containing more than fifty thousand. The difference in
  • their accounts of the populousness of several other principal towns of
  • Chili and Peru is nearly the same; and as there seems to be no reason to
  • doubt of the good information of either, it marks an increase which is
  • scarce inferior to that of the English colonies. America, therefore, is a
  • new market for the produce of its own silver mines, of which the demand
  • must increase much more rapidly than that of the most thriving country in
  • Europe.
  • Thirdly, the East Indies is another market for the produce of the silver
  • mines of America, and a market which, from the time of the first discovery
  • of those mines, has been continually taking off a greater and a greater
  • quantity of silver. Since that time, the direct trade between America and
  • the East Indies, which is carried on by means of the Acapulco ships, has
  • been continually augmenting, and the indirect intercourse by the way of
  • Europe has been augmenting in a still greater proportion. During the
  • sixteenth century, the Portuguese were the only European nation who
  • carried on any regular trade to the East Indies. In the last years of that
  • century, the Dutch began to encroach upon this monopoly, and in a few
  • years expelled them from their principal settlements in India. During the
  • greater part of the last century, those two nations divided the most
  • considerable part of the East India trade between them; the trade of the
  • Dutch continually augmenting in a still greater proportion than that of
  • the Portuguese declined. The English and French carried on some trade with
  • India in the last century, but it has been greatly augmented in the course
  • of the present. The East India trade of the Swedes and Danes began in the
  • course of the present century. Even the Muscovites now trade regularly
  • with China, by a sort of caravans which go over land through Siberia and
  • Tartary to Pekin. The East India trade of all these nations, if we except
  • that of the French, which the last war had well nigh annihilated, has been
  • almost continually augmenting. The increasing consumptions of East India
  • goods in Europe is, it seems, so great, as to afford a gradual increase of
  • employment to them all. Tea, for example, was a drug very little used in
  • Europe, before the middle of the last century. At present, the value of
  • the tea annually imported by the English East India company, for the use
  • of their own countrymen, amounts to more than a million and a half a year;
  • and even this is not enough; a great deal more being constantly smuggled
  • into the country from the ports of Holland, from Gottenburgh in Sweden,
  • and from the coast of France, too, as long as the French East India
  • company was in prosperity. The consumption of the porcelain of China, of
  • the spiceries of the Moluccas, of the piece goods of Bengal, and of
  • innumerable other articles, has increased very nearly in a like
  • proportion. The tonnage, accordingly, of all the European shipping
  • employed in the East India trade, at any one time during the last century,
  • was not, perhaps, much greater than that of the English East India company
  • before the late reduction of their shipping.
  • But in the East Indies, particularly in China and Indostan, the value of
  • the precious metals, when the Europeans first began to trade to those
  • countries, was much higher than in Europe; and it still continues to be
  • so. In rice countries, which generally yield two, sometimes three crops in
  • the year, each of them more plentiful than any common crop of corn, the
  • abundance of food must be much greater than in any corn country of equal
  • extent. Such countries are accordingly much more populous. In them, too,
  • the rich, having a greater superabundance of food to dispose of beyond
  • what they themselves can consume, have the means of purchasing a much
  • greater quantity of the labour of other people. The retinue of a grandee
  • in China or Indostan accordingly is, by all accounts, much more numerous
  • and splendid than that of the richest subjects in Europe. The same
  • superabundance of food, of which they have the disposal, enables them to
  • give a greater quantity of it for all those singular and rare productions
  • which nature furnishes but in very small quantities; such as the precious
  • metals and the precious stones, the great objects of the competition of
  • the rich. Though the mines, therefore, which supplied the Indian market,
  • had been as abundant as those which supplied the European, such
  • commodities would naturally exchange for a greater quantity of food in
  • India than in Europe. But the mines which supplied the Indian market with
  • the precious metals seem to have been a good deal less abundant, and those
  • which supplied it with the precious stones a good deal more so, than the
  • mines which supplied the European. The precious metals, therefore, would
  • naturally exchange in India for a somewhat greater quantity of the
  • precious stones, and for a much greater quantity of food than in Europe.
  • The money price of diamonds, the greatest of all superfluities, would be
  • somewhat lower, and that of food, the first of all necessaries, a great
  • deal lower in the one country than in the other. But the real price of
  • labour, the real quantity of the necessaries of life which is given to the
  • labourer, it has already been observed, is lower both in China and
  • Indostan, the two great markets of India, than it is through the greater
  • part of Europe. The wages of the labourer will there purchase a smaller
  • quantity of food: and as the money price of food is much lower in India
  • than in Europe, the money price of labour is there lower upon a double
  • account; upon account both of the small quantity of food which it will
  • purchase, and of the low price of that food. But in countries of equal art
  • and industry, the money price of the greater part of manufactures will be
  • in proportion to the money price of labour; and in manufacturing art and
  • industry, China and Indostan, though inferior, seem not to be much
  • inferior to any part of Europe. The money price of the greater part of
  • manufactures, therefore, will naturally be much lower in those great
  • empires than it is anywhere in Europe. Through the greater part of Europe,
  • too, the expense of land-carriage increases very much both the real and
  • nominal price of most manufactures. It costs more labour, and therefore
  • more money, to bring first the materials, and afterwards the complete
  • manufacture to market. In China and Indostan, the extent and variety of
  • inland navigations save the greater part of this labour, and consequently
  • of this money, and thereby reduce still lower both the real and the
  • nominal price of the greater part of their manufactures. Upon all these
  • accounts, the precious metals are a commodity which it always has been,
  • and still continues to be, extremely advantageous to carry from Europe to
  • India. There is scarce any commodity which brings a better price there; or
  • which, in proportion to the quantity of labour and commodities which it
  • costs in Europe, will purchase or command a greater quantity of labour and
  • commodities in India. It is more advantageous, too, to carry silver
  • thither than gold; because in China, and the greater part of the other
  • markets of India, the proportion between fine silver and fine gold is but
  • as ten, or at most as twelve to one; whereas in Europe it is as fourteen
  • or fifteen to one. In China, and the greater part of the other markets of
  • India, ten, or at most twelve ounces of silver, will purchase an ounce of
  • gold; in Europe, it requires from fourteen to fifteen ounces. In the
  • cargoes, therefore, of the greater part of European ships which sail to
  • India, silver has generally been one of the most valuable articles. It is
  • the most valuable article in the Acapulco ships which sail to Manilla. The
  • silver of the new continent seems, in this manner, to be one of the
  • principal commodities by which the commerce between the two extremities of
  • the old one is carried on; and it is by means of it, in a great measure,
  • that those distant parts of the world are connected with one another.
  • In order to supply so very widely extended a market, the quantity of
  • silver annually brought from the mines must not only be sufficient to
  • support that continued increase, both of coin and of plate, which is
  • required in all thriving countries; but to repair that continual waste and
  • consumption of silver which takes place in all countries where that metal
  • is used.
  • The continual consumption of the precious metals in coin by wearing, and
  • in plate both by wearing and cleaning, is very sensible; and in
  • commodities of which the use is so very widely extended, would alone
  • require a very great annual supply. The consumption of those metals in
  • some particular manufactures, though it may not perhaps be greater upon
  • the whole than this gradual consumption, is, however, much more sensible,
  • as it is much more rapid. In the manufactures of Birmingham alone, the
  • quantity of gold and silver annually employed in gilding and plating, and
  • thereby disqualified from ever afterwards appearing in the shape of those
  • metals, is said to amount to more than fifty thousand pounds sterling. We
  • may from thence form some notion how great must be the annual consumption
  • in all the different parts of the world, either in manufactures of the
  • same kind with those of Birmingham, or in laces, embroideries, gold and
  • silver stuffs, the gilding of books, furniture, etc. A considerable
  • quantity, too, must be annually lost in transporting those metals from one
  • place to another both by sea and by land. In the greater part of the
  • governments of Asia, besides, the almost universal custom of concealing
  • treasures in the bowels of the earth, of which the knowledge frequently
  • dies with the person who makes the concealment, must occasion the loss of
  • a still greater quantity.
  • The quantity of gold and silver imported at both Cadiz and Lisbon
  • (including not only what comes under register, but what may be supposed to
  • be smuggled) amounts, according to the best accounts, to about six
  • millions sterling a-year.
  • According to Mr Meggens {Postscript to the Universal Merchant p. 15 and
  • 16. This postscript was not printed till 1756, three years after the
  • publication of the book, which has never had a second edition. The
  • postscript is, therefore, to be found in few copies; it corrects several
  • errors in the book.}, the annual importation of the precious metals into
  • Spain, at an average of six years, viz. from 1748 to 1753, both inclusive,
  • and into Portugal, at an average of seven years, viz. from 1747 to 1753,
  • both inclusive, amounted in silver to 1,101,107 pounds weight, and in gold
  • to 49,940 pounds weight. The silver, at sixty two shillings the pound
  • troy, amounts to £ 3,413,431:10s. sterling. The gold, at forty-four
  • guineas and a half the pound troy, amounts to £ 2,333,446:14s. sterling.
  • Both together amount to £ 5,746,878:4s. sterling. The account of what was
  • imported under register, he assures us, is exact. He gives us the detail
  • of the particular places from which the gold and silver were brought, and
  • of the particular quantity of each metal, which, according to the
  • register, each of them afforded. He makes an allowance, too, for the
  • quantity of each metal which, he supposes, may have been smuggled. The
  • great experience of this judicious merchant renders his opinion of
  • considerable weight.
  • According to the eloquent, and sometimes well-informed, author of the
  • Philosophical and Political History of the Establishment of the Europeans
  • in the two Indies, the annual importation of registered gold and silver
  • into Spain, at an average of eleven years, viz. from 1754 to 1764, both
  • inclusive, amounted to 13,984,185 3/5 piastres of ten reals. On account of
  • what may have been smuggled, however, the whole annual importation, he
  • supposes, may have amounted to seventeen millions of piastres, which, at
  • 4s. 6d. the piastre, is equal to £ 3,825,000 sterling. He gives the
  • detail, too, of the particular places from which the gold and silver were
  • brought, and of the particular quantities of each metal, which according
  • to the register, each of them afforded. He informs us, too, that if we
  • were to judge of the quantity of gold annually imported from the Brazils
  • to Lisbon, by the amount of the tax paid to the king of Portugal, which it
  • seems, is one-fifth of the standard metal, we might value it at eighteen
  • millions of cruzadoes, or forty-five millions of French livres, equal to
  • about twenty millions sterling. On account of what may have been smuggled,
  • however, we may safely, he says, add to this sum an eighth more, or £
  • 250,000 sterling, so that the whole will amount to £ 2,250,000 sterling.
  • According to this account, therefore, the whole annual importation of the
  • precious metals into both Spain and Portugal, mounts to about £ 6,075,000
  • sterling.
  • Several other very well authenticated, though manuscript accounts, I have
  • been assured, agree in making this whole annual importation amount, at an
  • average, to about six millions sterling; sometimes a little more,
  • sometimes a little less.
  • The annual importation of the precious metals into Cadiz and Lisbon,
  • indeed, is not equal to the whole annual produce of the mines of America.
  • Some part is sent annually by the Acapulco ships to Manilla; some part is
  • employed in a contraband trade, which the Spanish colonies carry on with
  • those of other European nations; and some part, no doubt, remains in the
  • country. The mines of America, besides, are by no means the only gold and
  • silver mines in the world. They, are, however, by far the most abundant.
  • The produce of all the other mines which are known is insignificant, it is
  • acknowledged, in comparison with theirs; and the far greater part of
  • their produce, it is likewise acknowledged, is annually imported into
  • Cadiz and Lisbon. But the consumption of Birmingham alone, at the rate of
  • fifty thousand pounds a-year, is equal to the hundred-and-twentieth part
  • of this annual importation, at the rate of six millions a-year. The whole
  • annual consumption of gold and silver, therefore, in all the different
  • countries of the world where those metals are used, may, perhaps, be
  • nearly equal to the whole annual produce. The remainder may be no more
  • than sufficient to supply the increasing demand of all thriving countries.
  • It may even have fallen so far short of this demand, as somewhat to raise
  • the price of those metals in the European market.
  • The quantity of brass and iron annually brought from the mine to the
  • market, is out of all proportion greater than that of gold and silver. We
  • do not, however, upon this account, imagine that those coarse metals are
  • likely to multiply beyond the demand, or to become gradually cheaper and
  • cheaper. Why should we imagine that the precious metals are likely to do
  • so? The coarse metals, indeed, though harder, are put to much harder uses,
  • and, as they are of less value, less care is employed in their
  • preservation. The precious metals, however, are not necessarily immortal
  • any more than they, but are liable, too, to be lost, wasted, and consumed,
  • in a great variety of ways.
  • The price of all metals, though liable to slow and gradual variations,
  • varies less from year to year than that of almost any other part of the
  • rude produce of land: and the price of the precious metals is even less
  • liable to sudden variations than that of the coarse ones. The durableness
  • of metals is the foundation of this extraordinary steadiness of price. The
  • corn which was brought to market last year will be all, or almost all,
  • consumed, long before the end of this year. But some part of the iron
  • which was brought from the mine two or three hundred years ago, may be
  • still in use, and, perhaps, some part of the gold which was brought from
  • it two or three thousand years ago. The different masses of corn, which,
  • in different years, must supply the consumption of the world, will always
  • be nearly in proportion to the respective produce of those different
  • years. But the proportion between the different masses of iron which may
  • be in use in two different years, will be very little affected by any
  • accidental difference in the produce of the iron mines of those two years;
  • and the proportion between the masses of gold will be still less affected
  • by any such difference in the produce of the gold mines. Though the
  • produce of the greater part of metallic mines, therefore, varies, perhaps,
  • still more from year to year than that of the greater part of corn fields,
  • those variations have not the same effect upon the price of the one
  • species of commodities as upon that of the other.
  • _Variations in the Proportion between the respective Values of Gold and
  • Silver._
  • Before the discovery of the mines of America, the value of fine gold to
  • fine silver was regulated in the different mines of Europe, between the
  • proportions of one to ten and one to twelve; that is, an ounce of fine
  • gold was supposed to be worth from ten to twelve ounces of fine silver.
  • About the middle of the last century, it came to be regulated, between the
  • proportions of one to fourteen and one to fifteen; that is, an ounce of
  • fine gold came to be supposed worth between fourteen and fifteen ounces of
  • fine silver. Gold rose in its nominal value, or in the quantity of silver
  • which was given for it. Both metals sunk in their real value, or in the
  • quantity of labour which they could purchase; but silver sunk more than
  • gold. Though both the gold and silver mines of America exceeded in
  • fertility all those which had ever been known before, the fertility of the
  • silver mines had, it seems, been proportionally still greater than that of
  • the gold ones.
  • The great quantities of silver carried annually from Europe to India,
  • have, in some of the English settlements, gradually reduced the value of
  • that metal in proportion to gold. In the mint of Calcutta, an ounce of
  • fine gold is supposed to be worth fifteen ounces of fine silver, in the
  • same manner as in Europe. It is in the mint, perhaps, rated too high for
  • the value which it bears in the market of Bengal. In China, the proportion
  • of gold to silver still continues as one to ten, or one to twelve. In
  • Japan, it is said to be as one to eight.
  • The proportion between the quantities of gold and silver annually imported
  • into Europe, according to Mr Meggens’ account, is as one to twenty-two
  • nearly; that is, for one ounce of gold there are imported a little more
  • than twenty-two ounces of silver. The great quantity of silver sent
  • annually to the East Indies reduces, he supposes, the quantities of those
  • metals which remain in Europe to the proportion of one to fourteen or
  • fifteen, the proportion of their values. The proportion between their
  • values, he seems to think, must necessarily be the same as that between
  • their quantities, and would therefore be as one to twenty-two, were it not
  • for this greater exportation of silver.
  • But the ordinary proportion between the respective values of two
  • commodities is not necessarily the same as that between the quantities of
  • them which are commonly in the market. The price of an ox, reckoned at ten
  • guineas, is about three score times the price of a lamb, reckoned at 3s.
  • 6d. It would be absurd, however, to infer from thence, that there are
  • commonly in the market three score lambs for one ox; and it would be just
  • as absurd to infer, because an ounce of gold will commonly purchase from
  • fourteen or fifteen ounces of silver, that there are commonly in the
  • market only fourteen or fifteen ounces of silver for one ounce of gold.
  • The quantity of silver commonly in the market, it is probable, is much
  • greater in proportion to that of gold, than the value of a certain
  • quantity of gold is to that of an equal quantity of silver. The whole
  • quantity of a cheap commodity brought to market is commonly not only
  • greater, but of greater value, than the whole quantity of a dear one. The
  • whole quantity of bread annually brought to market, is not only greater,
  • but of greater value, than the whole quantity of butcher’s meat; the whole
  • quantity of butcher’s meat, than the whole quantity of poultry; and the
  • whole quantity of poultry, than the whole quantity of wild fowl. There are
  • so many more purchasers for the cheap than for the dear commodity, that,
  • not only a greater quantity of it, but a greater value can commonly be
  • disposed of. The whole quantity, therefore, of the cheap commodity, must
  • commonly be greater in proportion to the whole quantity of the dear one,
  • than the value of a certain quantity of the dear one, is to the value of
  • an equal quantity of the cheap one. When we compare the precious metals
  • with one another, silver is a cheap, and gold a dear commodity. We ought
  • naturally to expect, therefore, that there should always be in the market,
  • not only a greater quantity, but a greater value of silver than of gold.
  • Let any man, who has a little of both, compare his own silver with his
  • gold plate, and he will probably find, that not only the quantity, but the
  • value of the former, greatly exceeds that of the latter. Many people,
  • besides, have a good deal of silver who have no gold plate, which, even
  • with those who have it, is generally confined to watch-cases, snuff-boxes,
  • and such like trinkets, of which the whole amount is seldom of great
  • value. In the British coin, indeed, the value of the gold preponderates
  • greatly, but it is not so in that of all countries. In the coin of some
  • countries, the value of the two metals is nearly equal. In the Scotch
  • coin, before the union with England, the gold preponderated very little,
  • though it did somewhat {See Ruddiman’s Preface to Anderson’s Diplomata,
  • etc. Scotiae.}, as it appears by the accounts of the mint. In the coin of
  • many countries the silver preponderates. In France, the largest sums are
  • commonly paid in that metal, and it is there difficult to get more gold
  • than what is necessary to carry about in your pocket. The superior value,
  • however, of the silver plate above that of the gold, which takes place in
  • all countries, will much more than compensate the preponderancy of the
  • gold coin above the silver, which takes place only in some countries.
  • Though, in one sense of the word, silver always has been, and probably
  • always will be, much cheaper than gold; yet, in another sense, gold may
  • perhaps, in the present state of the Spanish market, be said to be
  • somewhat cheaper than silver. A commodity may be said to be dear or cheap
  • not only according to the absolute greatness or smallness of its usual
  • price, but according as that price is more or less above the lowest for
  • which it is possible to bring it to market for any considerable time
  • together. This lowest price is that which barely replaces, with a moderate
  • profit, the stock which must be employed in bringing the commodity
  • thither. It is the price which affords nothing to the landlord, of which
  • rent makes not any component part, but which resolves itself altogether
  • into wages and profit. But, in the present state of the Spanish market,
  • gold is certainly somewhat nearer to this lowest price than silver. The
  • tax of the king of Spain upon gold is only one-twentieth part of the
  • standard metal, or five per cent.; whereas his tax upon silver amounts to
  • one-tenth part of it, or to ten per cent. In these taxes, too, it has
  • already been observed, consists the whole rent of the greater part of the
  • gold and silver mines of Spanish America; and that upon gold is still
  • worse paid than that upon silver. The profits of the undertakers of gold
  • mines, too, as they more rarely make a fortune, must, in general, be still
  • more moderate than those of the undertakers of silver mines. The price of
  • Spanish gold, therefore, as it affords both less rent and less profit,
  • must, in the Spanish market, be somewhat nearer to the lowest price for
  • which it is possible to bring it thither, than the price of Spanish
  • silver. When all expenses are computed, the whole quantity of the one
  • metal, it would seem, cannot, in the Spanish market, be disposed of so
  • advantageously as the whole quantity of the other. The tax, indeed, of the
  • king of Portugal upon the gold of the Brazils, is the same with the
  • ancient tax of the king of Spain upon the silver of Mexico and Peru; or
  • one-fifth part of the standard metal. It may therefore be uncertain,
  • whether, to the general market of Europe, the whole mass of American gold
  • comes at a price nearer to the lowest for which it is possible to bring it
  • thither, than the whole mass of American silver.
  • The price of diamonds and other precious stones may, perhaps, be still
  • nearer to the lowest price at which it is possible to bring them to
  • market, than even the price of gold.
  • Though it is not very probable that any part of a tax, which is not only
  • imposed upon one of the most proper subjects of taxation, a mere luxury
  • and superfluity, but which affords so very important a revenue as the tax
  • upon silver, will ever be given up as long as it is possible to pay it;
  • yet the same impossibility of paying it, which, in 1736. made it necessary
  • to reduce it from one-fifth to one-tenth, may in time make it necessary to
  • reduce it still further; in the same manner as it made it necessary to
  • reduce the tax upon gold to one-twentieth. That the silver mines of
  • Spanish America, like all other mines, become gradually more expensive in
  • the working, on account of the greater depths at which it is necessary to
  • carry on the works, and of the greater expense of drawing out the water,
  • and of supplying them with fresh air at those depths, is acknowledged by
  • everybody who has inquired into the state of those mines.
  • These causes, which are equivalent to a growing scarcity of silver (for a
  • commodity may be said to grow scarcer when it becomes more difficult and
  • expensive to collect a certain quantity of it), must, in time, produce one
  • or other of the three following events: The increase of the expense must
  • either, first, be compensated altogether by a proportionable increase in
  • the price of the metal; or, secondly, it must be compensated altogether by
  • a proportionable diminution of the tax upon silver; or, thirdly, it must
  • be compensated partly by the one and partly by the other of those two
  • expedients. This third event is very possible. As gold rose in its price
  • in proportion to silver, notwithstanding a great diminution of the tax
  • upon gold, so silver might rise in its price in proportion to labour and
  • commodities, notwithstanding an equal diminution of the tax upon silver.
  • Such successive reductions of the tax, however, though they may not
  • prevent altogether, must certainly retard, more or less, the rise of the
  • value of silver in the European market. In consequence of such reductions,
  • many mines may be wrought which could not be wrought before, because they
  • could not afford to pay the old tax; and the quantity of silver annually
  • brought to market, must always be somewhat greater, and, therefore, the
  • value of any given quantity somewhat less, than it otherwise would have
  • been. In consequence of the reduction in 1736, the value of silver in the
  • European market, though it may not at this day be lower than before that
  • reduction, is, probably, at least ten per cent. lower than it would have
  • been, had the court of Spain continued to exact the old tax. That,
  • notwithstanding this reduction, the value of silver has, during the course
  • of the present century, begun to rise somewhat in the European market, the
  • facts and arguments which have been alleged above, dispose me to believe,
  • or more properly to suspect and conjecture; for the best opinion which I
  • can form upon this subject, scarce, perhaps, deserves the name of belief.
  • The rise, indeed, supposing there has been any, has hitherto been so very
  • small, that after all that has been said, it may, perhaps, appear to many
  • people uncertain, not only whether this event has actually taken place,
  • but whether the contrary may not have taken place, or whether the value of
  • silver may not still continue to fall in the European market.
  • It must be observed, however, that whatever may be the supposed annual
  • importation of gold and silver, there must be a certain period at which
  • the annual consumption of those metals will be equal to that annual
  • importation. Their consumption must increase as their mass increases, or
  • rather in a much greater proportion. As their mass increases, their value
  • diminishes. They are more used, and less cared for, and their consumption
  • consequently increases in a greater proportion than their mass. After a
  • certain period, therefore, the annual consumption of those metals must, in
  • this manner, become equal to their annual importation, provided that
  • importation is not continually increasing; which, in the present times, is
  • not supposed to be the case.
  • If, when the annual consumption has become equal to the annual
  • importation, the annual importation should gradually diminish, the annual
  • consumption may, for some time, exceed the annual importation. The mass of
  • those metals may gradually and insensibly diminish, and their value
  • gradually and insensibly rise, till the annual importation becoming again
  • stationary, the annual consumption will gradually and insensibly
  • accommodate itself to what that annual importation can maintain.
  • _Grounds of the suspicion that the Value of Silver still continues to
  • decrease._
  • The increase of the wealth of Europe, and the popular notion, that as the
  • quantity of the precious metals naturally increases with the increase of
  • wealth, so their value diminishes as their quantity increases, may,
  • perhaps, dispose many people to believe that their value still continues
  • to fall in the European market; and the still gradually increasing price
  • of many parts of the rude produce of land may confirm them still farther
  • in this opinion.
  • That that increase in the quantity of the precious metals, which arises in
  • any country from the increase of wealth, has no tendency to diminish their
  • value, I have endeavoured to shew already. Gold and silver naturally
  • resort to a rich country, for the same reason that all sorts of luxuries
  • and curiosities resort to it; not because they are cheaper there than in
  • poorer countries, but because they are dearer, or because a better price
  • is given for them. It is the superiority of price which attracts them; and
  • as soon as that superiority ceases, they necessarily cease to go thither.
  • If you except corn, and such other vegetables as are raised altogether by
  • human industry, that all other sorts of rude produce, cattle, poultry,
  • game of all kinds, the useful fossils and minerals of the earth, etc.
  • naturally grow dearer, as the society advances in wealth and improvement,
  • I have endeavoured to shew already. Though such commodities, therefore,
  • come to exchange for a greater quantity of silver than before, it will not
  • from thence follow that silver has become really cheaper, or will purchase
  • less labour than before; but that such commodities have become really
  • dearer, or will purchase more labour than before. It is not their nominal
  • price only, but their real price, which rises in the progress of
  • improvement. The rise of their nominal price is the effect, not of any
  • degradation of the value of silver, but of the rise in their real price.
  • Different Effects of the Progress of Improvement upon three different
  • sorts of rude Produce.
  • These different sorts of rude produce may be divided into three classes.
  • The first comprehends those which it is scarce in the power of human
  • industry to multiply at all. The second, those which it can multiply in
  • proportion to the demand. The third, those in which the efficacy of
  • industry is either limited or uncertain. In the progress of wealth and
  • improvement, the real price of the first may rise to any degree of
  • extravagance, and seems not to be limited by any certain boundary. That of
  • the second, though it may rise greatly, has, however, a certain boundary,
  • beyond which it cannot well pass for any considerable time together. That
  • of the third, though its natural tendency is to rise in the progress of
  • improvement, yet in the same degree of improvement it may sometimes happen
  • even to fall, sometimes to continue the same, and sometimes to rise more
  • or less, according as different accidents render the efforts of human
  • industry, in multiplying this sort of rude produce, more or less
  • successful.
  • First Sort.—The first sort of rude produce, of which the price rises
  • in the progress of improvement, is that which it is scarce in the power of
  • human industry to multiply at all. It consists in those things which
  • nature produces only in certain quantities, and which being of a very
  • perishable nature, it is impossible to accumulate together the produce of
  • many different seasons. Such are the greater part of rare and singular
  • birds and fishes, many different sorts of game, almost all wild-fowl, all
  • birds of passage in particular, as well as many other things. When wealth,
  • and the luxury which accompanies it, increase, the demand for these is
  • likely to increase with them, and no effort of human industry may be able
  • to increase the supply much beyond what it was before this increase of the
  • demand. The quantity of such commodities, therefore, remaining the same,
  • or nearly the same, while the competition to purchase them is continually
  • increasing, their price may rise to any degree of extravagance, and seems
  • not to be limited by any certain boundary. If woodcocks should become so
  • fashionable as to sell for twenty guineas a-piece, no effort of human
  • industry could increase the number of those brought to market, much beyond
  • what it is at present. The high price paid by the Romans, in the time of
  • their greatest grandeur, for rare birds and fishes, may in this manner
  • easily be accounted for. These prices were not the effects of the low
  • value of silver in those times, but of the high value of such rarities and
  • curiosities as human industry could not multiply at pleasure. The real
  • value of silver was higher at Rome, for sometime before, and after the
  • fall of the republic, than it is through the greater part of Europe at
  • present. Three sestertii equal to about sixpence sterling, was the price
  • which the republic paid for the modius or peck of the tithe wheat of
  • Sicily. This price, however, was probably below the average market price,
  • the obligation to deliver their wheat at this rate being considered as a
  • tax upon the Sicilian farmers. When the Romans, therefore, had occasion to
  • order more corn than the tithe of wheat amounted to, they were bound by
  • capitulation to pay for the surplus at the rate of four sestertii, or
  • eightpence sterling the peck; and this had probably been reckoned the
  • moderate and reasonable, that is, the ordinary or average contract price
  • of those times; it is equal to about one-and-twenty shillings the quarter.
  • Eight-and-twenty shillings the quarter was, before the late years of
  • scarcity, the ordinary contract price of English wheat, which in quality
  • is inferior to the Sicilian, and generally sells for a lower price in the
  • European market. The value of silver, therefore, in those ancient times,
  • must have been to its value in the present, as three to four inversely;
  • that is, three ounces of silver would then have purchased the same
  • quantity of labour and commodities which four ounces will do at present.
  • When we read in Pliny, therefore, that Seius {Lib. X, c. 29.} bought a
  • white nightingale, as a present for the empress Agrippina, at the price of
  • six thousand sestertii, equal to about fifty pounds of our present money;
  • and that Asinius Celer {Lib. IX, c. 17.} purchased a surmullet at the
  • price of eight thousand sestertii, equal to about sixty-six pounds
  • thirteen shillings and fourpence of our present money; the extravagance of
  • those prices, how much soever it may surprise us, is apt, notwithstanding,
  • to appear to us about one third less than it really was. Their real price,
  • the quantity of labour and subsistence which was given away for them, was
  • about one-third more than their nominal price is apt to express to us in
  • the present times. Seius gave for the nightingale the command of a
  • quantity of labour and subsistence, equal to what £ 66:13: 4d. would
  • purchase in the present times; and Asinius Celer gave for a surmullet the
  • command of a quantity equal to what £ 88:17: 9d. would purchase. What
  • occasioned the extravagance of those high prices was, not so much the
  • abundance of silver, as the abundance of labour and subsistence, of which
  • those Romans had the disposal, beyond what was necessary for their own
  • use. The quantity of silver, of which they had the disposal, was a good
  • deal less than what the command of the same quantity of labour and
  • subsistence would have procured to them in the present times.
  • Second sort.—The second sort of rude produce, of which the price
  • rises in the progress of improvement, is that which human industry can
  • multiply in proportion to the demand. It consists in those useful plants
  • and animals, which, in uncultivated countries, nature produces with such
  • profuse abundance, that they are of little or no value, and which, as
  • cultivation advances, are therefore forced to give place to some more
  • profitable produce. During a long period in the progress of improvement,
  • the quantity of these is continually diminishing, while, at the same time,
  • the demand for them is continually increasing. Their real value,
  • therefore, the real quantity of labour which they will purchase or
  • command, gradually rises, till at last it gets so high as to render them
  • as profitable a produce as any thing else which human industry can raise
  • upon the most fertile and best cultivated land. When it has got so high,
  • it cannot well go higher. If it did, more land and more industry would
  • soon be employed to increase their quantity.
  • When the price of cattle, for example, rises so high, that it is as
  • profitable to cultivate land in order to raise food for them as in order
  • to raise food for man, it cannot well go higher. If it did, more corn land
  • would soon be turned into pasture. The extension of tillage, by
  • diminishing the quantity of wild pasture, diminishes the quantity of
  • butcher’s meat, which the country naturally produces without labour or
  • cultivation; and, by increasing the number of those who have either corn,
  • or, what comes to the same thing, the price of corn, to give in exchange
  • for it, increases the demand. The price of butcher’s meat, therefore, and,
  • consequently, of cattle, must gradually rise, till it gets so high, that
  • it becomes as profitable to employ the most fertile and best cultivated
  • lands in raising food for them as in raising corn. But it must always be
  • late in the progress of improvement before tillage can be so far extended
  • as to raise the price of cattle to this height; and, till it has got to
  • this height, if the country is advancing at all, their price must be
  • continually rising. There are, perhaps, some parts of Europe in which the
  • price of cattle has not yet got to this height. It had not got to this
  • height in any part of Scotland before the Union. Had the Scotch cattle
  • been always confined to the market of Scotland, in a country in which the
  • quantity of land, which can be applied to no other purpose but the feeding
  • of cattle, is so great in proportion to what can be applied to other
  • purposes, it is scarce possible, perhaps, that their price could ever have
  • risen so high as to render it profitable to cultivate land for the sake of
  • feeding them. In England, the price of cattle, it has already been
  • observed, seems, in the neighbourhood of London, to have got to this
  • height about the beginning of the last century; but it was much later,
  • probably, before it got through the greater part of the remoter counties,
  • in some of which, perhaps, it may scarce yet have got to it. Of all the
  • different substances, however, which compose this second sort of rude
  • produce, cattle is, perhaps, that of which the price, in the progress of
  • improvement, rises first to this height.
  • Till the price of cattle, indeed, has got to this height, it seems scarce
  • possible that the greater part, even of those lands which are capable of
  • the highest cultivation, can be completely cultivated. In all farms too
  • distant from any town to carry manure from it, that is, in the far greater
  • part of those of every extensive country, the quantity of well cultivated
  • land must be in proportion to the quantity of manure which the farm itself
  • produces; and this, again, must be in proportion to the stock of cattle
  • which are maintained upon it. The land is manured, either by pasturing the
  • cattle upon it, or by feeding them in the stable, and from thence carrying
  • out their dung to it. But unless the price of the cattle be sufficient to
  • pay both the rent and profit of cultivated land, the farmer cannot afford
  • to pasture them upon it; and he can still less afford to feed them in the
  • stable. It is with the produce of improved and cultivated land only that
  • cattle can be fed in the stable; because, to collect the scanty and
  • scattered produce of waste and unimproved lands, would require too much
  • labour, and be too expensive. It the price of the cattle, therefore, is
  • not sufficient to pay for the produce of improved and cultivated land,
  • when they are allowed to pasture it, that price will be still less
  • sufficient to pay for that produce, when it must be collected with a good
  • deal of additional labour, and brought into the stable to them. In these
  • circumstances, therefore, no more cattle can with profit be fed in the
  • stable than what are necessary for tillage. But these can never afford
  • manure enough for keeping constantly in good condition all the lands which
  • they are capable of cultivating. What they afford, being insufficient for
  • the whole farm, will naturally be reserved for the lands to which it can
  • be most advantageously or conveniently applied; the most fertile, or
  • those, perhaps, in the neighbourhood of the farm-yard. These, therefore,
  • will be kept constantly in good condition, and fit for tillage. The rest
  • will, the greater part of them, be allowed to lie waste, producing scarce
  • any thing but some miserable pasture, just sufficient to keep alive a few
  • straggling, half-starved cattle; the farm, though much overstocked in
  • proportion to what would be necessary for its complete cultivation, being
  • very frequently overstocked in proportion to its actual produce. A portion
  • of this waste land, however, after having been pastured in this wretched
  • manner for six or seven years together, may be ploughed up, when it will
  • yield, perhaps, a poor crop or two of bad oats, or of some other coarse
  • grain; and then, being entirely exhausted, it must be rested and pastured
  • again as before, and another portion ploughed up, to be in the same manner
  • exhausted and rested again in its turn. Such, accordingly, was the general
  • system of management all over the low country of Scotland before the
  • Union. The lands which were kept constantly well manured and in good
  • condition seldom exceeded a third or fourth part of the whole farm, and
  • sometimes did not amount to a fifth or a sixth part of it. The rest were
  • never manured, but a certain portion of them was in its turn,
  • notwithstanding, regularly cultivated and exhausted. Under this system of
  • management, it is evident, even that part of the lands of Scotland which
  • is capable of good cultivation, could produce but little in comparison of
  • what it may be capable of producing. But how disadvantageous soever this
  • system may appear, yet, before the Union, the low price of cattle seems to
  • have rendered it almost unavoidable. If, notwithstanding a great rise in
  • the price, it still continues to prevail through a considerable part of
  • the country, it is owing in many places, no doubt, to ignorance and
  • attachment to old customs, but, in most places, to the unavoidable
  • obstructions which the natural course of things opposes to the immediate
  • or speedy establishment of a better system: first, to the poverty of the
  • tenants, to their not having yet had time to acquire a stock of cattle
  • sufficient to cultivate their lands more completely, the same rise of
  • price, which would render it advantageous for them to maintain a greater
  • stock, rendering it more difficult for them to acquire it; and, secondly,
  • to their not having yet had time to put their lands in condition to
  • maintain this greater stock properly, supposing they were capable of
  • acquiring it. The increase of stock and the improvement of land are two
  • events which must go hand in hand, and of which the one can nowhere much
  • outrun the other. Without some increase of stock, there can be scarce any
  • improvement of land, but there can be no considerable increase of stock,
  • but in consequence of a considerable improvement of land; because
  • otherwise the land could not maintain it. These natural obstructions to
  • the establishment of a better system, cannot be removed but by a long
  • course of frugality and industry; and half a century or a century more,
  • perhaps, must pass away before the old system, which is wearing out
  • gradually, can be completely abolished through all the different parts of
  • the country. Of all the commercial advantages, however, which Scotland has
  • derived from the Union with England, this rise in the price of cattle is,
  • perhaps, the greatest. It has not only raised the value of all highland
  • estates, but it has, perhaps, been the principal cause of the improvement
  • of the low country.
  • In all new colonies, the great quantity of waste land, which can for many
  • years be applied to no other purpose but the feeding of cattle, soon
  • renders them extremely abundant; and in every thing great cheapness is the
  • necessary consequence of great abundance. Though all the cattle of the
  • European colonies in America were originally carried from Europe, they
  • soon multiplied so much there, and became of so little value, that even
  • horses were allowed to run wild in the woods, without any owner thinking
  • it worth while to claim them. It must be a long time after the first
  • establishment of such colonies, before it can become profitable to feed
  • cattle upon the produce of cultivated land. The same causes, therefore,
  • the want of manure, and the disproportion between the stock employed in
  • cultivation and the land which it is destined to cultivate, are likely to
  • introduce there a system of husbandry, not unlike that which still
  • continues to take place in so many parts of Scotland. Mr Kalm, the Swedish
  • traveller, when he gives an account of the husbandry of some of the
  • English colonies in North America, as he found it in 1749, observes,
  • accordingly, that he can with difficulty discover there the character of
  • the English nation, so well skilled in all the different branches of
  • agriculture. They make scarce any manure for their corn fields, he says;
  • but when one piece of ground has been exhausted by continual cropping,
  • they clear and cultivate another piece of fresh land; and when that is
  • exhausted, proceed to a third. Their cattle are allowed to wander through
  • the woods and other uncultivated grounds, where they are half-starved;
  • having long ago extirpated almost all the annual grasses, by cropping them
  • too early in the spring, before they had time to form their flowers, or to
  • shed their seeds. {Kalm’s Travels, vol 1, pp. 343, 344.} The annual
  • grasses were, it seems, the best natural grasses in that part of North
  • America; and when the Europeans first settled there, they used to grow
  • very thick, and to rise three or four feet high. A piece of ground which,
  • when he wrote, could not maintain one cow, would in former times, he was
  • assured, have maintained four, each of which would have given four times
  • the quantity of milk which that one was capable of giving. The poorness of
  • the pasture had, in his opinion, occasioned the degradation of their
  • cattle, which degenerated sensibly from me generation to another. They
  • were probably not unlike that stunted breed which was common all over
  • Scotland thirty or forty years ago, and which is now so much mended
  • through the greater part of the low country, not so much by a change of
  • the breed, though that expedient has been employed in some places, as by a
  • more plentiful method of feeding them.
  • Though it is late, therefore, in the progress of improvement, before
  • cattle can bring such a price as to render it profitable to cultivate land
  • for the sake of feeding them; yet of all the different parts which compose
  • this second sort of rude produce, they are perhaps the first which bring
  • this price; because, till they bring it, it seems impossible that
  • improvement can be brought near even to that degree of perfection to which
  • it has arrived in many parts of Europe.
  • As cattle are among the first, so perhaps venison is among the last parts
  • of this sort of rude produce which bring this price. The price of venison
  • in Great Britain, how extravagant soever it may appear, is not near
  • sufficient to compensate the expense of a deer park, as is well known to
  • all those who have had any experience in the feeding of deer. If it was
  • otherwise, the feeding of deer would soon become an article of common
  • farming, in the same manner as the feeding of those small birds, called
  • turdi, was among the ancient Romans. Varro and Columella assure us, that
  • it was a most profitable article. The fattening of ortolans, birds of
  • passage which arrive lean in the country, is said to be so in some parts
  • of France. If venison continues in fashion, and the wealth and luxury of
  • Great Britain increase as they have done for some time past, its price may
  • very probably rise still higher than it is at present.
  • Between that period in the progress of improvement, which brings to its
  • height the price of so necessary an article as cattle, and that which
  • brings to it the price of such a superfluity as venison, there is a very
  • long interval, in the course of which many other sorts of rude produce
  • gradually arrive at their highest price, some sooner and some later,
  • according to different circumstances.
  • Thus, in every farm, the offals of the barn and stable will maintain a
  • certain number of poultry. These, as they are fed with what would
  • otherwise be lost, are a mere save-all; and as they cost the farmer scarce
  • any thing, so he can afford to sell them for very little. Almost all that
  • he gets is pure gain, and their price can scarce be so low as to
  • discourage him from feeding this number. But in countries ill cultivated,
  • and therefore but thinly inhabited, the poultry, which are thus raised
  • without expense, are often fully sufficient to supply the whole demand. In
  • this state of things, therefore, they are often as cheap as butcher’s
  • meat, or any other sort of animal food. But the whole quantity of poultry
  • which the farm in this manner produces without expense, must always be
  • much smaller than the whole quantity of butcher’s meat which is reared
  • upon it; and in times of wealth and luxury, what is rare, with only nearly
  • equal merit, is always preferred to what is common. As wealth and luxury
  • increase, therefore, in consequence of improvement and cultivation, the
  • price of poultry gradually rises above that of butcher’s meat, till at
  • last it gets so high, that it becomes profitable to cultivate land for the
  • sake of feeding them. When it has got to this height, it cannot well go
  • higher. If it did, more land would soon be turned to this purpose. In
  • several provinces of France, the feeding of poultry is considered as a
  • very important article in rural economy, and sufficiently profitable to
  • encourage the farmer to raise a considerable quantity of Indian corn and
  • buckwheat for this purpose. A middling farmer will there sometimes have
  • four hundred fowls in his yard. The feeding of poultry seems scarce yet to
  • be generally considered as a matter of so much importance in England. They
  • are certainly, however, dearer in England than in France, as England
  • receives considerable supplies from France. In the progress of
  • improvements, the period at which every particular sort of animal food is
  • dearest, must naturally be that which immediately precedes the general
  • practice of cultivating land for the sake of raising it. For some time
  • before this practice becomes general, the scarcity must necessarily raise
  • the price. After it has become general, new methods of feeding are
  • commonly fallen upon, which enable the farmer to raise upon the same
  • quantity of ground a much greater quantity of that particular sort of
  • animal food. The plenty not only obliges him to sell cheaper, but, in
  • consequence of these improvements, he can afford to sell cheaper; for if
  • he could not afford it, the plenty would not be of long continuance. It
  • has been probably in this manner that the introduction of clover, turnips,
  • carrots, cabbages, etc. has contributed to sink the common price of
  • butcher’s meat in the London market, somewhat below what it was about the
  • beginning of the last century.
  • The hog, that finds his food among ordure, and greedily devours many
  • things rejected by every other useful animal, is, like poultry, originally
  • kept as a save-all. As long as the number of such animals, which can thus
  • be reared at little or no expense, is fully sufficient to supply the
  • demand, this sort of butcher’s meat comes to market at a much lower price
  • than any other. But when the demand rises beyond what this quantity can
  • supply, when it becomes necessary to raise food on purpose for feeding and
  • fattening hogs, in the same manner as for feeding and fattening other
  • cattle, the price necessarily rises, and becomes proportionably either
  • higher or lower than that of other butcher’s meat, according as the nature
  • of the country, and the state of its agriculture, happen to render the
  • feeding of hogs more or less expensive than that of other cattle. In
  • France, according to Mr Buffon, the price of pork is nearly equal to that
  • of beef. In most parts of Great Britain it is at present somewhat higher.
  • The great rise in the price both of hogs and poultry, has, in Great
  • Britain, been frequently imputed to the diminution of the number of
  • cottagers and other small occupiers of land; an event which has in every
  • part of Europe been the immediate forerunner of improvement and better
  • cultivation, but which at the same time may have contributed to raise the
  • price of those articles, both somewhat sooner and somewhat faster than it
  • would otherwise have risen. As the poorest family can often maintain a cat
  • or a dog without any expense, so the poorest occupiers of land can
  • commonly maintain a few poultry, or a sow and a few pigs, at very little.
  • The little offals of their own table, their whey, skimmed milk, and butter
  • milk, supply those animals with a part of their food, and they find the
  • rest in the neighbouring fields, without doing any sensible damage to any
  • body. By diminishing the number of those small occupiers, therefore, the
  • quantity of this sort of provisions, which is thus produced at little or
  • no expense, must certainly have been a good deal diminished, and their
  • price must consequently have been raised both sooner and faster than it
  • would otherwise have risen. Sooner or later, however, in the progress of
  • improvement, it must at any rate have risen to the utmost height to which
  • it is capable of rising; or to the price which pays the labour and expense
  • of cultivating the land which furnishes them with food, as well as these
  • are paid upon the greater part of other cultivated land.
  • The business of the dairy, like the feeding of hogs and poultry, is
  • originally carried on as a save-all. The cattle necessarily kept upon the
  • farm produce more milk than either the rearing of their own young, or the
  • consumption of the farmer’s family requires; and they produce most at one
  • particular season. But of all the productions of land, milk is perhaps the
  • most perishable. In the warm season, when it is most abundant, it will
  • scarce keep four-and-twenty hours. The farmer, by making it into fresh
  • butter, stores a small part of it for a week; by making it into salt
  • butter, for a year; and by making it into cheese, he stores a much greater
  • part of it for several years. Part of all these is reserved for the use of
  • his own family; the rest goes to market, in order to find the best price
  • which is to be had, and which can scarce be so low is to discourage him
  • from sending thither whatever is over and above the use of his own family.
  • If it is very low indeed, he will be likely to manage his dairy in a very
  • slovenly and dirty manner, and will scarce, perhaps, think it worth while
  • to have a particular room or building on purpose for it, but will suffer
  • the business to be carried on amidst the smoke, filth, and nastiness of
  • his own kitchen, as was the case of almost all the farmers’ dairies in
  • Scotland thirty or forty years ago, and as is the case of many of them
  • still. The same causes which gradually raise the price of butcher’s meat,
  • the increase of the demand, and, in consequence of the improvement of the
  • country, the diminution of the quantity which can be fed at little or no
  • expense, raise, in the same manner, that of the produce of the dairy, of
  • which the price naturally connects with that of butcher’s meat, or with
  • the expense of feeding cattle. The increase of price pays for more labour,
  • care, and cleanliness. The dairy becomes more worthy of the farmer’s
  • attention, and the quality of its produce gradually improves. The price at
  • last gets so high, that it becomes worth while to employ some of the most
  • fertile and best cultivated lands in feeding cattle merely for the purpose
  • of the dairy; and when it has got to this height, it cannot well go
  • higher. If it did, more land would soon be turned to this purpose. It
  • seems to have got to this height through the greater part of England,
  • where much good land is commonly employed in this manner. If you except
  • the neighbourhood of a few considerable towns, it seems not yet to have
  • got to this height anywhere in Scotland, where common farmers seldom
  • employ much good land in raising food for cattle, merely for the purpose
  • of the dairy. The price of the produce, though it has risen very
  • considerably within these few years, is probably still too low to admit of
  • it. The inferiority of the quality, indeed, compared with that of the
  • produce of English dairies, is fully equal to that of the price. But this
  • inferiority of quality is, perhaps, rather the effect of this lowness of
  • price, than the cause of it. Though the quality was much better, the
  • greater part of what is brought to market could not, I apprehend, in the
  • present circumstances of the country, be disposed of at a much better
  • price; and the present price, it is probable, would not pay the expense of
  • the land and labour necessary for producing a much better quality. Through
  • the greater part of England, notwithstanding the superiority of price, the
  • dairy is not reckoned a more profitable employment of land than the
  • raising of corn, or the fattening of cattle, the two great objects of
  • agriculture. Through the greater part of Scotland, therefore, it cannot
  • yet be even so profitable.
  • The lands of no country, it is evident, can ever be completely cultivated
  • and improved, till once the price of every produce, which human industry
  • is obliged to raise upon them, has got so high as to pay for the expense
  • of complete improvement and cultivation. In order to do this, the price of
  • each particular produce must be sufficient, first, to pay the rent of good
  • corn land, as it is that which regulates the rent of the greater part of
  • other cultivated land; and, secondly, to pay the labour and expense of the
  • farmer, as well as they are commonly paid upon good corn land; or, in
  • other words, to replace with the ordinary profits the stock which he
  • employs about it. This rise in the price of each particular produce; must
  • evidently be previous to the improvement and cultivation of the land which
  • is destined for raising it. Gain is the end of all improvement; and
  • nothing could deserve that name, of which loss was to be the necessary
  • consequence. But loss must be the necessary consequence of improving land
  • for the sake of a produce of which the price could never bring back the
  • expense. If the complete improvement and cultivation of the country be, as
  • it most certainly is, the greatest of all public advantages, this rise in
  • the price of all those different sorts of rude produce, instead of being
  • considered as a public calamity, ought to be regarded as the necessary
  • forerunner and attendant of the greatest of all public advantages.
  • This rise, too, in the nominal or money price of all those different sorts
  • of rude produce, has been the effect, not of any degradation in the value
  • of silver, but of a rise in their real price. They have become worth, not
  • only a greater quantity of silver, but a greater quantity of labour and
  • subsistence than before. As it costs a greater quantity of labour and
  • subsistence to bring them to market, so, when they are brought thither
  • they represent, or are equivalent to a greater quantity.
  • Third Sort.—The third and last sort of rude produce, of which the
  • price naturally rises in the progress of improvement, is that in which the
  • efficacy of human industry, in augmenting the quantity, is either limited
  • or uncertain. Though the real price of this sort of rude produce,
  • therefore, naturally tends to rise in the progress of improvement, yet,
  • according as different accidents happen to render the efforts of human
  • industry more or less successful in augmenting the quantity, it may happen
  • sometimes even to fall, sometimes to continue the same, in very different
  • periods of improvement, and sometimes to rise more or less in the same
  • period.
  • There are some sorts of rude produce which nature has rendered a kind of
  • appendages to other sorts; so that the quantity of the one which any
  • country can afford, is necessarily limited by that of the other. The
  • quantity of wool or of raw hides, for example, which any country can
  • afford, is necessarily limited by the number of great and small cattle
  • that are kept in it. The state of its improvement, and the nature of its
  • agriculture, again necessarily determine this number.
  • The same causes which, in the progress of improvement, gradually raise the
  • price of butcher’s meat, should have the same effect, it may be thought,
  • upon the prices of wool and raw hides, and raise them, too, nearly in the
  • same proportion. It probably would be so, if, in the rude beginnings of
  • improvement, the market for the latter commodities was confined within as
  • narrow bounds as that for the former. But the extent of their respective
  • markets is commonly extremely different.
  • The market for butcher’s meat is almost everywhere confined to the country
  • which produces it. Ireland, and some part of British America, indeed,
  • carry on a considerable trade in salt provisions; but they are, I believe,
  • the only countries in the commercial world which do so, or which export to
  • other countries any considerable part of their butcher’s meat.
  • The market for wool and raw hides, on the contrary, is, in the rude
  • beginnings of improvement, very seldom confined to the country which
  • produces them. They can easily be transported to distant countries; wool
  • without any preparation, and raw hides with very little; and as they are
  • the materials of many manufactures, the industry of other countries may
  • occasion a demand for them, though that of the country which produces them
  • might not occasion any.
  • In countries ill cultivated, and therefore but thinly inhabited, the price
  • of the wool and the hide bears always a much greater proportion to that of
  • the whole beast, than in countries where, improvement and population being
  • further advanced, there is more demand for butcher’s meat. Mr Hume
  • observes, that in the Saxon times, the fleece was estimated at two-fifths
  • of the value of the whole sheep and that this was much above the
  • proportion of its present estimation. In some provinces of Spain, I have
  • been assured, the sheep is frequently killed merely for the sake of the
  • fleece and the tallow. The carcase is often left to rot upon the ground,
  • or to be devoured by beasts and birds of prey. If this sometimes happens
  • even in Spain, it happens almost constantly in Chili, at Buenos Ayres, and
  • in many other parts of Spanish America, where the horned cattle are almost
  • constantly killed merely for the sake of the hide and the tallow. This,
  • too, used to happen almost constantly in Hispaniola, while it was infested
  • by the buccaneers, and before the settlement, improvement, and
  • populousness of the French plantations ( which now extend round the coast
  • of almost the whole western half of the island) had given some value to
  • the cattle of the Spaniards, who still continue to possess, not only the
  • eastern part of the coast, but the whole inland mountainous part of the
  • country.
  • Though, in the progress of improvement and population, the price of the
  • whole beast necessarily rises, yet the price of the carcase is likely to
  • be much more affected by this rise than that of the wool and the hide. The
  • market for the carcase being in the rude state of society confined always
  • to the country which produces it, must necessarily be extended in
  • proportion to the improvement and population of that country. But the
  • market for the wool and the hides, even of a barbarous country, often
  • extending to the whole commercial world, it can very seldom be enlarged in
  • the same proportion. The state of the whole commercial world can seldom be
  • much affected by the improvement of any particular country; and the market
  • for such commodities may remain the same, or very nearly the same, after
  • such improvements, as before. It should, however, in the natural course of
  • things, rather, upon the whole, be somewhat extended in consequence of
  • them. If the manufactures, especially, of which those commodities are the
  • materials, should ever come to flourish in the country, the market, though
  • it might not be much enlarged, would at least be brought much nearer to
  • the place of growth than before; and the price of those materials might at
  • least be increased by what had usually been the expense of transporting
  • them to distant countries. Though it might not rise, therefore, in the
  • same proportion as that of butcher’s meat, it ought naturally to rise
  • somewhat, and it ought certainly not to fall.
  • In England, however, notwithstanding the flourishing state of its woollen
  • manufacture, the price of English wool has fallen very considerably since
  • the time of Edward III. There are many authentic records which demonstrate
  • that, during the reign of that prince (towards the middle of the
  • fourteenth century, or about 1339), what was reckoned the moderate and
  • reasonable price of the tod, or twenty-eight pounds of English wool, was
  • not less than ten shillings of the money of those times {See Smith’s
  • Memoirs of Wool, vol. i c. 5, 6, 7. also vol. ii.}, containing, at the
  • rate of twenty-pence the ounce, six ounces of silver, Tower weight, equal
  • to about thirty shillings of our present money. In the present times,
  • one-and-twenty shillings the tod may be reckoned a good price for very
  • good English wool. The money price of wool, therefore, in the time of
  • Edward III. was to its money price in the present times as ten to seven.
  • The superiority of its real price was still greater. At the rate of six
  • shillings and eightpence the quarter, ten shillings was in those ancient
  • times the price of twelve bushels of wheat. At the rate of twenty-eight
  • shillings the quarter, one-and-twenty shillings is in the present times
  • the price of six bushels only. The proportion between the real price of
  • ancient and modern times, therefore, is as twelve to six, or as two to
  • one. In those ancient times, a tod of wool would have purchased twice the
  • quantity of subsistence which it will purchase at present, and
  • consequently twice the quantity of labour, if the real recompence of
  • labour had been the same in both periods.
  • This degradation, both in the real and nominal value of wool, could never
  • have happened in consequence of the natural course of things. It has
  • accordingly been the effect of violence and artifice. First, of the
  • absolute prohibition of exporting wool from England: secondly, of the
  • permission of importing it from Spain, duty free: thirdly, of the
  • prohibition of exporting it from Ireland to another country but England.
  • In consequence of these regulations, the market for English wool, instead
  • of being somewhat extended, in consequence of the improvement of England,
  • has been confined to the home market, where the wool of several other
  • countries is allowed to come into competition with it, and where that of
  • Ireland is forced into competition with it. As the woollen manufactures,
  • too, of Ireland, are fully as much discouraged as is consistent with
  • justice and fair dealing, the Irish can work up but a smaller part of
  • their own wool at home, and are therefore obliged to send a greater
  • proportion of it to Great Britain, the only market they are allowed.
  • I have not been able to find any such authentic records concerning the
  • price of raw hides in ancient times. Wool was commonly paid as a subsidy
  • to the king, and its valuation in that subsidy ascertains, at least in
  • some degree, what was its ordinary price. But this seems not to have been
  • the case with raw hides. Fleetwood, however, from an account in 1425,
  • between the prior of Burcester Oxford and one of his canons, gives us
  • their price, at least as it was stated upon that particular occasion, viz.
  • five ox hides at twelve shillings; five cow hides at seven shillings and
  • threepence; thirtysix sheep skins of two years old at nine shillings;
  • sixteen calf skins at two shillings. In 1425, twelve shillings contained
  • about the same quantity of silver as four-and-twenty shillings of our
  • present money. An ox hide, therefore, was in this account valued at the
  • same quantity of silver as 4s. 4/5ths of our present money. Its nominal
  • price was a good deal lower than at present. But at the rate of six
  • shillings and eightpence the quarter, twelve shillings would in those
  • times have purchased fourteen bushels and four-fifths of a bushel of
  • wheat, which, at three and sixpence the bushel, would in the present times
  • cost 51s. 4d. An ox hide, therefore, would in those times have purchased
  • as much corn as ten shillings and threepence would purchase at present.
  • Its real value was equal to ten shillings and threepence of our present
  • money. In those ancient times, when the cattle were half starved during
  • the greater part of the winter, we cannot suppose that they were of a very
  • large size. An ox hide which weighs four stone of sixteen pounds of
  • avoirdupois, is not in the present times reckoned a bad one; and in those
  • ancient times would probably have been reckoned a very good one. But at
  • half-a-crown the stone, which at this moment (February 1773) I understand
  • to be the common price, such a hide would at present cost only ten
  • shillings. Through its nominal price, therefore, is higher in the present
  • than it was in those ancient times, its real price, the real quantity of
  • subsistence which it will purchase or command, is rather somewhat lower.
  • The price of cow hides, as stated in the above account, is nearly in the
  • common proportion to that of ox hides. That of sheep skins is a good deal
  • above it. They had probably been sold with the wool. That of calves skins,
  • on the contrary, is greatly below it. In countries where the price of
  • cattle is very low, the calves, which are not intended to be reared in
  • order to keep up the stock, are generally killed very young, as was the
  • case in Scotland twenty or thirty years ago. It saves the milk, which
  • their price would not pay for. Their skins, therefore, are commonly good
  • for little.
  • The price of raw hides is a good deal lower at present than it was a few
  • years ago; owing probably to the taking off the duty upon seal skins, and
  • to the allowing, for a limited time, the importation of raw hides from
  • Ireland, and from the plantations, duty free, which was done in 1769. Take
  • the whole of the present century at an average, their real price has
  • probably been somewhat higher than it was in those ancient times. The
  • nature of the commodity renders it not quite so proper for being
  • transported to distant markets as wool. It suffers more by keeping. A
  • salted hide is reckoned inferior to a fresh one, and sells for a lower
  • price. This circumstance must necessarily have some tendency to sink the
  • price of raw hides produced in a country which does not manufacture them,
  • but is obliged to export them, and comparatively to raise that of those
  • produced in a country which does manufacture them. It must have some
  • tendency to sink their price in a barbarous, and to raise it in an
  • improved and manufacturing country. It must have had some tendency,
  • therefore, to sink it in ancient, and to raise it in modern times. Our
  • tanners, besides, have not been quite so successful as our clothiers, in
  • convincing the wisdom of the nation, that the safety of the commonwealth
  • depends upon the prosperity of their particular manufacture. They have
  • accordingly been much less favoured. The exportation of raw hides has,
  • indeed, been prohibited, and declared a nuisance; but their importation
  • from foreign countries has been subjected to a duty; and though this duty
  • has been taken off from those of Ireland and the plantations (for the
  • limited time of five years only), yet Ireland has not been confined to the
  • market of Great Britain for the sale of its surplus hides, or of those
  • which are not manufactured at home. The hides of common cattle have, but
  • within these few years, been put among the enumerated commodities which
  • the plantations can send nowhere but to the mother country; neither has
  • the commerce of Ireland been in this case oppressed hitherto, in order to
  • support the manufactures of Great Britain.
  • Whatever regulations tend to sink the price, either of wool or of raw
  • hides, below what it naturally would he, must, in an improved and
  • cultivated country, have some tendency to raise the price of butcher’s
  • meat. The price both of the great and small cattle, which are fed on
  • improved and cultivated land, must be sufficient to pay the rent which the
  • landlord, and the profit which the farmer, has reason to expect from
  • improved and cultivated land. If it is not, they will soon cease to feed
  • them. Whatever part of this price, therefore, is not paid by the wool and
  • the hide, must be paid by the carcase. The less there is paid for the one,
  • the more must be paid for the other. In what manner this price is to be
  • divided upon the different parts of the beast, is indifferent to the
  • landlords and farmers, provided it is all paid to them. In an improved and
  • cultivated country, therefore, their interest as landlords and farmers
  • cannot be much affected by such regulations, though their interest as
  • consumers may, by the rise in the price of provisions. It would be quite
  • otherwise, however, in an unimproved and uncultivated country, where the
  • greater part of the lands could be applied to no other purpose but the
  • feeding of cattle, and where the wool and the hide made the principal part
  • of the value of those cattle. Their interest as landlords and farmers
  • would in this case be very deeply affected by such regulations, and their
  • interest as consumers very little. The fall in the price of the wool and
  • the hide would not in this case raise the price of the carcase; because
  • the greater part of the lands of the country being applicable to no other
  • purpose but the feeding of cattle, the same number would still continue to
  • be fed. The same quantity of butcher’s meat would still come to market.
  • The demand for it would be no greater than before. Its price, therefore,
  • would be the same as before. The whole price of cattle would fall, and
  • along with it both the rent and the profit of all those lands of which
  • cattle was the principal produce, that is, of the greater part of the
  • lands of the country. The perpetual prohibition of the exportation of
  • wool, which is commonly, but very falsely, ascribed to Edward III., would,
  • in the then circumstances of the country, have been the most destructive
  • regulation which could well have been thought of. It would not only have
  • reduced the actual value of the greater part of the lands in the kingdom,
  • but by reducing the price of the most important species of small cattle,
  • it would have retarded very much its subsequent improvement.
  • The wool of Scotland fell very considerably in its price in consequence of
  • the union with England, by which it was excluded from the great market of
  • Europe, and confined to the narrow one of Great Britain. The value of the
  • greater part of the lands in the southern counties of Scotland, which are
  • chiefly a sheep country, would have been very deeply affected by this
  • event, had not the rise in the price of butcher’s meat fully compensated
  • the fall in the price of wool.
  • As the efficacy of human industry, in increasing the quantity either of
  • wool or of raw hides, is limited, so far as it depends upon the produce of
  • the country where it is exerted; so it is uncertain so far as it depends
  • upon the produce of other countries. It so far depends not so much upon
  • the quantity which they produce, as upon that which they do not
  • manufacture; and upon the restraints which they may or may not think
  • proper to impose upon the exportation of this sort of rude produce. These
  • circumstances, as they are altogether independent of domestic industry, so
  • they necessarily render the efficacy of its efforts more or less
  • uncertain. In multiplying this sort of rude produce, therefore, the
  • efficacy of human industry is not only limited, but uncertain.
  • In multiplying another very important sort of rude produce, the quantity
  • of fish that is brought to market, it is likewise both limited and
  • uncertain. It is limited by the local situation of the country, by the
  • proximity or distance of its different provinces from the sea, by the
  • number of its lakes and rivers, and by what may be called the fertility or
  • barrenness of those seas, lakes, and rivers, as to this sort of rude
  • produce. As population increases, as the annual produce of the land and
  • labour of the country grows greater and greater, there come to be more
  • buyers of fish; and those buyers, too, have a greater quantity and variety
  • of other goods, or, what is the same thing, the price of a greater
  • quantity and variety of other goods, to buy with. But it will generally be
  • impossible to supply the great and extended market, without employing a
  • quantity of labour greater than in proportion to what had been requisite
  • for supplying the narrow and confined one. A market which, from requiring
  • only one thousand, comes to require annually ten thousand ton of fish, can
  • seldom be supplied, without employing more than ten times the quantity of
  • labour which had before been sufficient to supply it. The fish must
  • generally be sought for at a greater distance, larger vessels must be
  • employed, and more expensive machinery of every kind made use of. The real
  • price of this commodity, therefore, naturally rises in the progress of
  • improvement. It has accordingly done so, I believe, more or less in every
  • country.
  • Though the success of a particular day’s fishing maybe a very uncertain
  • matter, yet the local situation of the country being supposed, the general
  • efficacy of industry in bringing a certain quantity of fish to market,
  • taking the course of a year, or of several years together, it may,
  • perhaps, be thought is certain enough; and it, no doubt, is so. As it
  • depends more, however, upon the local situation of the country, than upon
  • the state of its wealth and industry; as upon this account it may in
  • different countries be the same in very different periods of improvement,
  • and very different in the same period; its connection with the state of
  • improvement is uncertain; and it is of this sort of uncertainty that I am
  • here speaking.
  • In increasing the quantity of the different minerals and metals which are
  • drawn from the bowels of the earth, that of the more precious ones
  • particularly, the efficacy of human industry seems not to be limited, but
  • to be altogether uncertain.
  • The quantity of the precious metals which is to be found in any country,
  • is not limited by any thing in its local situation, such as the fertility
  • or barrenness of its own mines. Those metals frequently abound in
  • countries which possess no mines. Their quantity, in every particular
  • country, seems to depend upon two different circumstances; first, upon its
  • power of purchasing, upon the state of its industry, upon the annual
  • produce of its land and labour, in consequence of which it can afford to
  • employ a greater or a smaller quantity of labour and subsistence, in
  • bringing or purchasing such superfluities as gold and silver, either from
  • its own mines, or from those of other countries; and, secondly, upon the
  • fertility or barrenness of the mines which may happen at any particular
  • time to supply the commercial world with those metals. The quantity of
  • those metals in the countries most remote from the mines, must be more or
  • less affected by this fertility or barrenness, on account of the easy and
  • cheap transportation of those metals, of their small bulk and great value.
  • Their quantity in China and Indostan must have been more or less affected
  • by the abundance of the mines of America.
  • So far as their quantity in any particular country depends upon the former
  • of those two circumstances (the power of purchasing), their real price,
  • like that of all other luxuries and superfluities, is likely to rise with
  • the wealth and improvement of the country, and to fall with its poverty
  • and depression. Countries which have a great quantity of labour and
  • subsistence to spare, can afford to purchase any particular quantity of
  • those metals at the expense of a greater quantity of labour and
  • subsistence, than countries which have less to spare.
  • So far as their quantity in any particular country depends upon the latter
  • of those two circumstances (the fertility or barrenness of the mines which
  • happen to supply the commercial world), their real price, the real
  • quantity of labour and subsistence which they will purchase or exchange
  • for, will, no doubt, sink more or less in proportion to the fertility, and
  • rise in proportion to the barrenness of those mines.
  • The fertility or barrenness of the mines, however, which may happen at any
  • particular time to supply the commercial world, is a circumstance which,
  • it is evident, may have no sort of connection with the state of industry
  • in a particular country. It seems even to have no very necessary
  • connection with that of the world in general. As arts and commerce,
  • indeed, gradually spread themselves over a greater and a greater part of
  • the earth, the search for new mines, being extended over a wider surface,
  • may have somewhat a better chance for being successful than when confined
  • within narrower bounds. The discovery of new mines, however, as the old
  • ones come to be gradually exhausted, is a matter of the greatest
  • uncertainty, and such as no human skill or industry can insure. All
  • indications, it is acknowledged, are doubtful; and the actual discovery
  • and successful working of a new mine can alone ascertain the reality of
  • its value, or even of its existence. In this search there seem to be no
  • certain limits, either to the possible success, or to the possible
  • disappointment of human industry. In the course of a century or two, it is
  • possible that new mines may be discovered, more fertile than any that have
  • ever yet been known; and it is just equally possible, that the most
  • fertile mine then known may be more barren than any that was wrought
  • before the discovery of the mines of America. Whether the one or the other
  • of those two events may happen to take place, is of very little importance
  • to the real wealth and prosperity of the world, to the real value of the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of mankind. Its nominal value, the
  • quantity of gold and silver by which this annual produce could be
  • expressed or represented, would, no doubt, be very different; but its real
  • value, the real quantity of labour which it could purchase or command,
  • would be precisely the same. A shilling might, in the one case, represent
  • no more labour than a penny does at present; and a penny, in the other,
  • might represent as much as a shilling does now. But in the one case, he
  • who had a shilling in his pocket would be no richer than he who has a
  • penny at present; and in the other, he who had a penny would be just as
  • rich as he who has a shilling now. The cheapness and abundance of gold and
  • silver plate would be the sole advantage which the world could derive from
  • the one event; and the dearness and scarcity of those trifling
  • superfluities, the only inconveniency it could suffer from the other.
  • Conclusion of the Digression concerning the Variations in the Value of
  • Silver.
  • The greater part of the writers who have collected the money price of
  • things in ancient times, seem to have considered the low money price of
  • corn, and of goods in general, or, in other words, the high value of gold
  • and silver, as a proof, not only of the scarcity of those metals, but of
  • the poverty and barbarism of the country at the time when it took place.
  • This notion is connected with the system of political economy, which
  • represents national wealth as consisting in the abundance and national
  • poverty in the scarcity, of gold and silver; a system which I shall
  • endeavour to explain and examine at great length in the fourth book of
  • this Inquiry. I shall only observe at present, that the high value of the
  • precious metals can be no proof of the poverty or barbarism of any
  • particular country at the time when it took place. It is a proof only of
  • the barrenness of the mines which happened at that time to supply the
  • commercial world. A poor country, as it cannot afford to buy more, so it
  • can as little afford to pay dearer for gold and silver than a rich one;
  • and the value of those metals, therefore, is not likely to be higher in
  • the former than in the latter. In China, a country much richer than any
  • part of Europe, the value of the precious metals is much higher than in
  • any part of Europe. As the wealth of Europe, indeed, has increased greatly
  • since the discovery of the mines of America, so the value of gold and
  • silver has gradually diminished. This diminution of their value, however,
  • has not been owing to the increase of the real wealth of Europe, of the
  • annual produce of its land and labour, but to the accidental discovery of
  • more abundant mines than any that were known before. The increase of the
  • quantity of gold and silver in Europe, and the increase of its
  • manufactures and agriculture, are two events which, though they have
  • happened nearly about the same time, yet have arisen from very different
  • causes, and have scarce any natural connection with one another. The one
  • has arisen from a mere accident, in which neither prudence nor policy
  • either had or could have any share; the other, from the fall of the feudal
  • system, and from the establishment of a government which afforded to
  • industry the only encouragement which it requires, some tolerable security
  • that it shall enjoy the fruits of its own labour. Poland, where the feudal
  • system still continues to take place, is at this day as beggarly a country
  • as it was before the discovery of America. The money price of corn,
  • however, has risen; the real value of the precious metals has fallen in
  • Poland, in the same manner as in other parts of Europe. Their quantity,
  • therefore, must have increased there as in other places, and nearly in the
  • same proportion to the annual produce of its land and labour. This
  • increase of the quantity of those metals, however, has not, it seems,
  • increased that annual produce, has neither improved the manufactures and
  • agriculture of the country, nor mended the circumstances of its
  • inhabitants. Spain and Portugal, the countries which possess the mines,
  • are, after Poland, perhaps the two most beggarly countries in Europe. The
  • value of the precious metals, however, must be lower in Spain and Portugal
  • than in any other part of Europe, as they come from those countries to all
  • other parts of Europe, loaded, not only with a freight and an insurance,
  • but with the expense of smuggling, their exportation being either
  • prohibited or subjected to a duty. In proportion to the annual produce of
  • the land and labour, therefore, their quantity must be greater in those
  • countries than in any other part of Europe; those countries, however, are
  • poorer than the greater part of Europe. Though the feudal system has been
  • abolished in Spain and Portugal, it has not been succeeded by a much
  • better.
  • As the low value of gold and silver, therefore, is no proof of the wealth
  • and flourishing state of the country where it takes place; so neither is
  • their high value, or the low money price either of goods in general, or of
  • corn in particular, any proof of its poverty and barbarism.
  • But though the low money price, either of goods in general, or of corn in
  • particular, be no proof of the poverty or barbarism of the times, the low
  • money price of some particular sorts of goods, such as cattle, poultry,
  • game of all kinds, etc. in proportion to that of corn, is a most decisive
  • one. It clearly demonstrates, first, their great abundance in proportion
  • to that of corn, and, consequently, the great extent of the land which
  • they occupied in proportion to what was occupied by corn; and, secondly,
  • the low value of this land in proportion to that of corn land, and,
  • consequently, the uncultivated and unimproved state of the far greater
  • part of the lands of the country. It clearly demonstrates, that the stock
  • and population of the country did not bear the same proportion to the
  • extent of its territory, which they commonly do in civilized countries;
  • and that society was at that time, and in that country, but in its
  • infancy. From the high or low money price, either of goods in general, or
  • of corn in particular, we can infer only, that the mines, which at that
  • time happened to supply the commercial world with gold and silver, were
  • fertile or barren, not that the country was rich or poor. But from the
  • high or low money price of some sorts of goods in proportion to that of
  • others, we can infer, with a degree of probability that approaches almost
  • to certainty, that it was rich or poor, that the greater part of its lands
  • were improved or unimproved, and that it was either in a more or less
  • barbarous state, or in a more or less civilized one.
  • Any rise in the money price of goods which proceeded altogether from the
  • degradation of the value of silver, would affect all sorts of goods
  • equally, and raise their price universally, a third, or a fourth, or a
  • fifth part higher, according as silver happened to lose a third, or a
  • fourth, or a fifth part of its former value. But the rise in the price of
  • provisions, which has been the subject of so much reasoning and
  • conversation, does not affect all sorts of provisions equally. Taking the
  • course of the present century at an average, the price of corn, it is
  • acknowledged, even by those who account for this rise by the degradation
  • of the value of silver, has risen much less than that of some other sorts
  • of provisions. The rise in the price of those other sorts of provisions,
  • therefore, cannot be owing altogether to the degradation of the value of
  • silver. Some other causes must be taken into the account; and those which
  • have been above assigned, will, perhaps, without having recourse to the
  • supposed degradation of the value of silver, sufficiently explain this
  • rise in those particular sorts of provisions, of which the price has
  • actually risen in proportion to that of corn.
  • As to the price of corn itself, it has, during the sixty-four first years
  • of the present century, and before the late extraordinary course of bad
  • seasons, been somewhat lower than it was during the sixty-four last years
  • of the preceding century. This fact is attested, not only by the accounts
  • of Windsor market, but by the public fiars of all the different counties
  • of Scotland, and by the accounts of several different markets in France,
  • which have been collected with great diligence and fidelity by Mr
  • Messance, and by Mr Dupré de St Maur. The evidence is more complete than
  • could well have been expected in a matter which is naturally so very
  • difficult to be ascertained.
  • As to the high price of corn during these last ten or twelve years, it can
  • be sufficiently accounted for from the badness of the seasons, without
  • supposing any degradation in the value of silver.
  • The opinion, therefore, that silver is continually sinking in its value,
  • seems not to be founded upon any good observations, either upon the prices
  • of corn, or upon those of other provisions.
  • The same quantity of silver, it may perhaps be said, will, in the present
  • times, even according to the account which has been here given, purchase a
  • much smaller quantity of several sorts of provisions than it would have
  • done during some part of the last century; and to ascertain whether this
  • change be owing to a rise in the value of those goods, or to a fall in the
  • value of silver, is only to establish a vain and useless distinction,
  • which can be of no sort of service to the man who has only a certain
  • quantity of silver to go to market with, or a certain fixed revenue in
  • money. I certainly do not pretend that the knowledge of this distinction
  • will enable him to buy cheaper. It may not, however, upon that account be
  • altogether useless.
  • It may be of some use to the public, by affording an easy proof of the
  • prosperous condition of the country. If the rise in the price of some
  • sorts of provisions be owing altogether to a fall in the value of silver,
  • it is owing to a circumstance, from which nothing can be inferred but the
  • fertility of the American mines. The real wealth of the country, the
  • annual produce of its land and labour, may, notwithstanding this
  • circumstance, be either gradually declining, as in Portugal and Poland; or
  • gradually advancing, as in most other parts of Europe. But if this rise in
  • the price of some sorts of provisions be owing to a rise in the real value
  • of the land which produces them, to its increased fertility, or, in
  • consequence of more extended improvement and good cultivation, to its
  • having been rendered fit for producing corn; it is owing to a circumstance
  • which indicates, in the clearest manner, the prosperous and advancing
  • state of the country. The land constitutes by far the greatest, the most
  • important, and the most durable part of the wealth of every extensive
  • country. It may surely be of some use, or, at least, it may give some
  • satisfaction to the public, to have so decisive a proof of the increasing
  • value of by far the greatest, the most important, and the most durable
  • part of its wealth.
  • It may, too, be of some use to the public, in regulating the pecuniary
  • reward of some of its inferior servants. If this rise in the price of some
  • sorts of provisions be owing to a fall in the value of silver, their
  • pecuniary reward, provided it was not too large before, ought certainly to
  • be augmented in proportion to the extent of this fall. If it is not
  • augmented, their real recompence will evidently be so much diminished. But
  • if this rise of price is owing to the increased value, in consequence of
  • the improved fertility of the land which produces such provisions, it
  • becomes a much nicer matter to judge, either in what proportion any
  • pecuniary reward ought to be augmented, or whether it ought to be
  • augmented at all. The extension of improvement and cultivation, as it
  • necessarily raises more or less, in proportion to the price of corn, that
  • of every sort of animal food, so it as necessarily lowers that of, I
  • believe, every sort of vegetable food. It raises the price of animal food;
  • because a great part of the land which produces it, being rendered fit for
  • producing corn, must afford to the landlord anti farmer the rent and
  • profit of corn land. It lowers the price of vegetable food; because, by
  • increasing the fertility of the land, it increases its abundance. The
  • improvements of agriculture, too, introduce many sorts of vegetable food,
  • which requiring less land, and not more labour than corn, come much
  • cheaper to market. Such are potatoes and maize, or what is called Indian
  • corn, the two most important improvements which the agriculture of Europe,
  • perhaps, which Europe itself, has received from the great extension of its
  • commerce and navigation. Many sorts of vegetable food, besides, which in
  • the rude state of agriculture are confined to the kitchen-garden, and
  • raised only by the spade, come, in its improved state, to be introduced
  • into common fields, and to be raised by the plough; such as turnips,
  • carrots, cabbages, etc. If, in the progress of improvement, therefore, the
  • real price of one species of food necessarily rises, that of another as
  • necessarily falls; and it becomes a matter of more nicety to judge how far
  • the rise in the one may be compensated by the fall in the other. When the
  • real price of butcher’s meat has once got to its height (which, with
  • regard to every sort, except perhaps that of hogs flesh, it seems to have
  • done through a great part of England more than a century ago), any rise
  • which can afterwards happen in that of any other sort of animal food,
  • cannot much affect the circumstances of the inferior ranks of people. The
  • circumstances of the poor, through a great part of England, cannot surely
  • be so much distressed by any rise in the price of poultry, fish,
  • wild-fowl, or venison, as they must be relieved by the fall in that of
  • potatoes.
  • In the present season of scarcity, the high price of corn no doubt
  • distresses the poor. But in times of moderate plenty, when corn is at its
  • ordinary or average price, the natural rise in the price of any other sort
  • of rude produce cannot much affect them. They suffer more, perhaps, by the
  • artificial rise which has been occasioned by taxes in the price of some
  • manufactured commodities, as of salt, soap, leather, candles, malt, beer,
  • ale, etc.
  • Effects of the Progress of Improvement upon the real Price of
  • Manufactures.
  • It is the natural effect of improvement, however, to diminish gradually
  • the real price of almost all manufactures. That of the manufacturing
  • workmanship diminishes, perhaps, in all of them without exception. In
  • consequence of better machinery, of greater dexterity, and of a more
  • proper division and distribution of work, all of which are the natural
  • effects of improvement, a much smaller quantity of labour becomes
  • requisite for executing any particular piece of work; and though, in
  • consequence of the flourishing circumstances of the society, the real
  • price of labour should rise very considerably, yet the great diminution of
  • the quantity will generally much more than compensate the greatest rise
  • which can happen in the price.
  • There are, indeed, a few manufactures, in which the necessary rise in the
  • real price of the rude materials will more than compensate all the
  • advantages which improvement can introduce into the execution of the work
  • in carpenters’ and joiners’ work, and in the coarser sort of cabinet work,
  • the necessary rise in the real price of barren timber, in consequence of
  • the improvement of land, will more than compensate all the advantages
  • which can be derived from the best machinery, the greatest dexterity, and
  • the most proper division and distribution of work.
  • But in all cases in which the real price of the rude material either does
  • not rise at all, or does not rise very much, that of the manufactured
  • commodity sinks very considerably.
  • This diminution of price has, in the course of the present and preceding
  • century, been most remarkable in those manufactures of which the materials
  • are the coarser metals. A better movement of a watch, than about the
  • middle of the last century could have been bought for twenty pounds, may
  • now perhaps be had for twenty shillings. In the work of cutlers and
  • locksmiths, in all the toys which are made of the coarser metals, and in
  • all those goods which are commonly known by the name of Birmingham and
  • Sheffield ware, there has been, during the same period, a very great
  • reduction of price, though not altogether so great as in watch-work. It
  • has, however, been sufficient to astonish the workmen of every other part
  • of Europe, who in many cases acknowledge that they can produce no work of
  • equal goodness for double or even for triple the price. There are perhaps
  • no manufactures, in which the division of labour can be carried further,
  • or in which the machinery employed admits of a greater variety of
  • improvements, than those of which the materials are the coarser metals.
  • In the clothing manufacture there has, during the same period, been no
  • such sensible reduction of price. The price of superfine cloth, I have
  • been assured, on the contrary, has, within these five-and-twenty or thirty
  • years, risen somewhat in proportion to its quality, owing, it was said, to
  • a considerable rise in the price of the material, which consists
  • altogether of Spanish wool. That of the Yorkshire cloth, which is made
  • altogether of English wool, is said, indeed, during the course of the
  • present century, to have fallen a good deal in proportion to its quality.
  • Quality, however, is so very disputable a matter, that I look upon all
  • information of this kind as somewhat uncertain. In the clothing
  • manufacture, the division of labour is nearly the same now as it was a
  • century ago, and the machinery employed is not very different. There may,
  • however, have been some small improvements in both, which may have
  • occasioned some reduction of price.
  • But the reduction will appear much more sensible and undeniable, if we
  • compare the price of this manufacture in the present times with what it
  • was in a much remoter period, towards the end of the fifteenth century,
  • when the labour was probably much less subdivided, and the machinery
  • employed much more imperfect, than it is at present.
  • In 1487, being the 4th of Henry VII., it was enacted, that “whosoever
  • shall sell by retail a broad yard of the finest scarlet grained, or of
  • other grained cloth of the finest making, above sixteen shillings, shall
  • forfeit forty shillings for every yard so sold.” Sixteen shillings,
  • therefore, containing about the same quantity of silver as four-and-twenty
  • shillings of our present money, was, at that time, reckoned not an
  • unreasonable price for a yard of the finest cloth; and as this is a
  • sumptuary law, such cloth, it is probable, had usually been sold somewhat
  • dearer. A guinea may be reckoned the highest price in the present times.
  • Even though the quality of the cloths, therefore, should be supposed
  • equal, and that of the present times is most probably much superior, yet,
  • even upon this supposition, the money price of the finest cloth appears to
  • have been considerably reduced since the end of the fifteenth century. But
  • its real price has been much more reduced. Six shillings and eightpence
  • was then, and long afterwards, reckoned the average price of a quarter of
  • wheat. Sixteen shillings, therefore, was the price of two quarters and
  • more than three bushels of wheat. Valuing a quarter of wheat in the
  • present times at eight-and-twenty shillings, the real price of a yard of
  • fine cloth must, in those times, have been equal to at least three pounds
  • six shillings and sixpence of our present money. The man who bought it
  • must have parted with the command of a quantity of labour and subsistence
  • equal to what that sum would purchase in the present times.
  • The reduction in the real price of the coarse manufacture, though
  • considerable, has not been so great as in that of the fine.
  • In 1463, being the 3rd of Edward IV. it was enacted, that “no servant in
  • husbandry nor common labourer, nor servant to any artificer inhabiting out
  • of a city or burgh, shall use or wear in their clothing any cloth above
  • two shillings the broad yard.” In the 3rd of Edward IV., two shillings
  • contained very nearly the same quantity of silver as four of our present
  • money. But the Yorkshire cloth which is now sold at four shillings the
  • yard, is probably much superior to any that was then made for the wearing
  • of the very poorest order of common servants. Even the money price of
  • their clothing, therefore, may, in proportion to the quality, be somewhat
  • cheaper in the present than it was in those ancient times. The real price
  • is certainly a good deal cheaper. Tenpence was then reckoned what is
  • called the moderate and reasonable price of a bushel of wheat. Two
  • shillings, therefore, was the price of two bushels and near two pecks of
  • wheat, which in the present times, at three shillings and sixpence the
  • bushel, would be worth eight shillings and ninepence. For a yard of this
  • cloth the poor servant must have parted with the power of purchasing a
  • quantity of subsistence equal to what eight shillings and ninepence would
  • purchase in the present times. This is a sumptuary law, too, restraining
  • the luxury and extravagance of the poor. Their clothing, therefore, had
  • commonly been much more expensive.
  • The same order of people are, by the same law, prohibited from wearing
  • hose, of which the price should exceed fourteen-pence the pair, equal to
  • about eight-and-twenty pence of our present money. But fourteen-pence was
  • in those times the price of a bushel and near two pecks of wheat; which in
  • the present times, at three and sixpence the bushel, would cost five
  • shillings and threepence. We should in the present times consider this as
  • a very high price for a pair of stockings to a servant of the poorest and
  • lowest order. He must however, in those times, have paid what was really
  • equivalent to this price for them.
  • In the time of Edward IV. the art of knitting stockings was probably not
  • known in any part of Europe. Their hose were made of common cloth, which
  • may have been one of the causes of their dearness. The first person that
  • wore stockings in England is said to have been Queen Elizabeth. She
  • received them as a present from the Spanish ambassador.
  • Both in the coarse and in the fine woollen manufacture, the machinery
  • employed was much more imperfect in those ancient, than it is in the
  • present times. It has since received three very capital improvements,
  • besides, probably, many smaller ones, of which it may be difficult to
  • ascertain either the number or the importance. The three capital
  • improvements are, first, the exchange of the rock and spindle for the
  • spinning-wheel, which, with the same quantity of labour, will perform more
  • than double the quantity of work. Secondly, the use of several very
  • ingenious machines, which facilitate and abridge, in a still greater
  • proportion, the winding of the worsted and woollen yarn, or the proper
  • arrangement of the warp and woof before they are put into the loom; an
  • operation which, previous to the invention of those machines, must have
  • been extremely tedious and troublesome. Thirdly, the employment of the
  • fulling-mill for thickening the cloth, instead of treading it in water.
  • Neither wind nor water mills of any kind were known in England so early as
  • the beginning of the sixteenth century, nor, so far as I know, in any
  • other part of Europe north of the Alps. They had been introduced into
  • Italy some time before.
  • The consideration of these circumstances may, perhaps, in some measure,
  • explain to us why the real price both of the coarse and of the fine
  • manufacture was so much higher in those ancient than it is in the present
  • times. It cost a greater quantity of labour to bring the goods to market.
  • When they were brought thither, therefore, they must have purchased, or
  • exchanged for the price of, a greater quantity.
  • The coarse manufacture probably was, in those ancient times, carried on in
  • England in the same manner as it always has been in countries where arts
  • and manufactures are in their infancy. It was probably a household
  • manufacture, in which every different part of the work was occasionally
  • performed by all the different members of almost every private family, but
  • so as to be their work only when they had nothing else to do, and not to
  • be the principal business from which any of them derived the greater part
  • of their subsistence. The work which is performed in this manner, it has
  • already been observed, comes always much cheaper to market than that which
  • is the principal or sole fund of the workman’s subsistence. The fine
  • manufacture, on the other hand, was not, in those times, carried on in
  • England, but in the rich and commercial country of Flanders; and it was
  • probably conducted then, in the same manner as now, by people who derived
  • the whole, or the principal part of their subsistence from it. It was,
  • besides, a foreign manufacture, and must have paid some duty, the ancient
  • custom of tonnage and poundage at least, to the king. This duty, indeed,
  • would not probably be very great. It was not then the policy of Europe to
  • restrain, by high duties, the importation of foreign manufactures, but
  • rather to encourage it, in order that merchants might be enabled to
  • supply, at as easy a rate as possible, the great men with the
  • conveniencies and luxuries which they wanted, and which the industry of
  • their own country could not afford them.
  • The consideration of these circumstances may, perhaps, in some measure
  • explain to us why, in those ancient times, the real price of the coarse
  • manufacture was, in proportion to that of the fine, so much lower than in
  • the present times.
  • Conclusion of the Chapter.
  • I shall conclude this very long chapter with observing, that every
  • improvement in the circumstances of the society tends, either directly or
  • indirectly, to raise the real rent of land to increase the real wealth of
  • the landlord, his power of purchasing the labour, or the produce of the
  • labour of other people.
  • The extension of improvement and cultivation tends to raise it directly.
  • The landlord’s share of the produce necessarily increases with the
  • increase of the produce.
  • That rise in the real price of those parts of the rude produce of land,
  • which is first the effect of the extended improvement and cultivation, and
  • afterwards the cause of their being still further extended, the rise in
  • the price of cattle, for example, tends, too, to raise the rent of land
  • directly, and in a still greater proportion. The real value of the
  • landlord’s share, his real command of the labour of other people, not only
  • rises with the real value of the produce, but the proportion of his share
  • to the whole produce rises with it.
  • That produce, after the rise in its real price, requires no more labour to
  • collect it than before. A smaller proportion of it will, therefore, be
  • sufficient to replace, with the ordinary profit, the stock which employs
  • that labour. A greater proportion of it must consequently belong to the
  • landlord.
  • All those improvements in the productive powers of labour, which tend
  • directly to reduce the rent price of manufactures, tend indirectly to
  • raise the real rent of land. The landlord exchanges that part of his rude
  • produce, which is over and above his own consumption, or, what comes to
  • the same thing, the price of that part of it, for manufactured produce.
  • Whatever reduces the real price of the latter, raises that of the former.
  • An equal quantity of the former becomes thereby equivalent to a greater
  • quantity of the latter; and the landlord is enabled to purchase a greater
  • quantity of the conveniencies, ornaments, or luxuries which he has
  • occasion for.
  • Every increase in the real wealth of the society, every increase in the
  • quantity of useful labour employed within it, tends indirectly to raise
  • the real rent of land. A certain proportion of this labour naturally goes
  • to the land. A greater number of men and cattle are employed in its
  • cultivation, the produce increases with the increase of the stock which is
  • thus employed in raising it, and the rent increases with the produce.
  • The contrary circumstances, the neglect of cultivation and improvement,
  • the fall in the real price of any part of the rude produce of land, the
  • rise in the real price of manufactures from the decay of manufacturing art
  • and industry, the declension of the real wealth of the society, all tend,
  • on the other hand, to lower the real rent of land, to reduce the real
  • wealth of the landlord, to diminish his power of purchasing either the
  • labour, or the produce of the labour, of other people.
  • The whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country, or, what
  • comes to the same thing, the whole price of that annual produce, naturally
  • divides itself, it has already been observed, into three parts; the rent
  • of land, the wages of labour, and the profits of stock; and constitutes a
  • revenue to three different orders of people; to those who live by rent, to
  • those who live by wages, and to those who live by profit. These are the
  • three great, original, and constituent, orders of every civilized society,
  • from whose revenue that of every other order is ultimately derived.
  • The interest of the first of those three great orders, it appears from
  • what has been just now said, is strictly and inseparably connected with
  • the general interest of the society. Whatever either promotes or obstructs
  • the one, necessarily promotes or obstructs the other. When the public
  • deliberates concerning any regulation of commerce or police, the
  • proprietors of land never can mislead it, with a view to promote the
  • interest of their own particular order; at least, if they have any
  • tolerable knowledge of that interest. They are, indeed, too often
  • defective in this tolerable knowledge. They are the only one of the three
  • orders whose revenue costs them neither labour nor care, but comes to
  • them, as it were, of its own accord, and independent of any plan or
  • project of their own. That indolence which is the natural effect of the
  • ease and security of their situation, renders them too often, not only
  • ignorant, but incapable of that application of mind, which is necessary in
  • order to foresee and understand the consequence of any public regulation.
  • The interest of the second order, that of those who live by wages, is as
  • strictly connected with the interest of the society as that of the first.
  • The wages of the labourer, it has already been shewn, are never so high as
  • when the demand for labour is continually rising, or when the quantity
  • employed is every year increasing considerably. When this real wealth of
  • the society becomes stationary, his wages are soon reduced to what is
  • barely enough to enable him to bring up a family, or to continue the race
  • of labourers. When the society declines, they fall even below this. The
  • order of proprietors may perhaps gain more by the prosperity of the
  • society than that of labourers; but there is no order that suffers so
  • cruelly from its decline. But though the interest of the labourer is
  • strictly connected with that of the society, he is incapable either of
  • comprehending that interest, or of understanding its connexion with his
  • own. His condition leaves him no time to receive the necessary
  • information, and his education and habits are commonly such as to render
  • him unfit to judge, even though he was fully informed. In the public
  • deliberations, therefore, his voice is little heard, and less regarded;
  • except upon particular occasions, when his clamour is animated, set on,
  • and supported by his employers, not for his, but their own particular
  • purposes.
  • His employers constitute the third order, that of those who live by
  • profit. It is the stock that is employed for the sake of profit, which
  • puts into motion the greater part of the useful labour of every society.
  • The plans and projects of the employers of stock regulate and direct all
  • the most important operation of labour, and profit is the end proposed by
  • all those plans and projects. But the rate of profit does not, like rent
  • and wages, rise with the prosperity, and fall with the declension of the
  • society. On the contrary, it is naturally low in rich, and high in poor
  • countries, and it is always highest in the countries which are going
  • fastest to ruin. The interest of this third order, therefore, has not the
  • same connexion with the general interest of the society, as that of the
  • other two. Merchants and master manufacturers are, in this order, the two
  • classes of people who commonly employ the largest capitals, and who by
  • their wealth draw to themselves the greatest share of the public
  • consideration. As during their whole lives they are engaged in plans and
  • projects, they have frequently more acuteness of understanding than the
  • greater part of country gentlemen. As their thoughts, however, are
  • commonly exercised rather about the interest of their own particular
  • branch of business. than about that of the society, their judgment, even
  • when given with the greatest candour (which it has not been upon every
  • occasion), is much more to be depended upon with regard to the former of
  • those two objects, than with regard to the latter. Their superiority over
  • the country gentleman is, not so much in their knowledge of the public
  • interest, as in their having a better knowledge of their own interest than
  • he has of his. It is by this superior knowledge of their own interest that
  • they have frequently imposed upon his generosity, and persuaded him to
  • give up both his own interest and that of the public, from a very simple
  • but honest conviction, that their interest, and not his, was the interest
  • of the public. The interest of the dealers, however, in any particular
  • branch of trade or manufactures, is always in some respects different
  • from, and even opposite to, that of the public. To widen the market, and
  • to narrow the competition, is always the interest of the dealers. To widen
  • the market may frequently be agreeable enough to the interest of the
  • public; but to narrow the competition must always be against it, and can
  • only serve to enable the dealers, by raising their profits above what they
  • naturally would be, to levy, for their own benefit, an absurd tax upon the
  • rest of their fellow-citizens. The proposal of any new law or regulation
  • of commerce which comes from this order, ought always to be listened to
  • with great precaution, and ought never to be adopted till after having
  • been long and carefully examined, not only with the most scrupulous, but
  • with the most suspicious attention. It comes from an order of men, whose
  • interest is never exactly the same with that of the public, who have
  • generally an interest to deceive and even to oppress the public, and who
  • accordingly have, upon many occasions, both deceived and oppressed it.
  • # PRICES OF WHEAT
  • Year Prices/Quarter Average of different Average prices of
  • in each year prices in one year each year in money
  • of 1776
  • £ s d £ s d £ s d
  • 1202 0 12 0 1 16 0
  • 1205 0 12 0
  • 0 13 4 0 13 5 2 0 3
  • 0 15 0
  • 1223 0 12 0 1 16 0
  • 1237 0 3 4 0 10 0
  • 1243 0 2 0 0 6 0
  • 1244 0 2 0 0 6 0
  • 1246 0 16 0 2 8 0
  • 1247 0 13 5 2 0 0
  • 1257 1 4 0 3 12 0
  • 1258 1 0 0
  • 0 15 0 0 17 0 2 11 0
  • 0 16 0
  • 1270 4 16 0
  • 6 8 0 5 12 0 16 16 0
  • 1286 0 2 8
  • 0 16 0 0 9 4 1 8 0
  • Total 35 9 3
  • Average 2 19 1¼
  • 1287 0 3 4 0 10 0
  • 1288 0 0 8
  • 0 1 0
  • 0 1 4
  • 0 1 6
  • 0 1 8 0 3 0¼ 0 9 1¾
  • 0 2 0
  • 0 3 4
  • 0 9 4
  • 1289 0 12 0
  • 0 6 0
  • 0 2 0 0 10 1½ 1 10 4½
  • 0 10 8
  • 1 0 0
  • 1290 0 16 0 2 8 0
  • 1294 0 16 0 2 8 0
  • 1302 0 4 0 0 12 0
  • 1309 0 7 2 1 1 6
  • 1315 1 0 0 3 0 0
  • 1316 1 0 0
  • 1 10 0 1 10 6 4 11 6
  • 1 12 0
  • 2 0 0
  • 1317 2 4 0
  • 0 14 0
  • 2 13 0 1 19 6 5 18 6
  • 4 0 0
  • 0 6 8
  • 1336 0 2 0 0 6 0
  • 1338 0 3 4 0 10 0
  • Total 23 4 11¼
  • Average 1 18 8
  • 1339 0 9 0 1 7 0
  • 1349 0 2 0 0 5 2
  • 1359 1 6 8 3 2 2
  • 1361 0 2 0 0 4 8
  • 1363 0 15 0 1 15 0
  • 1369 1 0 0
  • 1 4 0 1 2 0 2 9 4
  • 1379 0 4 0 0 9 4
  • 1387 0 2 0 0 4 8
  • 1390 0 13 4
  • 0 14 0 0 14 5 1 13 7
  • 0 16 0
  • 1401 0 16 0 1 17 6
  • 1407 0 4 4¾
  • 0 3 4 0 3 10 0 8 10
  • 1416 0 16 0 1 12 0
  • Total 15 9 4
  • Average 1 5 9½
  • 1423 0 8 0 0
  • 1425 0 4 0 0
  • 1434 1 6 8 4
  • 1435 0 5 4 8
  • 1439 1 0 0
  • 1 6 8 1 3 4 2 6 8
  • 1440 1 4 0 2 8 0
  • 1444 0 4 4 0 4 2 0 4 8
  • 0 4 0
  • 1445 0 4 6 0 9 0
  • 1447 0 8 0 0 16 0
  • 1448 0 6 8 0 13 4
  • 1449 0 5 0 0 10 0
  • 1451 0 8 0 0 16 0
  • Total 12 15 4
  • Average 1 1 3¹/³
  • 1453 0 5 4 0 10 8
  • 1455 0 1 2 0 2 4
  • 1457 0 7 8 1 15 4
  • 1459 0 5 0 0 10 0
  • 1460 0 8 0 0 16 0
  • 1463 0 2 0 0 1 10 0 3 8
  • 0 1 8
  • 1464 0 6 8 0 10 0
  • 1486 1 4 0 1 17 0
  • 1491 0 14 8 1 2 0
  • 1494 0 4 0 0 6 0
  • 1495 0 3 4 0 5 0
  • 1497 1 0 0 1 11 0
  • Total 8 9 0
  • Average 0 14 1
  • 1499 0 4 0 0 6 0
  • 1504 0 5 8 0 8 6
  • 1521 1 0 0 1 10 0
  • 1551 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1553 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1554 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1555 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1556 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1557 0 8 0
  • 0 4 0 0 17 8½ 0 17 8½
  • 0 5 0
  • 2 13 4
  • 1558 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1559 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1560 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • Total 6 0 2½
  • Average 0 10 0½
  • 1561 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1562 0 8 0 0 8 0
  • 1574 2 16 0
  • 1 4 0 2 0 0 2 0 0
  • 1587 3 4 0 3 4 0
  • 1594 2 16 0 2 16 0
  • 1595 2 13 0 2 13 0
  • 1596 4 0 0 4 0 0
  • 1597 5 4 0
  • 4 0 0 4 12 0 4 12 0
  • 1598 2 16 8 2 16 8
  • 1599 1 19 2 1 19 8
  • 1600 1 17 8 1 17 8
  • 1601 1 14 10 1 14 10
  • Total 28 9 4
  • Average 2 7 5½
  • PRICES OF THE QUARTER OF NINE BUSHELS OF THE BEST OR HIGHEST PRICED WHEAT
  • AT WINDSOR MARKET, ON LADY DAY AND MICHAELMAS, FROM 1595 TO 1764 BOTH
  • INCLUSIVE; THE PRICE OF EACH YEAR BEING THE MEDIUM BETWEEN THE HIGHEST
  • PRICES OF THESE TWO MARKET DAYS.
  • £ s d
  • 1595 2 0 0
  • 1596 2 8 0
  • 1597 3 9 6
  • 1598 2 16 8
  • 1599 1 19 2
  • 1600 1 17 8
  • 1601 1 14 10
  • 1602 1 9 4
  • 1603 1 15 4
  • 1604 1 10 8
  • 1605 1 15 10
  • 1606 1 13 0
  • 1607 1 16 8
  • 1608 2 16 8
  • 1609 2 10 0
  • 1610 1 15 10
  • 1611 1 18 8
  • 1612 2 2 4
  • 1613 2 8 8
  • 1614 2 1 8½
  • 1615 1 18 8
  • 1616 2 0 4
  • 1617 2 8 8
  • 1618 2 6 8
  • 1619 1 15 4
  • 1620 1 10 4
  • 26)54 0 6½
  • Average 2 1 6¾
  • 1621 1 10 4
  • 1622 2 18 8
  • 1623 2 12 0
  • 1624 2 8 0
  • 1625 2 12 0
  • 1626 2 9 4
  • 1627 1 16 0
  • 1628 1 8 0
  • 1629 2 2 0
  • 1630 2 15 8
  • 1631 3 8 0
  • 1632 2 13 4
  • 1633 2 18 0
  • 1634 2 16 0
  • 1635 2 16 0
  • 1636 2 16 8
  • 16)40 0 0
  • Average 2 10 0
  • 1637 2 13 0
  • 1638 2 17 4
  • 1639 2 4 10
  • 1640 2 4 8
  • 1641 2 8 0
  • 1646 2 8 0
  • 1647 3 13 0
  • 1648 4 5 0
  • 1649 4 0 0
  • 1650 3 16 8
  • 1651 3 13 4
  • 1652 2 9 6
  • 1653 1 15 6
  • 1654 1 6 0
  • 1655 1 13 4
  • 1656 2 3 0
  • 1657 2 6 8
  • 1658 3 5 0
  • 1659 3 6 0
  • 1660 2 16 6
  • 1661 3 10 0
  • 1662 3 14 0
  • 1663 2 17 0
  • 1664 2 0 6
  • 1665 2 9 4
  • 1666 1 16 0
  • 1667 1 16 0
  • 1668 2 0 0
  • 1669 2 4 4
  • 1670 2 1 8
  • 1671 2 2 0
  • 1672 2 1 0
  • 1673 2 6 8
  • 1674 3 8 8
  • 1675 3 4 8
  • 1676 1 18 0
  • 1677 2 2 0
  • 1678 2 19 0
  • 1679 3 0 0
  • 1680 2 5 0
  • 1681 2 6 8
  • 1682 2 4 0
  • 1683 2 0 0
  • 1684 2 4 0
  • 1685 2 6 8
  • 1686 1 14 0
  • 1687 1 5 2
  • 1688 2 6 0
  • 1689 1 10 0
  • 1690 1 14 8
  • 1691 1 14 0
  • 1692 2 6 8
  • 1693 3 7 8
  • 1694 3 4 0
  • 1695 2 13 0
  • 1696 3 11 0
  • 1697 3 0 0
  • 1698 3 8 4
  • 1699 3 4 0
  • 1700 2 0 0
  • 60) 153 1 8
  • Average 2 11 0¹/³
  • 1701 1 17 8
  • 1702 1 9 6
  • 1703 1 16 0
  • 1704 2 6 6
  • 1705 1 10 0
  • 1706 1 6 0
  • 1707 1 8 6
  • 1708 2 1 6
  • 1709 3 18 6
  • 1710 3 18 0
  • 1711 2 14 0
  • 1712 2 6 4
  • 1713 2 11 0
  • 1714 2 10 4
  • 1715 2 3 0
  • 1716 2 8 0
  • 1717 2 5 8
  • 1718 1 18 10
  • 1719 1 15 0
  • 1720 1 17 0
  • 1721 1 17 6
  • 1722 1 16 0
  • 1723 1 14 8
  • 1724 1 17 0
  • 1725 2 8 6
  • 1726 2 6 0
  • 1727 2 2 0
  • 1728 2 14 6
  • 1729 2 6 10
  • 1730 1 16 6
  • 1731 1 12 10 1 12 10
  • 1732 1 6 8 1 6 8
  • 1733 1 8 4 1 8 4
  • 1734 1 18 10 1 18 10
  • 1735 2 3 0 2 3 0
  • 1736 2 0 4 2 0 4
  • 1737 1 18 0 1 18 0
  • 1738 1 15 6 1 15 6
  • 1739 1 18 6 1 18 6
  • 1740 2 10 8 2 10 8
  • 10) 18 12 8
  • 1 17 3½
  • 1741 2 6 8 2 6 8
  • 1742 1 14 0 1 14 0
  • 1743 1 4 10 1 4 10
  • 1744 1 4 10 1 4 10
  • 1745 1 7 6 1 7 6
  • 1746 1 19 0 1 19 0
  • 1747 1 14 10 1 14 10
  • 1748 1 17 0 1 17 0
  • 1749 1 17 0 1 17 0
  • 1750 1 12 6 1 12 6
  • 10) 16 18 2
  • 1 13 9¾
  • 1751 1 18 6
  • 1752 2 1 10
  • 1753 2 4 8
  • 1754 1 13 8
  • 1755 1 14 10
  • 1756 2 5 3
  • 1757 3 0 0
  • 1758 2 10 0
  • 1759 1 19 10
  • 1760 1 16 6
  • 1761 1 10 3
  • 1762 1 19 0
  • 1763 2 0 9
  • 1764 2 6 9
  • 64) 129 13 6
  • Average 2 0 6¾
  • BOOK II.
  • OF THE NATURE, ACCUMULATION, AND EMPLOYMENT OF STOCK.
  • INTRODUCTION.
  • In that rude state of society, in which there is no division of labour, in
  • which exchanges are seldom made, and in which every man provides every
  • thing for himself, it is not necessary that any stock should be
  • accumulated, or stored up before-hand, in order to carry on the business
  • of the society. Every man endeavours to supply, by his own industry, his
  • own occasional wants, as they occur. When he is hungry, he goes to the
  • forest to hunt; when his coat is worn out, he clothes himself with the
  • skin of the first large animal he kills: and when his hut begins to go to
  • ruin, he repairs it, as well as he can, with the trees and the turf that
  • are nearest it.
  • But when the division of labour has once been thoroughly introduced, the
  • produce of a man’s own labour can supply but a very small part of his
  • occasional wants. The far greater part of them are supplied by the produce
  • of other men’s labour, which he purchases with the produce, or, what is
  • the same thing, with the price of the produce, of his own. But this
  • purchase cannot be made till such time as the produce of his own labour
  • has not only been completed, but sold. A stock of goods of different
  • kinds, therefore, must be stored up somewhere, sufficient to maintain him,
  • and to supply him with the materials and tools of his work, till such time
  • at least as both these events can be brought about. A weaver cannot apply
  • himself entirely to his peculiar business, unless there is before-hand
  • stored up somewhere, either in his own possession, or in that of some
  • other person, a stock sufficient to maintain him, and to supply him with
  • the materials and tools of his work, till he has not only completed, but
  • sold his web. This accumulation must evidently be previous to his applying
  • his industry for so long a time to such a peculiar business.
  • As the accumulation of stock must, in the nature of things, be previous to
  • the division of labour, so labour can be more and more subdivided in
  • proportion only as stock is previously more and more accumulated. The
  • quantity of materials which the same number of people can work up,
  • increases in a great proportion as labour comes to be more and more
  • subdivided; and as the operations of each workman are gradually reduced to
  • a greater degree of simplicity, a variety of new machines come to be
  • invented for facilitating and abridging those operations. As the division
  • of labour advances, therefore, in order to give constant employment to an
  • equal number of workmen, an equal stock of provisions, and a greater stock
  • of materials and tools than what would have been necessary in a ruder
  • state of things, must be accumulated before-hand. But the number of
  • workmen in every branch of business generally increases with the division
  • of labour in that branch; or rather it is the increase of their number
  • which enables them to class and subdivide themselves in this manner.
  • As the accumulation of stock is previously necessary for carrying on this
  • great improvement in the productive powers of labour, so that accumulation
  • naturally leads to this improvement. The person who employs his stock in
  • maintaining labour, necessarily wishes to employ it in such a manner as to
  • produce as great a quantity of work as possible. He endeavours, therefore,
  • both to make among his workmen the most proper distribution of employment,
  • and to furnish them with the best machines which he can either invent or
  • afford to purchase. His abilities, in both these respects, are generally
  • in proportion to the extent of his stock, or to the number of people whom
  • it can employ. The quantity of industry, therefore, not only increases in
  • every country with the increase of the stock which employs it, but, in
  • consequence of that increase, the same quantity of industry produces a
  • much greater quantity of work.
  • Such are in general the effects of the increase of stock upon industry and
  • its productive powers.
  • In the following book, I have endeavoured to explain the nature of stock,
  • the effects of its accumulation into capital of different kinds, and the
  • effects of the different employments of those capitals. This book is
  • divided into five chapters. In the first chapter, I have endeavoured to
  • shew what are the different parts or branches into which the stock, either
  • of an individual, or of a great society, naturally divides itself. In the
  • second, I have endeavoured to explain the nature and operation of money,
  • considered as a particular branch of the general stock of the society. The
  • stock which is accumulated into a capital, may either be employed by the
  • person to whom it belongs, or it may be lent to some other person. In the
  • third and fourth chapters, I have endeavoured to examine the manner in
  • which it operates in both these situations. The fifth and last chapter
  • treats of the different effects which the different employments of capital
  • immediately produce upon the quantity, both of national industry, and of
  • the annual produce of land and labour.
  • CHAPTER I.
  • OF THE DIVISION OF STOCK.
  • When the stock which a man possesses is no more than sufficient to
  • maintain him for a few days or a few weeks, he seldom thinks of deriving
  • any revenue from it. He consumes it as sparingly as he can, and
  • endeavours, by his labour, to acquire something which may supply its place
  • before it be consumed altogether. His revenue is, in this case, derived
  • from his labour only. This is the state of the greater part of the
  • labouring poor in all countries.
  • But when he possesses stock sufficient to maintain him for months or
  • years, he naturally endeavours to derive a revenue from the greater part
  • of it, reserving only so much for his immediate consumption as may
  • maintain him till this revenue begins to come in. His whole stock,
  • therefore, is distinguished into two parts. That part which he expects is
  • to afford him this revenue is called his capital. The other is that which
  • supplies his immediate consumption, and which consists either, first, in
  • that portion of his whole stock which was originally reserved for this
  • purpose; or, secondly, in his revenue, from whatever source derived, as it
  • gradually comes in; or, thirdly, in such things as had been purchased by
  • either of these in former years, and which are not yet entirely consumed,
  • such as a stock of clothes, household furniture, and the like. In one or
  • other, or all of these three articles, consists the stock which men
  • commonly reserve for their own immediate consumption.
  • There are two different ways in which a capital may be employed so as to
  • yield a revenue or profit to its employer.
  • First, it maybe employed in raising, manufacturing, or purchasing goods,
  • and selling them again with a profit. The capital employed in this manner
  • yields no revenue or profit to its employer, while it either remains in
  • his possession, or continues in the same shape. The goods of the merchant
  • yield him no revenue or profit till he sells them for money, and the money
  • yields him as little till it is again exchanged for goods. His capital is
  • continually going from him in one shape, and returning to him in another;
  • and it is only by means of such circulation, or successive changes, that
  • it can yield him any profit. Such capitals, therefore, may very properly
  • be called circulating capitals.
  • Secondly, it may be employed in the improvement of land, in the purchase
  • of useful machines and instruments of trade, or in such like things as
  • yield a revenue or profit without changing masters, or circulating any
  • further. Such capitals, therefore, may very properly be called fixed
  • capitals.
  • Different occupations require very different proportions between the fixed
  • and circulating capitals employed in them.
  • The capital of a merchant, for example, is altogether a circulating
  • capital. He has occasion for no machines or instruments of trade, unless
  • his shop or warehouse be considered as such.
  • Some part of the capital of every master artificer or manufacturer must be
  • fixed in the instruments of his trade. This part, however, is very small
  • in some, and very great in others, A master tailor requires no other
  • instruments of trade but a parcel of needles. Those of the master
  • shoemaker are a little, though but a very little, more expensive. Those of
  • the weaver rise a good deal above those of the shoemaker. The far greater
  • part of the capital of all such master artificers, however, is circulated
  • either in the wages of their workmen, or in the price of their materials,
  • and repaid, with a profit, by the price of the work.
  • In other works a much greater fixed capital is required. In a great
  • iron-work, for example, the furnace for melting the ore, the forge, the
  • slit-mill, are instruments of trade which cannot be erected without a very
  • great expense. In coal works, and mines of every kind, the machinery
  • necessary, both for drawing out the water, and for other purposes, is
  • frequently still more expensive.
  • That part of the capital of the farmer which is employed in the
  • instruments of agriculture is a fixed, that which is employed in the wages
  • and maintenance of his labouring servants is a circulating capital. He
  • makes a profit of the one by keeping it in his own possession, and of the
  • other by parting with it. The price or value of his labouring cattle is a
  • fixed capital, in the same manner as that of the instruments of husbandry;
  • their maintenance is a circulating capital, in the same manner as that of
  • the labouring servants. The farmer makes his profit by keeping the
  • labouring cattle, and by parting with their maintenance. Both the price
  • and the maintenance of the cattle which are bought in and fattened, not
  • for labour, but for sale, are a circulating capital. The farmer makes his
  • profit by parting with them. A flock of sheep or a herd of cattle, that,
  • in a breeding country, is brought in neither for labour nor for sale, but
  • in order to make a profit by their wool, by their milk, and by their
  • increase, is a fixed capital. The profit is made by keeping them. Their
  • maintenance is a circulating capital. The profit is made by parting with
  • it; and it comes back with both its own profit and the profit upon the
  • whole price of the cattle, in the price of the wool, the milk, and the
  • increase. The whole value of the seed, too, is properly a fixed capital.
  • Though it goes backwards and forwards between the ground and the granary,
  • it never changes masters, and therefore does not properly circulate. The
  • farmer makes his profit, not by its sale, but by its increase.
  • The general stock of any country or society is the same with that of all
  • its inhabitants or members; and, therefore, naturally divides itself into
  • the same three portions, each of which has a distinct function or office.
  • The first is that portion which is reserved for immediate consumption, and
  • of which the characteristic is, that it affords no revenue or profit. It
  • consists in the stock of food, clothes, household furniture, etc. which
  • have been purchased by their proper consumers, but which are not yet
  • entirely consumed. The whole stock of mere dwelling-houses, too,
  • subsisting at anyone time in the country, make a part of this first
  • portion. The stock that is laid out in a house, if it is to be the
  • dwelling-house of the proprietor, ceases from that moment to serve in the
  • function of a capital, or to afford any revenue to its owner. A
  • dwelling-house, as such, contributes nothing to the revenue of its
  • inhabitant; and though it is, no doubt, extremely useful to him, it is as
  • his clothes and household furniture are useful to him, which, however,
  • make a part of his expense, and not of his revenue. If it is to be let to
  • a tenant for rent, as the house itself can produce nothing, the tenant
  • must always pay the rent out of some other revenue, which he derives,
  • either from labour, or stock, or land. Though a house, therefore, may
  • yield a revenue to its proprietor, and thereby serve in the function of a
  • capital to him, it cannot yield any to the public, nor serve in the
  • function of a capital to it, and the revenue of the whole body of the
  • people can never be in the smallest degree increased by it. Clothes and
  • household furniture, in the same manner, sometimes yield a revenue, and
  • thereby serve in the function of a capital to particular persons. In
  • countries where masquerades are common, it is a trade to let out
  • masquerade dresses for a night. Upholsterers frequently let furniture by
  • the month or by the year. Undertakers let the furniture of funerals by the
  • day and by the week. Many people let furnished houses, and get a rent, not
  • only for the use of the house, but for that of the furniture. The revenue,
  • however, which is derived from such things, must always be ultimately
  • drawn from some other source of revenue. Of all parts of the stock, either
  • of an individual or of a society, reserved for immediate consumption, what
  • is laid out in houses is most slowly consumed. A stock of clothes may last
  • several years; a stock of furniture half a century or a century; but a
  • stock of houses, well built and properly taken care of, may last many
  • centuries. Though the period of their total consumption, however, is more
  • distant, they are still as really a stock reserved for immediate
  • consumption as either clothes or household furniture.
  • The second of the three portions into which the general stock of the
  • society divides itself, is the fixed capital; of which the characteristic
  • is, that it affords a revenue or profit without circulating or changing
  • masters. It consists chiefly of the four following articles.
  • First, of all useful machines and instruments of trade, which facilitate
  • and abridge labour.
  • Secondly, of all those profitable buildings which are the means of
  • procuring a revenue, not only to the proprietor who lets them for a rent,
  • but to the person who possesses them, and pays that rent for them; such as
  • shops, warehouses, work-houses, farm-houses, with all their necessary
  • buildings, stables, granaries, etc. These are very different from mere
  • dwelling-houses. They are a sort of instruments of trade, and may be
  • considered in the same light.
  • Thirdly, of the improvements of land, of what has been profitably laid out
  • in clearing, draining, inclosing, manuring, and reducing it into the
  • condition most proper for tillage and culture. An improved farm may very
  • justly be regarded in the same light as those useful machines which
  • facilitate and abridge labour, and by means of which an equal circulating
  • capital can afford a much greater revenue to its employer. An improved
  • farm is equally advantageous and more durable than any of those machines,
  • frequently requiring no other repairs than the most profitable application
  • of the farmer’s capital employed in cultivating it.
  • Fourthly, of the acquired and useful abilities of all the inhabitants and
  • members of the society. The acquisition of such talents, by the
  • maintenance of the acquirer during his education, study, or
  • apprenticeship, always costs a real expense, which is a capital fixed and
  • realized, as it were, in his person. Those talents, as they make a part of
  • his fortune, so do they likewise that of the society to which he belongs.
  • The improved dexterity of a workman may be considered in the same light as
  • a machine or instrument of trade which facilitates and abridges labour,
  • and which, though it costs a certain expense, repays that expense with a
  • profit.
  • The third and last of the three portions into which the general stock of
  • the society naturally divides itself, is the circulating capital, of which
  • the characteristic is, that it affords a revenue only by circulating or
  • changing masters. It is composed likewise of four parts.
  • First, of the money, by means of which all the other three are circulated
  • and distributed to their proper consumers.
  • Secondly, of the stock of provisions which are in the possession of the
  • butcher, the grazier, the farmer, the corn-merchant, the brewer, etc. and
  • from the sale of which they expect to derive a profit.
  • Thirdly, of the materials, whether altogether rude, or more or less
  • manufactured, of clothes, furniture, and building which are not yet made
  • up into any of those three shapes, but which remain in the hands of the
  • growers, the manufacturers, the mercers, and drapers, the
  • timber-merchants, the carpenters and joiners, the brick-makers, etc.
  • Fourthly, and lastly, of the work which is made up and completed, but
  • which is still in the hands of the merchant and manufacturer, and not yet
  • disposed of or distributed to the proper consumers; such as the finished
  • work which we frequently find ready made in the shops of the smith, the
  • cabinet-maker, the goldsmith, the jeweller, the china-merchant, etc. The
  • circulating capital consists, in this manner, of the provisions,
  • materials, and finished work of all kinds that are in the hands of their
  • respective dealers, and of the money that is necessary for circulating and
  • distributing them to those who are finally to use or to consume them.
  • Of these four parts, three—provisions, materials, and finished work,
  • are either annually or in a longer or shorter period, regularly withdrawn
  • from it, and placed either in the fixed capital, or in the stock reserved
  • for immediate consumption.
  • Every fixed capital is both originally derived from, and requires to be
  • continually supported by, a circulating capital. All useful machines and
  • instruments of trade are originally derived from a circulating capital,
  • which furnishes the materials of which they are made, and the maintenance
  • of the workmen who make them. They require, too, a capital of the same
  • kind to keep them in constant repair.
  • No fixed capital can yield any revenue but by means of a circulating
  • capital. The most useful machines and instruments of trade will produce
  • nothing, without the circulating capital, which affords the materials they
  • are employed upon, and the maintenance of the workmen who employ them.
  • Land, however improved, will yield no revenue without a circulating
  • capital, which maintains the labourers who cultivate and collect its
  • produce.
  • To maintain and augment the stock which maybe reserved for immediate
  • consumption, is the sole end and purpose both of the fixed and circulating
  • capitals. It is this stock which feeds, clothes, and lodges the people.
  • Their riches or poverty depend upon the abundant or sparing supplies which
  • those two capitals can afford to the stock reserved for immediate
  • consumption.
  • So great a part of the circulating capital being continually withdrawn
  • from it, in order to be placed in the other two branches of the general
  • stock of the society, it must in its turn require continual supplies
  • without which it would soon cease to exist. These supplies are principally
  • drawn from three sources; the produce of land, of mines, and of fisheries.
  • These afford continual supplies of provisions and materials, of which part
  • is afterwards wrought up into finished work and by which are replaced the
  • provisions, materials, and finished work, continually withdrawn from the
  • circulating capital. From mines, too, is drawn what is necessary for
  • maintaining and augmenting that part of it which consists in money. For
  • though, in the ordinary course of business, this part is not, like the
  • other three, necessarily withdrawn from it, in order to be placed in the
  • other two branches of the general stock of the society, it must, however,
  • like all other things, be wasted and worn out at last, and sometimes, too,
  • be either lost or sent abroad, and must, therefore, require continual,
  • though no doubt much smaller supplies.
  • Lands, mines, and fisheries, require all both a fixed and circulating
  • capital to cultivate them; and their produce replaces, with a profit not
  • only those capitals, but all the others in the society. Thus the farmer
  • annually replaces to the manufacturer the provisions which he had
  • consumed, and the materials which he had wrought up the year before; and
  • the manufacturer replaces to the farmer the finished work which he had
  • wasted and worn out in the same time. This is the real exchange that is
  • annually made between those two orders of people, though it seldom happens
  • that the rude produce of the one, and the manufactured produce of the
  • other, are directly bartered for one another; because it seldom happens
  • that the farmer sells his corn and his cattle, his flax and his wool, to
  • the very same person of whom he chuses to purchase the clothes, furniture,
  • and instruments of trade, which he wants. He sells, therefore, his rude
  • produce for money, with which he can purchase, wherever it is to be had,
  • the manufactured produce he has occasion for. Land even replaces, in part
  • at least, the capitals with which fisheries and mines are cultivated. It
  • is the produce of land which draws the fish from the waters; and it is the
  • produce of the surface of the earth which extracts the minerals from its
  • bowels.
  • The produce of land, mines, and fisheries, when their natural fertility is
  • equal, is in proportion to the extent and proper application of the
  • capitals employed about them. When the capitals are equal, and equally
  • well applied, it is in proportion to their natural fertility.
  • In all countries where there is a tolerable security, every man of common
  • understanding will endeavour to employ whatever stock he can command, in
  • procuring either present enjoyment or future profit. If it is employed in
  • procuring present enjoyment, it is a stock reserved for immediate
  • consumption. If it is employed in procuring future profit, it must procure
  • this profit either by staying with him, or by going from him. In the one
  • case it is a fixed, in the other it is a circulating capital. A man must
  • be perfectly crazy, who, where there is a tolerable security, does not
  • employ all the stock which he commands, whether it be his own, or borrowed
  • of other people, in some one or other of those three ways.
  • In those unfortunate countries, indeed, where men are continually afraid
  • of the violence of their superiors, they frequently bury or conceal a
  • great part of their stock, in order to have it always at hand to carry
  • with them to some place of safety, in case of their being threatened with
  • any of those disasters to which they consider themselves at all times
  • exposed. This is said to be a common practice in Turkey, in Indostan, and,
  • I believe, in most other governments of Asia. It seems to have been a
  • common practice among our ancestors during the violence of the feudal
  • government. Treasure-trove was, in these times, considered as no
  • contemptible part of the revenue of the greatest sovereigns in Europe. It
  • consisted in such treasure as was found concealed in the earth, and to
  • which no particular person could prove any right. This was regarded, in
  • those times, as so important an object, that it was always considered as
  • belonging to the sovereign, and neither to the finder nor to the
  • proprietor of the land, unless the right to it had been conveyed to the
  • latter by an express clause in his charter. It was put upon the same
  • footing with gold and silver mines, which, without a special clause in the
  • charter, were never supposed to be comprehended in the general grant of
  • the lands, though mines of lead, copper, tin, and coal were, as things of
  • smaller consequence.
  • CHAPTER II.
  • OF MONEY, CONSIDERED AS A PARTICULAR
  • BRANCH OF THE GENERAL STOCK OF THE SOCIETY, OR OF THE EXPENSE OF MAINTAINING
  • THE NATIONAL CAPITAL.
  • It has been shown in the First Book, that the price of the greater part of
  • commodities resolves itself into three parts, of which one pays the wages
  • of the labour, another the profits of the stock, and a third the rent of
  • the land which had been employed in producing and bringing them to market:
  • that there are, indeed, some commodities of which the price is made up of
  • two of those parts only, the wages of labour, and the profits of stock;
  • and a very few in which it consists altogether in one, the wages of
  • labour; but that the price of every commodity necessarily resolves itself
  • into some one or other, or all, of those three parts; every part of it
  • which goes neither to rent nor to wages, being necessarily profit to some
  • body.
  • Since this is the case, it has been observed, with regard to every
  • particular commodity, taken separately, it must be so with regard to all
  • the commodities which compose the whole annual produce of the land and
  • labour of every country, taken complexly. The whole price or exchangeable
  • value of that annual produce must resolve itself into the same three
  • parts, and be parcelled out among the different inhabitants of the
  • country, either as the wages of their labour, the profits of their stock,
  • or the rent of their land.
  • But though the whole value of the annual produce of the land and labour of
  • every country, is thus divided among, and constitutes a revenue to, its
  • different inhabitants; yet, as in the rent of a private estate, we
  • distinguish between the gross rent and the neat rent, so may we likewise
  • in the revenue of all the inhabitants of a great country.
  • The gross rent of a private estate comprehends whatever is paid by the
  • farmer; the neat rent, what remains free to the landlord, after deducting
  • the expense of management, of repairs, and all other necessary charges; or
  • what, without hurting his estate, he can afford to place in his stock
  • reserved for immediate consumption, or to spend upon his table, equipage,
  • the ornaments of his house and furniture, his private enjoyments and
  • amusements. His real wealth is in proportion, not to his gross, but to his
  • neat rent.
  • The gross revenue of all the inhabitants of a great country comprehends
  • the whole annual produce of their land and labour; the neat revenue, what
  • remains free to them, after deducting the expense of maintaining first,
  • their fixed, and, secondly, their circulating capital, or what, without
  • encroaching upon their capital, they can place in their stock reserved for
  • immediate consumption, or spend upon their subsistence, conveniencies, and
  • amusements. Their real wealth, too, is in proportion, not to their gross,
  • but to their neat revenue.
  • The whole expense of maintaining the fixed capital must evidently be
  • excluded from the neat revenue of the society. Neither the materials
  • necessary for supporting their useful machines and instruments of trade,
  • their profitable buildings, etc. nor the produce of the labour necessary
  • for fashioning those materials into the proper form, can ever make any
  • part of it. The price of that labour may indeed make a part of it; as the
  • workmen so employed may place the whole value of their wages in their
  • stock reserved for immediate consumption. But in other sorts of labour,
  • both the price and the produce go to this stock; the price to that of the
  • workmen, the produce to that of other people, whose subsistence,
  • conveniencies, and amusements, are augmented by the labour of those
  • workmen.
  • The intention of the fixed capital is to increase the productive powers of
  • labour, or to enable the same number of labourers to perform a much
  • greater quantity of work. In a farm where all the necessary buildings,
  • fences, drains, communications, etc. are in the most perfect good order,
  • the same number of labourers and labouring cattle will raise a much
  • greater produce, than in one of equal extent and equally good ground, but
  • not furnished with equal conveniencies. In manufactures, the same number
  • of hands, assisted with the best machinery, will work up a much greater
  • quantity of goods than with more imperfect instruments of trade. The
  • expense which is properly laid out upon a fixed capital of any kind, is
  • always repaid with great profit, and increases the annual produce by a
  • much greater value than that of the support which such improvements
  • require. This support, however, still requires a certain portion of that
  • produce. A certain quantity of materials, and the labour of a certain
  • number of workmen, both of which might have been immediately employed to
  • augment the food, clothing, and lodging, the subsistence and conveniencies
  • of the society, are thus diverted to another employment, highly
  • advantageous indeed, but still different from this one. It is upon this
  • account that all such improvements in mechanics, as enable the same number
  • of workmen to perform an equal quantity of work with cheaper and simpler
  • machinery than had been usual before, are always regarded as advantageous
  • to every society. A certain quantity of materials, and the labour of a
  • certain number of workmen, which had before been employed in supporting a
  • more complex and expensive machinery, can afterwards be applied to augment
  • the quantity of work which that or any other machinery is useful only for
  • performing. The undertaker of some great manufactory, who employs a
  • thousand a-year in the maintenance of his machinery, if he can reduce this
  • expense to five hundred, will naturally employ the other five hundred in
  • purchasing an additional quantity of materials, to be wrought up by an
  • additional number of workmen. The quantity of that work, therefore, which
  • his machinery was useful only for performing, will naturally be augmented,
  • and with it all the advantage and conveniency which the society can derive
  • from that work.
  • The expense of maintaining the fixed capital in a great country, may very
  • properly be compared to that of repairs in a private estate. The expense
  • of repairs may frequently be necessary for supporting the produce of the
  • estate, and consequently both the gross and the neat rent of the landlord.
  • When by a more proper direction, however, it can be diminished without
  • occasioning any diminution of produce, the gross rent remains at least the
  • same as before, and the neat rent is necessarily augmented.
  • But though the whole expense of maintaining the fixed capital is thus
  • necessarily excluded from the neat revenue of the society, it is not the
  • same case with that of maintaining the circulating capital. Of the four
  • parts of which this latter capital is composed, money, provisions,
  • materials, and finished work, the three last, it has already been
  • observed, are regularly withdrawn from it, and placed either in the fixed
  • capital of the society, or in their stock reserved for immediate
  • consumption. Whatever portion of those consumable goods is not employed in
  • maintaining the former, goes all to the latter, and makes a part of the
  • neat revenue of the society. The maintenance of those three parts of the
  • circulating capital, therefore, withdraws no portion of the annual produce
  • from the neat revenue of the society, besides what is necessary for
  • maintaining the fixed capital.
  • The circulating capital of a society is in this respect different from
  • that of an individual. That of an individual is totally excluded from
  • making any part of his neat revenue, which must consist altogether in his
  • profits. But though the circulating capital of every individual makes a
  • part of that of the society to which he belongs, it is not upon that
  • account totally excluded from making a part likewise of their neat
  • revenue. Though the whole goods in a merchant’s shop must by no means be
  • placed in his own stock reserved for immediate consumption, they may in
  • that of other people, who, from a revenue derived from other funds, may
  • regularly replace their value to him, together with its profits, without
  • occasioning any diminution either of his capital or of theirs.
  • Money, therefore, is the only part of the circulating capital of a
  • society, of which the maintenance can occasion any diminution in their
  • neat revenue.
  • The fixed capital, and that part of the circulating capital which consists
  • in money, so far as they affect the revenue of the society, bear a very
  • great resemblance to one another.
  • First, as those machines and instruments of trade, etc. require a certain
  • expense, first to erect them, and afterwards to support them, both which
  • expenses, though they make a part of the gross, are deductions from the
  • neat revenue of the society; so the stock of money which circulates in any
  • country must require a certain expense, first to collect it, and
  • afterwards to support it; both which expenses, though they make a part of
  • the gross, are, in the same manner, deductions from the neat revenue of
  • the society. A certain quantity of very valuable materials, gold and
  • silver, and of very curious labour, instead of augmenting the stock
  • reserved for immediate consumption, the subsistence, conveniencies, and
  • amusements of individuals, is employed in supporting that great but
  • expensive instrument of commerce, by means of which every individual in
  • the society has his subsistence, conveniencies, and amusements, regularly
  • distributed to him in their proper proportions.
  • Secondly, as the machines and instruments of trade, etc. which compose the
  • fixed capital either of an individual or of a society, make no part either
  • of the gross or of the neat revenue of either; so money, by means of which
  • the whole revenue of the society is regularly distributed among all its
  • different members, makes itself no part of that revenue. The great wheel
  • of circulation is altogether different from the goods which are circulated
  • by means of it. The revenue of the society consists altogether in those
  • goods, and not in the wheel which circulates them. In computing either the
  • gross or the neat revenue of any society, we must always, from the whole
  • annual circulation of money and goods, deduct the whole value of the
  • money, of which not a single farthing can ever make any part of either.
  • It is the ambiguity of language only which can make this proposition
  • appear either doubtful or paradoxical. When properly explained and
  • understood, it is almost self-evident.
  • When we talk of any particular sum of money, we sometimes mean nothing but
  • the metal pieces of which it is composed, and sometimes we include in our
  • meaning some obscure reference to the goods which can be had in exchange
  • for it, or to the power of purchasing which the possession of it conveys.
  • Thus, when we say that the circulating money of England has been computed
  • at eighteen millions, we mean only to express the amount of the metal
  • pieces, which some writers have computed, or rather have supposed, to
  • circulate in that country. But when we say that a man is worth fifty or a
  • hundred pounds a-year, we mean commonly to express, not only the amount of
  • the metal pieces which are annually paid to him, but the value of the
  • goods which he can annually purchase or consume; we mean commonly to
  • ascertain what is or ought to be his way of living, or the quantity and
  • quality of the necessaries and conveniencies of life in which he can with
  • propriety indulge himself.
  • When, by any particular sum of money, we mean not only to express the
  • amount of the metal pieces of which it is composed, but to include in its
  • signification some obscure reference to the goods which can be had in
  • exchange for them, the wealth or revenue which it in this case denotes, is
  • equal only to one of the two values which are thus intimated somewhat
  • ambiguously by the same word, and to the latter more properly than to the
  • former, to the money’s worth more properly than to the money.
  • Thus, if a guinea be the weekly pension of a particular person, he can in
  • the course of the week purchase with it a certain quantity of subsistence,
  • conveniencies, and amusements. In proportion as this quantity is great or
  • small, so are his real riches, his real weekly revenue. His weekly revenue
  • is certainly not equal both to the guinea and to what can be purchased
  • with it, but only to one or other of those two equal values, and to the
  • latter more properly than to the former, to the guinea’s worth rather than
  • to the guinea.
  • If the pension of such a person was paid to him, not in gold, but in a
  • weekly bill for a guinea, his revenue surely would not so properly consist
  • in the piece of paper, as in what he could get for it. A guinea may be
  • considered as a bill for a certain quantity of necessaries and
  • conveniencies upon all the tradesmen in the neighbourhood. The revenue of
  • the person to whom it is paid, does not so properly consist in the piece
  • of gold, as in what he can get for it, or in what he can exchange it for.
  • If it could be exchanged for nothing, it would, like a bill upon a
  • bankrupt, be of no more value than the most useless piece of paper.
  • Though the weekly or yearly revenue of all the different inhabitants of
  • any country, in the same manner, may be, and in reality frequently is,
  • paid to them in money, their real riches, however, the real weekly or
  • yearly revenue of all of them taken together, must always be great or
  • small, in proportion to the quantity of consumable goods which they can
  • all of them purchase with this money. The whole revenue of all of them
  • taken together is evidently not equal to both the money and the consumable
  • goods, but only to one or other of those two values, and to the latter
  • more properly than to the former.
  • Though we frequently, therefore, express a person’s revenue by the metal
  • pieces which are annually paid to him, it is because the amount of those
  • pieces regulates the extent of his power of purchasing, or the value of
  • the goods which he can annually afford to consume. We still consider his
  • revenue as consisting in this power of purchasing or consuming, and not in
  • the pieces which convey it.
  • But if this is sufficiently evident, even with regard to an individual, it
  • is still more so with regard to a society. The amount of the metal pieces
  • which are annually paid to an individual, is often precisely equal to his
  • revenue, and is upon that account the shortest and best expression of its
  • value. But the amount of the metal pieces which circulate in a society,
  • can never be equal to the revenue of all its members. As the same guinea
  • which pays the weekly pension of one man to-day, may pay that of another
  • to-morrow, and that of a third the day thereafter, the amount of the metal
  • pieces which annually circulate in any country, must always be of much
  • less value than the whole money pensions annually paid with them. But the
  • power of purchasing, or the goods which can successively be bought with
  • the whole of those money pensions, as they are successively paid, must
  • always be precisely of the same value with those pensions; as must
  • likewise be the revenue of the different persons to whom they are paid.
  • That revenue, therefore, cannot consist in those metal pieces, of which
  • the amount is so much inferior to its value, but in the power of
  • purchasing, in the goods which can successively be bought with them as
  • they circulate from hand to hand.
  • Money, therefore, the great wheel of circulation, the great instrument of
  • commerce, like all other instruments of trade, though it makes a part, and
  • a very valuable part, of the capital, makes no part of the revenue of the
  • society to which it belongs; and though the metal pieces of which it is
  • composed, in the course of their annual circulation, distribute to every
  • man the revenue which properly belongs to him, they make themselves no
  • part of that revenue.
  • Thirdly, and lastly, the machines and instruments of trade, etc. which
  • compose the fixed capital, bear this further resemblance to that part of
  • the circulating capital which consists in money; that as every saving in
  • the expense of erecting and supporting those machines, which does not
  • diminish the introductive powers of labour, is an improvement of the neat
  • revenue of the society; so every saving in the expense of collecting and
  • supporting that part of the circulating capital which consists in money is
  • an improvement of exactly the same kind.
  • It is sufficiently obvious, and it has partly, too, been explained
  • already, in what manner every saving in the expense of supporting the
  • fixed capital is an improvement of the neat revenue of the society. The
  • whole capital of the undertaker of every work is necessarily divided
  • between his fixed and his circulating capital. While his whole capital
  • remains the same, the smaller the one part, the greater must necessarily
  • be the other. It is the circulating capital which furnishes the materials
  • and wages of labour, and puts industry into motion. Every saving,
  • therefore, in the expense of maintaining the fixed capital, which does not
  • diminish the productive powers of labour, must increase the fund which
  • puts industry into motion, and consequently the annual produce of land and
  • labour, the real revenue of every society.
  • The substitution of paper in the room of gold and silver money, replaces a
  • very expensive instrument of commerce with one much less costly, and
  • sometimes equally convenient. Circulation comes to be carried on by a new
  • wheel, which it costs less both to erect and to maintain than the old one.
  • But in what manner this operation is performed, and in what manner it
  • tends to increase either the gross or the neat revenue of the society, is
  • not altogether so obvious, and may therefore require some further
  • explication.
  • There are several different sorts of paper money; but the circulating
  • notes of banks and bankers are the species which is best known, and which
  • seems best adapted for this purpose.
  • When the people of any particular country have such confidence in the
  • fortune, probity and prudence of a particular banker, as to believe that
  • he is always ready to pay upon demand such of his promissory notes as are
  • likely to be at any time presented to him, those notes come to have the
  • same currency as gold and silver money, from the confidence that such
  • money can at any time be had for them.
  • A particular banker lends among his customers his own promissory notes, to
  • the extent, we shall suppose, of a hundred thousand pounds. As those notes
  • serve all the purposes of money, his debtors pay him the same interest as
  • if he had lent them so much money. This interest is the source of his
  • gain. Though some of those notes are continually coming back upon him for
  • payment, part of them continue to circulate for months and years together.
  • Though he has generally in circulation, therefore, notes to the extent of
  • a hundred thousand pounds, twenty thousand pounds in gold and silver may,
  • frequently, be a sufficient provision for answering occasional demands. By
  • this operation, therefore, twenty thousand pounds in gold and silver
  • perform all the functions which a hundred thousand could otherwise have
  • performed. The same exchanges may be made, the same quantity of consumable
  • goods may be circulated and distributed to their proper consumers, by
  • means of his promissory notes, to the value of a hundred thousand pounds,
  • as by an equal value of gold and silver money. Eighty thousand pounds of
  • gold and silver, therefore, can in this manner be spared from the
  • circulation of the country; and if different operations of the the same
  • kind should, at the same time, be carried on by many different banks and
  • bankers, the whole circulation may thus be conducted with a fifth part
  • only of the gold and silver which would otherwise have been requisite.
  • Let us suppose, for example, that the whole circulating money of some
  • particular country amounted, at a particular time, to one million
  • sterling, that sum being then sufficient for circulating the whole annual
  • produce of their land and labour; let us suppose, too, that some time
  • thereafter, different banks and bankers issued promissory notes payable to
  • the bearer, to the extent of one million, reserving in their different
  • coffers two hundred thousand pounds for answering occasional demands;
  • there would remain, therefore, in circulation, eight hundred thousand
  • pounds in gold and silver, and a million of bank notes, or eighteen
  • hundred thousand pounds of paper and money together. But the annual
  • produce of the land and labour of the country had before required only one
  • million to circulate and distribute it to its proper consumers, and that
  • annual produce cannot be immediately augmented by those operations of
  • banking. One million, therefore, will be sufficient to circulate it after
  • them. The goods to be bought and sold being precisely the same as before,
  • the same quantity of money will be sufficient for buying and selling them.
  • The channel of circulation, if I may be allowed such an expression, will
  • remain precisely the same as before. One million we have supposed
  • sufficient to fill that channel. Whatever, therefore, is poured into it
  • beyond this sum, cannot run into it, but must overflow. One million eight
  • hundred thousand pounds are poured into it. Eight hundred thousand pounds,
  • therefore, must overflow, that sum being over and above what can be
  • employed in the circulation of the country. But though this sum cannot be
  • employed at home, it is too valuable to be allowed to lie idle. It will,
  • therefore, be sent abroad, in order to seek that profitable employment
  • which it cannot find at home. But the paper cannot go abroad; because at a
  • distance from the banks which issue it, and from the country in which
  • payment of it can be exacted by law, it will not be received in common
  • payments. Gold and silver, therefore, to the amount of eight hundred
  • thousand pounds, will be sent abroad, and the channel of home circulation
  • will remain filled with a million of paper instead of a million of those
  • metals which filled it before.
  • But though so great a quantity of gold and silver is thus sent abroad, we
  • must not imagine that it is sent abroad for nothing, or that its
  • proprietors make a present of it to foreign nations. They will exchange it
  • for foreign goods of some kind or another, in order to supply the
  • consumption either of some other foreign country, or of their own.
  • If they employ it in purchasing goods in one foreign country, in order to
  • supply the consumption of another, or in what is called the carrying
  • trade, whatever profit they make will be in addition to the neat revenue
  • of their own country. It is like a new fund, created for carrying on a new
  • trade; domestic business being now transacted by paper, and the gold and
  • silver being converted into a fund for this new trade.
  • If they employ it in purchasing foreign goods for home consumption, they
  • may either, first, purchase such goods as are likely to be consumed by
  • idle people, who produce nothing, such as foreign wines, foreign silks,
  • etc.; or, secondly, they may purchase an additional stock of materials,
  • tools, and provisions, in order to maintain and employ an additional
  • number of industrious people, who reproduce, with a profit, the value of
  • their annual consumption.
  • So far as it is employed in the first way, it promotes prodigality,
  • increases expense and consumption, without increasing production, or
  • establishing any permanent fund for supporting that expense, and is in
  • every respect hurtful to the society.
  • So far as it is employed in the second way, it promotes industry; and
  • though it increases the consumption of the society, it provides a
  • permanent fund for supporting that consumption; the people who consume
  • reproducing, with a profit, the whole value of their annual consumption.
  • The gross revenue of the society, the annual produce of their land and
  • labour, is increased by the whole value which the labour of those workmen
  • adds to the materials upon which they are employed, and their neat revenue
  • by what remains of this value, after deducting what is necessary for
  • supporting the tools and instruments of their trade.
  • That the greater part of the gold and silver which being forced abroad by
  • those operations of banking, is employed in purchasing foreign goods for
  • home consumption, is, and must be, employed in purchasing those of this
  • second kind, seems not only probable, but almost unavoidable. Though some
  • particular men may sometimes increase their expense very considerably,
  • though their revenue does not increase at all, we maybe assured that no
  • class or order of men ever does so; because, though the principles of
  • common prudence do not always govern the conduct of every individual, they
  • always influence that of the majority of every class or order. But the
  • revenue of idle people, considered as a class or order, cannot, in the
  • smallest degree, be increased by those operations of banking. Their
  • expense in general, therefore, cannot be much increased by them, though
  • that of a few individuals among them may, and in reality sometimes is. The
  • demand of idle people, therefore, for foreign goods, being the same, or
  • very nearly the same as before, a very small part of the money which,
  • being forced abroad by those operations of banking, is employed in
  • purchasing foreign goods for home consumption, is likely to be employed in
  • purchasing those for their use. The greater part of it will naturally be
  • destined for the employment of industry, and not for the maintenance of
  • idleness.
  • When we compute the quantity of industry which the circulating capital of
  • any society can employ, we must always have regard to those parts of it
  • only which consist in provisions, materials, and finished work; the other,
  • which consists in money, and which serves only to circulate those three,
  • must always be deducted. In order to put industry into motion, three
  • things are requisite; materials to work upon, tools to work with, and the
  • wages or recompence for the sake of which the work is done. Money is
  • neither a material to work upon, nor a tool to work with; and though the
  • wages of the workman are commonly paid to him in money, his real revenue,
  • like that of all other men, consists, not in the money, but in the money’s
  • worth; not in the metal pieces, but in what can be got for them.
  • The quantity of industry which any capital can employ, must evidently be
  • equal to the number of workmen whom it can supply with materials, tools,
  • and a maintenance suitable to the nature of the work. Money may be
  • requisite for purchasing the materials and tools of the work, as well as
  • the maintenance of the workmen; but the quantity of industry which the
  • whole capital can employ, is certainly not equal both to the money which
  • purchases, and to the materials, tools, and maintenance, which are
  • purchased with it, but only to one or other of those two values, and to
  • the latter more properly than to the former.
  • When paper is substituted in the room of gold and silver money, the
  • quantity of the materials, tools, and maintenance, which the whole
  • circulating capital can supply, may be increased by the whole value of
  • gold and silver which used to be employed in purchasing them. The whole
  • value of the great wheel of circulation and distribution is added to the
  • goods which are circulated and distributed by means of it. The operation,
  • in some measure, resembles that of the undertaker of some great work, who,
  • in consequence of some improvement in mechanics, takes down his old
  • machinery, and adds the difference between its price and that of the new
  • to his circulating capital, to the fund from which he furnishes materials
  • and wages to his workmen.
  • What is the proportion which the circulating money of any country bears to
  • the whole value of the annual produce circulated by means of it, it is
  • perhaps impossible to determine. It has been computed by different authors
  • at a fifth, at a tenth, at a twentieth, and at a thirtieth, part of that
  • value. But how small soever the proportion which the circulating money may
  • bear to the whole value of the annual produce, as but a part, and
  • frequently but a small part, of that produce, is ever destined for the
  • maintenance of industry, it must always bear a very considerable
  • proportion to that part. When, therefore, by the substitution of paper,
  • the gold and silver necessary for circulation is reduced to, perhaps, a
  • fifth part of the former quantity, if the value of only the greater part
  • of the other four-fifths be added to the funds which are destined for the
  • maintenance of industry, it must make a very considerable addition to the
  • quantity of that industry, and, consequently, to the value of the annual
  • produce of land and labour.
  • An operation of this kind has, within these five-and-twenty or thirty
  • years, been performed in Scotland, by the erection of new banking
  • companies in almost every considerable town, and even in some country
  • villages. The effects of it have been precisely those above described. The
  • business of the country is almost entirely carried on by means of the
  • paper of those different banking companies, with which purchases and
  • payments of all kinds are commonly made. Silver very seldom appears,
  • except in the change of a twenty shilling bank note, and gold still
  • seldomer. But though the conduct of all those different companies has not
  • been unexceptionable, and has accordingly required an act of parliament to
  • regulate it, the country, notwithstanding, has evidently derived great
  • benefit from their trade. I have heard it asserted, that the trade of the
  • city of Glasgow doubled in about fifteen years after the first erection of
  • the banks there; and that the trade of Scotland has more than quadrupled
  • since the first erection of the two public banks at Edinburgh; of which
  • the one, called the Bank of Scotland, was established by act of parliament
  • in 1695, and the other, called the Royal Bank, by royal charter in 1727.
  • Whether the trade, either of Scotland in general, or of the city of
  • Glasgow in particular, has really increased in so great a proportion,
  • during so short a period, I do not pretend to know. If either of them has
  • increased in this proportion, it seems to be an effect too great to be
  • accounted for by the sole operation of this cause. That the trade and
  • industry of Scotland, however, have increased very considerably during
  • this period, and that the banks have contributed a good deal to this
  • increase, cannot be doubted.
  • The value of the silver money which circulated in Scotland before the
  • Union in 1707, and which, immediately after it, was brought into the Bank
  • of Scotland, in order to be recoined, amounted to £411,117: 10: 9
  • sterling. No account has been got of the gold coin; but it appears from
  • the ancient accounts of the mint of Scotland, that the value of the gold
  • annually coined somewhat exceeded that of the silver. There were a good
  • many people, too, upon this occasion, who, from a diffidence of repayment,
  • did not bring their silver into the Bank of Scotland; and there was,
  • besides, some English coin, which was not called in. The whole value of
  • the gold and silver, therefore, which circulated in Scotland before the
  • Union, cannot be estimated at less than a million sterling. It seems to
  • have constituted almost the whole circulation of that country; for though
  • the circulation of the Bank of Scotland, which had then no rival, was
  • considerable, it seems to have made but a very small part of the whole. In
  • the present times, the whole circulation of Scotland cannot be estimated
  • at less than two millions, of which that part which consists in gold and
  • silver, most probably, does not amount to half a million. But though the
  • circulating gold and silver of Scotland have suffered so great a
  • diminution during this period, its real riches and prosperity do not
  • appear to have suffered any. Its agriculture, manufactures, and trade, on
  • the contrary, the annual produce of its land and labour, have evidently
  • been augmented.
  • It is chiefly by discounting bills of exchange, that is, by advancing
  • money upon them before they are due, that the greater part of banks and
  • bankers issue their promissory notes. They deduct always, upon whatever
  • sum they advance, the legal interest till the bill shall become due. The
  • payment of the bill, when it becomes due, replaces to the bank the value
  • of what had been advanced, together with a clear profit of the interest.
  • The banker, who advances to the merchant whose bill he discounts, not gold
  • and silver, but his own promissory notes, has the advantage of being able
  • to discount to a greater amount by the whole value of his promissory
  • notes, which he finds, by experience, are commonly in circulation. He is
  • thereby enabled to make his clear gain of interest on so much a larger
  • sum.
  • The commerce of Scotland, which at present is not very great, was still
  • more inconsiderable when the two first banking companies were established;
  • and those companies would have had but little trade, had they confined
  • their business to the discounting of bills of exchange. They invented,
  • therefore, another method of issuing their promissory notes; by granting
  • what they call cash accounts, that is, by giving credit, to the extent of
  • a certain sum (two or three thousand pounds for example), to any
  • individual who could procure two persons of undoubted credit and good
  • landed estate to become surety for him, that whatever money should be
  • advanced to him, within the sum for which the credit had been given,
  • should be repaid upon demand, together with the legal interest. Credits of
  • this kind are, I believe, commonly granted by banks and bankers in all
  • different parts of the world. But the easy terms upon which the Scotch
  • banking companies accept of repayment are, so far as I know, peculiar to
  • them, and have perhaps been the principal cause, both of the great trade
  • of those companies, and of the benefit which the country has received from
  • it.
  • Whoever has a credit of this kind with one of those companies, and borrows
  • a thousand pounds upon it, for example, may repay this sum piece-meal, by
  • twenty and thirty pounds at a time, the company discounting a
  • proportionable part of the interest of the great sum, from the day on
  • which each of those small sums is paid in, till the whole be in this
  • manner repaid. All merchants, therefore, and almost all men of business,
  • find it convenient to keep such cash accounts with them, and are thereby
  • interested to promote the trade of those companies, by readily receiving
  • their notes in all payments, and by encouraging all those with whom they
  • have any influence to do the same. The banks, when their customers apply
  • to them for money, generally advance it to them in their own promissory
  • notes. These the merchants pay away to the manufacturers for goods, the
  • manufacturers to the farmers for materials and provisions, the farmers to
  • their landlords for rent; the landlords repay them to the merchants for
  • the conveniencies and luxuries with which they supply them, and the
  • merchants again return them to the banks, in order to balance their cash
  • accounts, or to replace what they my have borrowed of them; and thus
  • almost the whole money business of the country is transacted by means of
  • them. Hence the great trade of those companies.
  • By means of those cash accounts, every merchant can, without imprudence,
  • carry on a greater trade than he otherwise could do. If there are two
  • merchants, one in London and the other in Edinburgh, who employ equal
  • stocks in the same branch of trade, the Edinburgh merchant can, without
  • imprudence, carry on a greater trade, and give employment to a greater
  • number of people, than the London merchant. The London merchant must
  • always keep by him a considerable sum of money, either in his own coffers,
  • or in those of his banker, who gives him no interest for it, in order to
  • answer the demands continually coming upon him for payment of the goods
  • which he purchases upon credit. Let the ordinary amount of this sum be
  • supposed five hundred pounds; the value of the goods in his warehouse must
  • always be less, by five hundred pounds, than it would have been, had he
  • not been obliged to keep such a sum unemployed. Let us suppose that he
  • generally disposes of his whole stock upon hand, or of goods to the value
  • of his whole stock upon hand, once in the year. By being obliged to keep
  • so great a sum unemployed, he must sell in a year five hundred pounds
  • worth less goods than he might otherwise have done. His annual profits
  • must be less by all that he could have made by the sale of five hundred
  • pounds worth more goods; and the number of people employed in preparing
  • his goods for the market must be less by all those that five hundred
  • pounds more stock could have employed. The merchant in Edinburgh, on the
  • other hand, keeps no money unemployed for answering such occasional
  • demands. When they actually come upon him, he satisfies them from his cash
  • account with the bank, and gradually replaces the sum borrowed with the
  • money or paper which comes in from the occasional sales of his goods. With
  • the same stock, therefore, he can, without imprudence, have at all times
  • in his warehouse a larger quantity of goods than the London merchant; and
  • can thereby both make a greater profit himself, and give constant
  • employment to a greater number of industrious people who prepare those
  • goods for the market. Hence the great benefit which the country has
  • derived from this trade.
  • The facility of discounting bills of exchange, it may be thought, indeed,
  • gives the English merchants a conveniency equivalent to the cash accounts
  • of the Scotch merchants. But the Scotch merchants, it must be remembered,
  • can discount their bills of exchange as easily as the English merchants;
  • and have, besides, the additional conveniency of their cash accounts.
  • The whole paper money of every kind which can easily circulate in any
  • country, never can exceed the value of the gold and silver, of which it
  • supplies the place, or which (the commerce being supposed the same) would
  • circulate there, if there was no paper money. If twenty shilling notes,
  • for example, are the lowest paper money current in Scotland, the whole of
  • that currency which can easily circulate there, cannot exceed the sum of
  • gold and silver which would be necessary for transacting the annual
  • exchanges of twenty shillings value and upwards usually transacted within
  • that country. Should the circulating paper at any time exceed that sum, as
  • the excess could neither be sent abroad nor be employed in the circulation
  • of the country, it must immediately return upon the banks, to be exchanged
  • for gold and silver. Many people would immediately perceive that they had
  • more of this paper than was necessary for transacting their business at
  • home; and as they could not send it abroad, they would immediately demand
  • payment for it from the banks. When this superfluous paper was converted
  • into gold and silver, they could easily find a use for it, by sending it
  • abroad; but they could find none while it remained in the shape of paper.
  • There would immediately, therefore, be a run upon the banks to the whole
  • extent of this superfluous paper, and if they showed any difficulty or
  • backwardness in payment, to a much greater extent; the alarm which this
  • would occasion necessarily increasing the run.
  • Over and above the expenses which are common to every branch of trade,
  • such as the expense of house-rent, the wages of servants, clerks,
  • accountants, etc. the expenses peculiar to a bank consist chiefly in two
  • articles: first, in the expense of keeping at all times in its coffers,
  • for answering the occasional demands of the holders of its notes, a large
  • sum of money, of which it loses the interest; and, secondly, in the
  • expense of replenishing those coffers as fast as they are emptied by
  • answering such occasional demands.
  • A banking company which issues more paper than can be employed in the
  • circulation of the country, and of which the excess is continually
  • returning upon them for payment, ought to increase the quantity of gold
  • and silver which they keep at all times in their coffers, not only in
  • proportion to this excessive increase of their circulation, but in a much
  • greater proportion; their notes returning upon them much faster than in
  • proportion to the excess of their quantity. Such a company, therefore,
  • ought to increase the first article of their expense, not only in
  • proportion to this forced increase of their business, but in a much
  • greater proportion.
  • The coffers of such a company, too, though they ought to be filled much
  • fuller, yet must empty themselves much faster than if their business was
  • confined within more reasonable bounds, and must require not only a more
  • violent, but a more constant and uninterrupted exertion of expense, in
  • order to replenish them, The coin, too, which is thus continually drawn in
  • such large quantities from their coffers, cannot be employed in the
  • circulation of the country. It comes in place of a paper which is over and
  • above what can be employed in that circulation, and is, therefore, over
  • and above what can be employed in it too. But as that coin will not be
  • allowed to lie idle, it must, in one shape or another, be sent abroad, in
  • order to find that profitable employment which it cannot find at home; and
  • this continual exportation of gold and silver, by enhancing the
  • difficulty, must necessarily enhance still farther the expense of the
  • bank, in finding new gold and silver in order to replenish those coffers,
  • which empty themselves so very rapidly. Such a company, therefore, must in
  • proportion to this forced increase of their business, increase the second
  • article of their expense still more than the first.
  • Let us suppose that all the paper of a particular bank, which the
  • circulation of the country can easily absorb and employ, amounts exactly
  • to forty thousand pounds, and that, for answering occasional demands, this
  • bank is obliged to keep at all times in its coffers ten thousand pounds in
  • gold and silver. Should this bank attempt to circulate forty-four thousand
  • pounds, the four thousand pounds which are over and above what the
  • circulation can easily absorb and employ, will return upon it almost as
  • fast as they are issued. For answering occasional demands, therefore, this
  • bank ought to keep at all times in its coffers, not eleven thousand pounds
  • only, but fourteen thousand pounds. It will thus gain nothing by the
  • interest of the four thousand pounds excessive circulation; and it will
  • lose the whole expense of continually collecting four thousand pounds in
  • gold and silver, which will be continually going out of its coffers as
  • fast as they are brought into them.
  • Had every particular banking company always understood and attended to its
  • own particular interest, the circulation never could have been overstocked
  • with paper money. But every particular banking company has not always
  • understood or attended to its own particular interest, and the circulation
  • has frequently been overstocked with paper money.
  • By issuing too great a quantity of paper, of which the excess was
  • continually returning, in order to be exchanged for gold and silver, the
  • Bank of England was for many years together obliged to coin gold to the
  • extent of between eight hundred thousand pounds and a million a-year; or,
  • at an average, about eight hundred and fifty thousand pounds. For this
  • great coinage, the bank (inconsequence of the worn and degraded state into
  • which the gold coin had fallen a few years ago) was frequently obliged to
  • purchase gold bullion at the high price of four pounds an ounce, which it
  • soon after issued in coin at £3:17:10 1/2 an ounce, losing in this manner
  • between two and a half and three per cent. upon the coinage of so very
  • large a sum. Though the bank, therefore, paid no seignorage, though the
  • government was properly at the expense of this coinage, this liberality of
  • government did not prevent altogether the expense of the bank.
  • The Scotch banks, in consequence of an excess of the same kind, were all
  • obliged to employ constantly agents at London to collect money for them,
  • at an expense which was seldom below one and a half or two per cent. This
  • money was sent down by the waggon, and insured by the carriers at an
  • additional expense of three quarters per cent. or fifteen shillings on the
  • hundred pounds. Those agents were not always able to replenish the coffers
  • of their employers so fast as they were emptied. In this case, the
  • resource of the banks was, to draw upon their correspondents in London
  • bills of exchange, to the extent of the sum which they wanted. When those
  • correspondents afterwards drew upon them for the payment of this sum,
  • together with the interest and commission, some of those banks, from the
  • distress into which their excessive circulation had thrown them, had
  • sometimes no other means of satisfying this draught, but by drawing a
  • second set of bills, either upon the same, or upon some other
  • correspondents in London; and the same sum, or rather bills for the same
  • sum, would in this manner make sometimes more than two or three journeys;
  • the debtor bank paying always the interest and commission upon the whole
  • accumulated sum. Even those Scotch banks which never distinguished
  • themselves by their extreme imprudence, were sometimes obliged to employ
  • this ruinous resource.
  • The gold coin which was paid out, either by the Bank of England or by the
  • Scotch banks, in exchange for that part of their paper which was over and
  • above what could be employed in the circulation of the country, being
  • likewise over and above what could be employed in that circulation, was
  • sometimes sent abroad in the shape of coin, sometimes melted down and sent
  • abroad in the shape of bullion, and sometimes melted down and sold to the
  • Bank of England at the high price of four pounds an ounce. It was the
  • newest, the heaviest, and the best pieces only, which were carefully
  • picked out of the whole coin, and either sent abroad or melted down. At
  • home, and while they remained in the shape of coin, those heavy pieces
  • were of no more value than the light; but they were of more value abroad,
  • or when melted down into bullion at home. The Bank of England,
  • notwithstanding their great annual coinage, found, to their astonishment,
  • that there was every year the same scarcity of coin as there had been the
  • year before; and that, notwithstanding the great quantity of good and new
  • coin which was every year issued from the bank, the state of the coin,
  • instead of growing better and better, became every year worse and worse.
  • Every year they found themselves under the necessity of coining nearly the
  • same quantity of gold as they had coined the year before; and from the
  • continual rise in the price of gold bullion, in consequence of the
  • continual wearing and clipping of the coin, the expense of this great
  • annual coinage became, every year, greater and greater. The Bank of
  • England, it is to be observed, by supplying its own coffers with coin, is
  • indirectly obliged to supply the whole kingdom, into which coin is
  • continually flowing from those coffers in a great variety of ways.
  • Whatever coin, therefore, was wanted to support this excessive circulation
  • both of Scotch and English paper money, whatever vacuities this excessive
  • circulation occasioned in the necessary coin of the kingdom, the Bank of
  • England was obliged to supply them. The Scotch banks, no doubt, paid all
  • of them very dearly for their own imprudence and inattention: but the Bank
  • of England paid very dearly, not only for its own imprudence, but for the
  • much greater imprudence of almost all the Scotch banks.
  • The over-trading of some bold projectors in both parts of the united
  • kingdom, was the original cause of this excessive circulation of paper
  • money.
  • What a bank can with propriety advance to a merchant or undertaker of any
  • kind, is not either the whole capital with which he trades, or even any
  • considerable part of that capital; but that part of it only which he would
  • otherwise be obliged to keep by him unemployed and in ready money, for
  • answering occasional demands. If the paper money which the bank advances
  • never exceeds this value, it can never exceed the value of the gold and
  • silver which would necessarily circulate in the country if there was no
  • paper money; it can never exceed the quantity which the circulation of the
  • country can easily absorb and employ.
  • When a bank discounts to a merchant a real bill of exchange, drawn by a
  • real creditor upon a real debtor, and which, as soon as it becomes due, is
  • really paid by that debtor; it only advances to him a part of the value
  • which he would otherwise be obliged to keep by him unemployed and in ready
  • money, for answering occasional demands. The payment of the bill, when it
  • becomes due, replaces to the bank the value of what it had advanced,
  • together with the interest. The coffers of the bank, so far as its
  • dealings are confined to such customers, resemble a water-pond, from
  • which, though a stream is continually running out, yet another is
  • continually running in, fully equal to that which runs out; so that,
  • without any further care or attention, the pond keeps always equally, or
  • very near equally full. Little or no expense can ever be necessary for
  • replenishing the coffers of such a bank.
  • A merchant, without over-trading, may frequently have occasion for a sum
  • of ready money, even when he has no bills to discount. When a bank,
  • besides discounting his bills, advances him likewise, upon such occasions,
  • such sums upon his cash account, and accepts of a piece-meal repayment, as
  • the money comes in from the occasional sale of his goods, upon the easy
  • terms of the banking companies of Scotland; it dispenses him entirely from
  • the necessity of keeping any part of his stock by him unemployed and in
  • ready money for answering occasional demands. When such demands actually
  • come upon him, he can answer them sufficiently from his cash account. The
  • bank, however, in dealing with such customers, ought to observe with great
  • attention, whether, in the course of some short period (of four, five,
  • six, or eight months, for example), the sum of the repayments which it
  • commonly receives from them, is, or is not, fully equal to that of the
  • advances which it commonly makes to them. If, within the course of such
  • short periods, the sum of the repayments from certain customers is, upon
  • most occasions, fully equal to that of the advances, it may safely
  • continue to deal with such customers. Though the stream which is in this
  • case continually running out from its coffers may be very large, that
  • which is continually running into them must be at least equally large, so
  • that, without any further care or attention, those coffers are likely to
  • be always equally or very near equally full, and scarce ever to require
  • any extraordinary expense to replenish them. If, on the contrary, the sum
  • of the repayments from certain other customers, falls commonly very much
  • short of the advances which it makes to them, it cannot with any safety
  • continue to deal with such customers, at least if they continue to deal
  • with it in this manner. The stream which is in this case continually
  • running out from its coffers, is necessarily much larger than that which
  • is continually running in; so that, unless they are replenished by some
  • great and continual effort of expense, those coffers must soon be
  • exhausted altogether.
  • The banking companies of Scotland, accordingly, were for a long time very
  • careful to require frequent and regular repayments from all their
  • customers, and did not care to deal with any person, whatever might be his
  • fortune or credit, who did not make, what they called, frequent and
  • regular operations with them. By this attention, besides saving almost
  • entirely the extraordinary expense of replenishing their coffers, they
  • gained two other very considerable advantages.
  • First, by this attention they were enabled to make some tolerable judgment
  • concerning the thriving or declining circumstances of their debtors,
  • without being obliged to look out for any other evidence besides what
  • their own books afforded them; men being, for the most part, either
  • regular or irregular in their repayments, according as their circumstances
  • are either thriving or declining. A private man who lends out his money to
  • perhaps half a dozen or a dozen of debtors, may, either by himself or his
  • agents, observe and inquire both constantly and carefully into the conduct
  • and situation of each of them. But a banking company, which lends money to
  • perhaps five hundred different people, and of which the attention is
  • continually occupied by objects of a very different kind, can have no
  • regular information concerning the conduct and circumstances of the
  • greater part of its debtors, beyond what its own books afford it. In
  • requiring frequent and regular repayments from all their customers, the
  • banking companies of Scotland had probably this advantage in view.
  • Secondly, by this attention they secured themselves from the possibility
  • of issuing more paper money than what the circulation of the country could
  • easily absorb and employ. When they observed, that within moderate periods
  • of time, the repayments of a particular customer were, upon most
  • occasions, fully equal to the advances which they had made to him, they
  • might be assured that the paper money which they had advanced to him had
  • not, at any time, exceeded the quantity of gold and silver which he would
  • otherwise have been obliged to keep by him for answering occasional
  • demands; and that, consequently, the paper money, which they had
  • circulated by his means, had not at any time exceeded the quantity of gold
  • and silver which would have circulated in the country, had there been no
  • paper money. The frequency, regularity, and amount of his repayments,
  • would sufficiently demonstrate that the amount of their advances had at no
  • time exceeded that part of his capital which he would otherwise have been
  • obliged to keep by him unemployed, and in ready money, for answering
  • occasional demands; that is, for the purpose of keeping the rest of his
  • capital in constant employment. It is this part of his capital only which,
  • within moderate periods of time, is continually returning to every dealer
  • in the shape of money, whether paper or coin, and continually going from
  • him in the same shape. If the advances of the bank had commonly exceeded
  • this part of his capital, the ordinary amount of his repayments could not,
  • within moderate periods of time, have equalled the ordinary amount of its
  • advances. The stream which, by means of his dealings, was continually
  • running into the coffers of the bank, could not have been equal to the
  • stream which, by means of the same dealings was continually running out.
  • The advances of the bank paper, by exceeding the quantity of gold and
  • silver which, had there been no such advances, he would have been obliged
  • to keep by him for answering occasional demands, might soon come to exceed
  • the whole quantity of gold and silver which ( the commerce being supposed
  • the same ) would have circulated in the country, had there been no paper
  • money; and, consequently, to exceed the quantity which the circulation of
  • the country could easily absorb and employ; and the excess of this paper
  • money would immediately have returned upon the bank, in order to be
  • exchanged for gold and silver. This second advantage, though equally real,
  • was not, perhaps, so well understood by all the different banking
  • companies in Scotland as the first.
  • When, partly by the conveniency of discounting bills, and partly by that
  • of cash accounts, the creditable traders of any country can be dispensed
  • from the necessity of keeping any part of their stock by them unemployed,
  • and in ready money, for answering occasional demands, they can reasonably
  • expect no farther assistance from hanks and bankers, who, when they have
  • gone thus far, cannot, consistently with their own interest and safety, go
  • farther. A bank cannot, consistently with its own interest, advance to a
  • trader the whole, or even the greater part of the circulating capital with
  • which he trades; because, though that capital is continually returning to
  • him in the shape of money, and going from him in the same shape, yet the
  • whole of the returns is too distant from the whole of the outgoings, and
  • the sum of his repayments could not equal the sum of his advances within
  • such moderate periods of time as suit the conveniency of a bank. Still
  • less could a bank afford to advance him any considerable part of his fixed
  • capital; of the capital which the undertaker of an iron forge, for
  • example, employs in erecting his forge and smelting-houses, his
  • work-houses, and warehouses, the dwelling-houses of his workmen, etc.; of
  • the capital which the undertaker of a mine employs in sinking his shafts,
  • in erecting engines for drawing out the water, in making roads and
  • waggon-ways, etc.; of the capital which the person who undertakes to
  • improve land employs in clearing, draining, inclosing, manuring, and
  • ploughing waste and uncultivated fields; in building farmhouses, with all
  • their necessary appendages of stables, granaries, etc. The returns of the
  • fixed capital are, in almost all cases, much slower than those of the
  • circulating capital: and such expenses, even when laid out with the
  • greatest prudence and judgment, very seldom return to the undertaker till
  • after a period of many years, a period by far too distant to suit the
  • conveniency of a bank. Traders and other undertakers may, no doubt with
  • great propriety, carry on a very considerable part of their projects with
  • borrowed money. In justice to their creditors, however, their own capital
  • ought in this case to be sufficient to insure, if I may say so, the
  • capital of those creditors; or to render it extremely improbable that
  • those creditors should incur any loss, even though the success of the
  • project should fall very much short of the expectation of the projectors.
  • Even with this precaution, too, the money which is borrowed, and which it
  • is meant should not be repaid till after a period of several years, ought
  • not to be borrowed of a bank, but ought to be borrowed upon bond or
  • mortgage, of such private people as propose to live upon the interest of
  • their money, without taking the trouble themselves to employ the capital,
  • and who are, upon that account, willing to lend that capital to such
  • people of good credit as are likely to keep it for several years. A bank,
  • indeed, which lends its money without the expense of stamped paper, or of
  • attorneys’ fees for drawing bonds and mortgages, and which accepts of
  • repayment upon the easy terms of the banking companies of Scotland, would,
  • no doubt, be a very convenient creditor to such traders and undertakers.
  • But such traders and undertakers would surely be most inconvenient debtors
  • to such a bank.
  • It is now more than five and twenty years since the paper money issued by
  • the different banking companies of Scotland was fully equal, or rather was
  • somewhat more than fully equal, to what the circulation of the country
  • could easily absorb and employ. Those companies, therefore, had so long
  • ago given all the assistance to the traders and other undertakers of
  • Scotland which it is possible for banks and bankers, consistently with
  • their own interest, to give. They had even done somewhat more. They had
  • over-traded a little, and had brought upon themselves that loss, or at
  • least that diminution of profit, which, in this particular business, never
  • fails to attend the smallest degree of over-trading. Those traders and
  • other undertakers, having got so much assistance from banks and bankers,
  • wished to get still more. The banks, they seem to have thought, could
  • extend their credits to whatever sum might be wanted, without incurring
  • any other expense besides that of a few reams of paper. They complained of
  • the contracted views and dastardly spirit of the directors of those banks,
  • which did not, they said, extend their credits in proportion to the
  • extension of the trade of the country; meaning, no doubt, by the extension
  • of that trade, the extension of their own projects beyond what they could
  • carry on either with their own capital, or with what they had credit to
  • borrow of private people in the usual way of bond or mortgage. The banks,
  • they seem to have thought, were in honour bound to supply the deficiency,
  • and to provide them with all the capital which they wanted to trade with.
  • The banks, however, were of a different opinion; and upon their refusing
  • to extend their credits, some of those traders had recourse to an
  • expedient which, for a time, served their purpose, though at a much
  • greater expense, yet as effectually as the utmost extension of bank
  • credits could have done. This expedient was no other than the well known
  • shift of drawing and redrawing; the shift to which unfortunate traders
  • have sometimes recourse, when they are upon the brink of bankruptcy. The
  • practice of raising money in this manner had been long known in England;
  • and, during the course of the late war, when the high profits of trade
  • afforded a great temptation to over-trading, is said to have been carried
  • on to a very great extent. From England it was brought into Scotland,
  • where, in proportion to the very limited commerce, and to the very
  • moderate capital of the country, it was soon carried on to a much greater
  • extent than it ever had been in England.
  • The practice of drawing and redrawing is so well known to all men of
  • business, that it may, perhaps, be thought unnecessary to give any account
  • of it. But as this book may come into the hands of many people who are not
  • men of business, and as the effects of this practice upon the banking
  • trade are not, perhaps, generally understood, even by men of business
  • themselves, I shall endeavour to explain it as distinctly as I can.
  • The customs of merchants, which were established when the barbarous laws
  • of Europe did not enforce the performance of their contracts, and which,
  • during the course of the two last centuries, have been adopted into the
  • laws of all European nations, have given such extraordinary privileges to
  • bills of exchange, that money is more readily advanced upon them than upon
  • any other species of obligation; especially when they are made payable
  • within so short a period as two or three months after their date. If, when
  • the bill becomes due, the acceptor does not pay it as soon as it is
  • presented, he becomes from that moment a bankrupt. The bill is protested,
  • and returns upon the drawer, who, if he does not immediately pay it,
  • becomes likewise a bankrupt. If, before it came to the person who presents
  • it to the acceptor for payment, it had passed through the hands of several
  • other persons, who had successively advanced to one another the contents
  • of it, either in money or goods, and who, to express that each of them had
  • in his turn received those contents, had all of them in their order
  • indorsed, that is, written their names upon the back of the bill; each
  • indorser becomes in his turn liable to the owner of the bill for those
  • contents, and, if he fails to pay, he becomes too, from that moment, a
  • bankrupt. Though the drawer, acceptor, and indorsers of the bill, should
  • all of them be persons of doubtful credit; yet, still the shortness of the
  • date gives some security to the owner of the bill. Though all of them may
  • be very likely to become bankrupts, it is a chance if they all become so
  • in so short a time. The house is crazy, says a weary traveller to himself,
  • and will not stand very long; but it is a chance if it falls to-night, and
  • I will venture, therefore, to sleep in it to-night.
  • The trader A in Edinburgh, we shall suppose, draws a bill upon B in
  • London, payable two months after date. In reality B in London owes nothing
  • to A in Edinburgh; but he agrees to accept of A’s bill, upon condition,
  • that before the term of payment he shall redraw upon A in Edinburgh for
  • the same sum, together with the interest and a commission, another bill,
  • payable likewise two months after date. B accordingly, before the
  • expiration of the first two months, redraws this bill upon A in Edinburgh;
  • who, again before the expiration of the second two months, draws a second
  • bill upon B in London, payable likewise two months after date; and before
  • the expiration of the third two months, B in London redraws upon A in
  • Edinburgh another bill payable also two months after date. This practice
  • has sometimes gone on, not only for several months, but for several years
  • together, the bill always returning upon A in Edinburgh with the
  • accumulated interest and commission of all the former bills. The interest
  • was five per cent. in the year, and the commission was never less than one
  • half per cent. on each draught. This commission being repeated more than
  • six times in the year, whatever money A might raise by this expedient
  • might necessarily have cost him something more than eight per cent. in the
  • year and sometimes a great deal more, when either the price of the
  • commission happened to rise, or when he was obliged to pay compound
  • interest upon the interest and commission of former bills. This practice
  • was called raising money by circulation.
  • In a country where the ordinary profits of stock, in the greater part of
  • mercantile projects, are supposed to run between six and ten per cent. it
  • must have been a very fortunate speculation, of which the returns could
  • not only repay the enormous expense at which the money was thus borrowed
  • for carrying it on, but afford, besides, a good surplus profit to the
  • projector. Many vast and extensive projects, however, were undertaken, and
  • for several years carried on, without any other fund to support them
  • besides what was raised at this enormous expense. The projectors, no
  • doubt, had in their golden dreams the most distinct vision of this great
  • profit. Upon their awakening, however, either at the end of their
  • projects, or when they were no longer able to carry them on, they very
  • seldom, I believe, had the good fortune to find it.
  • {The method described in the text was by no means either the most common
  • or the most expensive one in which those adventurers sometimes raised
  • money by circulation. It frequently happened, that A in Edinburgh would
  • enable B in London to pay the first bill of exchange, by drawing, a few
  • days before it became due, a second bill at three months date upon the
  • same B in London. This bill, being payable to his own order, A sold in
  • Edinburgh at par; and with its contents purchased bills upon London,
  • payable at sight to the order of B, to whom he sent them by the post.
  • Towards the end of the late war, the exchange between Edinburgh and London
  • was frequently three per cent. against Edinburgh, and those bills at sight
  • must frequently have cost A that premium. This transaction, therefore,
  • being repeated at least four times in the year, and being loaded with a
  • commission of at least one half per cent. upon each repetition, must at
  • that period have cost A, at least, fourteen per cent. in the year. At
  • other times A would enable to discharge the first bill of exchange, by
  • drawing, a few days before it became due, a second bill at two months
  • date, not upon B, but upon some third person, C, for example, in London.
  • This other bill was made payable to the order of B, who, upon its being
  • accepted by C, discounted it with some banker in London; and A enabled C
  • to discharge it, by drawing, a few day’s before it became due, a third
  • bill likewise at two months date, sometimes upon his first correspondent
  • B, and sometimes upon some fourth or fifth person, D or E, for example.
  • This third bill was made payable to the order of C, who, as soon as it was
  • accepted, discounted it in the same manner with some banker in London.
  • Such operations being repeated at least six times in the year, and being
  • loaded with a commission of at least one half per cent. upon each
  • repetition, together with the legal interest of five per cent. this method
  • of raising money, in the same manner as that described in the text, must
  • have cost A something more than eight per cent. By saving, however, the
  • exchange between Edinburgh and London, it was less expensive than that
  • mentioned in the foregoing part of this note; but then it required an
  • established credit with more houses than one in London, an advantage which
  • many of these adventurers could not always find it easy to procure.}
  • The bills which A in Edinburgh drew upon B in London, he regularly
  • discounted two months before they were due, with some bank or banker in
  • Edinburgh; and the bills which B in London redrew upon A in Edinburgh, he
  • as regularly discounted, either with the Bank of England, or with some
  • other banker in London. Whatever was advanced upon such circulating bills
  • was in Edinburgh advanced in the paper of the Scotch banks; and in London,
  • when they were discounted at the Bank of England in the paper of that
  • bank. Though the bills upon which this paper had been advanced were all of
  • them repaid in their turn as soon as they became due, yet the value which
  • had been really advanced upon the first bill was never really returned to
  • the banks which advanced it; because, before each bill became due, another
  • bill was always drawn to somewhat a greater amount than the bill which was
  • soon to be paid: and the discounting of this other bill was essentially
  • necessary towards the payment of that which was soon to be due. This
  • payment, therefore, was altogether fictitious. The stream which, by means
  • of those circulating bills of exchange, had once been made to run out from
  • the coffers of the banks, was never replaced by any stream which really
  • ran into them.
  • The paper which was issued upon those circulating bills of exchange
  • amounted, upon many occasions, to the whole fund destined for carrying on
  • some vast and extensive project of agriculture, commerce, or manufactures;
  • and not merely to that part of it which, had there been no paper money,
  • the projector would have been obliged to keep by him unemployed, and in
  • ready money, for answering occasional demands. The greater part of this
  • paper was, consequently, over and above the value of the gold and silver
  • which would have circulated in the country, had there been no paper money.
  • It was over and above, therefore, what the circulation of the country
  • could easily absorb and employ, and upon that account, immediately
  • returned upon the banks, in order to be exchanged for gold and silver,
  • which they were to find as they could. It was a capital which those
  • projectors had very artfully contrived to draw from those banks, not only
  • without their knowledge or deliberate consent, but for some time, perhaps,
  • without their having the most distant suspicion that they had really
  • advanced it.
  • When two people, who are continually drawing and redrawing upon one
  • another, discount their bills always with the same banker, he must
  • immediately discover what they are about, and see clearly that they are
  • trading, not with any capital of their own, but with the capital which he
  • advances to them. But this discovery is not altogether so easy when they
  • discount their bills sometimes with one banker, and sometimes with
  • another, and when the two same persons do not constantly draw and redraw
  • upon one another, but occasionally run the round of a great circle of
  • projectors, who find it for their interest to assist one another in this
  • method of raising money and to render it, upon that account, as difficult
  • as possible to distinguish between a real and a fictitious bill of
  • exchange, between a bill drawn by a real creditor upon a real debtor, and
  • a bill for which there was properly no real creditor but the bank which
  • discounted it, nor any real debtor but the projector who made use of the
  • money. When a banker had even made this discovery, he might sometimes make
  • it too late, and might find that he had already discounted the bills of
  • those projectors to so great an extent, that, by refusing to discount any
  • more, he would necessarily make them all bankrupts; and thus by ruining
  • them, might perhaps ruin himself. For his own interest and safety,
  • therefore, he might find it necessary, in this very perilous situation, to
  • go on for some time, endeavouring, however, to withdraw gradually, and,
  • upon that account, making every day greater and greater difficulties about
  • discounting, in order to force these projectors by degrees to have
  • recourse, either to other bankers, or to other methods of raising money:
  • so as that he himself might, as soon as possible, get out of the circle.
  • The difficulties, accordingly, which the Bank of England, which the
  • principal bankers in London, and which even the more prudent Scotch banks
  • began, after a certain time, and when all of them had already gone too
  • far, to make about discounting, not only alarmed, but enraged, in the
  • highest degree, those projectors. Their own distress, of which this
  • prudent and necessary reserve of the banks was, no doubt, the immediate
  • occasion, they called the distress of the country; and this distress of
  • the country, they said, was altogether owing to the ignorance,
  • pusillanimity, and bad conduct of the banks, which did not give a
  • sufficiently liberal aid to the spirited undertakings of those who exerted
  • themselves in order to beautify, improve, and enrich the country. It was
  • the duty of the banks, they seemed to think, to lend for as long a time,
  • and to as great an extent, as they might wish to borrow. The banks,
  • however, by refusing in this manner to give more credit to those to whom
  • they had already given a great deal too much, took the only method by
  • which it was now possible to save either their own credit, or the public
  • credit of the country.
  • In the midst of this clamour and distress, a new bank was established in
  • Scotland, for the express purpose of relieving the distress of the
  • country. The design was generous; but the execution was imprudent, and the
  • nature and causes of the distress which it meant to relieve, were not,
  • perhaps, well understood. This bank was more liberal than any other had
  • ever been, both in granting cash-accounts, and in discounting bills of
  • exchange. With regard to the latter, it seems to have made scarce any
  • distinction between real and circulating bills, but to have discounted all
  • equally. It was the avowed principle of this bank to advance upon any
  • reasonable security, the whole capital which was to be employed in those
  • improvements of which the returns are the most slow and distant, such as
  • the improvements of land. To promote such improvements was even said to be
  • the chief of the public-spirited purposes for which it was instituted. By
  • its liberality in granting cash-accounts, and in discounting bills of
  • exchange, it, no doubt, issued great quantities of its bank notes. But
  • those bank notes being, the greater part of them, over and above what the
  • circulation of the country could easily absorb and employ, returned upon
  • it, in order to be exchanged for gold and silver, as fast as they were
  • issued. Its coffers were never well filled. The capital which had been
  • subscribed to this bank, at two different subscriptions, amounted to one
  • hundred and sixty thousand pounds, of which eighty per cent. only was paid
  • up. This sum ought to have been paid in at several different instalments.
  • A great part of the proprietors, when they paid in their first instalment,
  • opened a cash-account with the bank; and the directors, thinking
  • themselves obliged to treat their own proprietors with the same liberality
  • with which they treated all other men, allowed many of them to borrow upon
  • this cash-account what they paid in upon all their subsequent instalments.
  • Such payments, therefore, only put into one coffer what had the moment
  • before been taken out of another. But had the coffers of this bank been
  • filled ever so well, its excessive circulation must have emptied them
  • faster than they could have been replenished by any other expedient but
  • the ruinous one of drawing upon London; and when the bill became due,
  • paying it, together with interest and commission, by another draught upon
  • the same place. Its coffers having been filled so very ill, it is said to
  • have been driven to this resource within a very few months after it began
  • to do business. The estates of the proprietors of this bank were worth
  • several millions, and, by their subscription to the original bond or
  • contract of the bank, were really pledged for answering all its
  • engagements. By means of the great credit which so great a pledge
  • necessarily gave it, it was, notwithstanding its too liberal conduct,
  • enabled to carry on business for more than two years. When it was obliged
  • to stop, it had in the circulation about two hundred thousand pounds in
  • bank notes. In order to support the circulation of those notes, which were
  • continually returning upon it as fast as they were issued, it had been
  • constantly in the practice of drawing bills of exchange upon London, of
  • which the number and value were continually increasing, and, when it
  • stopt, amounted to upwards of six hundred thousand pounds. This bank,
  • therefore, had, in little more than the course of two years, advanced to
  • different people upwards of eight hundred thousand pounds at five per
  • cent. Upon the two hundred thousand pounds which it circulated in bank
  • notes, this five per cent. might perhaps be considered as a clear gain,
  • without any other deduction besides the expense of management. But upon
  • upwards of six hundred thousand pounds, for which it was continually
  • drawing bills of exchange upon London, it was paying, in the way of
  • interest and commission, upwards of eight per cent. and was consequently
  • losing more than three per cent. upon more than three fourths of all its
  • dealings.
  • The operations of this bank seem to have produced effects quite opposite
  • to those which were intended by the particular persons who planned and
  • directed it. They seem to have intended to support the spirited
  • undertakings, for as such they considered them, which were at that time
  • carrying on in different parts of the country; and, at the same time, by
  • drawing the whole banking business to themselves, to supplant all the
  • other Scotch banks, particularly those established at Edinburgh, whose
  • backwardness in discounting bills of exchange had given some offence. This
  • bank, no doubt, gave some temporary relief to those projectors, and
  • enabled them to carry on their projects for about two years longer than
  • they could otherwise have done. But it thereby only enabled them to get so
  • much deeper into debt; so that, when ruin came, it fell so much the
  • heavier both upon them and upon their creditors. The operations of this
  • bank, therefore, instead of relieving, in reality aggravated in the
  • long-run the distress which those projectors had brought both upon
  • themselves and upon their country. It would have been much better for
  • themselves, their creditors, and their country, had the greater part of
  • them been obliged to stop two years sooner than they actually did. The
  • temporary relief, however, which this bank afforded to those projectors,
  • proved a real and permanent relief to the other Scotch banks. All the
  • dealers in circulating bills of exchange, which those other banks had
  • become so backward in discounting, had recourse to this new bank, where
  • they were received with open arms. Those other banks, therefore, were
  • enabled to get very easily out of that fatal circle, from which they could
  • not otherwise have disengaged themselves without incurring a considerable
  • loss, and perhaps, too, even some degree of discredit.
  • In the long-run, therefore, the operations of this bank increased the real
  • distress of the country, which it meant to relieve; and effectually
  • relieved, from a very great distress, those rivals whom it meant to
  • supplant.
  • At the first setting out of this bank, it was the opinion of some people,
  • that how fast soever its coffers might be emptied, it might easily
  • replenish them, by raising money upon the securities of those to whom it
  • had advanced its paper. Experience, I believe, soon convinced them that
  • this method of raising money was by much too slow to answer their purpose;
  • and that coffers which originally were so ill filled, and which emptied
  • themselves so very fast, could be replenished by no other expedient but
  • the ruinous one of drawing bills upon London, and when they became due,
  • paying them by other draughts on the same place, with accumulated interest
  • and commission. But though they had been able by this method to raise
  • money as fast as they wanted it, yet, instead of making a profit, they
  • must have suffered a loss of every such operation; so that in the long-run
  • they must have ruined themselves as a mercantile company, though perhaps
  • not so soon as by the more expensive practice of drawing and redrawing.
  • They could still have made nothing by the interest of the paper, which,
  • being over and above what the circulation of the country could absorb and
  • employ, returned upon them in order to be exchanged for gold and silver,
  • as fast as they issued it; and for the payment of which they were
  • themselves continually obliged to borrow money. On the contrary, the whole
  • expense of this borrowing, of employing agents to look out for people who
  • had money to lend, of negotiating with those people, and of drawing the
  • proper bond or assignment, must have fallen upon them, and have been so
  • much clear loss upon the balance of their accounts. The project of
  • replenishing their coffers in this manner may be compared to that of a man
  • who had a water-pond from which a stream was continually running out, and
  • into which no stream was continually running, but who proposed to keep it
  • always equally full, by employing a number of people to go continually
  • with buckets to a well at some miles distance, in order to bring water to
  • replenish it.
  • But though this operation had proved not only practicable, but profitable
  • to the bank, as a mercantile company; yet the country could have derived
  • no benefit front it, but, on the contrary, must have suffered a very
  • considerable loss by it. This operation could not augment, in the smallest
  • degree, the quantity of money to be lent. It could only have erected this
  • bank into a sort of general loan office for the whole country. Those who
  • wanted to borrow must have applied to this bank, instead of applying to
  • the private persons who had lent it their money. But a bank which lends
  • money, perhaps to five hundred different people, the greater part of whom
  • its directors can know very little about, is not likely to be more
  • judicious in the choice of its debtors than a private person who lends out
  • his money among a few people whom he knows, and in whose sober and frugal
  • conduct he thinks he has good reason to confide. The debtors of such a
  • bank as that whose conduct I have been giving some account of were likely,
  • the greater part of them, to be chimerical projectors, the drawers and
  • redrawers of circulating bills of exchange, who would employ the money in
  • extravagant undertakings, which, with all the assistance that could be
  • given them, they would probably never be able to complete, and which, if
  • they should be completed, would never repay the expense which they had
  • really cost, would never afford a fund capable of maintaining a quantity
  • of labour equal to that which had been employed about them. The sober and
  • frugal debtors of private persons, on the contrary, would be more likely
  • to employ the money borrowed in sober undertakings which were proportioned
  • to their capitals, and which, though they might have less of the grand and
  • the marvellous, would have more of the solid and the profitable; which
  • would repay with a large profit whatever had been laid out upon them, and
  • which would thus afford a fund capable of maintaining a much greater
  • quantity of labour than that which had been employed about them. The
  • success of this operation, therefore, without increasing in the smallest
  • degree the capital of the country, would only have transferred a great
  • part of it from prudent and profitable to imprudent and unprofitable
  • undertakings.
  • That the industry of Scotland languished for want of money to employ it,
  • was the opinion of the famous Mr Law. By establishing a bank of a
  • particular kind, which he seems to have imagined might issue paper to the
  • amount of the whole value of all the lands in the country, he proposed to
  • remedy this want of money. The parliament of Scotland, when he first
  • proposed his project, did not think proper to adopt it. It was afterwards
  • adopted, with some variations, by the Duke of Orleans, at that time regent
  • of France. The idea of the possibility of multiplying paper money to
  • almost any extent was the real foundation of what is called the
  • Mississippi scheme, the most extravagant project, both of banking and
  • stock-jobbing, that perhaps the world ever saw. The different operations
  • of this scheme are explained so fully, so clearly, and with so much order
  • and distinctness, by Mr Du Verney, in his Examination of the Political
  • Reflections upon commerce and finances of Mr Du Tot, that I shall not give
  • any account of them. The principles upon which it was founded are
  • explained by Mr Law himself, in a discourse concerning money and trade,
  • which he published in Scotland when he first proposed his project. The
  • splendid but visionary ideas which are set forth in that and some other
  • works upon the same principles, still continue to make an impression upon
  • many people, and have, perhaps, in part, contributed to that excess of
  • banking, which has of late been complained of, both in Scotland and in
  • other places.
  • The Bank of England is the greatest bank of circulation in Europe. It was
  • incorporated, in pursuance of an act of parliament, by a charter under the
  • great seal, dated the 27th of July 1694. It at that time advanced to
  • government the sum of £1,200,000 for an annuity of £100,000, or for £
  • 96,000 a-year, interest at the rate of eight per cent. and £4,000 year for
  • the expense of management. The credit of the new government, established
  • by the Revolution, we may believe, must have been very low, when it was
  • obliged to borrow at so high an interest.
  • In 1697, the bank was allowed to enlarge its capital stock, by an
  • ingraftment of £1,001,171:10s. Its whole capital stock, therefore,
  • amounted at this time to £2,201,171: 10s. This ingraftment is said to have
  • been for the support of public credit. In 1696, tallies had been at forty,
  • and fifty, and sixty, per cent. discount, and bank notes at twenty per
  • cent. {James Postlethwaite’s History of the Public Revenue, p.301.} During
  • the great re-coinage of the silver, which was going on at this time, the
  • bank had thought proper to discontinue the payment of its notes, which
  • necessarily occasioned their discredit.
  • In pursuance of the 7th Anne, c. 7, the bank advanced and paid into the
  • exchequer the sum of £400,000; making in all the sum of £1,600,000, which
  • it had advanced upon its original annuity of £96,000 interest, and £4,000
  • for expense of management. In 1708, therefore, the credit of government
  • was as good as that of private persons, since it could borrow at six per
  • cent. interest, the common legal and market rate of those times. In
  • pursuance of the same act, the bank cancelled exchequer bills to the
  • amount of £ 1,775,027: 17s: 10½d. at six per cent. interest, and was at
  • the same time allowed to take in subscriptions for doubling its capital.
  • In 1703, therefore, the capital of the bank amounted to £4,402,343; and it
  • had advanced to government the sum of £3,375,027:17:10½d.
  • By a call of fifteen per cent. in 1709, there was paid in, and made stock,
  • £ 656,204:1:9d.; and by another of ten per cent. in 1710, £501,448:12:11d.
  • In consequence of those two calls, therefore, the bank capital amounted to
  • £ 5,559,995:14:8d.
  • In pursuance of the 3rd George I. c.8, the bank delivered up two millions
  • of exchequer Bills to be cancelled. It had at this time, therefore,
  • advanced to government £5,375,027:17 10d. In pursuance of the 8th George
  • I. c.21, the bank purchased of the South-sea company, stock to the amount
  • of £4,000,000: and in 1722, in consequence of the subscriptions which it
  • had taken in for enabling it to make this purchase, its capital stock was
  • increased by £ 3,400,000. At this time, therefore, the bank had advanced
  • to the public £ 9,375,027 17s. 10½d.; and its capital stock amounted only
  • to £ 8,959,995:14:8d. It was upon this occasion that the sum which the
  • bank had advanced to the public, and for which it received interest, began
  • first to exceed its capital stock, or the sum for which it paid a dividend
  • to the proprietors of bank stock; or, in other words, that the bank began
  • to have an undivided capital, over and above its divided one. It has
  • continued to have an undivided capital of the same kind ever since. In
  • 1746, the bank had, upon different occasions, advanced to the public
  • £11,686,800, and its divided capital had been raised by different calls
  • and subscriptions to £ 10,780,000. The state of those two sums has
  • continued to be the same ever since. In pursuance of the 4th of George
  • III. c.25, the bank agreed to pay to government for the renewal of its
  • charter £110,000, without interest or re-payment. This sum, therefore did
  • not increase either of those two other sums.
  • The dividend of the bank has varied according to the variations in the
  • rate of the interest which it has, at different times, received for the
  • money it had advanced to the public, as well as according to other
  • circumstances. This rate of interest has gradually been reduced from eight
  • to three per cent. For some years past, the bank dividend has been at five
  • and a half per cent.
  • The stability of the bank of England is equal to that of the British
  • government. All that it has advanced to the public must be lost before its
  • creditors can sustain any loss. No other banking company in England can be
  • established by act of parliament, or can consist of more than six members.
  • It acts, not only as an ordinary bank, but as a great engine of state. It
  • receives and pays the greater part of the annuities which are due to the
  • creditors of the public; it circulates exchequer bills; and it advances to
  • government the annual amount of the land and malt taxes, which are
  • frequently not paid up till some years thereafter. In these different
  • operations, its duty to the public may sometimes have obliged it, without
  • any fault of its directors, to overstock the circulation with paper money.
  • It likewise discounts merchants’ bills, and has, upon several different
  • occasions, supported the credit of the principal houses, not only of
  • England, but of Hamburgh and Holland. Upon one occasion, in 1763, it is
  • said to have advanced for this purpose, in one week, about £1,600,000, a
  • great part of it in bullion. I do not, however, pretend to warrant either
  • the greatness of the sum, or the shortness of the time. Upon other
  • occasions, this great company has been reduced to the necessity of paying
  • in sixpences.
  • It is not by augmenting the capital of the country, but by rendering a
  • greater part of that capital active and productive than would otherwise be
  • so, that the most judicious operations of banking can increase the
  • industry of the country. That part of his capital which a dealer is
  • obliged to keep by him unemployed and in ready money, for answering
  • occasional demands, is so much dead stock, which, so long as it remains in
  • this situation, produces nothing, either to him or to his country. The
  • judicious operations of banking enable him to convert this dead stock into
  • active and productive stock; into materials to work upon; into tools to
  • work with; and into provisions and subsistence to work for; into stock
  • which produces something both to himself and to his country. The gold and
  • silver money which circulates in any country, and by means of which, the
  • produce of its land and labour is annually circulated and distributed to
  • the proper consumers, is, in the same manner as the ready money of the
  • dealer, all dead stock. It is a very valuable part of the capital of the
  • country, which produces nothing to the country. The judicious operations
  • of banking, by substituting paper in the room of a great part of this gold
  • and silver, enable the country to convert a great part of this dead stock
  • into active and productive stock; into stock which produces something to
  • the country. The gold and silver money which circulates in any country may
  • very properly be compared to a highway, which, while it circulates and
  • carries to market all the grass and corn of the country, produces itself
  • not a single pile of either. The judicious operations of banking, by
  • providing, if I may be allowed so violent a metaphor, a sort of waggon-way
  • through the air, enable the country to convert, as it were, a great part
  • of its highways into good pastures, and corn fields, and thereby to
  • increase, very considerably, the annual produce of its land and labour.
  • The commerce and industry of the country, however, it must be
  • acknowledged, though they may be somewhat augmented, cannot be altogether
  • so secure, when they are thus, as it were, suspended upon the Daedalian
  • wings of paper money, as when they travel about upon the solid ground of
  • gold and silver. Over and above the accidents to which they are exposed
  • from the unskilfulness of the conductors of this paper money, they are
  • liable to several others, from which no prudence or skill of those
  • conductors can guard them.
  • An unsuccessful war, for example, in which the enemy got possession of the
  • capital, and consequently of that treasure which supported the credit of
  • the paper money, would occasion a much greater confusion in a country
  • where the whole circulation was carried on by paper, than in one where the
  • greater part of it was carried on by gold and silver. The usual instrument
  • of commerce having lost its value, no exchanges could be made but either
  • by barter or upon credit. All taxes having been usually paid in paper
  • money, the prince would not have wherewithal either to pay his troops, or
  • to furnish his magazines; and the state of the country would be much more
  • irretrievable than if the greater part of its circulation had consisted in
  • gold and silver. A prince, anxious to maintain his dominions at all times
  • in the state in which he can most easily defend them, ought upon this
  • account to guard not only against that excessive multiplication of paper
  • money which ruins the very banks which issue it, but even against that
  • multiplication of it which enables them to fill the greater part of the
  • circulation of the country with it.
  • The circulation of every country may be considered as divided into two
  • different branches; the circulation of the dealers with one another, and
  • the circulation between the dealers and the consumers. Though the same
  • pieces of money, whether paper or metal, may be employed sometimes in the
  • one circulation and sometimes in the other; yet as both are constantly
  • going on at the same time, each requires a certain stock of money, of one
  • kind or another, to carry it on. The value of the goods circulated between
  • the different dealers never can exceed the value of those circulated
  • between the dealers and the consumers; whatever is bought by the dealers
  • being ultimately destined to be sold to the consumers. The circulation
  • between the dealers, as it is carried on by wholesale, requires generally
  • a pretty large sum for every particular transaction. That between the
  • dealers and the consumers, on the contrary, as it is generally carried on
  • by retail, frequently requires but very small ones, a shilling, or even a
  • halfpenny, being often sufficient. But small sums circulate much faster
  • than large ones. A shilling changes masters more frequently than a guinea,
  • and a halfpenny more frequently than a shilling. Though the annual
  • purchases of all the consumers, therefore, are at least equal in value to
  • those of all the dealers, they can generally be transacted with a much
  • smaller quantity of money; the same pieces, by a more rapid circulation,
  • serving as the instrument of many more purchases of the one kind than of
  • the other.
  • Paper money may be so regulated as either to confine itself very much to
  • the circulation between the different dealers, or to extend itself
  • likewise to a great part of that between the dealers and the consumers.
  • Where no bank notes are circulated under £10 value, as in London, paper
  • money confines itself very much to the circulation between the dealers.
  • When a ten pound bank note comes into the hands of a consumer, he is
  • generally obliged to change it at the first shop where he has occasion to
  • purchase five shillings worth of goods; so that it often returns into the
  • hands of a dealer before the consumer has spent the fortieth part of the
  • money. Where bank notes are issued for so small sums as 20s. as in
  • Scotland, paper money extends itself to a considerable part of the
  • circulation between dealers and consumers. Before the Act of parliament
  • which put a stop to the circulation of ten and five shilling notes, it
  • filled a still greater part of that circulation. In the currencies of
  • North America, paper was commonly issued for so small a sum as a shilling,
  • and filled almost the whole of that circulation. In some paper currencies
  • of Yorkshire, it was issued even for so small a sum as a sixpence.
  • Where the issuing of bank notes for such very small sums is allowed, and
  • commonly practised, many mean people are both enabled and encouraged to
  • become bankers. A person whose promissory note for £5, or even for 20s.
  • would be rejected by every body, will get it to be received without
  • scruple when it is issued for so small a sum as a sixpence. But the
  • frequent bankruptcies to which such beggarly bankers must be liable, may
  • occasion a very considerable inconveniency, and sometimes even a very
  • great calamity, to many poor people who had received their notes in
  • payment.
  • It were better, perhaps, that no bank notes were issued in any part of the
  • kingdom for a smaller sum than £5. Paper money would then, probably,
  • confine itself, in every part of the kingdom, to the circulation between
  • the different dealers, as much as it does at present in London, where no
  • bank notes are issued under £10 value; £5 being, in most part of the
  • kingdom, a sum which, though it will purchase, perhaps, little more than
  • half the quantity of goods, is as much considered, and is as seldom spent
  • all at once, as £10 are amidst the profuse expense of London.
  • Where paper money, it is to be observed, is pretty much confined to the
  • circulation between dealers and dealers, as at London, there is always
  • plenty of gold and silver. Where it extends itself to a considerable part
  • of the circulation between dealers and consumers, as in Scotland, and
  • still more in North America, it banishes gold and silver almost entirely
  • from the country; almost all the ordinary transactions of its interior
  • commerce being thus carried on by paper. The suppression of ten and five
  • shilling bank notes, somewhat relieved the scarcity of gold and silver in
  • Scotland; and the suppression of twenty shilling notes will probably
  • relieve it still more. Those metals are said to have become more abundant
  • in America, since the suppression of some of their paper currencies. They
  • are said, likewise, to have been more abundant before the institution of
  • those currencies.
  • Though paper money should be pretty much confined to the circulation
  • between dealers and dealers, yet banks and bankers might still be able to
  • give nearly the same assistance to the industry and commerce of the
  • country, as they had done when paper money filled almost the whole
  • circulation. The ready money which a dealer is obliged to keep by him, for
  • answering occasional demands, is destined altogether for the circulation
  • between himself and other dealers of whom he buys goods. He has no
  • occasion to keep any by him for the circulation between himself and the
  • consumers, who are his customers, and who bring ready money to him,
  • instead of taking any from him. Though no paper money, therefore, was
  • allowed to be issued, but for such sums as would confine it pretty much to
  • the circulation between dealers and dealers; yet partly by discounting
  • real bills of exchange, and partly by lending upon cash-accounts, banks
  • and bankers might still be able to relieve the greater part of those
  • dealers from the necessity of keeping any considerable part of their stock
  • by them unemployed, and in ready money, for answering occasional demands.
  • They might still be able to give the utmost assistance which banks and
  • bankers can with propriety give to traders of every kind.
  • To restrain private people, it may be said, from receiving in payment the
  • promissory notes of a banker for any sum, whether great or small, when
  • they themselves are willing to receive them; or, to restrain a banker from
  • issuing such notes, when all his neighbours are willing to accept of them,
  • is a manifest violation of that natural liberty, which it is the proper
  • business of law not to infringe, but to support. Such regulations may, no
  • doubt, be considered as in some respect a violation of natural liberty.
  • But those exertions of the natural liberty of a few individuals, which
  • might endanger the security of the whole society, are, and ought to be,
  • restrained by the laws of all governments; of the most free, as well as or
  • the most despotical. The obligation of building party walls, in order to
  • prevent the communication of fire, is a violation of natural liberty,
  • exactly of the same kind with the regulations of the banking trade which
  • are here proposed.
  • A paper money, consisting in bank notes, issued by people of undoubted
  • credit, payable upon demand, without any condition, and, in fact, always
  • readily paid as soon as presented, is, in every respect, equal in value to
  • gold and silver money, since gold and silver money can at anytime be had
  • for it. Whatever is either bought or sold for such paper, must necessarily
  • be bought or sold as cheap as it could have been for gold and silver.
  • The increase of paper money, it has been said, by augmenting the quantity,
  • and consequently diminishing the value, of the whole currency, necessarily
  • augments the money price of commodities. But as the quantity of gold and
  • silver, which is taken from the currency, is always equal to the quantity
  • of paper which is added to it, paper money does not necessarily increase
  • the quantity of the whole currency. From the beginning of the last century
  • to the present time, provisions never were cheaper in Scotland than in
  • 1759, though, from the circulation of ten and five shilling bank notes,
  • there was then more paper money in the country than at present. The
  • proportion between the price of provisions in Scotland and that in England
  • is the same now as before the great multiplication of banking companies in
  • Scotland. Corn is, upon most occasions, fully as cheap in England as in
  • France, though there is a great deal of paper money in England, and scarce
  • any in France. In 1751 and 1752, when Mr Hume published his Political
  • Discourses, and soon after the great multiplication of paper money in
  • Scotland, there was a very sensible rise in the price of provisions,
  • owing, probably, to the badness of the seasons, and not to the
  • multiplication of paper money.
  • It would be otherwise, indeed, with a paper money, consisting in
  • promissory notes, of which the immediate payment depended, in any respect,
  • either upon the good will of those who issued them, or upon a condition
  • which the holder of the notes might not always have it in his power to
  • fulfil, or of which the payment was not exigible till after a certain
  • number of years, and which, in the mean time, bore no interest. Such a
  • paper money would, no doubt, fall more or less below the value of gold and
  • silver, according as the difficulty or uncertainty of obtaining immediate
  • payment was supposed to be greater or less, or according to the greater or
  • less distance of time at which payment was exigible.
  • Some years ago the different banking companies of Scotland were in the
  • practice of inserting into their bank notes, what they called an optional
  • clause; by which they promised payment to the bearer, either as soon as
  • the note should be presented, or, in the option of the directors, six
  • months after such presentment, together with the legal interest for the
  • said six months. The directors of some of those banks sometimes took
  • advantage of this optional clause, and sometimes threatened those who
  • demanded gold and silver in exchange for a considerable number of their
  • notes, that they would take advantage of it, unless such demanders would
  • content themselves with a part of what they demanded. The promissory notes
  • of those banking companies constituted, at that time, the far greater part
  • of the currency of Scotland, which this uncertainty of payment necessarily
  • degraded below value of gold and silver money. During the continuance of
  • this abuse (which prevailed chiefly in 1762, 1763, and 1764), while the
  • exchange between London and Carlisle was at par, that between London and
  • Dumfries would sometimes be four per cent. against Dumfries, though this
  • town is not thirty miles distant from Carlisle. But at Carlisle, bills
  • were paid in gold and silver; whereas at Dumfries they were paid in Scotch
  • bank notes; and the uncertainty of getting these bank notes exchanged for
  • gold and silver coin, had thus degraded them four per cent. below the
  • value of that coin. The same act of parliament which suppressed ten and
  • five shilling bank notes, suppressed likewise this optional clause, and
  • thereby restored the exchange between England and Scotland to its natural
  • rate, or to what the course of trade and remittances might happen to make
  • it.
  • In the paper currencies of Yorkshire, the payment of so small a sum as 6d.
  • sometimes depended upon the condition, that the holder of the note should
  • bring the change of a guinea to the person who issued it; a condition
  • which the holders of such notes might frequently find it very difficult to
  • fulfil, and which must have degraded this currency below the value of gold
  • and silver money. An act of parliament, accordingly, declared all such
  • clauses unlawful, and suppressed, in the same manner as in Scotland, all
  • promissory notes, payable to the bearer, under 20s. value.
  • The paper currencies of North America consisted, not in bank notes payable
  • to the bearer on demand, but in a government paper, of which the payment
  • was not exigible till several years after it was issued; and though the
  • colony governments paid no interest to the holders of this paper, they
  • declared it to be, and in fact rendered it, a legal tender of payment for
  • the full value for which it was issued. But allowing the colony security
  • to be perfectly good, £100, payable fifteen years hence, for example, in a
  • country where interest is at six per cent., is worth little more than £40
  • ready money. To oblige a creditor, therefore, to accept of this as full
  • payment for a debt of £100, actually paid down in ready money, was an act
  • of such violent injustice, as has scarce, perhaps, been attempted by the
  • government of any other country which pretended to be free. It bears the
  • evident marks of having originally been, what the honest and downright
  • Doctor Douglas assures us it was, a scheme of fraudulent debtors to cheat
  • their creditors. The government of Pennsylvania, indeed, pretended, upon
  • their first emission of paper money, in 1722, to render their paper of
  • equal value with gold and silver, by enacting penalties against all those
  • who made any difference in the price of their goods when they sold them
  • for a colony paper, and when they sold them for gold and silver, a
  • regulation equally tyrannical, but much less, effectual, than that which
  • it was meant to support. A positive law may render a shilling a legal
  • tender for a guinea, because it may direct the courts of justice to
  • discharge the debtor who has made that tender; but no positive law can
  • oblige a person who sells goods, and who is at liberty to sell or not to
  • sell as he pleases, to accept of a shilling as equivalent to a guinea in
  • the price of them. Notwithstanding any regulation of this kind, it
  • appeared, by the course of exchange with Great Britain, that £100 sterling
  • was occasionally considered as equivalent, in some of the colonies, to
  • £130, and in others to so great a sum as £1100 currency; this difference
  • in the value arising from the difference in the quantity of paper emitted
  • in the different colonies, and in the distance and probability of the term
  • of its final discharge and redemption.
  • No law, therefore, could be more equitable than the act of parliament, so
  • unjustly complained of in the colonies, which declared, that no paper
  • currency to be emitted there in time coming, should be a legal tender of
  • payment.
  • Pennsylvania was always more moderate in its emissions of paper money than
  • any other of our colonies. Its paper currency, accordingly, is said never
  • to have sunk below the value of the gold and silver which was current in
  • the colony before the first emission of its paper money. Before that
  • emission, the colony had raised the denomination of its coin, and had, by
  • act of assembly, ordered 5s. sterling to pass in the colonies for 6s:3d.,
  • and afterwards for 6s:8d. A pound, colony currency, therefore, even when
  • that currency was gold and silver, was more than thirty per cent. below
  • the value of £1 sterling; and when that currency was turned into paper, it
  • was seldom much more than thirty per cent. below that value. The pretence
  • for raising the denomination of the coin was to prevent the exportation of
  • gold and silver, by making equal quantities of those metals pass for
  • greater sums in the colony than they did in the mother country. It was
  • found, however, that the price of all goods from the mother country rose
  • exactly in proportion as they raised the denomination of their coin, so
  • that their gold and silver were exported as fast as ever.
  • The paper of each colony being received in the payment of the provincial
  • taxes, for the full value for which it had been issued, it necessarily
  • derived from this use some additional value, over and above what it would
  • have had, from the real or supposed distance of the term of its final
  • discharge and redemption. This additional value was greater or less,
  • according as the quantity of paper issued was more or less above what
  • could be employed in the payment of the taxes of the particular colony
  • which issued it. It was in all the colonies very much above what could be
  • employed in this manner.
  • A prince, who should enact that a certain proportion of his taxes should
  • be paid in a paper money of a certain kind, might thereby give a certain
  • value to this paper money, even though the term of its final discharge and
  • redemption should depend altogether upon the will of the prince. If the
  • bank which issued this paper was careful to keep the quantity of it always
  • somewhat below what could easily be employed in this manner, the demand
  • for it might be such as to make it even bear a premium, or sell for
  • somewhat more in the market than the quantity of gold or silver currency
  • for which it was issued. Some people account in this manner for what is
  • called the agio of the bank of Amsterdam, or for the superiority of bank
  • money over current money, though this bank money, as they pretend, cannot
  • be taken out of the bank at the will of the owner. The greater part of
  • foreign bills of exchange must be paid in bank money, that is, by a
  • transfer in the books of the bank; and the directors of the bank, they
  • allege, are careful to keep the whole quantity of bank money always below
  • what this use occasions a demand for. It is upon this account, they say,
  • the bank money sells for a premium, or bears an agio of four or five per
  • cent. above the same nominal sum of the gold and silver currency of the
  • country. This account of the bank of Amsterdam, however, it will appear
  • hereafter, is in a great measure chimerical.
  • A paper currency which falls below the value of gold and silver coin, does
  • not thereby sink the value of those metals, or occasion equal quantities
  • of them to exchange for a smaller quantity of goods of any other kind. The
  • proportion between the value of gold and silver and that of goods of any
  • other kind, depends in all cases, not upon the nature and quantity of any
  • particular paper money, which may be current in any particular country,
  • but upon the richness or poverty of the mines, which happen at any
  • particular time to supply the great market of the commercial world with
  • those metals. It depends upon the proportion between the quantity of
  • labour which is necessary in order to bring a certain quantity of gold and
  • silver to market, and that which is necessary in order to bring thither a
  • certain quantity of any other sort of goods.
  • If bankers are restrained from issuing any circulating bank notes, or
  • notes payable to the bearer, for less than a certain sum; and if they are
  • subjected to the obligation of an immediate and unconditional payment of
  • such bank notes as soon as presented, their trade may, with safety to the
  • public, be rendered in all other respects perfectly free. The late
  • multiplication of banking companies in both parts of the united kingdom,
  • an event by which many people have been much alarmed, instead of
  • diminishing, increases the security of the public. It obliges all of them
  • to be more circumspect in their conduct, and, by not extending their
  • currency beyond its due proportion to their cash, to guard themselves
  • against those malicious runs, which the rivalship of so many competitors
  • is always ready to bring upon them. It restrains the circulation of each
  • particular company within a narrower circle, and reduces their circulating
  • notes to a smaller number. By dividing the whole circulation into a
  • greater number of parts, the failure of any one company, an accident
  • which, in the course of things, must sometimes happen, becomes of less
  • consequence to the public. This free competition, too, obliges all bankers
  • to be more liberal in their dealings with their customers, lest their
  • rivals should carry them away. In general, if any branch of trade, or any
  • division of labour, be advantageous to the public, the freer and more
  • general the competition, it will always be the more so.
  • CHAPTER III.
  • OF THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL, OR OF
  • PRODUCTIVE AND UNPRODUCTIVE LABOUR.
  • There is one sort of labour which adds to the value of the subject upon
  • which it is bestowed; there is another which has no such effect. The
  • former as it produces a value, may be called productive, the latter,
  • unproductive labour. {Some French authors of great learning and ingenuity
  • have used those words in a different sense. In the last chapter of the
  • fourth book, I shall endeavour to shew that their sense is an improper
  • one.} Thus the labour of a manufacturer adds generally to the value of the
  • materials which he works upon, that of his own maintenance, and of his
  • master’s profit. The labour of a menial servant, on the contrary, adds to
  • the value of nothing. Though the manufacturer has his wages advanced to
  • him by his master, he in reality costs him no expense, the value of those
  • wages being generally restored, together with a profit, in the improved
  • value of the subject upon which his labour is bestowed. But the
  • maintenance of a menial servant never is restored. A man grows rich by
  • employing a multitude of manufacturers; he grows poor by maintaining a
  • multitude or menial servants. The labour of the latter, however, has its
  • value, and deserves its reward as well as that of the former. But the
  • labour of the manufacturer fixes and realizes itself in some particular
  • subject or vendible commodity, which lasts for some time at least after
  • that labour is past. It is, as it were, a certain quantity of labour
  • stocked and stored up, to be employed, if necessary, upon some other
  • occasion. That subject, or, what is the same thing, the price of that
  • subject, can afterwards, if necessary, put into motion a quantity of
  • labour equal to that which had originally produced it. The labour of the
  • menial servant, on the contrary, does not fix or realize itself in any
  • particular subject or vendible commodity. His services generally perish in
  • the very instant of their performance, and seldom leave any trace of value
  • behind them, for which an equal quantity of service could afterwards be
  • procured.
  • The labour of some of the most respectable orders in the society is, like
  • that of menial servants, unproductive of any value, and does not fix or
  • realize itself in any permanent subject, or vendible commodity, which
  • endures after that labour is past, and for which an equal quantity of
  • labour could afterwards be procured. The sovereign, for example, with all
  • the officers both of justice and war who serve under him, the whole army
  • and navy, are unproductive labourers. They are the servants of the public,
  • and are maintained by a part of the annual produce of the industry of
  • other people. Their service, how honourable, how useful, or how necessary
  • soever, produces nothing for which an equal quantity of service can
  • afterwards be procured. The protection, security, and defence, of the
  • commonwealth, the effect of their labour this year, will not purchase its
  • protection, security, and defence, for the year to come. In the same class
  • must be ranked, some both of the gravest and most important, and some of
  • the most frivolous professions; churchmen, lawyers, physicians, men of
  • letters of all kinds; players, buffoons, musicians, opera-singers,
  • opera-dancers, etc. The labour of the meanest of these has a certain
  • value, regulated by the very same principles which regulate that of every
  • other sort of labour; and that of the noblest and most useful, produces
  • nothing which could afterwards purchase or procure an equal quantity of
  • labour. Like the declamation of the actor, the harangue of the orator, or
  • the tune of the musician, the work of all of them perishes in the very
  • instant of its production.
  • Both productive and unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour at
  • all, are all equally maintained by the annual produce of the land and
  • labour of the country. This produce, how great soever, can never be
  • infinite, but must have certain limits. According, therefore, as a smaller
  • or greater proportion of it is in any one year employed in maintaining
  • unproductive hands, the more in the one case, and the less in the other,
  • will remain for the productive, and the next year’s produce will be
  • greater or smaller accordingly; the whole annual produce, if we except the
  • spontaneous productions of the earth, being the effect of productive
  • labour.
  • Though the whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country is
  • no doubt ultimately destined for supplying the consumption of its
  • inhabitants, and for procuring a revenue to them; yet when it first comes
  • either from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, it
  • naturally divides itself into two parts. One of them, and frequently the
  • largest, is, in the first place, destined for replacing a capital, or for
  • renewing the provisions, materials, and finished work, which had been
  • withdrawn from a capital; the other for constituting a revenue either to
  • the owner of this capital, as the profit of his stock, or to some other
  • person, as the rent of his land. Thus, of the produce of land, one part
  • replaces the capital of the farmer; the other pays his profit and the rent
  • of the landlord; and thus constitutes a revenue both to the owner of this
  • capital, as the profits of his stock, and to some other person as the rent
  • of his land. Of the produce of a great manufactory, in the same manner,
  • one part, and that always the largest, replaces the capital of the
  • undertaker of the work; the other pays his profit, and thus constitutes a
  • revenue to the owner of this capital.
  • That part of the annual produce of the land and labour of any country
  • which replaces a capital, never is immediately employed to maintain any
  • but productive hands. It pays the wages of productive labour only. That
  • which is immediately destined for constituting a revenue, either as profit
  • or as rent, may maintain indifferently either productive or unproductive
  • hands.
  • Whatever part of his stock a man employs as a capital, he always expects
  • it to be replaced to him with a profit. He employs it, therefore, in
  • maintaining productive hands only; and after having served in the function
  • of a capital to him, it constitutes a revenue to them. Whenever he employs
  • any part of it in maintaining unproductive hands of any kind, that part is
  • from that moment withdrawn from his capital, and placed in his stock
  • reserved for immediate consumption.
  • Unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour at all, are all
  • maintained by revenue; either, first, by that part of the annual produce
  • which is originally destined for constituting a revenue to some particular
  • persons, either as the rent of land, or as the profits of stock; or,
  • secondly, by that part which, though originally destined for replacing a
  • capital, and for maintaining productive labourers only, yet when it comes
  • into their hands, whatever part of it is over and above their necessary
  • subsistence, may be employed in maintaining indifferently either
  • productive or unproductive hands. Thus, not only the great landlord or the
  • rich merchant, but even the common workman, if his wages are considerable,
  • may maintain a menial servant; or he may sometimes go to a play or a
  • puppet-show, and so contribute his share towards maintaining one set of
  • unproductive labourers; or he may pay some taxes, and thus help to
  • maintain another set, more honourable and useful, indeed, but equally
  • unproductive. No part of the annual produce, however, which had been
  • originally destined to replace a capital, is ever directed towards
  • maintaining unproductive hands, till after it has put into motion its full
  • complement of productive labour, or all that it could put into motion in
  • the way in which it was employed. The workman must have earned his wages
  • by work done, before he can employ any part of them in this manner. That
  • part, too, is generally but a small one. It is his spare revenue only, of
  • which productive labourers have seldom a great deal. They generally have
  • some, however; and in the payment of taxes, the greatness of their number
  • may compensate, in some measure, the smallness of their contribution. The
  • rent of land and the profits of stock are everywhere, therefore, the
  • principal sources from which unproductive hands derive their subsistence.
  • These are the two sorts of revenue of which the owners have generally most
  • to spare. They might both maintain indifferently, either productive or
  • unproductive hands. They seem, however, to have some predilection for the
  • latter. The expense of a great lord feeds generally more idle than
  • industrious people. The rich merchant, though with his capital he
  • maintains industrious people only, yet by his expense, that is, by the
  • employment of his revenue, he feeds commonly the very same sort as the
  • great lord.
  • The proportion, therefore, between the productive and unproductive hands,
  • depends very much in every country upon the proportion between that part
  • of the annual produce, which, as soon as it comes either from the ground,
  • or from the hands of the productive labourers, is destined for replacing a
  • capital, and that which is destined for constituting a revenue, either as
  • rent or as profit. This proportion is very different in rich from what it
  • is in poor countries.
  • Thus, at present, in the opulent countries of Europe, a very large,
  • frequently the largest, portion of the produce of the land, is destined
  • for replacing the capital of the rich and independent farmer; the other
  • for paying his profits, and the rent of the landlord. But anciently,
  • during the prevalency of the feudal government, a very small portion of
  • the produce was sufficient to replace the capital employed in cultivation.
  • It consisted commonly in a few wretched cattle, maintained altogether by
  • the spontaneous produce of uncultivated land, and which might, therefore,
  • be considered as a part of that spontaneous produce. It generally, too,
  • belonged to the landlord, and was by him advanced to the occupiers of the
  • land. All the rest of the produce properly belonged to him too, either as
  • rent for his land, or as profit upon this paltry capital. The occupiers of
  • land were generally bond-men, whose persons and effects were equally his
  • property. Those who were not bond-men were tenants at will; and though the
  • rent which they paid was often nominally little more than a quit-rent, it
  • really amounted to the whole produce of the land. Their lord could at all
  • times command their labour in peace and their service in war. Though they
  • lived at a distance from his house, they were equally dependent upon him
  • as his retainers who lived in it. But the whole produce of the land
  • undoubtedly belongs to him, who can dispose of the labour and service of
  • all those whom it maintains. In the present state of Europe, the share of
  • the landlord seldom exceeds a third, sometimes not a fourth part of the
  • whole produce of the land. The rent of land, however, in all the improved
  • parts of the country, has been tripled and quadrupled since those ancient
  • times; and this third or fourth part of the annual produce is, it seems,
  • three or four times greater than the whole had been before. In the
  • progress of improvement, rent, though it increases in proportion to the
  • extent, diminishes in proportion to the produce of the land.
  • In the opulent countries of Europe, great capitals are at present employed
  • in trade and manufactures. In the ancient state, the little trade that was
  • stirring, and the few homely and coarse manufactures that were carried on,
  • required but very small capitals. These, however, must have yielded very
  • large profits. The rate of interest was nowhere less than ten per cent.
  • and their profits must have been sufficient to afford this great interest.
  • At present, the rate of interest, in the improved parts of Europe, is
  • nowhere higher than six per cent.; and in some of the most improved, it is
  • so low as four, three, and two per cent. Though that part of the revenue
  • of the inhabitants which is derived from the profits of stock, is always
  • much greater in rich than in poor countries, it is because the stock is
  • much greater; in proportion to the stock, the profits are generally much
  • less.
  • That part of the annual produce, therefore, which, as soon as it comes
  • either from the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, is
  • destined for replacing a capital, is not only much greater in rich than in
  • poor countries, but bears a much greater proportion to that which is
  • immediately destined for constituting a revenue either as rent or as
  • profit. The funds destined for the maintenance of productive labour are
  • not only much greater in the former than in the latter, but bear a much
  • greater proportion to those which, though they may be employed to maintain
  • either productive or unproductive hands, have generally a predilection for
  • the latter.
  • The proportion between those different funds necessarily determines in
  • every country the general character of the inhabitants as to industry or
  • idleness. We are more industrious than our forefathers, because, in the
  • present times, the funds destined for the maintenance of industry are much
  • greater in proportion to those which are likely to be employed in the
  • maintenance of idleness, than they were two or three centuries ago. Our
  • ancestors were idle for want of a sufficient encouragement to industry. It
  • is better, says the proverb, to play for nothing, than to work for
  • nothing. In mercantile and manufacturing towns, where the inferior ranks
  • of people are chiefly maintained by the employment of capital, they are in
  • general industrious, sober, and thriving; as in many English, and in most
  • Dutch towns. In those towns which are principally supported by the
  • constant or occasional residence of a court, and in which the inferior
  • ranks of people are chiefly maintained by the spending of revenue, they
  • are in general idle, dissolute, and poor; as at Rome, Versailles,
  • Compeigne, and Fontainbleau. If you except Rouen and Bourdeaux, there is
  • little trade or industry in any of the parliament towns of France; and the
  • inferior ranks of people, being chiefly maintained by the expense of the
  • members of the courts of justice, and of those who come to plead before
  • them, are in general idle and poor. The great trade of Rouen and Bourdeaux
  • seems to be altogether the effect of their situation. Rouen is necessarily
  • the entrepot of almost all the goods which are brought either from foreign
  • countries, or from the maritime provinces of France, for the consumption
  • of the great city of Paris. Bourdeaux is, in the same manner, the entrepot
  • of the wines which grow upon the banks of the Garronne, and of the rivers
  • which run into it, one of the richest wine countries in the world, and
  • which seems to produce the wine fittest for exportation, or best suited to
  • the taste of foreign nations. Such advantageous situations necessarily
  • attract a great capital by the great employment which they afford it; and
  • the employment of this capital is the cause of the industry of those two
  • cities. In the other parliament towns of France, very little more capital
  • seems to be employed than what is necessary for supplying their own
  • consumption; that is, little more than the smallest capital which can be
  • employed in them. The same thing may be said of Paris, Madrid, and Vienna.
  • Of those three cities, Paris is by far the most industrious, but Paris
  • itself is the principal market of all the manufactures established at
  • Paris, and its own consumption is the principal object of all the trade
  • which it carries on. London, Lisbon, and Copenhagen, are, perhaps, the
  • only three cities in Europe, which are both the constant residence of a
  • court, and can at the same time be considered as trading cities, or as
  • cities which trade not only for their own consumption, but for that of
  • other cities and countries. The situation of all the three is extremely
  • advantageous, and naturally fits them to be the entrepots of a great part
  • of the goods destined for the consumption of distant places. In a city
  • where a great revenue is spent, to employ with advantage a capital for any
  • other purpose than for supplying the consumption of that city, is probably
  • more difficult than in one in which the inferior ranks of people have no
  • other maintenance but what they derive from the employment of such a
  • capital. The idleness of the greater part of the people who are maintained
  • by the expense of revenue, corrupts, it is probable, the industry of those
  • who ought to be maintained by the employment of capital, and renders it
  • less advantageous to employ a capital there than in other places. There
  • was little trade or industry in Edinburgh before the Union. When the
  • Scotch parliament was no longer to be assembled in it, when it ceased to
  • be the necessary residence of the principal nobility and gentry of
  • Scotland, it became a city of some trade and industry. It still continues,
  • however, to be the residence of the principal courts of justice in
  • Scotland, of the boards of customs and excise, etc. A considerable
  • revenue, therefore, still continues to be spent in it. In trade and
  • industry, it is much inferior to Glasgow, of which the inhabitants are
  • chiefly maintained by the employment of capital. The inhabitants of a
  • large village, it has sometimes been observed, after having made
  • considerable progress in manufactures, have become idle and poor, in
  • consequence of a great lord’s having taken up his residence in their
  • neighbourhood.
  • The proportion between capital and revenue, therefore, seems everywhere to
  • regulate the proportion between industry and idleness Wherever capital
  • predominates, industry prevails; wherever revenue, idleness. Every
  • increase or diminution of capital, therefore, naturally tends to increase
  • or diminish the real quantity of industry, the number of productive hands,
  • and consequently the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land
  • and labour of the country, the real wealth and revenue of all its
  • inhabitants.
  • Capitals are increased by parsimony, and diminished by prodigality and
  • misconduct.
  • Whatever a person saves from his revenue he adds to his capital, and
  • either employs it himself in maintaining an additional number of
  • productive hands, or enables some other person to do so, by lending it to
  • him for an interest, that is, for a share of the profits. As the capital
  • of an individual can be increased only by what he saves from his annual
  • revenue or his annual gains, so the capital of a society, which is the
  • same with that of all the individuals who compose it, can be increased
  • only in the same manner.
  • Parsimony, and not industry, is the immediate cause of the increase of
  • capital. Industry, indeed, provides the subject which parsimony
  • accumulates; but whatever industry might acquire, if parsimony did not
  • save and store up, the capital would never be the greater.
  • Parsimony, by increasing the fund which is destined for the maintenance of
  • productive hands, tends to increase the number of those hands whose labour
  • adds to the value of the subject upon which it is bestowed. It tends,
  • therefore, to increase the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the
  • land and labour of the country. It puts into motion an additional quantity
  • of industry, which gives an additional value to the annual produce.
  • What is annually saved, is as regularly consumed as what is annually
  • spent, and nearly in the same time too: but it is consumed by a different
  • set of people. That portion of his revenue which a rich man annually
  • spends, is, in most cases, consumed by idle guests and menial servants,
  • who leave nothing behind them in return for their consumption. That
  • portion which he annually saves, as, for the sake of the profit, it is
  • immediately employed as a capital, is consumed in the same manner, and
  • nearly in the same time too, but by a different set of people: by
  • labourers, manufacturers, and artificers, who reproduce, with a profit,
  • the value of their annual consumption. His revenue, we shall suppose, is
  • paid him in money. Had he spent the whole, the food, clothing, and
  • lodging, which the whole could have purchased, would have been distributed
  • among the former set of people. By saving a part of it, as that part is,
  • for the sake of the profit, immediately employed as a capital, either by
  • himself or by some other person, the food, clothing, and lodging, which
  • may be purchased with it, are necessarily reserved for the latter. The
  • consumption is the same, but the consumers are different.
  • By what a frugal man annually saves, he not only affords maintenance to an
  • additional number of productive hands, for that of the ensuing year, but
  • like the founder of a public work-house he establishes, as it were, a
  • perpetual fund for the maintenance of an equal number in all times to
  • come. The perpetual allotment and destination of this fund, indeed, is not
  • always guarded by any positive law, by any trust-right or deed of
  • mortmain. It is always guarded, however, by a very powerful principle, the
  • plain and evident interest of every individual to whom any share of it
  • shall ever belong. No part of it can ever afterwards be employed to
  • maintain any but productive hands, without an evident loss to the person
  • who thus perverts it from its proper destination.
  • The prodigal perverts it in this manner: By not confining his expense
  • within his income, he encroaches upon his capital. Like him who perverts
  • the revenues of some pious foundation to profane purposes, he pays the
  • wages of idleness with those funds which the frugality of his forefathers
  • had, as it were, consecrated to the maintenance of industry. By
  • diminishing the funds destined for the employment of productive labour, he
  • necessarily diminishes, so far as it depends upon him, the quantity of
  • that labour which adds a value to the subject upon which it is bestowed,
  • and, consequently, the value of the annual produce of the land and labour
  • of the whole country, the real wealth and revenue of its inhabitants. If
  • the prodigality of some were not compensated by the frugality of others,
  • the conduct of every prodigal, by feeding the idle with the bread of the
  • industrious, would tend not only to beggar himself, but to impoverish his
  • country.
  • Though the expense of the prodigal should be altogether in home made, and
  • no part of it in foreign commodities, its effect upon the productive funds
  • of the society would still be the same. Every year there would still be a
  • certain quantity of food and clothing, which ought to have maintained
  • productive, employed in maintaining unproductive hands. Every year,
  • therefore, there would still be some diminution in what would otherwise
  • have been the value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the
  • country.
  • This expense, it may be said, indeed, not being in foreign goods, and not
  • occasioning any exportation of gold and silver, the same quantity of money
  • would remain in the country as before. But if the quantity of food and
  • clothing which were thus consumed by unproductive, had been distributed
  • among productive hands, they would have reproduced, together with a
  • profit, the full value of their consumption. The same quantity of money
  • would, in this case, equally have remained in the country, and there
  • would, besides, have been a reproduction of an equal value of consumable
  • goods. There would have been two values instead of one.
  • The same quantity of money, besides, can not long remain in any country in
  • which the value of the annual produce diminishes. The sole use of money is
  • to circulate consumable goods. By means of it, provisions, materials, and
  • finished work, are bought and sold, and distributed to their proper
  • consumers. The quantity of money, therefore, which can be annually
  • employed in any country, must be determined by the value of the consumable
  • goods annually circulated within it. These must consist, either in the
  • immediate produce of the land and labour of the country itself, or in
  • something which had been purchased with some part of that produce. Their
  • value, therefore, must diminish as the value of that produce diminishes,
  • and along with it the quantity of money which can be employed in
  • circulating them. But the money which, by this annual diminution of
  • produce, is annually thrown out of domestic circulation, will not be
  • allowed to lie idle. The interest of whoever possesses it requires that it
  • should be employed; but having no employment at home, it will, in spite of
  • all laws and prohibitions, be sent abroad, and employed in purchasing
  • consumable goods, which may be of some use at home. Its annual exportation
  • will, in this manner, continue for some time to add something to the
  • annual consumption of the country beyond the value of its own annual
  • produce. What in the days of its prosperity had been saved from that
  • annual produce, and employed in purchasing gold and silver, will
  • contribute, for some little time, to support its consumption in adversity.
  • The exportation of gold and silver is, in this case, not the cause, but
  • the effect of its declension, and may even, for some little time,
  • alleviate the misery of that declension.
  • The quantity of money, on the contrary, must in every country naturally
  • increase as the value of the annual produce increases. The value of the
  • consumable goods annually circulated within the society being greater,
  • will require a greater quantity of money to circulate them. A part of the
  • increased produce, therefore, will naturally be employed in purchasing,
  • wherever it is to be had, the additional quantity of gold and silver
  • necessary for circulating the rest. The increase of those metals will, in
  • this case, be the effect, not the cause, of the public prosperity. Gold
  • and silver are purchased everywhere in the same manner. The food,
  • clothing, and lodging, the revenue and maintenance, of all those whose
  • labour or stock is employed in bringing them from the mine to the market,
  • is the price paid for them in Peru as well as in England. The country
  • which has this price to pay, will never belong without the quantity of
  • those metals which it has occasion for; and no country will ever long
  • retain a quantity which it has no occasion for.
  • Whatever, therefore, we may imagine the real wealth and revenue of a
  • country to consist in, whether in the value of the annual produce of its
  • land and labour, as plain reason seems to dictate, or in the quantity of
  • the precious metals which circulate within it, as vulgar prejudices
  • suppose; in either view of the matter, every prodigal appears to be a
  • public enemy, and every frugal man a public benefactor.
  • The effects of misconduct are often the same as those of prodigality.
  • Every injudicious and unsuccessful project in agriculture, mines,
  • fisheries, trade, or manufactures, tends in the same manner to diminish
  • the funds destined for the maintenance of productive labour. In every such
  • project, though the capital is consumed by productive hands only, yet as,
  • by the injudicious manner in which they are employed, they do not
  • reproduce the full value of their consumption, there must always be some
  • diminution in what would otherwise have been the productive funds of the
  • society.
  • It can seldom happen, indeed, that the circumstances of a great nation can
  • be much affected either by the prodigality or misconduct of individuals;
  • the profusion or imprudence of some being always more than compensated by
  • the frugality and good conduct of others.
  • With regard to profusion, the principle which prompts to expense is the
  • passion for present enjoyment; which, though sometimes violent and very
  • difficult to be restrained, is in general only momentary and occasional.
  • But the principle which prompts to save, is the desire of bettering our
  • condition; a desire which, though generally calm and dispassionate, comes
  • with us from the womb, and never leaves us till we go into the grave. In
  • the whole interval which separates those two moments, there is scarce,
  • perhaps, a single instance, in which any man is so perfectly and
  • completely satisfied with his situation, as to be without any wish of
  • alteration or improvement of any kind. An augmentation of fortune is the
  • means by which the greater part of men propose and wish to better their
  • condition. It is the means the most vulgar and the most obvious; and the
  • most likely way of augmenting their fortune, is to save and accumulate
  • some part of what they acquire, either regularly and annually, or upon
  • some extraordinary occasion. Though the principle of expense, therefore,
  • prevails in almost all men upon some occasions, and in some men upon
  • almost all occasions; yet in the greater part of men, taking the whole
  • course of their life at an average, the principle of frugality seems not
  • only to predominate, but to predominate very greatly.
  • With regard to misconduct, the number of prudent and successful
  • undertakings is everywhere much greater than that of injudicious and
  • unsuccessful ones. After all our complaints of the frequency of
  • bankruptcies, the unhappy men who fall into this misfortune, make but a
  • very small part of the whole number engaged in trade, and all other sorts
  • of business; not much more, perhaps, than one in a thousand. Bankruptcy
  • is, perhaps, the greatest and most humiliating calamity which can befal an
  • innocent man. The greater part of men, therefore, are sufficiently careful
  • to avoid it. Some, indeed, do not avoid it; as some do not avoid the
  • gallows.
  • Great nations are never impoverished by private, though they sometimes are
  • by public prodigality and misconduct. The whole, or almost the whole
  • public revenue is, in most countries, employed in maintaining unproductive
  • hands. Such are the people who compose a numerous and splendid court, a
  • great ecclesiastical establishment, great fleets and armies, who in time
  • of peace produce nothing, and in time of war acquire nothing which can
  • compensate the expense of maintaining them, even while the war lasts. Such
  • people, as they themselves produce nothing, are all maintained by the
  • produce of other men’s labour. When multiplied, therefore, to an
  • unnecessary number, they may in a particular year consume so great a share
  • of this produce, as not to leave a sufficiency for maintaining the
  • productive labourers, who should reproduce it next year. The next year’s
  • produce, therefore, will be less than that of the foregoing; and if the
  • same disorder should continue, that of the third year will be still less
  • than that of the second. Those unproductive hands who should be maintained
  • by a part only of the spare revenue of the people, may consume so great a
  • share of their whole revenue, and thereby oblige so great a number to
  • encroach upon their capitals, upon the funds destined for the maintenance
  • of productive labour, that all the frugality and good conduct of
  • individuals may not be able to compensate the waste and degradation of
  • produce occasioned by this violent and forced encroachment.
  • This frugality and good conduct, however, is, upon most occasions, it
  • appears from experience, sufficient to compensate, not only the private
  • prodigality and misconduct of individuals, but the public extravagance of
  • government. The uniform, constant, and uninterrupted effort of every man
  • to better his condition, the principle from which public and national, as
  • well as private opulence is originally derived, is frequently powerful
  • enough to maintain the natural progress of things towards improvement, in
  • spite both of the extravagance of government, and of the greatest errors
  • of administration. Like the unknown principle of animal life, it
  • frequently restores health and vigour to the constitution, in spite not
  • only of the disease, but of the absurd prescriptions of the doctor.
  • The annual produce of the land and labour of any nation can be increased
  • in its value by no other means, but by increasing either the number of its
  • productive labourers, or the productive powers of those labourers who had
  • before been employed. The number of its productive labourers, it is
  • evident, can never be much increased, but in consequence of an increase of
  • capital, or of the funds destined for maintaining them. The productive
  • powers of the same number of labourers cannot be increased, but in
  • consequence either of some addition and improvement to those machines and
  • instruments which facilitate and abridge labour, or of more proper
  • division and distribution of employment. In either case, an additional
  • capital is almost always required. It is by means of an additional capital
  • only, that the undertaker of any work can either provide his workmen with
  • better machinery, or make a more proper distribution of employment among
  • them. When the work to be done consists of a number of parts, to keep
  • every man constantly employed in one way, requires a much greater capital
  • than where every man is occasionally employed in every different part of
  • the work. When we compare, therefore, the state of a nation at two
  • different periods, and find that the annual produce of its land and labour
  • is evidently greater at the latter than at the former, that its lands are
  • better cultivated, its manufactures more numerous and more flourishing,
  • and its trade more extensive; we may be assured that its capital must have
  • increased during the interval between those two periods, and that more
  • must have been added to it by the good conduct of some, than had been
  • taken from it either by the private misconduct of others, or by the public
  • extravagance of government. But we shall find this to have been the case
  • of almost all nations, in all tolerably quiet and peaceable times, even of
  • those who have not enjoyed the most prudent and parsimonious governments.
  • To form a right judgment of it, indeed, we must compare the state of the
  • country at periods somewhat distant from one another. The progress is
  • frequently so gradual, that, at near periods, the improvement is not only
  • not sensible, but, from the declension either of certain branches of
  • industry, or of certain districts of the country, things which sometimes
  • happen, though the country in general is in great prosperity, there
  • frequently arises a suspicion, that the riches and industry of the whole
  • are decaying.
  • The annual produce of the land and labour of England, for example, is
  • certainly much greater than it was a little more than a century ago, at
  • the restoration of Charles II. Though at present few people, I believe,
  • doubt of this, yet during this period five years have seldom passed away,
  • in which some book or pamphlet has not been published, written, too, with
  • such abilities as to gain some authority with the public, and pretending
  • to demonstrate that the wealth of the nation was fast declining; that the
  • country was depopulated, agriculture neglected, manufactures decaying, and
  • trade undone. Nor have these publications been all party pamphlets, the
  • wretched offspring of falsehood and venality. Many of them have been
  • written by very candid and very intelligent people, who wrote nothing but
  • what they believed, and for no other reason but because they believed it.
  • The annual produce of the land and labour of England, again, was certainly
  • much greater at the Restoration than we can suppose it to have been about
  • a hundred years before, at the accession of Elizabeth. At this period,
  • too, we have all reason to believe, the country was much more advanced in
  • improvement, than it had been about a century before, towards the close of
  • the dissensions between the houses of York and Lancaster. Even then it
  • was, probably, in a better condition than it had been at the Norman
  • conquest: and at the Norman conquest, than during the confusion of the
  • Saxon heptarchy. Even at this early period, it was certainly a more
  • improved country than at the invasion of Julius Caesar, when its
  • inhabitants were nearly in the same state with the savages in North
  • America.
  • In each of those periods, however, there was not only much private and
  • public profusion, many expensive and unnecessary wars, great perversion of
  • the annual produce from maintaining productive to maintain unproductive
  • hands; but sometimes, in the confusion of civil discord, such absolute
  • waste and destruction of stock, as might be supposed, not only to retard,
  • as it certainly did, the natural accumulation of riches, but to have left
  • the country, at the end of the period, poorer than at the beginning. Thus,
  • in the happiest and most fortunate period of them all, that which has
  • passed since the Restoration, how many disorders and misfortunes have
  • occurred, which, could they have been foreseen, not only the
  • impoverishment, but the total ruin of the country would have been expected
  • from them? The fire and the plague of London, the two Dutch wars, the
  • disorders of the revolution, the war in Ireland, the four expensive French
  • wars of 1688, 1701, 1742, and 1756, together with the two rebellions of
  • 1715 and 1745. In the course of the four French wars, the nation has
  • contracted more than £145,000,000 of debt, over and above all the other
  • extraordinary annual expense which they occasioned; so that the whole
  • cannot be computed at less than £200,000,000. So great a share of the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of the country, has, since the
  • Revolution, been employed upon different occasions, in maintaining an
  • extraordinary number of unproductive hands. But had not those wars given
  • this particular direction to so large a capital, the greater part of it
  • would naturally have been employed in maintaining productive hands, whose
  • labour would have replaced, with a profit, the whole value of their
  • consumption. The value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the
  • country would have been considerably increased by it every year, and every
  • years increase would have augmented still more that of the following year.
  • More houses would have been built, more lands would have been improved,
  • and those which had been improved before would have been better
  • cultivated; more manufactures would have been established, and those which
  • had been established before would have been more extended; and to what
  • height the real wealth and revenue of the country might by this time have
  • been raised, it is not perhaps very easy even to imagine.
  • But though the profusion of government must undoubtedly have retarded the
  • natural progress of England towards wealth and improvement, it has not
  • been able to stop it. The annual produce of its land and labour is
  • undoubtedly much greater at present than it was either at the Restoration
  • or at the Revolution. The capital, therefore, annually employed in
  • cultivating this land, and in maintaining this labour, must likewise be
  • much greater. In the midst of all the exactions of government, this
  • capital has been silently and gradually accumulated by the private
  • frugality and good conduct of individuals, by their universal, continual,
  • and uninterrupted effort to better their own condition. It is this effort,
  • protected by law, and allowed by liberty to exert itself in the manner
  • that is most advantageous, which has maintained the progress of England
  • towards opulence and improvement in almost all former times, and which, it
  • is to be hoped, will do so in all future times. England, however, as it
  • has never been blessed with a very parsimonious government, so parsimony
  • has at no time been the characteristic virtue of its inhabitants. It is
  • the highest impertinence and presumption, therefore, in kings and
  • ministers to pretend to watch over the economy of private people, and to
  • restrain their expense, either by sumptuary laws, or by prohibiting the
  • importation of foreign luxuries. They are themselves always, and without
  • any exception, the greatest spendthrifts in the society. Let them look
  • well after their own expense, and they may safely trust private people
  • with theirs. If their own extravagance does not ruin the state, that of
  • the subject never will.
  • As frugality increases, and prodigality diminishes, the public capital, so
  • the conduct of those whose expense just equals their revenue, without
  • either accumulating or encroaching, neither increases nor diminishes it.
  • Some modes of expense, however, seem to contribute more to the growth of
  • public opulence than others.
  • The revenue of an individual may be spent, either in things which are
  • consumed immediately, and in which one day’s expense can neither alleviate
  • nor support that of another; or it may be spent in things mere durable,
  • which can therefore be accumulated, and in which every day’s expense may,
  • as he chooses, either alleviate, or support and heighten, the effect of
  • that of the following day. A man of fortune, for example, may either spend
  • his revenue in a profuse and sumptuous table, and in maintaining a great
  • number of menial servants, and a multitude of dogs and horses; or,
  • contenting himself with a frugal table, and few attendants, he may lay out
  • the greater part of it in adorning his house or his country villa, in
  • useful or ornamental buildings, in useful or ornamental furniture, in
  • collecting books, statues, pictures; or in things more frivolous, jewels,
  • baubles, ingenious trinkets of different kinds; or, what is most trifling
  • of all, in amassing a great wardrobe of fine clothes, like the favourite
  • and minister of a great prince who died a few years ago. Were two men of
  • equal fortune to spend their revenue, the one chiefly in the one way, the
  • other in the other, the magnificence of the person whose expense had been
  • chiefly in durable commodities, would be continually increasing, every
  • day’s expense contributing something to support and heighten the effect of
  • that of the following day; that of the other, on the contrary, would be no
  • greater at the end of the period than at the beginning. The former too
  • would, at the end of the period, be the richer man of the two. He would
  • have a stock of goods of some kind or other, which, though it might not be
  • worth all that it cost, would always be worth something. No trace or
  • vestige of the expense of the latter would remain, and the effects of ten
  • or twenty years’ profusion would be as completely annihilated as if they
  • had never existed.
  • As the one mode of expense is more favourable than the other to the
  • opulence of an individual, so is it likewise to that of a nation. The
  • houses, the furniture, the clothing of the rich, in a little time, become
  • useful to the inferior and middling ranks of people. They are able to
  • purchase them when their superiors grow weary of them; and the general
  • accommodation of the whole people is thus gradually improved, when this
  • mode of expense becomes universal among men of fortune. In countries which
  • have long been rich, you will frequently find the inferior ranks of people
  • in possession both of houses and furniture perfectly good and entire, but
  • of which neither the one could have been built, nor the other have been
  • made for their use. What was formerly a seat of the family of Seymour, is
  • now an inn upon the Bath road. The marriage-bed of James I. of Great
  • Britain, which his queen brought with her from Denmark, as a present fit
  • for a sovereign to make to a sovereign, was, a few years ago, the ornament
  • of an alehouse at Dunfermline. In some ancient cities, which either have
  • been long stationary, or have gone somewhat to decay, you will sometimes
  • scarce find a single house which could have been built for its present
  • inhabitants. If you go into those houses, too, you will frequently find
  • many excellent, though antiquated pieces of furniture, which are still
  • very fit for use, and which could as little have been made for them. Noble
  • palaces, magnificent villas, great collections of books, statues,
  • pictures, and other curiosities, are frequently both an ornament and an
  • honour, not only to the neighbourhood, but to the whole country to which
  • they belong. Versailles is an ornament and an honour to France, Stowe and
  • Wilton to England. Italy still continues to command some sort of
  • veneration, by the number of monuments of this kind which it possesses,
  • though the wealth which produced them has decayed, and though the genius
  • which planned them seems to be extinguished, perhaps from not having the
  • same employment.
  • The expense, too, which is laid out in durable commodities, is favourable
  • not only to accumulation, but to frugality. If a person should at any time
  • exceed in it, he can easily reform without exposing himself to the censure
  • of the public. To reduce very much the number of his servants, to reform
  • his table from great profusion to great frugality, to lay down his
  • equipage after he has once set it up, are changes which cannot escape the
  • observation of his neighbours, and which are supposed to imply some
  • acknowledgment of preceding bad conduct. Few, therefore, of those who have
  • once been so unfortunate as to launch out too far into this sort of
  • expense, have afterwards the courage to reform, till ruin and bankruptcy
  • oblige them. But if a person has, at any time, been at too great an
  • expense in building, in furniture, in books, or pictures, no imprudence
  • can be inferred from his changing his conduct. These are things in which
  • further expense is frequently rendered unnecessary by former expense; and
  • when a person stops short, he appears to do so, not because he has
  • exceeded his fortune, but because he has satisfied his fancy.
  • The expense, besides, that is laid out in durable commodities, gives
  • maintenance, commonly, to a greater number of people than that which is
  • employed in the most profuse hospitality. Of two or three hundred weight
  • of provisions, which may sometimes be served up at a great festival, one
  • half, perhaps, is thrown to the dunghill, and there is always a great deal
  • wasted and abused. But if the expense of this entertainment had been
  • employed in setting to work masons, carpenters, upholsterers, mechanics,
  • etc. a quantity of provisions of equal value would have been distributed
  • among a still greater number of people, who would have bought them in
  • pennyworths and pound weights, and not have lost or thrown away a single
  • ounce of them. In the one way, besides, this expense maintains productive,
  • in the other unproductive hands. In the one way, therefore, it increases,
  • in the other it does not increase the exchangeable value of the annual
  • produce of the land and labour of the country.
  • I would not, however, by all this, be understood to mean, that the one
  • species of expense always betokens a more liberal or generous spirit than
  • the other. When a man of fortune spends his revenue chiefly in
  • hospitality, he shares the greater part of it with his friends and
  • companions; but when he employs it in purchasing such durable commodities,
  • he often spends the whole upon his own person, and gives nothing to any
  • body without an equivalent. The latter species of expense, therefore,
  • especially when directed towards frivolous objects, the little ornaments
  • of dress and furniture, jewels, trinkets, gew-gaws, frequently indicates,
  • not only a trifling, but a base and selfish disposition. All that I mean
  • is, that the one sort of expense, as it always occasions some accumulation
  • of valuable commodities, as it is more favourable to private frugality,
  • and, consequently, to the increase of the public capital, and as it
  • maintains productive rather than unproductive hands, conduces more than
  • the other to the growth of public opulence.
  • CHAPTER IV.
  • OF STOCK LENT AT INTEREST.
  • The stock which is lent at interest is always considered as a capital by
  • the lender. He expects that in due time it is to be restored to him, and
  • that, in the mean time, the borrower is to pay him a certain annual rent
  • for the use of it. The borrower may use it either as a capital, or as a
  • stock reserved for immediate consumption. If he uses it as a capital, he
  • employs it in the maintenance of productive labourers, who reproduce the
  • value, with a profit. He can, in this case, both restore the capital, and
  • pay the interest, without alienating or encroaching upon any other source
  • of revenue. If he uses it as a stock reserved for immediate consumption,
  • he acts the part of a prodigal, and dissipates, in the maintenance of the
  • idle, what was destined for the support of the industrious. He can, in
  • this case, neither restore the capital nor pay the interest, without
  • either alienating or encroaching upon some other source of revenue, such
  • as the property or the rent of land.
  • The stock which is lent at interest is, no doubt, occasionally employed in
  • both these ways, but in the former much more frequently than in the
  • latter. The man who borrows in order to spend will soon be ruined, and he
  • who lends to him will generally have occasion to repent of his folly. To
  • borrow or to lend for such a purpose, therefore, is, in all cases, where
  • gross usury is out of the question, contrary to the interest of both
  • parties; and though it no doubt happens sometimes, that people do both the
  • one and the other, yet, from the regard that all men have for their own
  • interest, we may be assured, that it cannot happen so very frequently as
  • we are sometimes apt to imagine. Ask any rich man of common prudence, to
  • which of the two sorts of people he has lent the greater part of his
  • stock, to those who he thinks will employ it profitably, or to those who
  • will spend it idly, and he will laugh at you for proposing the question.
  • Even among borrowers, therefore, not the people in the world most famous
  • for frugality, the number of the frugal and industrious surpasses
  • considerably that of the prodigal and idle.
  • The only people to whom stock is commonly lent, without their being
  • expected to make any very profitable use of it, are country gentlemen, who
  • borrow upon mortgage. Even they scarce ever borrow merely to spend. What
  • they borrow, one may say, is commonly spent before they borrow it. They
  • have generally consumed so great a quantity of goods, advanced to them
  • upon credit by shop-keepers and tradesmen, that they find it necessary to
  • borrow at interest, in order to pay the debt. The capital borrowed
  • replaces the capitals of those shop-keepers and tradesmen which the
  • country gentlemen could not have replaced from the rents of their estates.
  • It is not properly borrowed in order to be spent, but in order to replace
  • a capital which had been spent before.
  • Almost all loans at interest are made in money, either of paper, or of
  • gold and silver; but what the borrower really wants, and what the lender
  • readily supplies him with, is not the money, but the money’s worth, or the
  • goods which it can purchase. If he wants it as a stock for immediate
  • consumption, it is those goods only which he can place in that stock. If
  • he wants it as a capital for employing industry, it is from those goods
  • only that the industrious can be furnished with the tools, materials, and
  • maintenance necessary for carrying on their work. By means of the loan,
  • the lender, as it were, assigns to the borrower his right to a certain
  • portion of the annual produce of the land and labour of the country, to be
  • employed as the borrower pleases.
  • The quantity of stock, therefore, or, as it is commonly expressed, of
  • money, which can be lent at interest in any country, is not regulated by
  • the value of the money, whether paper or coin, which serves as the
  • instrument of the different loans made in that country, but by the value
  • of that part of the annual produce, which, as soon as it comes either from
  • the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, is destined,
  • not only for replacing a capital, but such a capital as the owner does not
  • care to be at the trouble of employing himself. As such capitals are
  • commonly lent out and paid back in money, they constitute what is called
  • the monied interest. It is distinct, not only from the landed, but from
  • the trading and manufacturing interests, as in these last the owners
  • themselves employ their own capitals. Even in the monied interest,
  • however, the money is, as it were, but the deed of assignment, which
  • conveys from one hand to another those capitals which the owners do not
  • care to employ themselves. Those capitals may be greater, in almost any
  • proportion, than the amount of the money which serves as the instrument of
  • their conveyance; the same pieces of money successively serving for many
  • different loans, as well as for many different purchases. A, for example,
  • lends to W £1000, with which W immediately purchases of B £1000 worth of
  • goods. B having no occasion for the money himself, lends the identical
  • pieces to X, with which X immediately purchases of C another £1000 worth
  • of goods. C, in the same manner, and for the same reason, lends them to Y,
  • who again purchases goods with them of D. In this manner, the same pieces,
  • either of coin or of paper, may, in the course of a few days, serve as the
  • Instrument of three different loans, and of three different purchases,
  • each of which is, in value, equal to the whole amount of those pieces.
  • What the three monied men, A, B, and C, assigned to the three borrowers,
  • W, X, and Y, is the power of making those purchases. In this power consist
  • both the value and the use of the loans. The stock lent by the three
  • monied men is equal to the value of the goods which can be purchased with
  • it, and is three times greater than that of the money with which the
  • purchases are made. Those loans, however, may be all perfectly well
  • secured, the goods purchased by the different debtors being so employed
  • as, in due time, to bring back, with a profit, an equal value either of
  • coin or of paper. And as the same pieces of money can thus serve as the
  • instrument of different loans to three, or, for the same reason, to thirty
  • times their value, so they may likewise successively serve as the
  • instrument of repayment.
  • A capital lent at interest may, in this manner, be considered as an
  • assignment, from the lender to the borrower, of a certain considerable
  • portion of the annual produce, upon condition that the burrower in return
  • shall, during the continuance of the loan, annually assign to the lender a
  • small portion, called the interest; and, at the end of it, a portion
  • equally considerable with that which had originally been assigned to him,
  • called the repayment. Though money, either coin or paper, serves generally
  • as the deed of assignment, both to the smaller and to the more
  • considerable portion, it is itself altogether different from what is
  • assigned by it.
  • In proportion as that share of the annual produce which, as soon as it
  • comes either from the ground, or from the hands of the productive
  • labourers, is destined for replacing a capital, increases in any country,
  • what is called the monied interest naturally increases with it. The
  • increase of those particular capitals from which the owners wish to derive
  • a revenue, without being at the trouble of employing them themselves,
  • naturally accompanies the general increase of capitals; or, in other
  • words, as stock increases, the quantity of stock to be lent at interest
  • grows gradually greater and greater.
  • As the quantity of stock to be lent at interest increases, the interest,
  • or the price which must be paid for the use of that stock, necessarily
  • diminishes, not only from those general causes which make the market price
  • of things commonly diminish as their quantity increases, but from other
  • causes which are peculiar to this particular case. As capitals increase in
  • any country, the profits which can be made by employing them necessarily
  • diminish. It becomes gradually more and more difficult to find within the
  • country a profitable method of employing any new capital. There arises, in
  • consequence, a competition between different capitals, the owner of one
  • endeavouring to get possession of that employment which is occupied by
  • another; but, upon most occasions, he can hope to justle that other out of
  • this employment by no other means but by dealing upon more reasonable
  • terms. He must not only sell what he deals in somewhat cheaper, but, in
  • order to get it to sell, he must sometimes, too, buy it dearer. The demand
  • for productive labour, by the increase of the funds which are destined for
  • maintaining it, grows every day greater and greater. Labourers easily find
  • employment; but the owners of capitals find it difficult to get labourers
  • to employ. Their competition raises the wages of labour, and sinks the
  • profits of stock. But when the profits which can be made by the use of a
  • capital are in this manner diminished, as it were, at both ends, the price
  • which can be paid for the use of it, that is, the rate of interest, must
  • necessarily be diminished with them.
  • Mr Locke, Mr Lawe, and Mr Montesquieu, as well as many other writers, seem
  • to have imagined that the increase of the quantity of gold and silver, in
  • consequence of the discovery of the Spanish West Indies, was the real
  • cause of the lowering of the rate of interest through the greater part of
  • Europe. Those metals, they say, having become of less value themselves,
  • the use of any particular portion of them necessarily became of less value
  • too, and, consequently, the price which could be paid for it. This notion,
  • which at first sight seems so plausible, has been so fully exposed by Mr
  • Hume, that it is, perhaps, unnecessary to say any thing more about it. The
  • following very short and plain argument, however, may serve to explain
  • more distinctly the fallacy which seems to have misled those gentlemen.
  • Before the discovery of the Spanish West Indies, ten per cent. seems to
  • have been the common rate of interest through the greater part of Europe.
  • It has since that time, in different countries, sunk to six, five, four,
  • and three per cent. Let us suppose, that in every particular country the
  • value of silver has sunk precisely in the same proportion as the rate of
  • interest; and that in those countries, for example, where interest has
  • been reduced from ten to five per cent. the same quantity of silver can
  • now purchase just half the quantity of goods which it could have purchased
  • before. This supposition will not, I believe, be found anywhere agreeable
  • to the truth; but it is the most favourable to the opinion which we are
  • going to examine; and, even upon this supposition, it is utterly
  • impossible that the lowering of the value of silver could have the
  • smallest tendency to lower the rate of interest. If £100 are in those
  • countries now of no more value than £50 were then, £10 must now be of no
  • more value than £5 were then. Whatever were the causes which lowered the
  • value of the capital, the same must necessarily have lowered that of the
  • interest, and exactly in the same proportion. The proportion between the
  • value of the capital and that of the interest must have remained the same,
  • though the rate had never been altered. By altering the rate, on the
  • contrary, the proportion between those two values is necessarily altered.
  • If £100 now are worth no more than £50 were then, £5 now can be worth no
  • more than £2:10s. were then. By reducing the rate of interest, therefore,
  • from ten to five per cent. we give for the use of a capital, which is
  • supposed to be equal to one half of its former value, an interest which is
  • equal to one fourth only of the value of the former interest.
  • An increase in the quantity of silver, while that of the commodities
  • circulated by means of it remained the same, could have no other effect
  • than to diminish the value of that metal. The nominal value of all sorts
  • of goods would be greater, but their real value would be precisely the
  • same as before. They would be exchanged for a greater number of pieces of
  • silver; but the quantity of labour which they could command, the number of
  • people whom they could maintain and employ, would be precisely the same.
  • The capital of the country would be the same, though a greater number of
  • pieces might be requisite for conveying any equal portion of it from one
  • hand to another. The deeds of assignment, like the conveyances of a
  • verbose attorney, would be more cumbersome; but the thing assigned would
  • be precisely the same as before, and could produce only the same effects.
  • The funds for maintaining productive labour being the same, the demand for
  • it would be the same. Its price or wages, therefore, though nominally
  • greater, would really be the same. They would be paid in a greater number
  • of pieces of silver, but they would purchase only the same quantity of
  • goods. The profits of stock would be the same, both nominally and really.
  • The wages of labour are commonly computed by the quantity of silver which
  • is paid to the labourer. When that is increased, therefore, his wages
  • appear to be increased, though they may sometimes be no greater than
  • before. But the profits of stock are not computed by the number of pieces
  • of silver with which they are paid, but by the proportion which those
  • pieces bear to the whole capital employed. Thus, in a particular country,
  • 5s. a-week are said to be the common wages of labour, and ten per cent.
  • the common profits of stock; but the whole capital of the country being
  • the same as before, the competition between the different capitals of
  • individuals into which it was divided would likewise be the same. They
  • would all trade with the same advantages and disadvantages. The common
  • proportion between capital and profit, therefore, would be the same, and
  • consequently the common interest of money; what can commonly be given for
  • the use of money being necessarily regulated by what can commonly be made
  • by the use of it.
  • Any increase in the quantity of commodities annually circulated within the
  • country, while that of the money which circulated them remained the same,
  • would, on the contrary, produce many other important effects, besides that
  • of raising the value of the money. The capital of the country, though it
  • might nominally be the same, would really be augmented. It might continue
  • to be expressed by the same quantity of money, but it would command a
  • greater quantity of labour. The quantity of productive labour which it
  • could maintain and employ would be increased, and consequently the demand
  • for that labour. Its wages would naturally rise with the demand, and yet
  • might appear to sink. They might be paid with a smaller quantity of money,
  • but that smaller quantity might purchase a greater quantity of goods than
  • a greater had done before. The profits of stock would be diminished, both
  • really and in appearance. The whole capital of the country being
  • augmented, the competition between the different capitals of which it was
  • composed would naturally be augmented along with it. The owners of those
  • particular capitals would be obliged to content themselves with a smaller
  • proportion of the produce of that labour which their respective capitals
  • employed. The interest of money, keeping pace always with the profits of
  • stock, might, in this manner, be greatly diminished, though the value of
  • money, or the quantity of goods which any particular sum could purchase,
  • was greatly augmented.
  • In some countries the interest of money has been prohibited by law. But as
  • something can everywhere be made by the use of money, something ought
  • everywhere to be paid for the use of it. This regulation, instead of
  • preventing, has been found from experience to increase the evil of usury.
  • The debtor being obliged to pay, not only for the use of the money, but
  • for the risk which his creditor runs by accepting a compensation for that
  • use, he is obliged, if one may say so, to insure his creditor from the
  • penalties of usury.
  • In countries where interest is permitted, the law in order to prevent the
  • extortion of usury, generally fixes the highest rate which can be taken
  • without incurring a penalty. This rate ought always to be somewhat above
  • the lowest market price, or the price which is commonly paid for the use
  • of money by those who can give the most undoubted security. If this legal
  • rate should be fixed below the lowest market rate, the effects of this
  • fixation must be nearly the same as those of a total prohibition of
  • interest. The creditor will not lend his money for less than the use of it
  • is worth, and the debtor must pay him for the risk which he runs by
  • accepting the full value of that use. If it is fixed precisely at the
  • lowest market price, it ruins, with honest people who respect the laws of
  • their country, the credit of all those who cannot give the very best
  • security, and obliges them to have recourse to exorbitant usurers. In a
  • country such as Great Britain, where money is lent to government at three
  • per cent. and to private people, upon good security, at four and four and
  • a-half, the present legal rate, five per cent. is perhaps as proper as
  • any.
  • The legal rate, it is to be observed, though it ought to be somewhat
  • above, ought not to be much above the lowest market rate. If the legal
  • rate of interest in Great Britain, for example, was fixed so high as eight
  • or ten per cent. the greater part of the money which was to be lent, would
  • be lent to prodigals and projectors, who alone would be willing to give
  • this high interest. Sober people, who will give for the use of money no
  • more than a part of what they are likely to make by the use of it, would
  • not venture into the competition. A great part of the capital of the
  • country would thus be kept out of the hands which were most likely to make
  • a profitable and advantageous use of it, and thrown into those which were
  • most likely to waste and destroy it. Where the legal rate of interest, on
  • the contrary, is fixed but a very little above the lowest market rate,
  • sober people are universally preferred, as borrowers, to prodigals and
  • projectors. The person who lends money gets nearly as much interest from
  • the former as he dares to take from the latter, and his money is much
  • safer in the hands of the one set of people than in those of the other. A
  • great part of the capital of the country is thus thrown into the hands in
  • which it is most likely to be employed with advantage.
  • No law can reduce the common rate of interest below the lowest ordinary
  • market rate at the time when that law is made. Notwithstanding the edict
  • of 1766, by which the French king attempted to reduce the rate of interest
  • from five to four per cent. money continued to be lent in France at five
  • per cent. the law being evaded in several different ways.
  • The ordinary market price of land, it is to be observed, depends
  • everywhere upon the ordinary market rate of interest. The person who has a
  • capital from which he wishes to derive a revenue, without taking the
  • trouble to employ it himself, deliberates whether he should buy land with
  • it, or lend it out at interest. The superior security of land, together
  • with some other advantages which almost everywhere attend upon this
  • species of property, will generally dispose him to content himself with a
  • smaller revenue from land, than what he might have by lending out his
  • money at interest. These advantages are sufficient to compensate a certain
  • difference of revenue; but they will compensate a certain difference only;
  • and if the rent of land should fall short of the interest of money by a
  • greater difference, nobody would buy land, which would soon reduce its
  • ordinary price. On the contrary, if the advantages should much more than
  • compensate the difference, everybody would buy land, which again would
  • soon raise its ordinary price. When interest was at ten per cent. land was
  • commonly sold for ten or twelve years purchase. As interest sunk to six,
  • five, and four per cent. the price of land rose to twenty,
  • five-and-twenty, and thirty years purchase. The market rate of interest is
  • higher in France than in England, and the common price of land is lower.
  • In England it commonly sells at thirty, in France at twenty years
  • purchase.
  • CHAPTER V.
  • OF THE DIFFERENT EMPLOYMENTS OF CAPITALS.
  • Though all capitals are destined for the maintenance of productive labour
  • only, yet the quantity of that labour which equal capitals are capable of
  • putting into motion, varies extremely according to the diversity of their
  • employment; as does likewise the value which that employment adds to the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of the country.
  • A capital may be employed in four different ways; either, first, in
  • procuring the rude produce annually required for the use and consumption
  • of the society; or, secondly, in manufacturing and preparing that rude
  • produce for immediate use and consumption; or, thirdly in transporting
  • either the rude or manufactured produce from the places where they abound
  • to those where they are wanted; or, lastly, in dividing particular
  • portions of either into such small parcels as suit the occasional demands
  • of those who want them. In the first way are employed the capitals of all
  • those who undertake improvement or cultivation of lands, mines, or
  • fisheries; in the second, those of all master manufacturers; in the third,
  • those of all wholesale merchants; and in the fourth, those of all
  • retailers. It is difficult to conceive that a capital should be employed
  • in any way which may not be classed under some one or other of those four.
  • Each of those four methods of employing a capital is essentially
  • necessary, either to the existence or extension of the other three, or to
  • the general conveniency of the society.
  • Unless a capital was employed in furnishing rude produce to a certain
  • degree of abundance, neither manufactures nor trade of any kind could
  • exist.
  • Unless a capital was employed in manufacturing that part of the rude
  • produce which requires a good deal of preparation before it can be fit for
  • use and consumption, it either would never be produced, because there
  • could be no demand for it; or if it was produced spontaneously, it would
  • be of no value in exchange, and could add nothing to the wealth of the
  • society.
  • Unless a capital was employed in transporting either the rude or
  • manufactured produce from the places where it abounds to those where it is
  • wanted, no more of either could be produced than was necessary for the
  • consumption of the neighbourhood. The capital of the merchant exchanges
  • the surplus produce of one place for that of another, and thus encourages
  • the industry, and increases the enjoyments of both.
  • Unless a capital was employed in breaking and dividing certain portions
  • either of the rude or manufactured produce into such small parcels as suit
  • the occasional demands of those who want them, every man would be obliged
  • to purchase a greater quantity of the goods he wanted than his immediate
  • occasions required. If there was no such trade as a butcher, for example,
  • every man would be obliged to purchase a whole ox or a whole sheep at a
  • time. This would generally be inconvenient to the rich, and much more so
  • to the poor. If a poor workman was obliged to purchase a month’s or six
  • months’ provisions at a time, a great part of the stock which he employs
  • as a capital in the instruments of his trade, or in the furniture of his
  • shop, and which yields him a revenue, he would be forced to place in that
  • part of his stock which is reserved for immediate consumption, and which
  • yields him no revenue. Nothing can be more convenient for such a person
  • than to be able to purchase his subsistence from day to day, or even from
  • hour to hour, as he wants it. He is thereby enabled to employ almost his
  • whole stock as a capital. He is thus enabled to furnish work to a greater
  • value; and the profit which he makes by it in this way much more than
  • compensates the additional price which the profit of the retailer imposes
  • upon the goods. The prejudices of some political writers against
  • shopkeepers and tradesmen are altogether without foundation. So far is it
  • from being necessary either to tax them, or to restrict their numbers,
  • that they can never be multiplied so as to hurt the public, though they
  • may so as to hurt one another. The quantity of grocery goods, for example,
  • which can be sold in a particular town, is limited by the demand of that
  • town and its neighbourhood. The capital, therefore, which can be employed
  • in the grocery trade, cannot exceed what is sufficient to purchase that
  • quantity. If this capital is divided between two different grocers, their
  • competition will tend to make both of them sell cheaper than if it were in
  • the hands of one only; and if it were divided among twenty, their
  • competition would be just so much the greater, and the chance of their
  • combining together, in order to raise the price, just so much the less.
  • Their competition might, perhaps, ruin some of themselves; but to take
  • care of this, is the business of the parties concerned, and it may safely
  • be trusted to their discretion. It can never hurt either the consumer or
  • the producer; on the contrary, it must tend to make the retailers both
  • sell cheaper and buy dearer, than if the whole trade was monopolized by
  • one or two persons. Some of them, perhaps, may sometimes decoy a weak
  • customer to buy what he has no occasion for. This evil, however, is of too
  • little importance to deserve the public attention, nor would it
  • necessarily be prevented by restricting their numbers. It is not the
  • multitude of alehouses, to give the must suspicious example, that
  • occasions a general disposition to drunkenness among the common people;
  • but that disposition, arising from other causes, necessarily gives
  • employment to a multitude of alehouses.
  • The persons whose capitals are employed in any of those four ways, are
  • themselves productive labourers. Their labour, when properly directed,
  • fixes and realizes itself in the subject or vendible commodity upon which
  • it is bestowed, and generally adds to its price the value at least of
  • their own maintenance and consumption. The profits of the farmer, of the
  • manufacturer, of the merchant, and retailer, are all drawn from the price
  • of the goods which the two first produce, and the two last buy and sell.
  • Equal capitals, however, employed in each of those four different ways,
  • will immediately put into motion very different quantities of productive
  • labour; and augment, too, in very different proportions, the value of the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of the society to which they belong.
  • The capital of the retailer replaces, together with its profits, that of
  • the merchant of whom he purchases goods, and thereby enables him to
  • continue his business. The retailer himself is the only productive
  • labourer whom it immediately employs. In his profit consists the whole
  • value which its employment adds to the annual produce of the land and
  • labour of the society.
  • The capital of the wholesale merchant replaces, together with their
  • profits, the capitals of the farmers and manufacturers of whom he
  • purchases the rude and manufactured produce which he deals in, and thereby
  • enables them to continue their respective trades. It is by this service
  • chiefly that he contributes indirectly to support the productive labour of
  • the society, and to increase the value of its annual produce. His capital
  • employs, too, the sailors and carriers who transport his goods from one
  • place to another; and it augments the price of those goods by the value,
  • not only of his profits, but of their wages. This is all the productive
  • labour which it immediately puts into motion, and all the value which it
  • immediately adds to the annual produce. Its operation in both these
  • respects is a good deal superior to that of the capital of the retailer.
  • Part of the capital of the master manufacturer is employed as a fixed
  • capital in the instruments of his trade, and replaces, together with its
  • profits, that of some other artificer of whom he purchases them. Part of
  • his circulating capital is employed in purchasing materials, and replaces,
  • with their profits, the capitals of the farmers and miners of whom he
  • purchases them. But a great part of it is always, either annually, or in a
  • much shorter period, distributed among the different workmen whom he
  • employs. It augments the value of those materials by their wages, and by
  • their masters’ profits upon the whole stock of wages, materials, and
  • instruments of trade employed in the business. It puts immediately into
  • motion, therefore, a much greater quantity of productive labour, and adds
  • a much greater value to the annual produce of the land and labour of the
  • society, than an equal capital in the hands of any wholesale merchant.
  • No equal capital puts into motion a greater quantity of productive labour
  • than that of the farmer. Not only his labouring servants, but his
  • labouring cattle, are productive labourers. In agriculture, too, Nature
  • labours along with man; and though her labour costs no expense, its
  • produce has its value, as well as that of the most expensive workmen. The
  • most important operations of agriculture seem intended, not so much to
  • increase, though they do that too, as to direct the fertility of Nature
  • towards the production of the plants most profitable to man. A field
  • overgrown with briars and brambles, may frequently produce as great a
  • quantity of vegetables as the best cultivated vineyard or corn field.
  • Planting and tillage frequently regulate more than they animate the active
  • fertility of Nature; and after all their labour, a great part of the work
  • always remains to be done by her. The labourers and labouring cattle,
  • therefore, employed in agriculture, not only occasion, like the workmen in
  • manufactures, the reproduction of a value equal to their own consumption,
  • or to the capital which employs them, together with its owner’s profits,
  • but of a much greater value. Over and above the capital of the farmer, and
  • all its profits, they regularly occasion the reproduction of the rent of
  • the landlord. This rent may be considered as the produce of those powers
  • of Nature, the use of which the landlord lends to the farmer. It is
  • greater or smaller, according to the supposed extent of those powers, or,
  • in other words, according to the supposed natural or improved fertility of
  • the land. It is the work of Nature which remains, after deducting or
  • compensating every thing which can be regarded as the work of man. It is
  • seldom less than a fourth, and frequently more than a third, of the whole
  • produce. No equal quantity of productive labour employed in manufactures,
  • can ever occasion so great reproduction. In them Nature does nothing; man
  • does all; and the reproduction must always be in proportion to the
  • strength of the agents that occasion it. The capital employed in
  • agriculture, therefore, not only puts into motion a greater quantity of
  • productive labour than any equal capital employed in manufactures; but in
  • proportion, too, to the quantity of productive labour which it employs, it
  • adds a much greater value to the annual produce of the land and labour of
  • the country, to the real wealth and revenue of its inhabitants. Of all the
  • ways in which a capital can be employed, it is by far the most
  • advantageous to society.
  • The capitals employed in the agriculture and in the retail trade of any
  • society, must always reside within that society. Their employment is
  • confined almost to a precise spot, to the farm, and to the shop of the
  • retailer. They must generally, too, though there are some exceptions to
  • this, belong to resident members of the society.
  • The capital of a wholesale merchant, on the contrary, seems to have no
  • fixed or necessary residence anywhere, but may wander about from place to
  • place, according as it can either buy cheap or sell dear.
  • The capital of the manufacturer must, no doubt, reside where the
  • manufacture is carried on; but where this shall be, is not always
  • necessarily determined. It may frequently be at a great distance, both
  • from the place where the materials grow, and from that where the complete
  • manufacture is consumed. Lyons is very distant, both from the places which
  • afford the materials of its manufactures, and from those which consume
  • them. The people of fashion in Sicily are clothed in silks made in other
  • countries, from the materials which their own produces. Part of the wool
  • of Spain is manufactured in Great Britain, and some part of that cloth is
  • afterwards sent back to Spain.
  • Whether the merchant whose capital exports the surplus produce of any
  • society, be a native or a foreigner, is of very little importance. If he
  • is a foreigner, the number of their productive labourers is necessarily
  • less than if he had been a native, by one man only; and the value of their
  • annual produce, by the profits of that one man. The sailors or carriers
  • whom he employs, may still belong indifferently either to his country, or
  • to their country, or to some third country, in the same manner as if he
  • had been a native. The capital of a foreigner gives a value to their
  • surplus produce equally with that of a native, by exchanging it for
  • something for which there is a demand at home. It as effectually replaces
  • the capital of the person who produces that surplus, and as effectually
  • enables him to continue his business, the service by which the capital of
  • a wholesale merchant chiefly contributes to support the productive labour,
  • and to augment the value of the annual produce of the society to which he
  • belongs.
  • It is of more consequence that the capital of the manufacturer should
  • reside within the country. It necessarily puts into motion a greater
  • quantity of productive labour, and adds a greater value to the annual
  • produce of the land and labour of the society. It may, however, be very
  • useful to the country, though it should not reside within it. The capitals
  • of the British manufacturers who work up the flax and hemp annually
  • imported from the coasts of the Baltic, are surely very useful to the
  • countries which produce them. Those materials are a part of the surplus
  • produce of those countries, which, unless it was annually exchanged for
  • something which is in demand here, would be of no value, and would soon
  • cease to be produced. The merchants who export it, replace the capitals of
  • the people who produce it, and thereby encourage them to continue the
  • production; and the British manufacturers replace the capitals of those
  • merchants.
  • A particular country, in the same manner as a particular person, may
  • frequently not have capital sufficient both to improve and cultivate all
  • its lands, to manufacture and prepare their whole rude produce for
  • immediate use and consumption, and to transport the surplus part either of
  • the rude or manufactured produce to those distant markets, where it can be
  • exchanged for something for which there is a demand at home. The
  • inhabitants of many different parts of Great Britain have not capital
  • sufficient to improve and cultivate all their lands. The wool of the
  • southern counties of Scotland is, a great part of it, after a long land
  • carriage through very bad roads, manufactured in Yorkshire, for want of a
  • capital to manufacture it at home. There are many little manufacturing
  • towns in Great Britain, of which the inhabitants have not capital
  • sufficient to transport the produce of their own industry to those distant
  • markets where there is demand and consumption for it. If there are any
  • merchants among them, they are, properly, only the agents of wealthier
  • merchants who reside in some of the great commercial cities.
  • When the capital of any country is not sufficient for all those three
  • purposes, in proportion as a greater share of it is employed in
  • agriculture, the greater will be the quantity of productive labour which
  • it puts into motion within the country; as will likewise be the value
  • which its employment adds to the annual produce of the land and labour of
  • the society. After agriculture, the capital employed in manufactures puts
  • into motion the greatest quantity of productive labour, and adds the
  • greatest value to the annual produce. That which is employed in the trade
  • of exportation has the least effect of any of the three.
  • The country, indeed, which has not capital sufficient for all those three
  • purposes, has not arrived at that degree of opulence for which it seems
  • naturally destined. To attempt, however, prematurely, and with an
  • insufficient capital, to do all the three, is certainly not the shortest
  • way for a society, no more than it would be for an individual, to acquire
  • a sufficient one. The capital of all the individuals of a nation has its
  • limits, in the same manner as that of a single individual, and is capable
  • of executing only certain purposes. The capital of all the individuals of
  • a nation is increased in the same manner as that of a single individual,
  • by their continually accumulating and adding to it whatever they save out
  • of their revenue. It is likely to increase the fastest, therefore, when it
  • is employed in the way that affords the greatest revenue to all the
  • inhabitants or the country, as they will thus be enabled to make the
  • greatest savings. But the revenue of all the inhabitants of the country is
  • necessarily in proportion to the value of the annual produce of their land
  • and labour.
  • It has been the principal cause of the rapid progress of our American
  • colonies towards wealth and greatness, that almost their whole capitals
  • have hitherto been employed in agriculture. They have no manufactures,
  • those household and coarser manufactures excepted, which necessarily
  • accompany the progress of agriculture, and which are the work of the women
  • and children in every private family. The greater part, both of the
  • exportation and coasting trade of America, is carried on by the capitals
  • of merchants who reside in Great Britain. Even the stores and warehouses
  • from which goods are retailed in some provinces, particularly in Virginia
  • and Maryland, belong many of them to merchants who reside in the mother
  • country, and afford one of the few instances of the retail trade of a
  • society being carried on by the capitals of those who are not resident
  • members of it. Were the Americans, either by combination, or by any other
  • sort of violence, to stop the importation of European manufactures, and,
  • by thus giving a monopoly to such of their own countrymen as could
  • manufacture the like goods, divert any considerable part of their capital
  • into this employment, they would retard, instead of accelerating, the
  • further increase in the value of their annual produce, and would obstruct,
  • instead of promoting, the progress of their country towards real wealth
  • and greatness. This would be still more the case, were they to attempt, in
  • the same manner, to monopolize to themselves their whole exportation
  • trade.
  • The course of human prosperity, indeed, seems scarce ever to have been of
  • so long continuance as to unable any great country to acquire capital
  • sufficient for all those three purposes; unless, perhaps, we give credit
  • to the wonderful accounts of the wealth and cultivation of China, of those
  • of ancient Egypt, and of the ancient state of Indostan. Even those three
  • countries, the wealthiest, according to all accounts, that ever were in
  • the world, are chiefly renowned for their superiority in agriculture and
  • manufactures. They do not appear to have been eminent for foreign trade.
  • The ancient Egyptians had a superstitious antipathy to the sea; a
  • superstition nearly of the same kind prevails among the Indians; and the
  • Chinese have never excelled in foreign commerce. The greater part of the
  • surplus produce of all those three countries seems to have been always
  • exported by foreigners, who gave in exchange for it something else, for
  • which they found a demand there, frequently gold and silver.
  • It is thus that the same capital will in any country put into motion a
  • greater or smaller quantity of productive labour, and add a greater or
  • smaller value to the annual produce of its land and labour, according to
  • the different proportions in which it is employed in agriculture,
  • manufactures, and wholesale trade. The difference, too, is very great,
  • according to the different sorts of wholesale trade in which any part of
  • it is employed.
  • All wholesale trade, all buying in order to sell again by wholesale, maybe
  • reduced to three different sorts: the home trade, the foreign trade of
  • consumption, and the carrying trade. The home trade is employed in
  • purchasing in one part of the same country, and selling in another, the
  • produce of the industry of that country. It comprehends both the inland
  • and the coasting trade. The foreign trade of consumption is employed in
  • purchasing foreign goods for home consumption. The carrying trade is
  • employed in transacting the commerce of foreign countries, or in carrying
  • the surplus produce of one to another.
  • The capital which is employed in purchasing in one part of the country, in
  • order to sell in another, the produce of the industry of that country,
  • generally replaces, by every such operation, two distinct capitals, that
  • had both been employed in the agriculture or manufactures of that country,
  • and thereby enables them to continue that employment. When it sends out
  • from the residence of the merchant a certain value of commodities, it
  • generally brings hack in return at least an equal value of other
  • commodities. When both are the produce of domestic industry, it
  • necessarily replaces, by every such operation, two distinct capitals,
  • which had both been employed in supporting productive labour, and thereby
  • enables them to continue that support. The capital which sends Scotch
  • manufactures to London, and brings back English corn and manufactures to
  • Edinburgh, necessarily replaces, by every such operation, two British
  • capitals, which had both been employed in the agriculture or manufactures
  • of Great Britain.
  • The capital employed in purchasing foreign goods for home consumption,
  • when this purchase is made with the produce of domestic industry,
  • replaces, too, by every such operation, two distinct capitals; but one of
  • them only is employed in supporting domestic industry. The capital which
  • sends British goods to Portugal, and brings back Portuguese goods to Great
  • Britain, replaces, by every such operation, only one British capital. The
  • other is a Portuguese one. Though the returns, therefore, of the foreign
  • trade of consumption, should be as quick as those of the home trade, the
  • capital employed in it will give but one half of the encouragement to the
  • industry or productive labour of the country.
  • But the returns of the foreign trade of consumption are very seldom so
  • quick as those of the home trade. The returns of the home trade generally
  • come in before the end of the year, and sometimes three or four times in
  • the year. The returns of the foreign trade of consumption seldom come in
  • before the end of the year, and sometimes not till after two or three
  • years. A capital, therefore, employed in the home trade, will sometimes
  • make twelve operations, or be sent out and returned twelve times, before a
  • capital employed in the foreign trade of consumption has made one. If the
  • capitals are equal, therefore, the one will give four-and-twenty times
  • more encouragement and support to the industry of the country than the
  • other.
  • The foreign goods for home consumption may sometimes be purchased, not
  • with the produce of domestic industry but with some other foreign goods.
  • These last, however, must have been purchased, either immediately with the
  • produce of domestic industry, or with something else that had been
  • purchased with it; for, the case of war and conquest excepted, foreign
  • goods can never be acquired, but in exchange for something that had been
  • produced at home, either immediately, or after two or more different
  • exchanges. The effects, therefore, of a capital employed in such a
  • round-about foreign trade of consumption, are, in every respect, the same
  • as those of one employed in the most direct trade of the same kind, except
  • that the final returns are likely to be still more distant, as they must
  • depend upon the returns of two or three distinct foreign trades. If the
  • hemp and flax of Riga are purchased with the tobacco of Virginia, which
  • had been purchased with British manufactures, the merchant must wait for
  • the returns of two distinct foreign trades, before he can employ the same
  • capital in repurchasing a like quantity of British manufactures. If the
  • tobacco of Virginia had been purchased, not with British manufactures, but
  • with the sugar and rum of Jamaica, which had been purchased with those
  • manufactures, he must wait for the returns of three. If those two or three
  • distinct foreign trades should happen to be carried on by two or three
  • distinct merchants, of whom the second buys the goods imported by the
  • first, and the third buys those imported by the second, in order to export
  • them again, each merchant, indeed, will, in this case, receive the returns
  • of his own capital more quickly; but the final returns of the whole
  • capital employed in the trade will be just as slow as ever. Whether the
  • whole capital employed in such a round about trade belong to one merchant
  • or to three, can make no difference with regard to the country, though it
  • may with regard to the particular merchants. Three times a greater capital
  • must in both cases be employed, in order to exchange a certain value of
  • British manufactures for a certain quantity of flax and hemp, than would
  • have been necessary, had the manufactures and the flax and hemp been
  • directly exchanged for one another. The whole capital employed, therefore,
  • in such a round-about foreign trade of consumption, will generally give
  • less encouragement and support to the productive labour of the country,
  • than an equal capital employed in a more direct trade of the same kind.
  • Whatever be the foreign commodity with which the foreign goods for home
  • consumption are purchased, it can occasion no essential difference, either
  • in the nature of the trade, or in the encouragement and support which it
  • can give to the productive labour of the country from which it is carried
  • on. If they are purchased with the gold of Brazil, for example, or with
  • the silver of Peru, this gold and silver, like the tobacco of Virginia,
  • must have been purchased with something that either was the produce of the
  • industry of the country, or that had been purchased with something else
  • that was so. So far, therefore, as the productive labour of the country is
  • concerned, the foreign trade of consumption, which is carried on by means
  • of gold and silver, has all the advantages and all the inconveniencies of
  • any other equally round-about foreign trade of consumption; and will
  • replace, just as fast, or just as slow, the capital which is immediately
  • employed in supporting that productive labour. It seems even to have one
  • advantage over any other equally round-about foreign trade. The
  • transportation of those metals from one place to another, on account of
  • their small bulk and great value, is less expensive than that of almost
  • any other foreign goods of equal value. Their freight is much less, and
  • their insurance not greater; and no goods, besides, are less liable to
  • suffer by the carriage. An equal quantity of foreign goods, therefore, may
  • frequently be purchased with a smaller quantity of the produce of domestic
  • industry, by the intervention of gold and silver, than by that of any
  • other foreign goods. The demand of the country may frequently, in this
  • manner, be supplied more completely, and at a smaller expense, than in any
  • other. Whether, by the continual exportation of those metals, a trade of
  • this kind is likely to impoverish the country from which it is carried on
  • in any other way, I shall have occasion to examine at great length
  • hereafter.
  • That part of the capital of any country which is employed in the carrying
  • trade, is altogether withdrawn from supporting the productive labour of
  • that particular country, to support that of some foreign countries. Though
  • it may replace, by every operation, two distinct capitals, yet neither of
  • them belongs to that particular country. The capital of the Dutch
  • merchant, which carries the corn of Poland to Portugal, and brings back
  • the fruits and wines of Portugal to Poland, replaces by every such
  • operation two capitals, neither of which had been employed in supporting
  • the productive labour of Holland; but one of them in supporting that of
  • Poland, and the other that of Portugal. The profits only return regularly
  • to Holland, and constitute the whole addition which this trade necessarily
  • makes to the annual produce of the land and labour of that country. When,
  • indeed, the carrying trade of any particular country is carried on with
  • the ships and sailors of that country, that part of the capital employed
  • in it which pays the freight is distributed among, and puts into motion, a
  • certain number of productive labourers of that country. Almost all nations
  • that have had any considerable share of the carrying trade have, in fact,
  • carried it on in this manner. The trade itself has probably derived its
  • name from it, the people of such countries being the carriers to other
  • countries. It does not, however, seem essential to the nature of the trade
  • that it should be so. A Dutch merchant may, for example, employ his
  • capital in transacting the commerce of Poland and Portugal, by carrying
  • part of the surplus produce of the one to the other, not in Dutch, but in
  • British bottoms. It maybe presumed, that he actually does so upon some
  • particular occasions. It is upon this account, however, that the carrying
  • trade has been supposed peculiarly advantageous to such a country as Great
  • Britain, of which the defence and security depend upon the number of its
  • sailors and shipping. But the same capital may employ as many sailors and
  • shipping, either in the foreign trade of consumption, or even in the home
  • trade, when carried on by coasting vessels, as it could in the carrying
  • trade. The number of sailors and shipping which any particular capital can
  • employ, does not depend upon the nature of the trade, but partly upon the
  • bulk of the goods, in proportion to their value, and partly upon the
  • distance of the ports between which they are to be carried; chiefly upon
  • the former of those two circumstances. The coal trade from Newcastle to
  • London, for example, employs more shipping than all the carrying trade of
  • England, though the ports are at no great distance. To force, therefore,
  • by extraordinary encouragements, a larger share of the capital of any
  • country into the carrying trade, than what would naturally go to it, will
  • not always necessarily increase the shipping of that country.
  • The capital, therefore, employed in the home trade of any country, will
  • generally give encouragement and support to a greater quantity of
  • productive labour in that country, and increase the value of its annual
  • produce, more than an equal capital employed in the foreign trade of
  • consumption; and the capital employed in this latter trade has, in both
  • these respects, a still greater advantage over an equal capital employed
  • in the carrying trade. The riches, and so far as power depends upon
  • riches, the power of every country must always be in proportion to the
  • value of its annual produce, the fund from which all taxes must ultimately
  • be paid. But the great object of the political economy of every country,
  • is to increase the riches and power of that country. It ought, therefore,
  • to give no preference nor superior encouragement to the foreign trade of
  • consumption above the home trade, nor to the carrying trade above either
  • of the other two. It ought neither to force nor to allure into either of
  • those two channels a greater share of the capital of the country, than
  • what would naturally flow into them of its own accord.
  • Each of those different branches of trade, however, is not only
  • advantageous, but necessary and unavoidable, when the course of things,
  • without any constraint or violence, naturally introduces it.
  • When the produce of any particular branch of industry exceeds what the
  • demand of the country requires, the surplus must be sent abroad, and
  • exchanged for something for which there is a demand at home. Without such
  • exportation, a part of the productive labour of the country must cease,
  • and the value of its annual produce diminish. The land and labour of Great
  • Britain produce generally more corn, woollens, and hardware, than the
  • demand of the home market requires. The surplus part of them, therefore,
  • must be sent abroad, and exchanged for something for which there is a
  • demand at home. It is only by means of such exportation, that this surplus
  • can acquired value sufficient to compensate the labour and expense of
  • producing it. The neighbourhood of the sea-coast, and the banks of all
  • navigable rivers, are advantageous situations for industry, only because
  • they facilitate the exportation and exchange of such surplus produce for
  • something else which is more in demand there.
  • When the foreign goods which are thus purchased with the surplus produce
  • of domestic industry exceed the demand of the home market, the surplus
  • part of them must be sent abroad again, and exchanged for something more
  • in demand at home. About 96,000 hogsheads of tobacco are annually
  • purchased in Virginia and Maryland with a part of the surplus produce of
  • British industry. But the demand of Great Britain does not require,
  • perhaps, more than 14,000. If the remaining 82,000, therefore, could not
  • be sent abroad, and exchanged for something more in demand at home, the
  • importation of them must cease immediately, and with it the productive
  • labour of all those inhabitants of Great Britain who are at present
  • employed in preparing the goods with which these 82,000 hogsheads are
  • annually purchased. Those goods, which are part of the produce of the land
  • and labour of Great Britain, having no market at home, and being deprived
  • of that which they had abroad, must cease to be produced. The most
  • round-about foreign trade of consumption, therefore, may, upon some
  • occasions, be as necessary for supporting the productive labour of the
  • country, and the value of its annual produce, as the most direct.
  • When the capital stock of any country is increased to such a degree that
  • it cannot be all employed in supplying the consumption, and supporting the
  • productive labour of that particular country, the surplus part of it
  • naturally disgorges itself into the carrying trade, and is employed in
  • performing the same offices to other countries. The carrying trade is the
  • natural effect and symptom of great national wealth; but it does not seem
  • to be the natural cause of it. Those statesmen who have been disposed to
  • favour it with particular encouragement, seem to have mistaken the effect
  • and symptom for the cause. Holland, in proportion to the extent of the
  • land and the number of its inhabitants, by far the richest country in
  • Europe, has accordingly the greatest share of the carrying trade of
  • Europe. England, perhaps the second richest country of Europe, is likewise
  • supposed to have a considerable share in it; though what commonly passes
  • for the carrying trade of England will frequently, perhaps, be found to be
  • no more than a round-about foreign trade of consumption. Such are, in a
  • great measure, the trades which carry the goods of the East and West
  • Indies and of America to the different European markets. Those goods are
  • generally purchased, either immediately with the produce of British
  • industry, or with something else which had been purchased with that
  • produce, and the final returns of those trades are generally used or
  • consumed in Great Britain. The trade which is carried on in British
  • bottoms between the different ports of the Mediterranean, and some trade
  • of the same kind carried on by British merchants between the different
  • ports of India, make, perhaps, the principal branches of what is properly
  • the carrying trade of Great Britain.
  • The extent of the home trade, and of the capital which can be employed in
  • it, is necessarily limited by the value of the surplus produce of all
  • those distant places within the country which have occasion to exchange
  • their respective productions with one another; that of the foreign trade
  • of consumption, by the value of the surplus produce of the whole country,
  • and of what can be purchased with it; that of the carrying trade, by the
  • value of the surplus produce of all the different countries in the world.
  • Its possible extent, therefore, is in a manner infinite in comparison of
  • that of the other two, and is capable of absorbing the greatest capitals.
  • The consideration of his own private profit is the sole motive which
  • determines the owner of any capital to employ it either in agriculture, in
  • manufactures, or in some particular branch of the wholesale or retail
  • trade. The different quantities of productive labour which it may put into
  • motion, and the different values which it may add to the annual produce of
  • the land and labour of the society, according as it is employed in one or
  • other of those different ways, never enter into his thoughts. In
  • countries, therefore, where agriculture is the most profitable of all
  • employments, and farming and improving the most direct roads to a splendid
  • fortune, the capitals of individuals will naturally be employed in the
  • manner most advantageous to the whole society. The profits of agriculture,
  • however, seem to have no superiority over those of other employments in
  • any part of Europe. Projectors, indeed, in every corner of it, have,
  • within these few years, amused the public with most magnificent accounts
  • of the profits to be made by the cultivation and improvement of land.
  • Without entering into any particular discussion of their calculations, a
  • very simple observation may satisfy us that the result of them must be
  • false. We see, every day, the most splendid fortunes, that have been
  • acquired in the course of a single life, by trade and manufactures,
  • frequently from a very small capital, sometimes from no capital. A single
  • instance of such a fortune, acquired by agriculture in the same time, and
  • from such a capital, has not, perhaps, occurred in Europe, during the
  • course of the present century. In all the great countries of Europe,
  • however, much good land still remains uncultivated; and the greater part
  • of what is cultivated, is far from being improved to the degree of which
  • it is capable. Agriculture, therefore, is almost everywhere capable of
  • absorbing a much greater capital than has ever yet been employed in it.
  • What circumstances in the policy of Europe have given the trades which are
  • carried on in towns so great an advantage over that which is carried on in
  • the country, that private persons frequently find it more for their
  • advantage to employ their capitals in the most distant carrying trades of
  • Asia and America than in the improvement and cultivation of the most
  • fertile fields in their own neighbourhood, I shall endeavour to explain at
  • full length in the two following books.
  • BOOK III.
  • OF THE DIFFERENT PROGRESS OF OPULENCE IN
  • DIFFERENT NATIONS
  • CHAPTER I.
  • OF THE NATURAL PROGRESS OF OPULENCE.
  • The great commerce of every civilized society is that carried on between
  • the inhabitants of the town and those of the country. It consists in the
  • exchange of rude for manufactured produce, either immediately, or by the
  • intervention of money, or of some sort of paper which represents money.
  • The country supplies the town with the means of subsistence and the
  • materials of manufacture. The town repays this supply, by sending back a
  • part of the manufactured produce to the inhabitants of the country. The
  • town, in which there neither is nor can be any reproduction of substances,
  • may very properly be said to gain its whole wealth and subsistence from
  • the country. We must not, however, upon this account, imagine that the
  • gain of the town is the loss of the country. The gains of both are mutual
  • and reciprocal, and the division of labour is in this, as in all other
  • cases, advantageous to all the different persons employed in the various
  • occupations into which it is subdivided. The inhabitants of the country
  • purchase of the town a greater quantity of manufactured goods with the
  • produce of a much smaller quantity of their own labour, than they must
  • have employed had they attempted to prepare them themselves. The town
  • affords a market for the surplus produce of the country, or what is over
  • and above the maintenance of the cultivators; and it is there that the
  • inhabitants of the country exchange it for something else which is in
  • demand among them. The greater the number and revenue of the inhabitants
  • of the town, the more extensive is the market which it affords to those of
  • the country; and the more extensive that market, it is always the more
  • advantageous to a great number. The corn which grows within a mile of the
  • town, sells there for the same price with that which comes from twenty
  • miles distance. But the price of the latter must, generally, not only pay
  • the expense of raising it and bringing it to market, but afford, too, the
  • ordinary profits of agriculture to the farmer. The proprietors and
  • cultivators of the country, therefore, which lies in the neighbourhood of
  • the town, over and above the ordinary profits of agriculture, gain, in the
  • price of what they sell, the whole value of the carriage of the like
  • produce that is brought from more distant parts; and they save, besides,
  • the whole value of this carriage in the price of what they buy. Compare
  • the cultivation of the lands in the neighbourhood of any considerable
  • town, with that of those which lie at some distance from it, and you will
  • easily satisfy yourself bow much the country is benefited by the commerce
  • of the town. Among all the absurd speculations that have been propagated
  • concerning the balance of trade, it has never been pretended that either
  • the country loses by its commerce with the town, or the town by that with
  • the country which maintains it.
  • As subsistence is, in the nature of things, prior to conveniency and
  • luxury, so the industry which procures the former, must necessarily be
  • prior to that which ministers to the latter. The cultivation and
  • improvement of the country, therefore, which affords subsistence, must,
  • necessarily, be prior to the increase of the town, which furnishes only
  • the means of conveniency and luxury. It is the surplus produce of the
  • country only, or what is over and above the maintenance of the
  • cultivators, that constitutes the subsistence of the town, which can
  • therefore increase only with the increase of the surplus produce. The
  • town, indeed, may not always derive its whole subsistence from the country
  • in its neighbourhood, or even from the territory to which it belongs, but
  • from very distant countries; and this, though it forms no exception from
  • the general rule, has occasioned considerable variations in the progress
  • of opulence in different ages and nations.
  • That order of things which necessity imposes, in general, though not in
  • every particular country, is in every particular country promoted by the
  • natural inclinations of man. If human institutions had never thwarted
  • those natural inclinations, the towns could nowhere have increased beyond
  • what the improvement and cultivation of the territory in which they were
  • situated could support; till such time, at least, as the whole of that
  • territory was completely cultivated and improved. Upon equal, or nearly
  • equal profits, most men will choose to employ their capitals, rather in
  • the improvement and cultivation of land, than either in manufactures or in
  • foreign trade. The man who employs his capital in land, has it more under
  • his view and command; and his fortune is much less liable to accidents
  • than that of the trader, who is obliged frequently to commit it, not only
  • to the winds and the waves, but to the more uncertain elements of human
  • folly and injustice, by giving great credits, in distant countries, to men
  • with whose character and situation he can seldom be thoroughly acquainted.
  • The capital of the landlord, on the contrary, which is fixed in the
  • improvement of his land, seems to be as well secured as the nature of
  • human affairs can admit of. The beauty of the country, besides, the
  • pleasure of a country life, the tranquillity of mind which it promises,
  • and, wherever the injustice of human laws does not disturb it, the
  • independency which it really affords, have charms that, more or less,
  • attract everybody; and as to cultivate the ground was the original
  • destination of man, so, in every stage of his existence, he seems to
  • retain a predilection for this primitive employment.
  • Without the assistance of some artificers, indeed, the cultivation of land
  • cannot be carried on, but with great inconveniency and continual
  • interruption. Smiths, carpenters, wheelwrights and ploughwrights, masons
  • and bricklayers, tanners, shoemakers, and tailors, are people whose
  • service the farmer has frequent occasion for. Such artificers, too, stand
  • occasionally in need of the assistance of one another; and as their
  • residence is not, like that of the farmer, necessarily tied down to a
  • precise spot, they naturally settle in the neighbourhood of one another,
  • and thus form a small town or village. The butcher, the brewer, and the
  • baker, soon join them, together with many other artificers and retailers,
  • necessary or useful for supplying their occasional wants, and who
  • contribute still further to augment the town. The inhabitants of the town,
  • and those of the country, are mutually the servants of one another. The
  • town is a continual fair or market, to which the inhabitants of the
  • country resort, in order to exchange their rude for manufactured produce.
  • It is this commerce which supplies the inhabitants of the town, both with
  • the materials of their work, and the means of their subsistence. The
  • quantity of the finished work which they sell to the inhabitants of the
  • country, necessarily regulates the quantity of the materials and
  • provisions which they buy. Neither their employment nor subsistence,
  • therefore, can augment, but in proportion to the augmentation of the
  • demand from the country for finished work; and this demand can augment
  • only in proportion to the extension of improvement and cultivation. Had
  • human institutions, therefore, never disturbed the natural course of
  • things, the progressive wealth and increase of the towns would, in every
  • political society, be consequential, and in proportion to the improvement
  • and cultivation of the territory of country.
  • In our North American colonies, where uncultivated land is still to be had
  • upon easy terms, no manufactures for distant sale have ever yet been
  • established in any of their towns. When an artificer has acquired a little
  • more stock than is necessary for carrying on his own business in supplying
  • the neighbouring country, he does not, in North America, attempt to
  • establish with it a manufacture for more distant sale, but employs it in
  • the purchase and improvement of uncultivated land. From artificer he
  • becomes planter; and neither the large wages nor the easy subsistence
  • which that country affords to artificers, can bribe him rather to work for
  • other people than for himself. He feels that an artificer is the servant
  • of his customers, from whom he derives his subsistence; but that a planter
  • who cultivates his own land, and derives his necessary subsistence from
  • the labour of his own family, is really a master, and independent of all
  • the world.
  • In countries, on the contrary, where there is either no uncultivated land,
  • or none that can be had upon easy terms, every artificer who has acquired
  • more stock than he can employ in the occasional jobs of the neighbourhood,
  • endeavours to prepare work for more distant sale. The smith erects some
  • sort of iron, the weaver some sort of linen or woollen manufactory. Those
  • different manufactures come, in process of time, to be gradually
  • subdivided, and thereby improved and refined in a great variety of ways,
  • which may easily be conceived, and which it is therefore unnecessary to
  • explain any farther.
  • In seeking for employment to a capital, manufactures are, upon equal or
  • nearly equal profits, naturally preferred to foreign commerce, for the
  • same reason that agriculture is naturally preferred to manufactures. As
  • the capital of the landlord or farmer is more secure than that of the
  • manufacturer, so the capital of the manufacturer, being at all times more
  • within his view and command, is more secure than that of the foreign
  • merchant. In every period, indeed, of every society, the surplus part both
  • of the rude and manufactured produce, or that for which there is no demand
  • at home, must be sent abroad, in order to be exchanged for something for
  • which there is some demand at home. But whether the capital which carries
  • this surplus produce abroad be a foreign or a domestic one, is of very
  • little importance. If the society has not acquired sufficient capital,
  • both to cultivate all its lands, and to manufacture in the completest
  • manner the whole of its rude produce, there is even a considerable
  • advantage that the rude produce should be exported by a foreign capital,
  • in order that the whole stock of the society may be employed in more
  • useful purposes. The wealth of ancient Egypt, that of China and Indostan,
  • sufficiently demonstrate that a nation may attain a very high degree of
  • opulence, though the greater part of its exportation trade be carried on
  • by foreigners. The progress of our North American and West Indian
  • colonies, would have been much less rapid, had no capital but what
  • belonged to themselves been employed in exporting their surplus produce.
  • According to the natural course of things, therefore, the greater part of
  • the capital of every growing society is, first, directed to agriculture,
  • afterwards to manufactures, and, last of all, to foreign commerce. This
  • order of things is so very natural, that in every society that had any
  • territory, it has always, I believe, been in some degree observed. Some of
  • their lands must have been cultivated before any considerable towns could
  • be established, and some sort of coarse industry of the manufacturing kind
  • must have been carried on in those towns, before they could well think of
  • employing themselves in foreign commerce.
  • But though this natural order of things must have taken place in some
  • degree in every such society, it has, in all the modern states of Europe,
  • been in many respects entirely inverted. The foreign commerce of some of
  • their cities has introduced all their finer manufactures, or such as were
  • fit for distant sale; and manufactures and foreign commerce together have
  • given birth to the principal improvements of agriculture. The manners and
  • customs which the nature of their original government introduced, and
  • which remained after that government was greatly altered, necessarily
  • forced them into this unnatural and retrograde order.
  • CHAPTER II.
  • OF THE DISCOURAGEMENT OF AGRICULTURE
  • IN THE ANCIENT STATE OF EUROPE, AFTER THE FALL OF THE ROMAN EMPIRE.
  • When the German and Scythian nations overran the western provinces of the
  • Roman empire, the confusions which followed so great a revolution lasted
  • for several centuries. The rapine and violence which the barbarians
  • exercised against the ancient inhabitants, interrupted the commerce
  • between the towns and the country. The towns were deserted, and the
  • country was left uncultivated; and the western provinces of Europe, which
  • had enjoyed a considerable degree of opulence under the Roman empire, sunk
  • into the lowest state of poverty and barbarism. During the continuance of
  • those confusions, the chiefs and principal leaders of those nations
  • acquired, or usurped to themselves, the greater part of the lands of those
  • countries. A great part of them was uncultivated; but no part of them,
  • whether cultivated or uncultivated, was left without a proprietor. All of
  • them were engrossed, and the greater part by a few great proprietors.
  • This original engrossing of uncultivated lands, though a great, might have
  • been but a transitory evil. They might soon have been divided again, and
  • broke into small parcels, either by succession or by alienation. The law
  • of primogeniture hindered them from being divided by succession; the
  • introduction of entails prevented their being broke into small parcels by
  • alienation.
  • When land, like moveables, is considered as the means only of subsistence
  • and enjoyment, the natural law of succession divides it, like them, among
  • all the children of the family; of all of whom the subsistence and
  • enjoyment may be supposed equally dear to the father. This natural law of
  • succession, accordingly, took place among the Romans who made no more
  • distinction between elder and younger, between male and female, in the
  • inheritance of lands, than we do in the distribution of moveables. But
  • when land was considered as the means, not of subsistence merely, but of
  • power and protection, it was thought better that it should descend
  • undivided to one. In those disorderly times, every great landlord was a
  • sort of petty prince. His tenants were his subjects. He was their judge,
  • and in some respects their legislator in peace and their leader in war. He
  • made war according to his own discretion, frequently against his
  • neighbours, and sometimes against his sovereign. The security of a landed
  • estate, therefore, the protection which its owner could afford to those
  • who dwelt on it, depended upon its greatness. To divide it was to ruin it,
  • and to expose every part of it to be oppressed and swallowed up by the
  • incursions of its neighbours. The law of primogeniture, therefore, came to
  • take place, not immediately indeed, but in process of time, in the
  • succession of landed estates, for the same reason that it has generally
  • taken place in that of monarchies, though not always at their first
  • institution. That the power, and consequently the security of the
  • monarchy, may not be weakened by division, it must descend entire to one
  • of the children. To which of them so important a preference shall be
  • given, must be determined by some general rule, founded not upon the
  • doubtful distinctions of personal merit, but upon some plain and evident
  • difference which can admit of no dispute. Among the children of the same
  • family there can be no indisputable difference but that of sex, and that
  • of age. The male sex is universally preferred to the female; and when all
  • other things are equal, the elder everywhere takes place of the younger.
  • Hence the origin of the right of primogeniture, and of what is called
  • lineal succession.
  • Laws frequently continue in force long after the circumstances which first
  • gave occasion to them, and which could alone render them reasonable, are
  • no more. In the present state of Europe, the proprietor of a single acre
  • of land is as perfectly secure in his possession as the proprietor of
  • 100,000. The right of primogeniture, however, still continues to be
  • respected; and as of all institutions it is the fittest to support the
  • pride of family distinctions, it is still likely to endure for many
  • centuries. In every other respect, nothing can be more contrary to the
  • real interest of a numerous family, than a right which, in order to enrich
  • one, beggars all the rest of the children.
  • Entails are the natural consequences of the law of primogeniture. They
  • were introduced to preserve a certain lineal succession, of which the law
  • of primogeniture first gave the idea, and to hinder any part of the
  • original estate from being carried out of the proposed line, either by
  • gift, or device, or alienation; either by the folly, or by the misfortune
  • of any of its successive owners. They were altogether unknown to the
  • Romans. Neither their substitutions, nor fidei commisses, bear any
  • resemblance to entails, though some French lawyers have thought proper to
  • dress the modern institution in the language and garb of those ancient
  • ones.
  • When great landed estates were a sort of principalities, entails might not
  • be unreasonable. Like what are called the fundamental laws of some
  • monarchies, they might frequently hinder the security of thousands from
  • being endangered by the caprice or extravagance of one man. But in the
  • present state of Europe, when small as well as great estates derive their
  • security from the laws of their country, nothing can be more completely
  • absurd. They are founded upon the most absurd of all suppositions, the
  • supposition that every successive generation of men have not an equal
  • right to the earth, and to all that it possesses; but that the property of
  • the present generation should be restrained and regulated according to the
  • fancy of those who died, perhaps five hundred years ago. Entails, however,
  • are still respected, through the greater part of Europe; In those
  • countries, particularly, in which noble birth is a necessary qualification
  • for the enjoyment either of civil or military honours. Entails are thought
  • necessary for maintaining this exclusive privilege of the nobility to the
  • great offices and honours of their country; and that order having usurped
  • one unjust advantage over the rest of their fellow-citizens, lest their
  • poverty should render it ridiculous, it is thought reasonable that they
  • should have another. The common law of England, indeed, is said to abhor
  • perpetuities, and they are accordingly more restricted there than in any
  • other European monarchy; though even England is not altogether without
  • them. In Scotland, more than one fifth, perhaps more than one third part
  • of the whole lands in the country, are at present supposed to be under
  • strict entail.
  • Great tracts of uncultivated land were in this manner not only engrossed
  • by particular families, but the possibility of their being divided again
  • was as much as possible precluded for ever. It seldom happens, however,
  • that a great proprietor is a great improver. In the disorderly times which
  • gave birth to those barbarous institutions, the great proprietor was
  • sufficiently employed in defending his own territories, or in extending
  • his jurisdiction and authority over those of his neighbours. He had no
  • leisure to attend to the cultivation and improvement of land. When the
  • establishment of law and order afforded him this leisure, he often wanted
  • the inclination, and almost always the requisite abilities. If the expense
  • of his house and person either equalled or exceeded his revenue, as it did
  • very frequently, he had no stock to employ in this manner. If he was an
  • economist, he generally found it more profitable to employ his annual
  • savings in new purchases than in the improvement of his old estate. To
  • improve land with profit, like all other commercial projects, requires an
  • exact attention to small savings and small gains, of which a man born to a
  • great fortune, even though naturally frugal, is very seldom capable. The
  • situation of such a person naturally disposes him to attend rather to
  • ornament, which pleases his fancy, than to profit, for which he has so
  • little occasion. The elegance of his dress, of his equipage, of his house
  • and household furniture, are objects which, from his infancy, he has been
  • accustomed to have some anxiety about. The turn of mind which this habit
  • naturally forms, follows him when he comes to think of the improvement of
  • land. He embellishes, perhaps, four or five hundred acres in the
  • neighbourhood of his house, at ten times the expense which the land is
  • worth after all his improvements; and finds, that if he was to improve his
  • whole estate in the same manner, and he has little taste for any other, he
  • would be a bankrupt before he had finished the tenth part of it. There
  • still remain, in both parts of the united kingdom, some great estates
  • which have continued, without interruption, in the hands of the same
  • family since the times of feudal anarchy. Compare the present condition of
  • those estates with the possessions of the small proprietors in their
  • neighbourhood, and you will require no other argument to convince you how
  • unfavourable such extensive property is to improvement.
  • If little improvement was to be expected from such great proprietors,
  • still less was to be hoped for from those who occupied the land under
  • them. In the ancient state of Europe, the occupiers of land were all
  • tenants at will. They were all, or almost all, slaves, but their slavery
  • was of a milder kind than that known among the ancient Greeks and Romans,
  • or even in our West Indian colonies. They were supposed to belong more
  • directly to the land than to their master. They could, therefore, be sold
  • with it, but not separately. They could marry, provided it was with the
  • consent of their master; and he could not afterwards dissolve the marriage
  • by selling the man and wife to different persons. If he maimed or murdered
  • any of them, he was liable to some penalty, though generally but to a
  • small one. They were not, however, capable of acquiring property. Whatever
  • they acquired was acquired to their master, and he could take it from them
  • at pleasure. Whatever cultivation and improvement could be carried on by
  • means of such slaves, was properly carried on by their master. It was at
  • his expense. The seed, the cattle, and the instruments of husbandry, were
  • all his. It was for his benefit. Such slaves could acquire nothing but
  • their daily maintenance. It was properly the proprietor himself,
  • therefore, that in this case occupied his own lands, and cultivated them
  • by his own bondmen. This species of slavery still subsists in Russia,
  • Poland, Hungary, Bohemia, Moravia, and other parts of Germany. It is only
  • in the western and south-western provinces of Europe that it has gradually
  • been abolished altogether.
  • But if great improvements are seldom to be expected from great
  • proprietors, they are least of all to be expected when they employ slaves
  • for their workmen. The experience of all ages and nations, I believe,
  • demonstrates that the work done by slaves, though it appears to cost only
  • their maintenance, is in the end the dearest of any. A person who can
  • acquire no property can have no other interest but to eat as much and to
  • labour as little as possible. Whatever work he does beyond what is
  • sufficient to purchase his own maintenance, can be squeezed out of him by
  • violence only, and not by any interest of his own. In ancient Italy, how
  • much the cultivation of corn degenerated, how unprofitable it became to
  • the master, when it fell under the management of slaves, is remarked both
  • by Pliny and Columella. In the time of Aristotle, it had not been much
  • better in ancient Greece. Speaking of the ideal republic described in the
  • laws of Plato, to maintain 5000 idle men (the number of warriors supposed
  • necessary for its defence), together with their women and servants, would
  • require, he says, a territory of boundless extent and fertility, like the
  • plains of Babylon.
  • The pride of man makes him love to domineer, and nothing mortifies him so
  • much as to be obliged to condescend to persuade his inferiors. Wherever
  • the law allows it, and the nature of the work can afford it, therefore, he
  • will generally prefer the service of slaves to that of freemen. The
  • planting of sugar and tobacco can afford the expense of slave cultivation.
  • The raising of corn, it seems, in the present times, cannot. In the
  • English colonies, of which the principal produce is corn, the far greater
  • part of the work is done by freemen. The late resolution of the Quakers in
  • Pennsylvania, to set at liberty all their negro slaves, may satisfy us
  • that their number cannot be very great. Had they made any considerable
  • part of their property, such a resolution could never have been agreed to.
  • In our sugar colonies., on the contrary, the whole work is done by slaves,
  • and in our tobacco colonies a very great part of it. The profits of a
  • sugar plantation in any of our West Indian colonies, are generally much
  • greater than those of any other cultivation that is known either in Europe
  • or America; and the profits of a tobacco plantation, though inferior to
  • those of sugar, are superior to those of corn, as has already been
  • observed. Both can afford the expense of slave cultivation but sugar can
  • afford it still better than tobacco. The number of negroes, accordingly,
  • is much greater, in proportion to that of whites, in our sugar than in our
  • tobacco colonies.
  • To the slave cultivators of ancient times gradually succeeded a species of
  • farmers, known at present in France by the name of metayers. They are
  • called in Latin Coloni Partiarii. They have been so long in disuse in
  • England, that at present I know no English name for them. The proprietor
  • furnished them with the seed, cattle, and instruments of husbandry, the
  • whole stock, in short, necessary for cultivating the farm. The produce was
  • divided equally between the proprietor and the farmer, after setting aside
  • what was judged necessary for keeping up the stock, which was restored to
  • the proprietor, when the farmer either quitted or was turned out of the
  • farm.
  • Land occupied by such tenants is properly cultivated at the expense of the
  • proprietors, as much as that occupied by slaves. There is, however, one
  • very essential difference between them. Such tenants, being freemen, are
  • capable of acquiring property; and having a certain proportion of the
  • produce of the land, they have a plain interest that the whole produce
  • should be as great as possible, in order that their own proportion may be
  • so. A slave, on the contrary, who can acquire nothing but his maintenance,
  • consults his own ease, by making the land produce as little as possible
  • over and above that maintenance. It is probable that it was partly upon
  • account of this advantage, and partly upon account of the encroachments
  • which the sovereigns, always jealous of the great lords, gradually
  • encouraged their villains to make upon their authority, and which seem, at
  • least, to have been such as rendered this species of servitude altogether
  • inconvenient, that tenure in villanage gradually wore out through the
  • greater part of Europe. The time and manner, however, in which so
  • important a revolution was brought about, is one of the most obscure
  • points in modern history. The church of Rome claims great merit in it; and
  • it is certain, that so early as the twelfth century, Alexander III.
  • published a bull for the general emancipation of slaves. It seems,
  • however, to have been rather a pious exhortation, than a law to which
  • exact obedience was required from the faithful. Slavery continued to take
  • place almost universally for several centuries afterwards, till it was
  • gradually abolished by the joint operation of the two interests above
  • mentioned; that of the proprietor on the one hand, and that of the
  • sovereign on the other. A villain, enfranchised, and at the same time
  • allowed to continue in possession of the land, having no stock of his own,
  • could cultivate it only by means of what the landlord advanced to him, and
  • must therefore have been what the French call a metayer.
  • It could never, however, be the interest even of this last species of
  • cultivators, to lay out, in the further improvement of the land, any part
  • of the little stock which they might save from their own share of the
  • produce; because the landlord, who laid out nothing, was to get one half
  • of whatever it produced. The tithe, which is but a tenth of the produce,
  • is found to be a very great hindrance to improvement. A tax, therefore,
  • which amounted to one half, must have been an effectual bar to it. It
  • might be the interest of a metayer to make the land produce as much as
  • could be brought out of it by means of the stock furnished by the
  • proprietor; but it could never be his interest to mix any part of his own
  • with it. In France, where five parts out of six of the whole kingdom are
  • said to be still occupied by this species of cultivators, the proprietors
  • complain, that their metayers take every opportunity of employing their
  • master’s cattle rather in carriage than in cultivation; because, in the
  • one case, they get the whole profits to themselves, in the other they
  • share them with their landlord. This species of tenants still subsists in
  • some parts of Scotland. They are called steel-bow tenants. Those ancient
  • English tenants, who are said by Chief-Baron Gilbert and Dr Blackstone to
  • have been rather bailiffs of the landlord than farmers, properly so
  • called, were probably of the same kind.
  • To this species of tenantry succeeded, though by very slow degrees,
  • farmers, properly so called, who cultivated the land with their own stock,
  • paying a rent certain to the landlord. When such farmers have a lease for
  • a term of years, they may sometimes find it for their interest to lay out
  • part of their capital in the further improvement of the farm; because they
  • may sometimes expect to recover it, with a large profit, before the
  • expiration of the lease. The possession, even of such farmers, however,
  • was long extremely precarious, and still is so in many parts of Europe.
  • They could, before the expiration of their term, be legally ousted of
  • their leases by a new purchaser; in England, even, by the fictitious
  • action of a common recovery. If they were turned out illegally by the
  • violence of their master, the action by which they obtained redress was
  • extremely imperfect. It did not always reinstate them in the possession of
  • the land, but gave them damages, which never amounted to a real loss. Even
  • in England, the country, perhaps of Europe, where the yeomanry has always
  • been most respected, it was not till about the 14th of Henry VII. that the
  • action of ejectment was invented, by which the tenant recovers, not
  • damages only, but possession, and in which his claim is not necessarily
  • concluded by the uncertain decision of a single assize. This action has
  • been found so effectual a remedy, that, in the modern practice, when the
  • landlord has occasion to sue for the possession of the land, he seldom
  • makes use of the actions which properly belong to him as a landlord, the
  • writ of right or the writ of entry, but sues in the name of his tenant, by
  • the writ of ejectment. In England, therefore the security of the tenant is
  • equal to that of the proprietor. In England, besides, a lease for life of
  • forty shillings a-year value is a freehold, and entitles the lessee to a
  • vote for a member of parliament; and as a great part of the yeomanry have
  • freeholds of this kind, the whole order becomes respectable to their
  • landlords, on account of the political consideration which this gives
  • them. There is, I believe, nowhere in Europe, except in England, any
  • instance of the tenant building upon the land of which he had no lease,
  • and trusting that the honour of his landlord would take no advantage of so
  • important an improvement. Those laws and customs, so favourable to the
  • yeomanry, have perhaps contributed more to the present grandeur of
  • England, than all their boasted regulations of commerce taken together.
  • The law which secures the longest leases against successors of every kind,
  • is, so far as I know, peculiar to Great Britain. It was introduced into
  • Scotland so early as 1449, by a law of James II. Its beneficial influence,
  • however, has been much obstructed by entails; the heirs of entail being
  • generally restrained from letting leases for any long term of years,
  • frequently for more than one year. A late act of parliament has, in this
  • respect, somewhat slackened their fetters, though they are still by much
  • too strait. In Scotland, besides, as no leasehold gives a vote for a
  • member of parliament, the yeomanry are upon this account less respectable
  • to their landlords than in England.
  • In other parts of Europe, after it was found convenient to secure tenants
  • both against heirs and purchasers, the term of their security was still
  • limited to a very short period; in France, for example, to nine years from
  • the commencement of the lease. It has in that country, indeed, been lately
  • extended to twentyseven, a period still too short to encourage the tenant
  • to make the most important improvements. The proprietors of land were
  • anciently the legislators of every part of Europe. The laws relating to
  • land, therefore, were all calculated for what they supposed the interest
  • of the proprietor. It was for his interest, they had imagined, that no
  • lease granted by any of his predecessors should hinder him from enjoying,
  • during a long term of years, the full value of his land. Avarice and
  • injustice are always short-sighted, and they did not foresee how much this
  • regulation must obstruct improvement, and thereby hurt, in the long-run,
  • the real interest of the landlord.
  • The farmers, too, besides paying the rent, were anciently, it was
  • supposed, bound to perform a great number of services to the landlord,
  • which were seldom either specified in the lease, or regulated by any
  • precise rule, but by the use and wont of the manor or barony. These
  • services, therefore, being almost entirely arbitrary, subjected the tenant
  • to many vexations. In Scotland the abolition of all services not precisely
  • stipulated in the lease, has, in the course of a few years, very much
  • altered for the better the condition of the yeomanry of that country.
  • The public services to which the yeomanry were bound, were not less
  • arbitrary than the private ones. To make and maintain the high roads, a
  • servitude which still subsists, I believe, everywhere, though with
  • different degrees of oppression in different countries, was not the only
  • one. When the king’s troops, when his household, or his officers of any
  • kind, passed through any part of the country, the yeomanry were bound to
  • provide them with horses, carriages, and provisions, at a price regulated
  • by the purveyor. Great Britain is, I believe, the only monarchy in Europe
  • where the oppression of purveyance has been entirely abolished. It still
  • subsists in France and Germany.
  • The public taxes, to which they were subject, were as irregular and
  • oppressive as the services. The ancient lords, though extremely unwilling
  • to grant, themselves, any pecuniary aid to their sovereign, easily allowed
  • him to tallage, as they called it, their tenants, and had not knowledge
  • enough to foresee how much this must, in the end, affect their own
  • revenue. The taille, as it still subsists in France may serve as an
  • example of those ancient tallages. It is a tax upon the supposed profits
  • of the farmer, which they estimate by the stock that he has upon the farm.
  • It is his interest, therefore, to appear to have as little as possible,
  • and consequently to employ as little as possible in its cultivation, and
  • none in its improvement. Should any stock happen to accumulate in the
  • hands of a French farmer, the taille is almost equal to a prohibition of
  • its ever being employed upon the land. This tax, besides, is supposed to
  • dishonour whoever is subject to it, and to degrade him below, not only the
  • rank of a gentleman, but that of a burgher; and whoever rents the lands of
  • another becomes subject to it. No gentleman, nor even any burgher, who has
  • stock, will submit to this degradation. This tax, therefore, not only
  • hinders the stock which accumulates upon the land from being employed in
  • its improvement, but drives away all other stock from it. The ancient
  • tenths and fifteenths, so usual in England in former times, seem, so far
  • as they affected the land, to have been taxes of the same nature with the
  • taille.
  • Under all these discouragements, little improvement could be expected from
  • the occupiers of land. That order of people, with all the liberty and
  • security which law can give, must always improve under great disadvantage.
  • The farmer, compared with the proprietor, is as a merchant who trades with
  • burrowed money, compared with one who trades with his own. The stock of
  • both may improve; but that of the one, with only equal good conduct, must
  • always improve more slowly than that of the other, on account of the large
  • share of the profits which is consumed by the interest of the loan. The
  • lands cultivated by the farmer must, in the same manner, with only equal
  • good conduct, be improved more slowly than those cultivated by the
  • proprietor, on account of the large share of the produce which is consumed
  • in the rent, and which, had the farmer been proprietor, he might have
  • employed in the further improvement of the land. The station of a farmer,
  • besides, is, from the nature of things, inferior to that of a proprietor.
  • Through the greater part of Europe, the yeomanry are regarded as an
  • inferior rank of people, even to the better sort of tradesmen and
  • mechanics, and in all parts of Europe to the great merchants and master
  • manufacturers. It can seldom happen, therefore, that a man of any
  • considerable stock should quit the superior, in order to place himself in
  • an inferior station. Even in the present state of Europe, therefore,
  • little stock is likely to go from any other profession to the improvement
  • of land in the way of farming. More does, perhaps, in Great Britain than
  • in any other country, though even there the great stocks which are in some
  • places employed in farming, have generally been acquired by fanning, the
  • trade, perhaps, in which, of all others, stock is commonly acquired most
  • slowly. After small proprietors, however, rich and great farmers are in
  • every country the principal improvers. There are more such, perhaps, in
  • England than in any other European monarchy. In the republican governments
  • of Holland, and of Berne in Switzerland, the farmers are said to be not
  • inferior to those of England.
  • The ancient policy of Europe was, over and above all this, unfavourable to
  • the improvement and cultivation of land, whether carried on by the
  • proprietor or by the farmer; first, by the general prohibition of the
  • exportation of corn, without a special licence, which seems to have been a
  • very universal regulation; and, secondly, by the restraints which were
  • laid upon the inland commerce, not only of corn, but of almost every other
  • part of the produce of the farm, by the absurd laws against engrossers,
  • regraters, and forestallers, and by the privileges of fairs and markets.
  • It has already been observed in what manner the prohibition of the
  • exportation of corn, together with some encouragement given to the
  • importation of foreign corn, obstructed the cultivation of ancient Italy,
  • naturally the most fertile country in Europe, and at that time the seat of
  • the greatest empire in the world. To what degree such restraints upon the
  • inland commerce of this commodity, joined to the general prohibition of
  • exportation, must have discouraged the cultivation of countries less
  • fertile, and less favourably circumstanced, it is not, perhaps, very easy
  • to imagine.
  • CHAPTER III.
  • OF THE RISE AND PROGRESS OF CITIES
  • AND TOWNS, AFTER THE FALL OF THE ROMAN EMPIRE.
  • The inhabitants of cities and towns were, after the fall of the Roman
  • empire, not more favoured than those of the country. They consisted,
  • indeed, of a very different order of people from the first inhabitants of
  • the ancient republics of Greece and Italy. These last were composed
  • chiefly of the proprietors of lands, among whom the public territory was
  • originally divided, and who found it convenient to build their houses in
  • the neighbourhood of one another, and to surround them with a wall, for
  • the sake of common defence. After the fall of the Roman empire, on the
  • contrary, the proprietors of land seem generally to have lived in
  • fortified castles on their own estates, and in the midst of their own
  • tenants and dependants. The towns were chiefly inhabited by tradesmen and
  • mechanics, who seem, in those days, to have been of servile, or very
  • nearly of servile condition. The privileges which we find granted by
  • ancient charters to the inhabitants of some of the principal towns in
  • Europe, sufficiently show what they were before those grants. The people
  • to whom it is granted as a privilege, that they might give away their own
  • daughters in marriage without the consent of their lord, that upon their
  • death their own children, and not their lord, should succeed to their
  • goods, and that they might dispose of their own effects by will, must,
  • before those grants, have been either altogether, or very nearly, in the
  • same state of villanage with the occupiers of land in the country.
  • They seem, indeed, to have been a very poor, mean set of people, who
  • seemed to travel about with their goods from place to place, and from fair
  • to fair, like the hawkers and pedlars of the present times. In all the
  • different countries of Europe then, in the same manner as in several of
  • the Tartar governments of Asia at present, taxes used to be levied upon
  • the persons and goods of travellers, when they passed through certain
  • manors, when they went over certain bridges, when they carried about their
  • goods from place to place in a fair, when they erected in it a booth or
  • stall to sell them in. These different taxes were known in England by the
  • names of passage, pontage, lastage, and stallage. Sometimes the king,
  • sometimes a great lord, who had, it seems, upon some occasions, authority
  • to do this, would grant to particular traders, to such particularly as
  • lived in their own demesnes, a general exemption from such taxes. Such
  • traders, though in other respects of servile, or very nearly of servile
  • condition, were upon this account called free traders. They, in return,
  • usually paid to their protector a sort of annual poll-tax. In those days
  • protection was seldom granted without a valuable consideration, and this
  • tax might perhaps be considered as compensation for what their patrons
  • might lose by their exemption from other taxes. At first, both those
  • poll-taxes and those exemptions seem to have been altogether personal, and
  • to have affected only particular individuals, during either their lives,
  • or the pleasure of their protectors. In the very imperfect accounts which
  • have been published from Doomsday-book, of several of the towns of
  • England, mention is frequently made, sometimes of the tax which particular
  • burghers paid, each of them, either to the king, or to some other great
  • lord, for this sort of protection, and sometimes of the general amount
  • only of all those taxes. {see Brady’s Historical Treatise of Cities and
  • Boroughs, p. 3. etc.}
  • But how servile soever may have been originally the condition of the
  • inhabitants of the towns, it appears evidently, that they arrived at
  • liberty and independency much earlier than the occupiers of land in the
  • country. That part of the king’s revenue which arose from such poll-taxes
  • in any particular town, used commonly to be let in farm, during a term of
  • years, for a rent certain, sometimes to the sheriff of the county, and
  • sometimes to other persons. The burghers themselves frequently got credit
  • enough to be admitted to farm the revenues of this sort which arose out of
  • their own town, they becoming jointly and severally answerable for the
  • whole rent. {See Madox, Firma Burgi, p. 18; also History of the Exchequer,
  • chap. 10, sect. v, p. 223, first edition.} To let a farm in this manner,
  • was quite agreeable to the usual economy of, I believe, the sovereigns of
  • all the different countries of Europe, who used frequently to let whole
  • manors to all the tenants of those manors, they becoming jointly and
  • severally answerable for the whole rent; but in return being allowed to
  • collect it in their own way, and to pay it into the king’s exchequer by
  • the hands of their own bailiff, and being thus altogether freed from the
  • insolence of the king’s officers; a circumstance in those days regarded as
  • of the greatest importance.
  • At first, the farm of the town was probably let to the burghers, in the
  • same manner as it had been to other farmers, for a term of years only. In
  • process of time, however, it seems to have become the general practice to
  • grant it to them in fee, that is for ever, reserving a rent certain, never
  • afterwards to be augmented. The payment having thus become perpetual, the
  • exemptions, in return, for which it was made, naturally became perpetual
  • too. Those exemptions, therefore, ceased to be personal, and could not
  • afterwards be considered as belonging to individuals, as individuals, but
  • as burghers of a particular burgh, which, upon this account, was called a
  • free burgh, for the same reason that they had been called free burghers or
  • free traders.
  • Along with this grant, the important privileges, above mentioned, that
  • they might give away their own daughters in marriage, that their children
  • should succeed to them, and that they might dispose of their own effects
  • by will, were generally bestowed upon the burghers of the town to whom it
  • was given. Whether such privileges had before been usually granted, along
  • with the freedom of trade, to particular burghers, as individuals, I know
  • not. I reckon it not improbable that they were, though I cannot produce
  • any direct evidence of it. But however this may have been, the principal
  • attributes of villanage and slavery being thus taken away from them, they
  • now at least became really free, in our present sense of the word freedom.
  • Nor was this all. They were generally at the same time erected into a
  • commonalty or corporation, with the privilege of having magistrates and a
  • town-council of their own, of making bye-laws for their own government, of
  • building walls for their own defence, and of reducing all their
  • inhabitants under a sort of military discipline, by obliging them to watch
  • and ward; that is, as anciently understood, to guard and defend those
  • walls against all attacks and surprises, by night as well as by day. In
  • England they were generally exempted from suit to the hundred and county
  • courts: and all such pleas as should arise among them, the pleas of the
  • crown excepted, were left to the decision of their own magistrates. In
  • other countries, much greater and more extensive jurisdictions were
  • frequently granted to them. {See Madox, Firma Burgi. See also Pfeffel in
  • the Remarkable events under Frederick II. and his Successors of the House
  • of Suabia.}
  • It might, probably, be necessary to grant to such towns as were admitted
  • to farm their own revenues, some sort of compulsive jurisdiction to oblige
  • their own citizens to make payment. In those disorderly times, it might
  • have been extremely inconvenient to have left them to seek this sort of
  • justice from any other tribunal. But it must seem extraordinary, that the
  • sovereigns of all the different countries of Europe should have exchanged
  • in this manner for a rent certain, never more to be augmented, that branch
  • of their revenue, which was, perhaps, of all others, the most likely to be
  • improved by the natural course of things, without either expense or
  • attention of their own; and that they should, besides, have in this manner
  • voluntarily erected a sort of independent republics in the heart of their
  • own dominions.
  • In order to understand this, it must be remembered, that, in those days,
  • the sovereign of perhaps no country in Europe was able to protect, through
  • the whole extent of his dominions, the weaker part of his subjects from
  • the oppression of the great lords. Those whom the law could not protect,
  • and who were not strong enough to defend themselves, were obliged either
  • to have recourse to the protection of some great lord, and in order to
  • obtain it, to become either his slaves or vassals; or to enter into a
  • league of mutual defence for the common protection of one another. The
  • inhabitants of cities and burghs, considered as single individuals, had no
  • power to defend themselves; but by entering into a league of mutual
  • defence with their neighbours, they were capable of making no contemptible
  • resistance. The lords despised the burghers, whom they considered not only
  • as a different order, but as a parcel of emancipated slaves, almost of a
  • different species from themselves. The wealth of the burghers never failed
  • to provoke their envy and indignation, and they plundered them upon every
  • occasion without mercy or remorse. The burghers naturally hated and feared
  • the lords. The king hated and feared them too; but though, perhaps, he
  • might despise, he had no reason either to hate or fear the burghers.
  • Mutual interest, therefore, disposed them to support the king, and the
  • king to support them against the lords. They were the enemies of his
  • enemies, and it was his interest to render them as secure and independent
  • of those enemies as he could. By granting them magistrates of their own,
  • the privilege of making bye-laws for their own government, that of
  • building walls for their own defence, and that of reducing all their
  • inhabitants under a sort of military discipline, he gave them all the
  • means of security and independency of the barons which it was in his power
  • to bestow. Without the establishment of some regular government of this
  • kind, without some authority to compel their inhabitants to act according
  • to some certain plan or system, no voluntary league of mutual defence
  • could either have afforded them any permanent security, or have enabled
  • them to give the king any considerable support. By granting them the farm
  • of their own town in fee, he took away from those whom he wished to have
  • for his friends, and, if one may say so, for his allies, all ground of
  • jealousy and suspicion, that he was ever afterwards to oppress them,
  • either by raising the farm-rent of their town, or by granting it to some
  • other farmer.
  • The princes who lived upon the worst terms with their barons, seem
  • accordingly to have been the most liberal in grants of this kind to their
  • burghs. King John of England, for example, appears to have been a most
  • munificent benefactor to his towns. {See Madox.} Philip I. of France lost
  • all authority over his barons. Towards the end of his reign, his son
  • Lewis, known afterwards by the name of Lewis the Fat, consulted, according
  • to Father Daniel, with the bishops of the royal demesnes, concerning the
  • most proper means of restraining the violence of the great lords. Their
  • advice consisted of two different proposals. One was to erect a new order
  • of jurisdiction, by establishing magistrates and a town-council in every
  • considerable town of his demesnes. The other was to form a new militia, by
  • making the inhabitants of those towns, under the command of their own
  • magistrates, march out upon proper occasions to the assistance of the
  • king. It is from this period, according to the French antiquarians, that
  • we are to date the institution of the magistrates and councils of cities
  • in France. It was during the unprosperous reigns of the princes of the
  • house of Suabia, that the greater part of the free towns of Germany
  • received the first grants of their privileges, and that the famous
  • Hanseatic league first became formidable. {See Pfeffel.}
  • The militia of the cities seems, in those times, not to have been inferior
  • to that of the country; and as they could be more readily assembled upon
  • any sudden occasion, they frequently had the advantage in their disputes
  • with the neighbouring lords. In countries such as Italy or Switzerland, in
  • which, on account either of their distance from the principal seat of
  • government, of the natural strength of the country itself, or of some
  • other reason, the sovereign came to lose the whole of his authority; the
  • cities generally became independent republics, and conquered all the
  • nobility in their neighbourhood; obliging them to pull down their castles
  • in the country, and to live, like other peaceable inhabitants, in the
  • city. This is the short history of the republic of Berne, as well as of
  • several other cities in Switzerland. If you except Venice, for of that
  • city the history is somewhat different, it is the history of all the
  • considerable Italian republics, of which so great a number arose and
  • perished between the end of the twelfth and the beginning of the sixteenth
  • century.
  • In countries such as France and England, where the authority of the
  • sovereign, though frequently very low, never was destroyed altogether, the
  • cities had no opportunity of becoming entirely independent. They became,
  • however, so considerable, that the sovereign could impose no tax upon
  • them, besides the stated farm-rent of the town, without their own consent.
  • They were, therefore, called upon to send deputies to the general assembly
  • of the states of the kingdom, where they might join with the clergy and
  • the barons in granting, upon urgent occasions, some extraordinary aid to
  • the king. Being generally, too, more favourable to his power, their
  • deputies seem sometimes to have been employed by him as a counterbalance
  • in those assemblies to the authority of the great lords. Hence the origin
  • of the representation of burghs in the states-general of all great
  • monarchies in Europe.
  • Order and good government, and along with them the liberty and security of
  • individuals, were in this manner established in cities, at a time when the
  • occupiers of land in the country, were exposed to every sort of violence.
  • But men in this defenceless state naturally content themselves with their
  • necessary subsistence; because, to acquire more, might only tempt the
  • injustice of their oppressors. On the contrary, when they are secure of
  • enjoying the fruits of their industry, they naturally exert it to better
  • their condition, and to acquire not only the necessaries, but the
  • conveniencies and elegancies of life. That industry, therefore, which aims
  • at something more than necessary subsistence, was established in cities
  • long before it was commonly practised by the occupiers of land in the
  • country. If, in the hands of a poor cultivator, oppressed with the
  • servitude of villanage, some little stock should accumulate, he would
  • naturally conceal it with great care from his master, to whom it would
  • otherwise have belonged, and take the first opportunity of running away to
  • a town. The law was at that time so indulgent to the inhabitants of towns,
  • and so desirous of diminishing the authority of the lords over those of
  • the country, that if he could conceal himself there from the pursuit of
  • his lord for a year, he was free for ever. Whatever stock, therefore,
  • accumulated in the hands of the industrious part of the inhabitants of the
  • country, naturally took refuge in cities, as the only sanctuaries in which
  • it could be secure to the person that acquired it.
  • The inhabitants of a city, it is true, must always ultimately derive their
  • subsistence, and the whole materials and means of their industry, from the
  • country. But those of a city, situated near either the sea-coast or the
  • banks of a navigable river, are not necessarily confined to derive them
  • from the country in their neighbourhood. They have a much wider range, and
  • may draw them from the most remote corners of the world, either in
  • exchange for the manufactured produce of their own industry, or by
  • performing the office of carriers between distant countries, and
  • exchanging the produce of one for that of another. A city might, in this
  • manner, grow up to great wealth and splendour, while not only the country
  • in its neighbourhood, but all those to which it traded, were in poverty
  • and wretchedness. Each of those countries, perhaps, taken singly, could
  • afford it but a small part, either of its subsistence or of its
  • employment; but all of them taken together, could afford it both a great
  • subsistence and a great employment. There were, however, within the narrow
  • circle of the commerce of those times, some countries that were opulent
  • and industrious. Such was the Greek empire as long as it subsisted, and
  • that of the Saracens during the reigns of the Abassides. Such, too, was
  • Egypt till it was conquered by the Turks, some part of the coast of
  • Barbary, and all those provinces of Spain which were under the government
  • of the Moors.
  • The cities of Italy seem to have been the first in Europe which were
  • raised by commerce to any considerable degree of opulence. Italy lay in
  • the centre of what was at that time the improved and civilized part of the
  • world. The crusades, too, though, by the great waste of stock and
  • destruction of inhabitants which they occasioned, they must necessarily
  • have retarded the progress of the greater part of Europe, were extremely
  • favourable to that of some Italian cities. The great armies which marched
  • from all parts to the conquest of the Holy Land, gave extraordinary
  • encouragement to the shipping of Venice, Genoa, and Pisa, sometimes in
  • transporting them thither, and always in supplying them with provisions.
  • They were the commissaries, if one may say so, of those armies; and the
  • most destructive frenzy that ever befel the European nations, was a source
  • of opulence to those republics.
  • The inhabitants of trading cities, by importing the improved manufactures
  • and expensive luxuries of richer countries, afforded some food to the
  • vanity of the great proprietors, who eagerly purchased them with great
  • quantities of the rude produce of their own lands. The commerce of a great
  • part of Europe in those times, accordingly, consisted chiefly in the
  • exchange of their own rude, for the manufactured produce of more civilized
  • nations. Thus the wool of England used to be exchanged for the wines of
  • France, and the fine cloths of Flanders, in the same manner as the corn in
  • Poland is at this day, exchanged for the wines and brandies of France, and
  • for the silks and velvets of France and Italy.
  • A taste for the finer and more improved manufactures was, in this manner,
  • introduced by foreign commerce into countries where no such works were
  • carried on. But when this taste became so general as to occasion a
  • considerable demand, the merchants, in order to save the expense of
  • carriage, naturally endeavoured to establish some manufactures of the same
  • kind in their own country. Hence the origin of the first manufactures for
  • distant sale, that seem to have been established in the western provinces
  • of Europe, after the fall of the Roman empire.
  • No large country, it must be observed, ever did or could subsist without
  • some sort of manufactures being carried on in it; and when it is said of
  • any such country that it has no manufactures, it must always be understood
  • of the finer and more improved, or of such as are fit for distant sale. In
  • every large country both the clothing and household furniture or the far
  • greater part of the people, are the produce of their own industry. This is
  • even more universally the case in those poor countries which are commonly
  • said to have no manufactures, than in those rich ones that are said to
  • abound in them. In the latter you will generally find, both in the clothes
  • and household furniture of the lowest rank of people, a much greater
  • proportion of foreign productions than in the former.
  • Those manufactures which are fit for distant sale, seem to have been
  • introduced into different countries in two different ways.
  • Sometimes they have been introduced in the manner above mentioned, by the
  • violent operation, if one may say so, of the stocks of particular
  • merchants and undertakers, who established them in imitation of some
  • foreign manufactures of the same kind. Such manufactures, therefore, are
  • the offspring of foreign commerce; and such seem to have been the ancient
  • manufactures of silks, velvets, and brocades, which flourished in Lucca
  • during the thirteenth century. They were banished from thence by the
  • tyranny of one of Machiavel’s heroes, Castruccio Castracani. In 1310, nine
  • hundred families were driven out of Lucca, of whom thirty-one retired to
  • Venice, and offered to introduce there the silk manufacture. {See Sandi
  • Istoria civile de Vinezia, part 2 vol. i, page 247 and 256.} Their offer
  • was accepted, many privileges were conferred upon them, and they began the
  • manufacture with three hundred workmen. Such, too, seem to have been the
  • manufactures of fine cloths that anciently flourished in Flanders, and
  • which were introduced into England in the beginning of the reign of
  • Elizabeth, and such are the present silk manufactures of Lyons and
  • Spitalfields. Manufactures introduced in this manner are generally
  • employed upon foreign materials, being imitations of foreign manufactures.
  • When the Venetian manufacture was first established, the materials were
  • all brought from Sicily and the Levant. The more ancient manufacture of
  • Lucca was likewise carried on with foreign materials. The cultivation of
  • mulberry trees, and the breeding of silk-worms, seem not to have been
  • common in the northern parts of Italy before the sixteenth century. Those
  • arts were not introduced into France till the reign of Charles IX. The
  • manufactures of Flanders were carried on chiefly with Spanish and English
  • wool. Spanish wool was the material, not of the first woollen manufacture
  • of England, but of the first that was fit for distant sale. More than one
  • half the materials of the Lyons manufacture is at this day foreign silk;
  • when it was first established, the whole, or very nearly the whole, was
  • so. No part of the materials of the Spitalfields manufacture is ever
  • likely to be the produce of England. The seat of such manufactures, as
  • they are generally introduced by the scheme and project of a few
  • individuals, is sometimes established in a maritime city, and sometimes in
  • an inland town, according as their interest, judgment, or caprice, happen
  • to determine.
  • At other times, manufactures for distant sale grow up naturally, and as it
  • were of their own accord, by the gradual refinement of those household and
  • coarser manufactures which must at all times be carried on even in the
  • poorest and rudest countries. Such manufactures are generally employed
  • upon the materials which the country produces, and they seem frequently to
  • have been first refined and improved in such inland countries as were not,
  • indeed, at a very great, but at a considerable distance from the
  • sea-coast, and sometimes even from all water carriage. An inland country,
  • naturally fertile and easily cultivated, produces a great surplus of
  • provisions beyond what is necessary for maintaining the cultivators; and
  • on account of the expense of land carriage, and inconveniency of river
  • navigation, it may frequently be difficult to send this surplus abroad.
  • Abundance, therefore, renders provisions cheap, and encourages a great
  • number of workmen to settle in the neighbourhood, who find that their
  • industry can there procure them more of the necessaries and conveniencies
  • of life than in other places. They work up the materials of manufacture
  • which the land produces, and exchange their finished work, or, what is the
  • same thing, the price of it, for more materials and provisions. They give
  • a new value to the surplus part of the rude produce, by saving the expense
  • of carrying it to the water-side, or to some distant market; and they
  • furnish the cultivators with something in exchange for it that is either
  • useful or agreeable to them, upon easier terms than they could have
  • obtained it before. The cultivators get a better price for their surplus
  • produce, and can purchase cheaper other conveniencies which they have
  • occasion for. They are thus both encouraged and enabled to increase this
  • surplus produce by a further improvement and better cultivation of the
  • land; and as the fertility of she land had given birth to the manufacture,
  • so the progress of the manufacture reacts upon the land, and increases
  • still further its fertility. The manufacturers first supply the
  • neighbourhood, and afterwards, as their work improves and refines, more
  • distant markets. For though neither the rude produce, nor even the coarse
  • manufacture, could, without the greatest difficulty, support the expense
  • of a considerable land-carriage, the refined and improved manufacture
  • easily may. In a small bulk it frequently contains the price of a great
  • quantity of rude produce. A piece of fine cloth, for example which weighs
  • only eighty pounds, contains in it the price, not only of eighty pounds
  • weight of wool, but sometimes of several thousand weight of corn, the
  • maintenance of the different working people, and of their immediate
  • employers. The corn which could with difficulty have been carried abroad
  • in its own shape, is in this manner virtually exported in that of the
  • complete manufacture, and may easily be sent to the remotest corners of
  • the world. In this manner have grown up naturally, and, as it were, of
  • their own accord, the manufactures of Leeds, Halifax, Sheffield,
  • Birmingham, and Wolverhampton. Such manufactures are the offspring of
  • agriculture. In the modern history of Europe, their extension and
  • improvement have generally been posterior to those which were the
  • offspring of foreign commerce. England was noted for the manufacture of
  • fine cloths made of Spanish wool, more than a century before any of those
  • which now flourish in the places above mentioned were fit for foreign
  • sale. The extension and improvement of these last could not take place but
  • in consequence of the extension and improvement of agriculture, the last
  • and greatest effect of foreign commerce, and of the manufactures
  • immediately introduced by it, and which I shall now proceed to explain.
  • CHAPTER IV.
  • HOW THE COMMERCE OF TOWNS CONTRIBUTED
  • TO THE IMPROVEMENT OF THE COUNTRY.
  • The increase and riches of commercial and manufacturing towns contributed
  • to the improvement and cultivation of the countries to which they
  • belonged, in three different ways.
  • First, by affording a great and ready market for the rude produce of the
  • country, they gave encouragement to its cultivation and further
  • improvement. This benefit was not even confined to the countries in which
  • they were situated, but extended more or less to all those with which they
  • had any dealings. To all of them they afforded a market for some part
  • either of their rude or manufactured produce, and, consequently, gave some
  • encouragement to the industry and improvement of all. Their own country,
  • however, on account of its neighbourhood, necessarily derived the greatest
  • benefit from this market. Its rude produce being charged with less
  • carriage, the traders could pay the growers a better price for it, and yet
  • afford it as cheap to the consumers as that of more distant countries.
  • Secondly, the wealth acquired by the inhabitants of cities was frequently
  • employed in purchasing such lands as were to be sold, of which a great
  • part would frequently be uncultivated. Merchants are commonly ambitious of
  • becoming country gentlemen, and, when they do, they are generally the best
  • of all improvers. A merchant is accustomed to employ his money chiefly in
  • profitable projects; whereas a mere country gentleman is accustomed to
  • employ it chiefly in expense. The one often sees his money go from him,
  • and return to him again with a profit; the other, when once he parts with
  • it, very seldom expects to see any more of it. Those different habits
  • naturally affect their temper and disposition in every sort of business.
  • The merchant is commonly a bold, a country gentleman a timid undertaker.
  • The one is not afraid to lay out at once a large capital upon the
  • improvement of his land, when he has a probable prospect of raising the
  • value of it in proportion to the expense; the other, if he has any
  • capital, which is not always the case, seldom ventures to employ it in
  • this manner. If he improves at all, it is commonly not with a capital, but
  • with what he can save out or his annual revenue. Whoever has had the
  • fortune to live in a mercantile town, situated in an unimproved country,
  • must have frequently observed how much more spirited the operations of
  • merchants were in this way, than those of mere country gentlemen. The
  • habits, besides, of order, economy, and attention, to which mercantile
  • business naturally forms a merchant, render him much fitter to execute,
  • with profit and success, any project of improvement.
  • Thirdly, and lastly, commerce and manufactures gradually introduced order
  • and good government, and with them the liberty and security of
  • individuals, among the inhabitants of the country, who had before lived
  • almost in a continual state of war with their neighbours, and of servile
  • dependency upon their superiors. This, though it has been the least
  • observed, is by far the most important of all their effects. Mr Hume is
  • the only writer who, so far as I know, has hitherto taken notice of it.
  • In a country which has neither foreign commerce nor any of the finer
  • manufactures, a great proprietor, having nothing for which he can exchange
  • the greater part of the produce of his lands which is over and above the
  • maintenance of the cultivators, consumes the whole in rustic hospitality
  • at home. If this surplus produce is sufficient to maintain a hundred or a
  • thousand men, he can make use of it in no other way than by maintaining a
  • hundred or a thousand men. He is at all times, therefore, surrounded with
  • a multitude of retainers and dependants, who, having no equivalent to give
  • in return for their maintenance, but being fed entirely by his bounty,
  • must obey him, for the same reason that soldiers must obey the prince who
  • pays them. Before the extension of commerce and manufactures in Europe,
  • the hospitality of the rich and the great, from the sovereign down to the
  • smallest baron, exceeded every thing which, in the present times, we can
  • easily form a notion of Westminster-hall was the dining-room of William
  • Rufus, and might frequently, perhaps, not be too large for his company. It
  • was reckoned a piece of magnificence in Thomas Becket, that he strewed the
  • floor of his hall with clean hay or rushes in the season, in order that
  • the knights and squires, who could not get seats, might not spoil their
  • fine clothes when they sat down on the floor to eat their dinner. The
  • great Earl of Warwick is said to have entertained every day, at his
  • different manors, 30,000 people; and though the number here may have been
  • exaggerated, it must, however, have been very great to admit of such
  • exaggeration. A hospitality nearly of the same kind was exercised not many
  • years ago in many different parts of the Highlands of Scotland. It seems
  • to be common in all nations to whom commerce and manufactures are little
  • known. I have seen, says Doctor Pocock, an Arabian chief dine in the
  • streets of a town where he had come to sell his cattle, and invite all
  • passengers, even common beggars, to sit down with him and partake of his
  • banquet.
  • The occupiers of land were in every respect as dependent upon the great
  • proprietor as his retainers. Even such of them as were not in a state of
  • villanage, were tenants at will, who paid a rent in no respect equivalent
  • to the subsistence which the land afforded them. A crown, half a crown, a
  • sheep, a lamb, was some years ago, in the Highlands of Scotland, a common
  • rent for lands which maintained a family. In some places it is so at this
  • day; nor will money at present purchase a greater quantity of commodities
  • there than in other places. In a country where the surplus produce of a
  • large estate must be consumed upon the estate itself, it will frequently
  • be more convenient for the proprietor, that part of it be consumed at a
  • distance from his own house, provided they who consume it are as dependent
  • upon him as either his retainers or his menial servants. He is thereby
  • saved from the embarrassment of either too large a company, or too large a
  • family. A tenant at will, who possesses land sufficient to maintain his
  • family for little more than a quit-rent, is as dependent upon the
  • proprietor as any servant or retainer whatever, and must obey him with as
  • little reserve. Such a proprietor, as he feeds his servants and retainers
  • at his own house, so he feeds his tenants at their houses. The subsistence
  • of both is derived from his bounty, and its continuance depends upon his
  • good pleasure.
  • Upon the authority which the great proprietors necessarily had, in such a
  • state of things, over their tenants and retainers, was founded the power
  • of the ancient barons. They necessarily became the judges in peace, and
  • the leaders in war, of all who dwelt upon their estates. They could
  • maintain order, and execute the law, within their respective demesnes,
  • because each of them could there turn the whole force of all the
  • inhabitants against the injustice of anyone. No other person had
  • sufficient authority to do this. The king, in particular, had not. In
  • those ancient times, he was little more than the greatest proprietor in
  • his dominions, to whom, for the sake of common defence against their
  • common enemies, the other great proprietors paid certain respects. To have
  • enforced payment of a small debt within the lands of a great proprietor,
  • where all the inhabitants were armed, and accustomed to stand by one
  • another, would have cost the king, had he attempted it by his own
  • authority, almost the same effort as to extinguish a civil war. He was,
  • therefore, obliged to abandon the administration of justice, through the
  • greater part of the country, to those who were capable of administering
  • it; and, for the same reason, to leave the command of the country militia
  • to those whom that militia would obey.
  • It is a mistake to imagine that those territorial jurisdictions took their
  • origin from the feudal law. Not only the highest jurisdictions, both civil
  • and criminal, but the power of levying troops, of coining money, and even
  • that of making bye-laws for the government of their own people, were all
  • rights possessed allodially by the great proprietors of land, several
  • centuries before even the name of the feudal law was known in Europe. The
  • authority and jurisdiction of the Saxon lords in England appear to have
  • been as great before the Conquest as that of any of the Norman lords after
  • it. But the feudal law is not supposed to have become the common law of
  • England till after the Conquest. That the most extensive authority and
  • jurisdictions were possessed by the great lords in France allodially, long
  • before the feudal law was introduced into that country, is a matter of
  • fact that admits of no doubt. That authority, and those jurisdictions, all
  • necessarily flowed from the state of property and manners just now
  • described. Without remounting to the remote antiquities of either the
  • French or English monarchies, we may find, in much later times, many
  • proofs that such effects must always flow from such causes. It is not
  • thirty years ago since Mr Cameron of Lochiel, a gentleman of Lochaber in
  • Scotland, without any legal warrant whatever, not being what was then
  • called a lord of regality, nor even a tenant in chief, but a vassal of the
  • Duke of Argyll, and with out being so much as a justice of peace, used,
  • notwithstanding, to exercise the highest criminal jurisdictions over his
  • own people. He is said to have done so with great equity, though without
  • any of the formalities of justice; and it is not improbable that the state
  • of that part of the country at that time made it necessary for him to
  • assume this authority, in order to maintain the public peace. That
  • gentleman, whose rent never exceeded £500 a-year, carried, in 1745, 800 of
  • his own people into the rebellion with him.
  • The introduction of the feudal law, so far from extending, may be regarded
  • as an attempt to moderate, the authority of the great allodial lords. It
  • established a regular subordination, accompanied with a long train of
  • services and duties, from the king down to the smallest proprietor. During
  • the minority of the proprietor, the rent, together with the management of
  • his lands, fell into the hands of his immediate superior; and,
  • consequently, those of all great proprietors into the hands of the king,
  • who was charged with the maintenance and education of the pupil, and who,
  • from his authority as guardian, was supposed to have a right of disposing
  • of him in marriage, provided it was in a manner not unsuitable to his
  • rank. But though this institution necessarily tended to strengthen the
  • authority of the king, and to weaken that of the great proprietors, it
  • could not do either sufficiently for establishing order and good
  • government among the inhabitants of the country; because it could not
  • alter sufficiently that state of property and manners from which the
  • disorders arose. The authority of government still continued to be, as
  • before, too weak in the head, and too strong in the inferior members; and
  • the excessive strength of the inferior members was the cause of the
  • weakness of the head. After the institution of feudal subordination, the
  • king was as incapable of restraining the violence of the great lords as
  • before. They still continued to make war according to their own
  • discretion, almost continually upon one another, and very frequently upon
  • the king; and the open country still continued to be a scene of violence,
  • rapine, and disorder.
  • But what all the violence of the feudal institutions could never have
  • effected, the silent and insensible operation of foreign commerce and
  • manufactures gradually brought about. These gradually furnished the great
  • proprietors with something for which they could exchange the whole surplus
  • produce of their lands, and which they could consume themselves, without
  • sharing it either with tenants or retainers. All for ourselves, and
  • nothing for other people, seems, in every age of the world, to have been
  • the vile maxim of the masters of mankind. As soon, therefore, as they
  • could find a method of consuming the whole value of their rents
  • themselves, they had no disposition to share them with any other persons.
  • For a pair of diamond buckles, perhaps, or for something as frivolous and
  • useless, they exchanged the maintenance, or, what is the same thing, the
  • price of the maintenance of 1000 men for a year, and with it the whole
  • weight and authority which it could give them. The buckles, however, were
  • to be all their own, and no other human creature was to have any share of
  • them; whereas, in the more ancient method of expense, they must have
  • shared with at least 1000 people. With the judges that were to determine
  • the preference, this difference was perfectly decisive; and thus, for the
  • gratification of the most childish, the meanest, and the most sordid of
  • all vanities they gradually bartered their whole power and authority.
  • In a country where there is no foreign commerce, nor any of the finer
  • manufactures, a man of £10,000 a-year cannot well employ his revenue in
  • any other way than in maintaining, perhaps, 1000 families, who are all of
  • them necessarily at his command. In the present state of Europe, a man of
  • £10,000 a-year can spend his whole revenue, and he generally does so,
  • without directly maintaining twenty people, or being able to command more
  • than ten footmen, not worth the commanding. Indirectly, perhaps, he
  • maintains as great, or even a greater number of people, than he could have
  • done by the ancient method of expense. For though the quantity of precious
  • productions for which he exchanges his whole revenue be very small, the
  • number of workmen employed in collecting and preparing it must necessarily
  • have been very great. Its great price generally arises from the wages of
  • their labour, and the profits of all their immediate employers. By paying
  • that price, he indirectly pays all those wages and profits, and thus
  • indirectly contributes to the maintenance of all the workmen and their
  • employers. He generally contributes, however, but a very small proportion
  • to that of each; to a very few, perhaps, not a tenth, to many not a
  • hundredth, and to some not a thousandth, or even a ten thousandth part of
  • their whole annual maintenance. Though he contributes, therefore, to the
  • maintenance of them all, they are all more or less independent of him,
  • because generally they can all be maintained without him.
  • When the great proprietors of land spend their rents in maintaining their
  • tenants and retainers, each of them maintains entirely all his own tenants
  • and all his own retainers. But when they spend them in maintaining
  • tradesmen and artificers, they may, all of them taken together, perhaps
  • maintain as great, or, on account of the waste which attends rustic
  • hospitality, a greater number of people than before. Each of them,
  • however, taken singly, contributes often but a very small share to the
  • maintenance of any individual of this greater number. Each tradesman or
  • artificer derives his subsistence from the employment, not of one, but of
  • a hundred or a thousand different customers. Though in some measure
  • obliged to them all, therefore, he is not absolutely dependent upon any
  • one of them.
  • The personal expense of the great proprietors having in this manner
  • gradually increased, it was impossible that the number of their retainers
  • should not as gradually diminish, till they were at last dismissed
  • altogether. The same cause gradually led them to dismiss the unnecessary
  • part of their tenants. Farms were enlarged, and the occupiers of land,
  • notwithstanding the complaints of depopulation, reduced to the number
  • necessary for cultivating it, according to the imperfect state of
  • cultivation and improvement in those times. By the removal of the
  • unnecessary mouths, and by exacting from the farmer the full value of the
  • farm, a greater surplus, or, what is the same thing, the price of a
  • greater surplus, was obtained for the proprietor, which the merchants and
  • manufacturers soon furnished him with a method of spending upon his own
  • person, in the same manner as he had done the rest. The cause continuing
  • to operate, he was desirous to raise his rents above what his lands, in
  • the actual state of their improvement, could afford. His tenants could
  • agree to this upon one condition only, that they should be secured in
  • their possession for such a term of years as might give them time to
  • recover, with profit, whatever they should lay not in the further
  • improvement of the land. The expensive vanity of the landlord made him
  • willing to accept of this condition; and hence the origin of long leases.
  • Even a tenant at will, who pays the full value of the land, is not
  • altogether dependent upon the landlord. The pecuniary advantages which
  • they receive from one another are mutual and equal, and such a tenant will
  • expose neither his life nor his fortune in the service of the proprietor.
  • But if he has a lease for along term of years, he is altogether
  • independent; and his landlord must not expect from him even the most
  • trifling service, beyond what is either expressly stipulated in the lease,
  • or imposed upon him by the common and known law of the country.
  • The tenants having in this manner become independent, and the retainers
  • being dismissed, the great proprietors were no longer capable of
  • interrupting the regular execution of justice, or of disturbing the peace
  • of the country. Having sold their birth-right, not like Esau, for a mess
  • of pottage in time of hunger and necessity, but, in the wantonness of
  • plenty, for trinkets and baubles, fitter to be the playthings of children
  • than the serious pursuits of men, they became as insignificant as any
  • substantial burgher or tradesmen in a city. A regular government was
  • established in the country as well as in the city, nobody having
  • sufficient power to disturb its operations in the one, any more than in
  • the other.
  • It does not, perhaps, relate to the present subject, but I cannot help
  • remarking it, that very old families, such as have possessed some
  • considerable estate from father to son for many successive generations,
  • are very rare in commercial countries. In countries which have little
  • commerce, on the contrary, such as Wales, or the Highlands of Scotland,
  • they are very common. The Arabian histories seem to be all full of
  • genealogies; and there is a history written by a Tartar Khan, which has
  • been translated into several European languages, and which contains scarce
  • any thing else; a proof that ancient families are very common among those
  • nations. In countries where a rich man can spend his revenue in no other
  • way than by maintaining as many people as it can maintain, he is apt to
  • run out, and his benevolence, it seems, is seldom so violent as to attempt
  • to maintain more than he can afford. But where he can spend the greatest
  • revenue upon his own person, he frequently has no bounds to his expense,
  • because he frequently has no bounds to his vanity, or to his affection for
  • his own person. In commercial countries, therefore, riches, in spite of
  • the most violent regulations of law to prevent their dissipation, very
  • seldom remain long in the same family. Among simple nations, on the
  • contrary, they frequently do, without any regulations of law; for among
  • nations of shepherds, such as the Tartars and Arabs, the consumable nature
  • of their property necessarily renders all such regulations impossible.
  • A revolution of the greatest importance to the public happiness, was in
  • this manner brought about by two different orders of people, who had not
  • the least intention to serve the public. To gratify the most childish
  • vanity was the sole motive of the great proprietors. The merchants and
  • artificers, much less ridiculous, acted merely from a view to their own
  • interest, and in pursuit of their own pedlar principle of turning a penny
  • wherever a penny was to be got. Neither of them had either knowledge or
  • foresight of that great revolution which the folly of the one, and the
  • industry of the other, was gradually bringing about.
  • It was thus, that, through the greater part of Europe, the commerce and
  • manufactures of cities, instead of being the effect, have been the cause
  • and occasion of the improvement and cultivation of the country.
  • This order, however, being contrary to the natural course of things, is
  • necessarily both slow and uncertain. Compare the slow progress of those
  • European countries of which the wealth depends very much upon their
  • commerce and manufactures, with the rapid advances of our North American
  • colonies, of which the wealth is founded altogether in agriculture.
  • Through the greater part of Europe, the number of inhabitants is not
  • supposed to double in less than five hundred years. In several of our
  • North American colonies, it is found to double in twenty or
  • five-and-twenty years. In Europe, the law of primogeniture, and
  • perpetuities of different kinds, prevent the division of great estates,
  • and thereby hinder the multiplication of small proprietors. A small
  • proprietor, however, who knows every part of his little territory, views
  • it with all the affection which property, especially small property,
  • naturally inspires, and who upon that account takes pleasure, not only in
  • cultivating, but in adorning it, is generally of all improvers the most
  • industrious, the most intelligent, and the most successful. The same
  • regulations, besides, keep so much land out of the market, that there are
  • always more capitals to buy than there is land to sell, so that what is
  • sold always sells at a monopoly price. The rent never pays the interest of
  • the purchase-money, and is, besides, burdened with repairs and other
  • occasional charges, to which the interest of money is not liable. To
  • purchase land, is, everywhere in Europe, a most unprofitable employment of
  • a small capital. For the sake of the superior security, indeed, a man of
  • moderate circumstances, when he retires from business, will sometimes
  • choose to lay out his little capital in land. A man of profession, too
  • whose revenue is derived from another source often loves to secure his
  • savings in the same way. But a young man, who, instead of applying to
  • trade or to some profession, should employ a capital of two or three
  • thousand pounds in the purchase and cultivation of a small piece of land,
  • might indeed expect to live very happily and very independently, but must
  • bid adieu for ever to all hope of either great fortune or great
  • illustration, which, by a different employment of his stock, he might have
  • had the same chance of acquiring with other people. Such a person, too,
  • though he cannot aspire at being a proprietor, will often disdain to be a
  • farmer. The small quantity of land, therefore, which is brought to market,
  • and the high price of what is brought thither, prevents a great number of
  • capitals from being employed in its cultivation and improvement, which
  • would otherwise have taken that direction. In North America, on the
  • contrary, fifty or sixty pounds is often found a sufficient stock to begin
  • a plantation with. The purchase and improvement of uncultivated land is
  • there the most profitable employment of the smallest as well as of the
  • greatest capitals, and the most direct road to all the fortune and
  • illustration which can be required in that country. Such land, indeed, is
  • in North America to be had almost for nothing, or at a price much below
  • the value of the natural produce; a thing impossible in Europe, or indeed
  • in any country where all lands have long been private property. If landed
  • estates, however, were divided equally among all the children, upon the
  • death of any proprietor who left a numerous family, the estate would
  • generally be sold. So much land would come to market, that it could no
  • longer sell at a monopoly price. The free rent of the land would go no
  • nearer to pay the interest of the purchase-money, and a small capital
  • might be employed in purchasing land as profitable as in any other way.
  • England, on account of the natural fertility of the soil, of the great
  • extent of the sea-coast in proportion to that of the whole country, and of
  • the many navigable rivers which run through it, and afford the conveniency
  • of water carriage to some of the most inland parts of it, is perhaps as
  • well fitted by nature as any large country in Europe to be the seat of
  • foreign commerce, of manufactures for distant sale, and of all the
  • improvements which these can occasion. From the beginning of the reign of
  • Elizabeth, too, the English legislature has been peculiarly attentive to
  • the interest of commerce and manufactures, and in reality there is no
  • country in Europe, Holland itself not excepted, of which the law is, upon
  • the whole, more favourable to this sort of industry. Commerce and
  • manufactures have accordingly been continually advancing during all this
  • period. The cultivation and improvement of the country has, no doubt, been
  • gradually advancing too; but it seems to have followed slowly, and at a
  • distance, the more rapid progress of commerce and manufactures. The
  • greater part of the country must probably have been cultivated before the
  • reign of Elizabeth; and a very great part of it still remains
  • uncultivated, and the cultivation of the far greater part much inferior to
  • what it might be, The law of England, however, favours agriculture, not
  • only indirectly, by the protection of commerce, but by several direct
  • encouragements. Except in times of scarcity, the exportation of corn is
  • not only free, but encouraged by a bounty. In times of moderate plenty,
  • the importation of foreign corn is loaded with duties that amount to a
  • prohibition. The importation of live cattle, except from Ireland, is
  • prohibited at all times; and it is but of late that it was permitted from
  • thence. Those who cultivate the land, therefore, have a monopoly against
  • their countrymen for the two greatest and most important articles of land
  • produce, bread and butcher’s meat. These encouragements, although at
  • bottom, perhaps, as I shall endeavour to show hereafter, altogether
  • illusory, sufficiently demonstrate at least the good intention of the
  • legislature to favour agriculture. But what is of much more importance
  • than all of them, the yeomanry of England are rendered as secure, as
  • independent, and as respectable, as law can make them. No country,
  • therefore, which the right of primogeniture takes place, which pays
  • tithes, and where perpetuities, though contrary to the spirit of the law,
  • are admitted in some cases, can give more encouragement to agriculture
  • than England. Such, however, notwithstanding, is the state of its
  • cultivation. What would it have been, had the law given no direct
  • encouragement to agriculture besides what arises indirectly from the
  • progress of commerce, and had left the yeomanry in the same condition as
  • in most other countries of Europe? It is now more than two hundred years
  • since the beginning of the reign of Elizabeth, a period as long as the
  • course of human prosperity usually endures.
  • France seems to have had a considerable share of foreign commerce, near a
  • century before England was distinguished as a commercial country. The
  • marine of France was considerable, according to the notions of the times,
  • before the expedition of Charles VIII. to Naples. The cultivation and
  • improvement of France, however, is, upon the whole, inferior to that of
  • England. The law of the country has never given the same direct
  • encouragement to agriculture.
  • The foreign commerce of Spain and Portual to the other parts of Europe,
  • though chiefly carried on in foreign ships, is very considerable. That to
  • their colonies is carried on in their own, and is much greater, on account
  • of the great riches and extent of those colonies. But it has never
  • introduced any considerable manufactures for distant sale into either of
  • those countries, and the greater part of both still remains uncultivated.
  • The foreign commerce of Portugal is of older standing than that of any
  • great country in Europe, except Italy.
  • Italy is the only great country of Europe which seems to have been
  • cultivated and improved in every part, by means of foreign commerce and
  • manufactures for distant sale. Before the invasion of Charles VIII.,
  • Italy, according to Guicciardini, was cultivated not less in the most
  • mountainous and barren parts of the country, than in the plainest and most
  • fertile. The advantageous situation of the country, and the great number
  • of independent status which at that time subsisted in it, probably
  • contributed not a little to this general cultivation. It is not
  • impossible, too, notwithstanding this general expression of one of the
  • most judicious and reserved of modern historians, that Italy was not at
  • that time better cultivated than England is at present.
  • The capital, however, that is acquired to any country by commerce and
  • manufactures, is always a very precarious and uncertain possession, till
  • some part of it has been secured and realized in the cultivation and
  • improvement of its lands. A merchant, it has been said very properly, is
  • not necessarily the citizen of any particular country. It is in a great
  • measure indifferent to him from what place he carries on his trade; and a
  • very trifling disgust will make him remove his capital, and, together with
  • it, all the industry which it supports, from one country to another. No
  • part of it can be said to belong to any particular country, till it has
  • been spread, as it were, over the face of that country, either in
  • buildings, or in the lasting improvement of lands. No vestige now remains
  • of the great wealth said to have been possessed by the greater part of the
  • Hanse Towns, except in the obscure histories of the thirteenth and
  • fourteenth centuries. It is even uncertain where some of them were
  • situated, or to what towns in Europe the Latin names given to some of them
  • belong. But though the misfortunes of Italy, in the end of the fifteenth
  • and beginning of the sixteenth centuries, greatly diminished the commerce
  • and manufactures of the cities of Lombardy and Tuscany, those countries
  • still continue to be among the most populous and best cultivated in
  • Europe. The civil wars of Flanders, and the Spanish government which
  • succeeded them, chased away the great commerce of Antwerp, Ghent, and
  • Bruges. But Flanders still continues to be one of the richest, best
  • cultivated, and most populous provinces of Europe. The ordinary
  • revolutions of war and government easily dry up the sources of that wealth
  • which arises from commerce only. That which arises from the more solid
  • improvements of agriculture is much more durable, and cannot be destroyed
  • but by those more violent convulsions occasioned by the depredations of
  • hostile and barbarous nations continued for a century or two together;
  • such as those that happened for some time before and after the fall of the
  • Roman empire in the western provinces of Europe.
  • BOOK IV.
  • OF SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY.
  • Political economy, considered as a branch of the science of a statesman or
  • legislator, proposes two distinct objects; first, to provide a plentiful
  • revenue or subsistence for the people, or, more properly, to enable them
  • to provide such a revenue or subsistence for themselves; and, secondly, to
  • supply the state or commonwealth with a revenue sufficient for the public
  • services. It proposes to enrich both the people and the sovereign.
  • The different progress of opulence in different ages and nations, has
  • given occasion to two different systems of political economy, with regard
  • to enriching the people. The one may be called the system of commerce, the
  • other that of agriculture. I shall endeavour to explain both as fully and
  • distinctly as I can, and shall begin with the system of commerce. It is
  • the modern system, and is best understood in our own country and in our
  • own times.
  • CHAPTER I.
  • OF THE PRINCIPLE OF THE COMMERCIAL OR
  • MERCANTILE SYSTEM.
  • That wealth consists in money, or in gold and silver, is a popular notion
  • which naturally arises from the double function of money, as the
  • instrument of commerce, and as the measure of value. In consequence of its
  • being the instrument of commerce, when we have money we can more readily
  • obtain whatever else we have occasion for, than by means of any other
  • commodity. The great affair, we always find, is to get money. When that is
  • obtained, there is no difficulty in making any subsequent purchase. In
  • consequence of its being the measure of value, we estimate that of all
  • other commodities by the quantity of money which they will exchange for.
  • We say of a rich man, that he is worth a great deal, and of a poor man,
  • that he is worth very little money. A frugal man, or a man eager to be
  • rich, is said to love money; and a careless, a generous, or a profuse man,
  • is said to be indifferent about it. To grow rich is to get money; and
  • wealth and money, in short, are, in common language, considered as in
  • every respect synonymous.
  • A rich country, in the same manner as a rich man, is supposed to be a
  • country abounding in money; and to heap up gold and silver in any country
  • is supposed to be the readiest way to enrich it. For some time after the
  • discovery of America, the first inquiry of the Spaniards, when they
  • arrived upon any unknown coast, used to be, if there was any gold or
  • silver to be found in the neighbourhood? By the information which they
  • received, they judged whether it was worth while to make a settlement
  • there, or if the country was worth the conquering. Plano Carpino, a monk
  • sent ambassador from the king of France to one of the sons of the famous
  • Gengis Khan, says, that the Tartars used frequently to ask him, if there
  • was plenty of sheep and oxen in the kingdom of France? Their inquiry had
  • the same object with that of the Spaniards. They wanted to know if the
  • country was rich enough to be worth the conquering. Among the Tartars, as
  • among all other nations of shepherds, who are generally ignorant of the
  • use of money, cattle are the instruments of commerce and the measures of
  • value. Wealth, therefore, according to them, consisted in cattle, as,
  • according to the Spaniards, it consisted in gold and silver. Of the two,
  • the Tartar notion, perhaps, was the nearest to the truth.
  • Mr Locke remarks a distinction between money and other moveable goods. All
  • other moveable goods, he says, are of so consumable a nature, that the
  • wealth which consists in them cannot be much depended on; and a nation
  • which abounds in them one year may, without any exportation, but merely by
  • their own waste and extravagance, be in great want of them the next.
  • Money, on the contrary, is a steady friend, which, though it may travel
  • about from hand to hand, yet if it can be kept from going out of the
  • country, is not very liable to be wasted and consumed. Gold and silver,
  • therefore, are, according to him, the must solid and substantial part of
  • the moveable wealth of a nation; and to multiply those metals ought, he
  • thinks, upon that account, to be the great object of its political
  • economy.
  • Others admit, that if a nation could be separated from all the world, it
  • would be of no consequence how much or how little money circulated in it.
  • The consumable goods, which were circulated by means of this money, would
  • only be exchanged for a greater or a smaller number of pieces; but the
  • real wealth or poverty of the country, they allow, would depend altogether
  • upon the abundance or scarcity of those consumable goods. But it is
  • otherwise, they think, with countries which have connections with foreign
  • nations, and which are obliged to carry on foreign wars, and to maintain
  • fleets and armies in distant countries. This, they say, cannot be done,
  • but by sending abroad money to pay them with; and a nation cannot send
  • much money abroad, unless it has a good deal at home. Every such nation,
  • therefore, must endeavour, in time of peace, to accumulate gold and
  • silver, that when occasion requires, it may have wherewithal to carry on
  • foreign wars.
  • In consequence of those popular notions, all the different nations of
  • Europe have studied, though to little purpose, every possible means of
  • accumulating gold and silver in their respective countries. Spain and
  • Portugal, the proprietors of the principal mines which supply Europe with
  • those metals, have either prohibited their exportation under the severest
  • penalties, or subjected it to a considerable duty. The like prohibition
  • seems anciently to have made a part of the policy of most other European
  • nations. It is even to be found, where we should least of all expect to
  • find it, in some old Scotch acts of Parliament, which forbid, under heavy
  • penalties, the carrying gold or silver forth of the kingdom. The like
  • policy anciently took place both in France and England.
  • When those countries became commercial, the merchants found this
  • prohibition, upon many occasions, extremely inconvenient. They could
  • frequently buy more advantageously with gold and silver, than with any
  • other commodity, the foreign goods which they wanted, either to import
  • into their own, or to carry to some other foreign country. They
  • remonstrated, therefore, against this prohibition as hurtful to trade.
  • They represented, first, that the exportation of gold and silver, in order
  • to purchase foreign goods, did not always diminish the quantity of those
  • metals in the kingdom; that, on the contrary, it might frequently increase
  • the quantity; because, if the consumption of foreign goods was not thereby
  • increased in the country, those goods might be re-exported to foreign
  • countries, and being there sold for a large profit, might bring back much
  • more treasure than was originally sent out to purchase them. Mr Mun
  • compares this operation of foreign trade to the seed-time and harvest of
  • agriculture. “If we only behold,” says he, “the actions of the husbandman
  • in the seed time, when he casteth away much good corn into the ground, we
  • shall account him rather a madman than a husbandman. But when we consider
  • his labours in the harvest, which is the end of his endeavours, we shall
  • find the worth and plentiful increase of his actions.”
  • They represented, secondly, that this prohibition could not hinder the
  • exportation of gold and silver, which, on account of the smallness of
  • their bulk in proportion to their value, could easily be smuggled abroad.
  • That this exportation could only be prevented by a proper attention to
  • what they called the balance of trade. That when the country exported to a
  • greater value than it imported, a balance became due to it from foreign
  • nations, which was necessarily paid to it in gold and silver, and thereby
  • increased the quantity of those metals in the kingdom. But that when it
  • imported to a greater value than it exported, a contrary balance became
  • due to foreign nations, which was necessarily paid to them in the same
  • manner, and thereby diminished that quantity: that in this case, to
  • prohibit the exportation of those metals, could not prevent it, but only,
  • by making it more dangerous, render it more expensive: that the exchange
  • was thereby turned more against the country which owed the balance, than
  • it otherwise might have been; the merchant who purchased a bill upon the
  • foreign country being obliged to pay the banker who sold it, not only for
  • the natural risk, trouble, and expense of sending the money thither, but
  • for the extraordinary risk arising from the prohibition; but that the more
  • the exchange was against any country, the more the balance of trade became
  • necessarily against it; the money of that country becoming necessarily of
  • so much less value, in comparison with that of the country to which the
  • balance was due. That if the exchange between England and Holland, for
  • example, was five per cent. against England, it would require 105 ounces
  • of silver in England to purchase a bill for 100 ounces of silver in
  • Holland: that 105 ounces of silver in England, therefore, would be worth
  • only 100 ounces of silver in Holland, and would purchase only a
  • proportionable quantity of Dutch goods; but that 100 ounces of silver in
  • Holland, on the contrary, would be worth 105 ounces in England, and would
  • purchase a proportionable quantity of English goods; that the English
  • goods which were sold to Holland would be sold so much cheaper, and the
  • Dutch goods which were sold to England so much dearer, by the difference
  • of the exchange: that the one would draw so much less Dutch money to
  • England, and the other so much more English money to Holland, as this
  • difference amounted to: and that the balance of trade, therefore, would
  • necessarily be so much more against England, and would require a greater
  • balance of gold and silver to be exported to Holland.
  • Those arguments were partly solid and partly sophistical. They were solid,
  • so far as they asserted that the exportation of gold and silver in trade
  • might frequently be advantageous to the country. They were solid, too, in
  • asserting that no prohibition could prevent their exportation, when
  • private people found any advantage in exporting them. But they were
  • sophistical, in supposing, that either to preserve or to augment the
  • quantity of those metals required more the attention of government, than
  • to preserve or to augment the quantity of any other useful commodities,
  • which the freedom of trade, without any such attention, never fails to
  • supply in the proper quantity. They were sophistical, too, perhaps, in
  • asserting that the high price of exchange necessarily increased what they
  • called the unfavourable balance of trade, or occasioned the exportation of
  • a greater quantity of gold and silver. That high price, indeed, was
  • extremely disadvantageous to the merchants who had any money to pay in
  • foreign countries. They paid so much dearer for the bills which their
  • bankers granted them upon those countries. But though the risk arising
  • from the prohibition might occasion some extraordinary expense to the
  • bankers, it would not necessarily carry any more money out of the country.
  • This expense would generally be all laid out in the country, in smuggling
  • the money out of it, and could seldom occasion the exportation of a single
  • sixpence beyond the precise sum drawn for. The high price of exchange,
  • too, would naturally dispose the merchants to endeavour to make their
  • exports nearly balance their imports, in order that they might have this
  • high exchange to pay upon as small a sum as possible. The high price of
  • exchange, besides, must necessarily have operated as a tax, in raising the
  • price of foreign goods, and thereby diminishing their consumption. It
  • would tend, therefore, not to increase, but to diminish, what they called
  • the unfavourable balance of trade, and consequently the exportation of
  • gold and silver.
  • Such as they were, however, those arguments convinced the people to whom
  • they were addressed. They were addressed by merchants to parliaments and
  • to the councils of princes, to nobles, and to country gentlemen; by those
  • who were supposed to understand trade, to those who were conscious to them
  • selves that they knew nothing about the matter. That foreign trade
  • enriched the country, experience demonstrated to the nobles and country
  • gentlemen, as well as to the merchants; but how, or in what manner, none
  • of them well knew. The merchants knew perfectly in what manner it enriched
  • themselves, it was their business to know it. But to know in what manner
  • it enriched the country, was no part of their business. The subject never
  • came into their consideration, but when they had occasion to apply to
  • their country for some change in the laws relating to foreign trade. It
  • then became necessary to say something about the beneficial effects of
  • foreign trade, and the manner in which those effects were obstructed by
  • the laws as they then stood. To the judges who were to decide the
  • business, it appeared a most satisfactory account of the matter, when they
  • were told that foreign trade brought money into the country, but that the
  • laws in question hindered it from bringing so much as it otherwise would
  • do. Those arguments, therefore, produced the wished-for effect. The
  • prohibition of exporting gold and silver was, in France and England,
  • confined to the coin of those respective countries. The exportation of
  • foreign coin and of bullion was made free. In Holland, and in some other
  • places, this liberty was extended even to the coin of the country. The
  • attention of government was turned away from guarding against the
  • exportation of gold and silver, to watch over the balance of trade, as the
  • only cause which could occasion any augmentation or diminution of those
  • metals. From one fruitless care, it was turned away to another care much
  • more intricate, much more embarrassing, and just equally fruitless. The
  • title of Mun’s book, England’s Treasure in Foreign Trade, became a
  • fundamental maxim in the political economy, not of England only, but of
  • all other commercial countries. The inland or home trade, the most
  • important of all, the trade in which an equal capital affords the greatest
  • revenue, and creates the greatest employment to the people of the country,
  • was considered as subsidiary only to foreign trade. It neither brought
  • money into the country, it was said, nor carried any out of it. The
  • country, therefore, could never become either richer or poorer by means of
  • it, except so far as its prosperity or decay might indirectly influence
  • the state of foreign trade.
  • A country that has no mines of its own, must undoubtedly draw its gold and
  • silver from foreign countries, in the same manner as one that has no
  • vineyards of its own must draw its wines. It does not seem necessary,
  • however, that the attention of government should be more turned towards
  • the one than towards the other object. A country that has wherewithal to
  • buy wine, will always get the wine which it has occasion for; and a
  • country that has wherewithal to buy gold and silver, will never be in want
  • of those metals. They are to be bought for a certain price, like all other
  • commodities; and as they are the price of all other commodities, so all
  • other commodities are the price of those metals. We trust, with perfect
  • security, that the freedom of trade, without any attention of government,
  • will always supply us with the wine which we have occasion for; and we may
  • trust, with equal security, that it will always supply us with all the
  • gold and silver which we can afford to purchase or to employ, either in
  • circulating our commodities or in other uses.
  • The quantity of every commodity which human industry can either purchase
  • or produce, naturally regulates itself in every country according to the
  • effectual demand, or according to the demand of those who are willing to
  • pay the whole rent, labour, and profits, which must be paid in order to
  • prepare and bring it to market. But no commodities regulate themselves
  • more easily or more exactly, according to this effectual demand, than gold
  • and silver; because, on account of the small bulk and great value of those
  • metals, no commodities can be more easily transported from one place to
  • another; from the places where they are cheap, to those where they are
  • dear; from the places where they exceed, to those where they fall short of
  • this effectual demand. If there were in England, for example, an effectual
  • demand for an additional quantity of gold, a packet-boat could bring from
  • Lisbon, or from wherever else it was to be had, fifty tons of gold, which
  • could be coined into more than five millions of guineas. But if there were
  • an effectual demand for grain to the same value, to import it would
  • require, at five guineas a-ton, a million of tons of shipping, or a
  • thousand ships of a thousand tons each. The navy of England would not be
  • sufficient.
  • When the quantity of gold and silver imported into any country exceeds the
  • effectual demand, no vigilance of government can prevent their
  • exportation. All the sanguinary laws of Spain and Portugal are not able to
  • keep their gold and silver at home. The continual importations from Peru
  • and Brazil exceed the effectual demand of those countries, and sink the
  • price of those metals there below that in the neighbouring countries. If,
  • on the contrary, in any particular country, their quantity fell short of
  • the effectual demand, so as to raise their price above that of the
  • neighbouring countries, the government would have no occasion to take any
  • pains to import them. If it were even to take pains to prevent their
  • importation, it would not be able to effectuate it. Those metals, when the
  • Spartans had got wherewithal to purchase them, broke through all the
  • barriers which the laws of Lycurgus opposed to their entrance into
  • Lacedaemon. All the sanguinary laws of the customs are not able to prevent
  • the importation of the teas of the Dutch and Gottenburg East India
  • companies; because somewhat cheaper than those of the British company. A
  • pound of tea, however, is about a hundred times the bulk of one of the
  • highest prices, sixteen shillings, that is commonly paid for it in silver,
  • and more than two thousand times the bulk of the same price in gold, and,
  • consequently, just so many times more difficult to smuggle.
  • It is partly owing to the easy transportation of gold and silver, from the
  • places where they abound to those where they are wanted, that the price of
  • those metals does not fluctuate continually, like that of the greater part
  • of other commodities, which are hindered by their bulk from shifting their
  • situation, when the market happens to be either over or under-stocked with
  • them. The price of those metals, indeed, is not altogether exempted from
  • variation; but the changes to which it is liable are generally slow,
  • gradual, and uniform. In Europe, for example, it is supposed, without much
  • foundation, perhaps, that during the course of the present and preceding
  • century, they have been constantly, but gradually, sinking in their value,
  • on account of the continual importations from the Spanish West Indies. But
  • to make any sudden change in the price of gold and silver, so as to raise
  • or lower at once, sensibly and remarkably, the money price of all other
  • commodities, requires such a revolution in commerce as that occasioned by
  • the discovery of America.
  • If, not withstanding all this, gold and silver should at any time fall
  • short in a country which has wherewithal to purchase them, there are more
  • expedients for supplying their place, than that of almost any other
  • commodity. If the materials of manufacture are wanted, industry must stop.
  • If provisions are wanted, the people must starve. But if money is wanted,
  • barter will supply its place, though with a good deal of inconveniency.
  • Buying and selling upon credit, and the different dealers compensating
  • their credits with one another, once a-month, or once a-year, will supply
  • it with less inconveniency. A well-regulated paper-money will supply it
  • not only without any inconveniency, but, in some cases, with some
  • advantages. Upon every account, therefore, the attention of government
  • never was so unnecessarily employed, as when directed to watch over the
  • preservation or increase of the quantity of money in any country.
  • No complaint, however, is more common than that of a scarcity of money.
  • Money, like wine, must always be scarce with those who have neither
  • wherewithal to buy it, nor credit to borrow it. Those who have either,
  • will seldom be in want either of the money, or of the wine which they have
  • occasion for. This complaint, however, of the scarcity of money, is not
  • always confined to improvident spendthrifts. It is sometimes general
  • through a whole mercantile town and the country in its neighbourhood.
  • Over-trading is the common cause of it. Sober men, whose projects have
  • been disproportioned to their capitals, are as likely to have neither
  • wherewithal to buy money, nor credit to borrow it, as prodigals, whose
  • expense has been disproportioned to their revenue. Before their projects
  • can be brought to bear, their stock is gone, and their credit with it.
  • They run about everywhere to borrow money, and everybody tells them that
  • they have none to lend. Even such general complaints of the scarcity of
  • money do not always prove that the usual number of gold and silver pieces
  • are not circulating in the country, but that many people want those pieces
  • who have nothing to give for them. When the profits of trade happen to be
  • greater than ordinary over-trading becomes a general error, both among
  • great and small dealers. They do not always send more money abroad than
  • usual, but they buy upon credit, both at home and abroad, an unusual
  • quantity of goods, which they send to some distant market, in hopes that
  • the returns will come in before the demand for payment. The demand comes
  • before the returns, and they have nothing at hand with which they can
  • either purchase money or give solid security for borrowing. It is not any
  • scarcity of gold and silver, but the difficulty which such people find in
  • borrowing, and which their creditor find in getting payment, that
  • occasions the general complaint of the scarcity of money.
  • It would be too ridiculous to go about seriously to prove, that wealth
  • does not consist in money, or in gold and silver; but in what money
  • purchases, and is valuable only for purchasing. Money, no doubt, makes
  • always a part of the national capital; but it has already been shown that
  • it generally makes but a small part, and always the most unprofitable part
  • of it.
  • It is not because wealth consists more essentially in money than in goods,
  • that the merchant finds it generally more easy to buy goods with money,
  • than to buy money with goods; but because money is the known and
  • established instrument of commerce, for which every thing is readily given
  • in exchange, but which is not always with equal readiness to be got in
  • exchange for every thing. The greater part of goods, besides, are more
  • perishable than money, and he may frequently sustain a much greater loss
  • by keeping them. When his goods are upon hand, too, he is more liable to
  • such demands for money as he may not be able to answer, than when he has
  • got their price in his coffers. Over and above all this, his profit arises
  • more directly from selling than from buying; and he is, upon all these
  • accounts, generally much more anxious to exchange his goods for money than
  • his money for goods. But though a particular merchant, with abundance of
  • goods in his warehouse, may sometimes be ruined by not being able to sell
  • them in time, a nation or country is not liable to the same accident, The
  • whole capital of a merchant frequently consists in perishable goods
  • destined for purchasing money. But it is but a very small part of the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of a country, which can ever be
  • destined for purchasing gold and silver from their neighbours. The far
  • greater part is circulated and consumed among themselves; and even of the
  • surplus which is sent abroad, the greater part is generally destined for
  • the purchase of other foreign goods. Though gold and silver, therefore,
  • could not be had in exchange for the goods destined to purchase them, the
  • nation would not be ruined. It might, indeed, suffer some loss and
  • inconveniency, and be forced upon some of those expedients which are
  • necessary for supplying the place of money. The annual produce of its land
  • and labour, however, would be the same, or very nearly the same as usual;
  • because the same, or very nearly the same consumable capital would be
  • employed in maintaining it. And though goods do not always draw money so
  • readily as money draws goods, in the long-run they draw it more
  • necessarily than even it draws them. Goods can serve many other purposes
  • besides purchasing money, but money can serve no other purpose besides
  • purchasing goods. Money, therefore, necessarily runs after goods, but
  • goods do not always or necessarily run after money. The man who buys, does
  • not always mean to sell again, but frequently to use or to consume;
  • whereas he who sells always means to buy again. The one may frequently
  • have done the whole, but the other can never have done more than the one
  • half of his business. It is not for its own sake that men desire money,
  • but for the sake of what they can purchase with it.
  • Consumable commodities, it is said, are soon destroyed; whereas gold and
  • silver are of a more durable nature, and were it not for this continual
  • exportation, might be accumulated for ages together, to the incredible
  • augmentation of the real wealth of the country. Nothing, therefore, it is
  • pretended, can be more disadvantageous to any country, than the trade
  • which consists in the exchange of such lasting for such perishable
  • commodities. We do not, however, reckon that trade disadvantageous, which
  • consists in the exchange of the hardware of England for the wines of
  • France, and yet hardware is a very durable commodity, and were it not for
  • this continual exportation, might too be accumulated for ages together, to
  • the incredible augmentation of the pots and pans of the country. But it
  • readily occurs, that the number of such utensils is in every country
  • necessarily limited by the use which there is for them; that it would be
  • absurd to have more pots and pans than were necessary for cooking the
  • victuals usually consumed there; and that, if the quantity of victuals
  • were to increase, the number of pots and pans would readily increase along
  • with it; a part of the increased quantity of victuals being employed in
  • purchasing them, or in maintaining an additional number of workmen whose
  • business it was to make them. It should as readily occur, that the
  • quantity of gold and silver is, in every country, limited by the use which
  • there is for those metals; that their use consists in circulating
  • commodities, as coin, and in affording a species of household furniture,
  • as plate; that the quantity of coin in every country is regulated by the
  • value of the commodities which are to be circulated by it; increase that
  • value, and immediately a part of it will be sent abroad to purchase,
  • wherever it is to be had, the additional quantity of coin requisite for
  • circulating them: that the quantity of plate is regulated by the number
  • and wealth of those private families who choose to indulge themselves in
  • that sort of magnificence; increase the number and wealth of such
  • families, and a part of this increased wealth will most probably be
  • employed in purchasing, wherever it is to be found, an additional quantity
  • of plate; that to attempt to increase the wealth of any country, either by
  • introducing or by detaining in it an unnecessary quantity of gold and
  • silver, is as absurd as it would be to attempt to increase the good cheer
  • of private families, by obliging them to keep an unnecessary number of
  • kitchen utensils. As the expense of purchasing those unnecessary utensils
  • would diminish, instead of increasing, either the quantity or goodness of
  • the family provisions; so the expense of purchasing an unnecessary
  • quantity of gold and silver must, in every country, as necessarily
  • diminish the wealth which feeds, clothes, and lodges, which maintains and
  • employs the people. Gold and silver, whether in the shape of coin or of
  • plate, are utensils, it must be remembered, as much as the furniture of
  • the kitchen. Increase the use of them, increase the consumable commodities
  • which are to be circulated, managed, and prepared by means of them, and
  • you will infallibly increase the quantity; but if you attempt by
  • extraordinary means to increase the quantity, you will as infallibly
  • diminish the use, and even the quantity too, which in those metals can
  • never be greater than what the use requires. Were they ever to be
  • accumulated beyond this quantity, their transportation is so easy, and the
  • loss which attends their lying idle and unemployed so great, that no law
  • could prevent their being immediately sent out of the country.
  • It is not always necessary to accumulate gold and silver, in order to
  • enable a country to carry on foreign wars, and to maintain fleets and
  • armies in distant countries. Fleets and armies are maintained, not with
  • gold and silver, but with consumable goods. The nation which, from the
  • annual produce of its domestic industry, from the annual revenue arising
  • out of its lands, and labour, and consumable stock, has wherewithal to
  • purchase those consumable goods in distant countries, can maintain foreign
  • wars there.
  • A nation may purchase the pay and provisions of an army in a distant
  • country three different ways; by sending abroad either, first, some part
  • of its accumulated gold and silver; or, secondly, some part of the annual
  • produce of its manufactures; or, last of all, some part of its annual rude
  • produce.
  • The gold and silver which can properly be considered as accumulated, or
  • stored up in any country, may be distinguished into three parts; first,
  • the circulating money; secondly, the plate of private families; and, last
  • of all, the money which may have been collected by many years parsimony,
  • and laid up in the treasury of the prince.
  • It can seldom happen that much can be spared from the circulating money of
  • the country; because in that there can seldom be much redundancy. The
  • value of goods annually bought and sold in any country requires a certain
  • quantity of money to circulate and distribute them to their proper
  • consumers, and can give employment to no more. The channel of circulation
  • necessarily draws to itself a sum sufficient to fill it, and never admits
  • any more. Something, however, is generally withdrawn from this channel in
  • the case of foreign war. By the great number of people who are maintained
  • abroad, fewer are maintained at home. Fewer goods are circulated there,
  • and less money becomes necessary to circulate them. An extraordinary
  • quantity of paper money of some sort or other, too, such as exchequer
  • notes, navy bills, and bank bills, in England, is generally issued upon
  • such occasions, and, by supplying the place of circulating gold and
  • silver, gives an opportunity of sending a greater quantity of it abroad.
  • All this, however, could afford but a poor resource for maintaining a
  • foreign war, of great expense, and several years duration.
  • The melting down of the plate of private families has, upon every
  • occasion, been found a still more insignificant one. The French, in the
  • beginning of the last war, did not derive so much advantage from this
  • expedient as to compensate the loss of the fashion.
  • The accumulated treasures of the prince have in former times afforded a
  • much greater and more lasting resource. In the present times, if you
  • except the king of Prussia, to accumulate treasure seems to be no part of
  • the policy of European princes.
  • The funds which maintained the foreign wars of the present century, the
  • most expensive perhaps which history records, seem to have had little
  • dependency upon the exportation either of the circulating money, or of the
  • plate of private families, or of the treasure of the prince. The last
  • French war cost Great Britain upwards of £90,000,000, including not only
  • the £75,000,000 of new debt that was contracted, but the additional 2s. in
  • the pound land-tax, and what was annually borrowed of the sinking fund.
  • More than two-thirds of this expense were laid out in distant countries;
  • in Germany, Portugal, America, in the ports of the Mediterranean, in the
  • East and West Indies. The kings of England had no accumulated treasure. We
  • never heard of any extraordinary quantity of plate being melted down. The
  • circulating gold and silver of the country had not been supposed to exceed
  • £18,000,000. Since the late recoinage of the gold, however, it is believed
  • to have been a good deal under-rated. Let us suppose, therefore, according
  • to the most exaggerated computation which I remember to have either seen
  • or heard of, that, gold and silver together, it amounted to £30,000,000.
  • Had the war been carried on by means of our money, the whole of it must,
  • even according to this computation, have been sent out and returned again,
  • at least twice in a period of between six and seven years. Should this be
  • supposed, it would afford the most decisive argument, to demonstrate how
  • unnecessary it is for government to watch over the preservation of money,
  • since, upon this supposition, the whole money of the country must have
  • gone from it, and returned to it again, two different times in so short a
  • period, without any body’s knowing any thing of the matter. The channel of
  • circulation, however, never appeared more empty than usual during any part
  • of this period. Few people wanted money who had wherewithal to pay for it.
  • The profits of foreign trade, indeed, were greater than usual during the
  • whole war, but especially towards the end of it. This occasioned, what it
  • always occasions, a general over-trading in all the ports of Great
  • Britain; and this again occasioned the usual complaint of the scarcity of
  • money, which always follows over-trading. Many people wanted it, who had
  • neither wherewithal to buy it, nor credit to borrow it; and because the
  • debtors found it difficult to borrow, the creditors found it difficult to
  • get payment. Gold and silver, however, were generally to be had for their
  • value, by those who had that value to give for them.
  • The enormous expense of the late war, therefore, must have been chiefly
  • defrayed, not by the exportation of gold and silver, but by that of
  • British commodities of some kind or other. When the government, or those
  • who acted under them, contracted with a merchant for a remittance to some
  • foreign country, he would naturally endeavour to pay his foreign
  • correspondent, upon whom he granted a bill, by sending abroad rather
  • commodities than gold and silver. If the commodities of Great Britain were
  • not in demand in that country, he would endeavour to send them to some
  • other country in which he could purchase a bill upon that country. The
  • transportation of commodities, when properly suited to the market, is
  • always attended with a considerable profit; whereas that of gold and
  • silver is scarce ever attended with any. When those metals are sent abroad
  • in order to purchase foreign commodities, the merchant’s profit arises,
  • not from the purchase, but from the sale of the returns. But when they are
  • sent abroad merely to pay a debt, he gets no returns, and consequently no
  • profit. He naturally, therefore, exerts his invention to find out a way of
  • paying his foreign debts, rather by the exportation of commodities, than
  • by that of gold and silver. The great quantity of British goods, exported
  • during the course of the late war, without bringing back any returns, is
  • accordingly remarked by the author of the Present State of the Nation.
  • Besides the three sorts of gold and silver above mentioned, there is in
  • all great commercial countries a good deal of bullion alternately imported
  • and exported, for the purposes of foreign trade. This bullion, as it
  • circulates among different commercial countries, in the same manner as the
  • national coin circulates in every country, may be considered as the money
  • of the great mercantile republic. The national coin receives its movement
  • and direction from the commodities circulated within the precincts of each
  • particular country; the money in the mercantile republic, from those
  • circulated between different countries. Both are employed in facilitating
  • exchanges, the one between different individuals of the same, the other
  • between those of different nations. Part of this money of the great
  • mercantile republic may have been, and probably was, employed in carrying
  • on the late war. In time of a general war, it is natural to suppose that a
  • movement and direction should be impressed upon it, different from what it
  • usually follows in profound peace, that it should circulate more about the
  • seat of the war, and be more employed in purchasing there, and in the
  • neighbouring countries, the pay and provisions of the different armies.
  • But whatever part of this money of the mercantile republic Great Britain
  • may have annually employed in this manner, it must have been annually
  • purchased, either with British commodities, or with something else that
  • had been purchased with them; which still brings us back to commodities,
  • to the annual produce of the land and labour of the country, as the
  • ultimate resources which enabled us to carry on the war. It is natural,
  • indeed, to suppose, that so great an annual expense must have been
  • defrayed from a great annual produce. The expense of 1761, for example,
  • amounted to more than £19,000,000. No accumulation could have supported so
  • great an annual profusion. There is no annual produce, even of gold and
  • silver, which could have supported it. The whole gold and silver annually
  • imported into both Spain and Portugal, according to the best accounts,
  • does not commonly much exceed £6,000,000 sterling, which, in some years,
  • would scarce have paid four months expense of the late war.
  • The commodities most proper for being transported to distant countries, in
  • order to purchase there either the pay and provisions of an army, or some
  • part of the money of the mercantile republic to be employed in purchasing
  • them, seem to be the finer and more improved manufactures; such as contain
  • a great value in a small bulk, and can therefore be exported to a great
  • distance at little expense. A country whose industry produces a great
  • annual surplus of such manufactures, which are usually exported to foreign
  • countries, may carry on for many years a very expensive foreign war,
  • without either exporting any considerable quantity of gold and silver, or
  • even having any such quantity to export. A considerable part of the annual
  • surplus of its manufactures must, indeed, in this case, be exported
  • without bringing back any returns to the country, though it does to the
  • merchant; the government purchasing of the merchant his bills upon foreign
  • countries, in order to purchase there the pay and provisions of an army.
  • Some part of this surplus, however, may still continue to bring back a
  • return. The manufacturers during; the war will have a double demand upon
  • them, and be called upon first to work up goods to be sent abroad, for
  • paying the bills drawn upon foreign countries for the pay and provisions
  • of the army: and, secondly, to work up such as are necessary for
  • purchasing the common returns that had usually been consumed in the
  • country. In the midst of the most destructive foreign war, therefore, the
  • greater part of manufactures may frequently flourish greatly; and, on the
  • contrary, they may decline on the return of peace. They may flourish
  • amidst the ruin of their country, and begin to decay upon the return of
  • its prosperity. The different state of many different branches of the
  • British manufactures during the late war, and for some time after the
  • peace, may serve as an illustration of what has been just now said.
  • No foreign war, of great expense or duration, could conveniently be
  • carried on by the exportation of the rude produce of the soil. The expense
  • of sending such a quantity of it into a foreign country as might purchase
  • the pay and provisions of an army would be too great. Few countries, too,
  • produce much more rude produce than what is sufficient for the subsistence
  • of their own inhabitants. To send abroad any great quantity of it,
  • therefore, would be to send abroad a part of the necessary subsistence of
  • the people. It is otherwise with the exportation of manufactures. The
  • maintenance of the people employed in them is kept at home, and only the
  • surplus part of their work is exported. Mr Hume frequently takes notice of
  • the inability of the ancient kings of England to carry on, without
  • interruption, any foreign war of long duration. The English in those days
  • had nothing wherewithal to purchase the pay and provisions of their armies
  • in foreign countries, but either the rude produce of the soil, of which no
  • considerable part could be spared from the home consumption, or a few
  • manufactures of the coarsest kind, of which, as well as of the rude
  • produce, the transportation was too expensive. This inability did not
  • arise from the want of money, but of the finer and more improved
  • manufactures. Buying and selling was transacted by means of money in
  • England then as well as now. The quantity of circulating money must have
  • borne the same proportion, to the number and value of purchases and sales
  • usually transacted at that time, which it does to those transacted at
  • present; or, rather, it must have borne a greater proportion, because
  • there was then no paper, which now occupies a great part of the employment
  • of gold and silver. Among nations to whom commerce and manufactures are
  • little known, the sovereign, upon extraordinary occasions, can seldom draw
  • any considerable aid from his subjects, for reasons which shall be
  • explained hereafter. It is in such countries, therefore, that he generally
  • endeavours to accumulate a treasure, as the only resource against such
  • emergencies. Independent of this necessity, he is, in such a situation,
  • naturally disposed to the parsimony requisite for accumulation. In that
  • simple state, the expense even of a sovereign is not directed by the
  • vanity which delights in the gaudy finery of a court, but is employed in
  • bounty to his tenants, and hospitality to his retainers. But bounty and
  • hospitality very seldom lead to extravagance; though vanity almost always
  • does. Every Tartar chief, accordingly, has a treasure. The treasures of
  • Mazepa, chief of the Cossacks in the Ukraine, the famous ally of Charles
  • XII., are said to have been very great. The French kings of the
  • Merovingian race had all treasures. When they divided their kingdom among
  • their different children, they divided their treasures too. The Saxon
  • princes, and the first kings after the Conquest, seem likewise to have
  • accumulated treasures. The first exploit of every new reign was commonly
  • to seize the treasure of the preceding king, as the most essential measure
  • for securing the succession. The sovereigns of improved and commercial
  • countries are not under the same necessity of accumulating treasures,
  • because they can generally draw from their subjects extraordinary aids
  • upon extraordinary occasions. They are likewise less disposed to do so.
  • They naturally, perhaps necessarily, follow the mode of the times; and
  • their expense comes to be regulated by the same extravagant vanity which
  • directs that of all the other great proprietors in their dominions. The
  • insignificant pageantry of their court becomes every day more brilliant;
  • and the expense of it not only prevents accumulation, but frequently
  • encroaches upon the funds destined for more necessary expenses. What
  • Dercyllidas said of the court of Persia, may be applied to that of several
  • European princes, that he saw there much splendour, but little strength,
  • and many servants, but few soldiers.
  • The importation of gold and silver is not the principal, much less the
  • sole benefit, which a nation derives from its foreign trade. Between
  • whatever places foreign trade is carried on, they all of them derive two
  • distinct benefits from it. It carries out that surplus part of the produce
  • of their land and labour for which there is no demand among them, and
  • brings back in return for it something else for which there is a demand.
  • It gives a value to their superfluities, by exchanging them for something
  • else, which may satisfy a part of their wants and increase their
  • enjoyments. By means of it, the narrowness of the home market does not
  • hinder the division of labour in any particular branch of art or
  • manufacture from being carried to the highest perfection. By opening a
  • more extensive market for whatever part of the produce of their labour may
  • exceed the home consumption, it encourages them to improve its productive
  • power, and to augment its annual produce to the utmost, and thereby to
  • increase the real revenue and wealth of the society. These great and
  • important services foreign trade is continually occupied in performing to
  • all the different countries between which it is carried on. They all
  • derive great benefit from it, though that in which the merchant resides
  • generally derives the greatest, as he is generally more employed in
  • supplying the wants, and carrying out the superfluities of his own, than
  • of any other particular country. To import the gold and silver which may
  • be wanted into the countries which have no mines, is, no doubt a part of
  • the business of foreign commerce. It is, however, a most insignificant
  • part of it. A country which carried on foreign trade merely upon this
  • account, could scarce have occasion to freight a ship in a century.
  • It is not by the importation of gold and silver that the discovery of
  • America has enriched Europe. By the abundance of the American mines, those
  • metals have become cheaper. A service of plate can now be purchased for
  • about a third part of the corn, or a third part of the labour, which it
  • would have cost in the fifteenth century. With the same annual expense of
  • labour and commodities, Europe can annually purchase about three times the
  • quantity of plate which it could have purchased at that time. But when a
  • commodity comes to be sold for a third part of what bad been its usual
  • price, not only those who purchased it before can purchase three times
  • their former quantity, but it is brought down to the level of a much
  • greater number of purchasers, perhaps to more than ten, perhaps to more
  • than twenty times the former number. So that there may be in Europe at
  • present, not only more than three times, but more than twenty or thirty
  • times the quantity of plate which would have been in it, even in its
  • present state of improvement, had the discovery of the American mines
  • never been made. So far Europe has, no doubt, gained a real conveniency,
  • though surely a very trifling one. The cheapness of gold and silver
  • renders those metals rather less fit for the purposes of money than they
  • were before. In order to make the same purchases, we must load ourselves
  • with a greater quantity of them, and carry about a shilling in our pocket,
  • where a groat would have done before. It is difficult to say which is most
  • trifling, this inconveniency, or the opposite conveniency. Neither the one
  • nor the other could have made any very essential change in the state of
  • Europe. The discovery of America, however, certainly made a most essential
  • one. By opening a new and inexhaustible market to all the commodities of
  • Europe, it gave occasion to new divisions of labour and improvements of
  • art, which in the narrow circle of the ancient commerce could never have
  • taken place, for want of a market to take off the greater part of their
  • produce. The productive powers of labour were improved, and its produce
  • increased in all the different countries of Europe, and together with it
  • the real revenue and wealth of the inhabitants. The commodities of Europe
  • were almost all new to America, and many of those of America were new to
  • Europe. A new set of exchanges, therefore, began to take place, which had
  • never been thought of before, and which should naturally have proved as
  • advantageous to the new, as it certainly did to the old continent. The
  • savage injustice of the Europeans rendered an event, which ought to have
  • been beneficial to all, ruinous and destructive to several of those
  • unfortunate countries.
  • The discovery of a passage to the East Indies by the Cape of Good Hope,
  • which happened much about the same time, opened perhaps a still more
  • extensive range to foreign commerce, than even that of America,
  • notwithstanding the greater distance. There were but two nations in
  • America, in any respect, superior to the savages, and these were destroyed
  • almost as soon as discovered. The rest were mere savages. But the empires
  • of China, Indostan, Japan, as well as several others in the East Indies,
  • without having richer mines of gold or silver, were, in every other
  • respect, much richer, better cultivated, and more advanced in all arts and
  • manufactures, than either Mexico or Peru, even though we should credit,
  • what plainly deserves no credit, the exaggerated accounts of the Spanish
  • writers concerning the ancient state of those empires. But rich and
  • civilized nations can always exchange to a much greater value with one
  • another, than with savages and barbarians. Europe, however, has hitherto
  • derived much less advantage from its commerce with the East Indies, than
  • from that with America. The Portuguese monopolized the East India trade to
  • themselves for about a century; and it was only indirectly, and through
  • them, that the other nations of Europe could either send out or receive
  • any goods from that country. When the Dutch, in the beginning of the last
  • century, began to encroach upon them, they vested their whole East India
  • commerce in an exclusive company. The English, French, Swedes, and Danes,
  • have all followed their example; so that no great nation of Europe has
  • ever yet had the benefit of a free commerce to the East Indies. No other
  • reason need be assigned why it has never been so advantageous as the trade
  • to America, which, between almost every nation of Europe and its own
  • colonies, is free to all its subjects. The exclusive privileges of those
  • East India companies, their great riches, the great favour and protection
  • which these have procured them from their respective governments, have
  • excited much envy against them. This envy has frequently represented their
  • trade as altogether pernicious, on account of the great quantities of
  • silver which it every year exports from the countries from which it is
  • carried on. The parties concerned have replied, that their trade by this
  • continual exportation of silver, might indeed tend to impoverish Europe in
  • general, but not the particular country from which it was carried on;
  • because, by the exportation of a part of the returns to other European
  • countries, it annually brought home a much greater quantity of that metal
  • than it carried out. Both the objection and the reply are founded in the
  • popular notion which I have been just now examining. It is therefore
  • unnecessary to say any thing further about either. By the annual
  • exportation of silver to the East Indies, plate is probably somewhat
  • dearer in Europe than it otherwise might have been; and coined silver
  • probably purchases a larger quantity both of labour and commodities. The
  • former of these two effects is a very small loss, the latter a very small
  • advantage; both too insignificant to deserve any part of the public
  • attention. The trade to the East Indies, by opening a market to the
  • commodities of Europe, or, what comes nearly to the same thing, to the
  • gold and silver which is purchased with those commodities, must
  • necessarily tend to increase the annual production of European
  • commodities, and consequently the real wealth and revenue of Europe. That
  • it has hitherto increased them so little, is probably owing to the
  • restraints which it everywhere labours under.
  • I thought it necessary, though at the hazard of being tedious, to examine
  • at full length this popular notion, that wealth consists in money or in
  • gold and silver. Money, in common language, as I have already observed,
  • frequently signifies wealth; and this ambiguity of expression has rendered
  • this popular notion so familiar to us, that even they who are convinced of
  • its absurdity, are very apt to forget their own principles, and, in the
  • course of their reasonings, to take it for granted as a certain and
  • undeniable truth. Some of the best English writers upon commerce set out
  • with observing, that the wealth of a country consists, not in its gold and
  • silver only, but in its lands, houses, and consumable goods of all
  • different kinds. In the course of their reasonings, however, the lands,
  • houses, and consumable goods, seem to slip out of their memory; and the
  • strain of their argument frequently supposes that all wealth consists in
  • gold and silver, and that to multiply those metals is the great object of
  • national industry and commerce.
  • The two principles being established, however, that wealth consisted in
  • gold and silver, and that those metals could be brought into a country
  • which had no mines, only by the balance of trade, or by exporting to a
  • greater value than it imported; it necessarily became the great object of
  • political economy to diminish as much as possible the importation of
  • foreign goods for home consumption, and to increase as much as possible
  • the exportation of the produce of domestic industry. Its two great engines
  • for enriching the country, therefore, were restraints upon importation,
  • and encouragement to exportation.
  • The restraints upon importation were of two kinds.
  • First, restraints upon the importation of such foreign goods for home
  • consumption as could be produced at home, from whatever country they were
  • imported.
  • Secondly, restraints upon the importation of goods of almost all kinds,
  • from those particular countries with which the balance of trade was
  • supposed to be disadvantageous.
  • Those different restraints consisted sometimes in high duties, and
  • sometimes in absolute prohibitions.
  • Exportation was encouraged sometimes by drawbacks, sometimes by bounties,
  • sometimes by advantageous treaties of commerce with foreign states, and
  • sometimes by the establishment of colonies in distant countries.
  • Drawbacks were given upon two different occasions. When the home
  • manufactures were subject to any duty or excise, either the whole or a
  • part of it was frequently drawn back upon their exportation; and when
  • foreign goods liable to a duty were imported, in order to be exported
  • again, either the whole or a part of this duty was sometimes given back
  • upon such exportation.
  • Bounties were given for the encouragement, either of some beginning
  • manufactures, or of such sorts of industry of other kinds as were supposed
  • to deserve particular favour.
  • By advantageous treaties of commerce, particular privileges were procured
  • in some foreign state for the goods and merchants of the country, beyond
  • what were granted to those of other countries.
  • By the establishment of colonies in distant countries, not only particular
  • privileges, but a monopoly was frequently procured for the goods and
  • merchants of the country which established them.
  • The two sorts of restraints upon importation above mentioned, together
  • with these four encouragements to exportation, constitute the six
  • principal means by which the commercial system proposes to increase the
  • quantity of gold and silver in any country, by turning the balance of
  • trade in its favour. I shall consider each of them in a particular
  • chapter, and, without taking much farther notice of their supposed
  • tendency to bring money into the country, I shall examine chiefly what are
  • likely to be the effects of each of them upon the annual produce of its
  • industry. According as they tend either to increase or diminish the value
  • of this annual produce, they must evidently tend either to increase or
  • diminish the real wealth and revenue of the country.
  • CHAPTER II.
  • OF RESTRAINTS UPON IMPORTATION FROM
  • FOREIGN COUNTRIES OF SUCH GOODS AS CAN BE PRODUCED AT HOME.
  • By restraining, either by high duties, or by absolute prohibitions, the
  • importation of such goods from foreign countries as can be produced at
  • home, the monopoly of the home market is more or less secured to the
  • domestic industry employed in producing them. Thus the prohibition of
  • importing either live cattle or salt provisions from foreign countries,
  • secures to the graziers of Great Britain the monopoly of the home market
  • for butcher’s meat. The high duties upon the importation of corn, which,
  • in times of moderate plenty, amount to a prohibition, give a like
  • advantage to the growers of that commodity. The prohibition of the
  • importation of foreign woollen is equally favourable to the woollen
  • manufacturers. The silk manufacture, though altogether employed upon
  • foreign materials, has lately obtained the same advantage. The linen
  • manufacture has not yet obtained it, but is making great strides towards
  • it. Many other sorts of manufactures have, in the same manner obtained in
  • Great Britain, either altogether, or very nearly, a monopoly against their
  • countrymen. The variety of goods, of which the importation into Great
  • Britain is prohibited, either absolutely, or under certain circumstances,
  • greatly exceeds what can easily be suspected by those who are not well
  • acquainted with the laws of the customs.
  • That this monopoly of the home market frequently gives great encouragement
  • to that particular species of industry which enjoys it, and frequently
  • turns towards that employment a greater share of both the labour and stock
  • of the society than would otherwise have gone to it, cannot be doubted.
  • But whether it tends either to increase the general industry of the
  • society, or to give it the most advantageous direction, is not, perhaps,
  • altogether so evident.
  • The general industry of the society can never exceed what the capital of
  • the society can employ. As the number of workmen that can be kept in
  • employment by any particular person must bear a certain proportion to his
  • capital, so the number of those that can be continually employed by all
  • the members of a great society must bear a certain proportion to the whole
  • capital of the society, and never can exceed that proportion. No
  • regulation of commerce can increase the quantity of industry in any
  • society beyond what its capital can maintain. It can only divert a part of
  • it into a direction into which it might not otherwise have gone; and it is
  • by no means certain that this artificial direction is likely to be more
  • advantageous to the society, than that into which it would have gone of
  • its own accord.
  • Every individual is continually exerting himself to find out the most
  • advantageous employment for whatever capital he can command. It is his own
  • advantage, indeed, and not that of the society, which he has in view. But
  • the study of his own advantage naturally, or rather necessarily, leads him
  • to prefer that employment which is most advantageous to the society.
  • First, every individual endeavours to employ his capital as near home as
  • he can, and consequently as much as he can in the support of domestic
  • industry, provided always that he can thereby obtain the ordinary, or not
  • a great deal less than the ordinary profits of stock.
  • Thus, upon equal, or nearly equal profits, every wholesale merchant
  • naturally prefers the home trade to the foreign trade of consumption, and
  • the foreign trade of consumption to the carrying trade. In the home trade,
  • his capital is never so long out of his sight as it frequently is in the
  • foreign trade of consumption. He can know better the character and
  • situation of the persons whom he trusts; and if he should happen to be
  • deceived, he knows better the laws of the country from which he must seek
  • redress. In the carrying trade, the capital of the merchant is, as it
  • were, divided between two foreign countries, and no part of it is ever
  • necessarily brought home, or placed under his own immediate view and
  • command. The capital which an Amsterdam merchant employs in carrying corn
  • from Koningsberg to Lisbon, and fruit and wine from Lisbon to Koningsberg,
  • must generally be the one half of it at Koningsberg, and the other half at
  • Lisbon. No part of it need ever come to Amsterdam. The natural residence
  • of such a merchant should either be at Koningsberg or Lisbon; and it can
  • only be some very particular circumstances which can make him prefer the
  • residence of Amsterdam. The uneasiness, however, which he feels at being
  • separated so far from his capital, generally determines him to bring part
  • both of the Koningsberg goods which he destines for the market of Lisbon,
  • and of the Lisbon goods which he destines for that of Koningsberg, to
  • Amsterdam; and though this necessarily subjects him to a double charge of
  • loading and unloading as well as to the payment of some duties and
  • customs, yet, for the sake of having some part of his capital always under
  • his own view and command, he willingly submits to this extraordinary
  • charge; and it is in this manner that every country which has any
  • considerable share of the carrying trade, becomes always the emporium, or
  • general market, for the goods of all the different countries whose trade
  • it carries on. The merchant, in order to save a second loading and
  • unloading, endeavours always to sell in the home market, as much of the
  • goods of all those different countries as he can; and thus, so far as he
  • can, to convert his carrying trade into a foreign trade of consumption. A
  • merchant, in the same manner, who is engaged in the foreign trade of
  • consumption, when he collects goods for foreign markets, will always be
  • glad, upon equal or nearly equal profits, to sell as great a part of them
  • at home as he can. He saves himself the risk and trouble of exportation,
  • when, so far as he can, he thus converts his foreign trade of consumption
  • into a home trade. Home is in this manner the centre, if I may say so,
  • round which the capitals of the inhabitants of every country are
  • continually circulating, and towards which they are always tending,
  • though, by particular causes, they may sometimes be driven off and
  • repelled from it towards more distant employments. But a capital employed
  • in the home trade, it has already been shown, necessarily puts into motion
  • a greater quantity of domestic industry, and gives revenue and employment
  • to a greater number of the inhabitants of the country, than an equal
  • capital employed in the foreign trade of consumption; and one employed in
  • the foreign trade of consumption has the same advantage over an equal
  • capital employed in the carrying trade. Upon equal, or only nearly equal
  • profits, therefore, every individual naturally inclines to employ his
  • capital in the manner in which it is likely to afford the greatest support
  • to domestic industry, and to give revenue and employment to the greatest
  • number of people of his own country.
  • Secondly, every individual who employs his capital in the support of
  • domestic industry, necessarily endeavours so to direct that industry, that
  • its produce may be of the greatest possible value.
  • The produce of industry is what it adds to the subject or materials upon
  • which it is employed. In proportion as the value of this produce is great
  • or small, so will likewise be the profits of the employer. But it is only
  • for the sake of profit that any man employs a capital in the support of
  • industry; and he will always, therefore, endeavour to employ it in the
  • support of that industry of which the produce is likely to be of the
  • greatest value, or to exchange for the greatest quantity either of money
  • or of other goods.
  • But the annual revenue of every society is always precisely equal to the
  • exchangeable value of the whole annual produce of its industry, or rather
  • is precisely the same thing with that exchangeable value. As every
  • individual, therefore, endeavours as much as he can, both to employ his
  • capital in the support of domestic industry, and so to direct that
  • industry that its produce maybe of the greatest value; every individual
  • necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great
  • as he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public
  • interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it. By preferring the support
  • of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security;
  • and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of
  • the greatest value, he intends only his own gain; and he is in this, as in
  • many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no
  • part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it
  • was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest, he frequently promotes
  • that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to
  • promote it. I have never known much good done by those who affected to
  • trade for the public good. It is an affectation, indeed, not very common
  • among merchants, and very few words need be employed in dissuading them
  • from it.
  • What is the species of domestic industry which his capital can employ, and
  • of which the produce is likely to be of the greatest value, every
  • individual, it is evident, can in his local situation judge much better
  • than any statesman or lawgiver can do for him. The statesman, who should
  • attempt to direct private people in what manner they ought to employ their
  • capitals, would not only load himself with a most unnecessary attention,
  • but assume an authority which could safely be trusted, not only to no
  • single person, but to no council or senate whatever, and which would
  • nowhere be so dangerous as in the hands of a man who had folly and
  • presumption enough to fancy himself fit to exercise it.
  • To give the monopoly of the home market to the produce of domestic
  • industry, in any particular art or manufacture, is in some measure to
  • direct private people in what manner they ought to employ their capitals,
  • and must in almost all cases be either a useless or a hurtful regulation.
  • If the produce of domestic can be brought there as cheap as that of
  • foreign industry, the regulation is evidently useless. If it cannot, it
  • must generally be hurtful. It is the maxim of every prudent master of a
  • family, never to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to
  • make than to buy. The tailor does not attempt to make his own shoes, but
  • buys them of the shoemaker. The shoemaker does not attempt to make his own
  • clothes, but employs a tailor. The farmer attempts to make neither the one
  • nor the other, but employs those different artificers. All of them find it
  • for their interest to employ their whole industry in a way in which they
  • have some advantage over their neighbours, and to purchase with a part of
  • its produce, or, what is the same thing, with the price of a part of it,
  • whatever else they have occasion for.
  • What is prudence in the conduct of every private family, can scarce be
  • folly in that of a great kingdom. If a foreign country can supply us with
  • a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it of them
  • with some part of the produce of our own industry, employed in a way in
  • which we have some advantage. The general industry of the country being
  • always in proportion to the capital which employs it, will not thereby be
  • diminished, no more than that of the abovementioned artificers; but only
  • left to find out the way in which it can be employed with the greatest
  • advantage. It is certainly not employed to the greatest advantage, when it
  • is thus directed towards an object which it can buy cheaper than it can
  • make. The value of its annual produce is certainly more or less
  • diminished, when it is thus turned away from producing commodities
  • evidently of more value than the commodity which it is directed to
  • produce. According to the supposition, that commodity could be purchased
  • from foreign countries cheaper than it can be made at home; it could
  • therefore have been purchased with a part only of the commodities, or,
  • what is the same thing, with a part only of the price of the commodities,
  • which the industry employed by an equal capital would have produced at
  • home, had it been left to follow its natural course. The industry of the
  • country, therefore, is thus turned away from a more to a less advantageous
  • employment; and the exchangeable value of its annual produce, instead of
  • being increased, according to the intention of the lawgiver, must
  • necessarily be diminished by every such regulation.
  • By means of such regulations, indeed, a particular manufacture may
  • sometimes be acquired sooner than it could have been otherwise, and after
  • a certain time may be made at home as cheap, or cheaper, than in the
  • foreign country. But though the industry of the society may be thus
  • carried with advantage into a particular channel sooner than it could have
  • been otherwise, it will by no means follow that the sum-total, either of
  • its industry, or of its revenue, can ever be augmented by any such
  • regulation. The industry of the society can augment only in proportion as
  • its capital augments, and its capital can augment only in proportion to
  • what can be gradually saved out of its revenue. But the immediate effect
  • of every such regulation is to diminish its revenue; and what diminishes
  • its revenue is certainly not very likely to augment its capital faster
  • than it would have augmented of its own accord, had both capital and
  • industry been left to find out their natural employments.
  • Though, for want of such regulations, the society should never acquire the
  • proposed manufacture, it would not upon that account necessarily be the
  • poorer in anyone period of its duration. In every period of its duration
  • its whole capital and industry might still have been employed, though upon
  • different objects, in the manner that was most advantageous at the time.
  • In every period its revenue might have been the greatest which its capital
  • could afford, and both capital and revenue might have been augmented with
  • the greatest possible rapidity.
  • The natural advantages which one country has over another, in producing
  • particular commodities, are sometimes so great, that it is acknowledged by
  • all the world to be in vain to struggle with them. By means of glasses,
  • hot-beds, and hot-walls, very good grapes can be raised in Scotland, and
  • very good wine, too, can be made of them, at about thirty times the
  • expense for which at least equally good can be brought from foreign
  • countries. Would it be a reasonable law to prohibit the importation of all
  • foreign wines, merely to encourage the making of claret and Burgundy in
  • Scotland? But if there would be a manifest absurdity in turning towards
  • any employment thirty times more of the capital and industry of the
  • country than would be necessary to purchase from foreign countries an
  • equal quantity of the commodities wanted, there must be an absurdity,
  • though not altogether so glaring, yet exactly of the same kind, in turning
  • towards any such employment a thirtieth, or even a three hundredth part
  • more of either. Whether the advantages which one country has over another
  • be natural or acquired, is in this respect of no consequence. As long as
  • the one country has those advantages, and the other wants them, it will
  • always be more advantageous for the latter rather to buy of the former
  • than to make. It is an acquired advantage only, which one artificer has
  • over his neighbour, who exercises another trade; and yet they both find it
  • more advantageous to buy of one another, than to make what does not belong
  • to their particular trades.
  • Merchants and manufacturers are the people who derive the greatest
  • advantage from this monopoly of the home market. The prohibition of the
  • importation of foreign cattle and of salt provisions, together with the
  • high duties upon foreign corn, which in times of moderate plenty amount to
  • a prohibition, are not near so advantageous to the graziers and farmers of
  • Great Britain, as other regulations of the same kind are to its merchants
  • and manufacturers. Manufactures, those of the finer kind especially, are
  • more easily transported from one country to another than corn or cattle.
  • It is in the fetching and carrying manufactures, accordingly, that foreign
  • trade is chiefly employed. In manufactures, a very small advantage will
  • enable foreigners to undersell our own workmen, even in the home market.
  • It will require a very great one to enable them to do so in the rude
  • produce of the soil. If the free importation of foreign manufactures were
  • permitted, several of the home manufactures would probably suffer, and
  • some of them perhaps go to ruin altogether, and a considerable part of the
  • stock and industry at present employed in them, would be forced to find
  • out some other employment. But the freest importation of the rude produce
  • of the soil could have no such effect upon the agriculture of the country.
  • If the importation of foreign cattle, for example, were made ever so free,
  • so few could be imported, that the grazing trade of Great Britain could be
  • little affected by it. Live cattle are, perhaps, the only commodity of
  • which the transportation is more expensive by sea than by land. By land
  • they carry themselves to market. By sea, not only the cattle, but their
  • food and their water too, must be carried at no small expense and
  • inconveniency. The short sea between Ireland and Great Britain, indeed,
  • renders the importation of Irish cattle more easy. But though the free
  • importation of them, which was lately permitted only for a limited time,
  • were rendered perpetual, it could have no considerable effect upon the
  • interest of the graziers of Great Britain. Those parts of Great Britain
  • which border upon the Irish sea are all grazing countries. Irish cattle
  • could never be imported for their use, but must be drove through those
  • very extensive countries, at no small expense and inconveniency, before
  • they could arrive at their proper market. Fat cattle could not be drove so
  • far. Lean cattle, therefore, could only be imported; and such importation
  • could interfere not with the interest of the feeding or fattening
  • countries, to which, by reducing the price of lean cattle it would rather
  • be advantageous, but with that of the breeding countries only. The small
  • number of Irish cattle imported since their importation was permitted,
  • together with the good price at which lean cattle still continue to sell,
  • seem to demonstrate, that even the breeding countries of Great Britain are
  • never likely to be much affected by the free importation of Irish cattle.
  • The common people of Ireland, indeed, are said to have sometimes opposed
  • with violence the exportation of their cattle. But if the exporters had
  • found any great advantage in continuing the trade, they could easily, when
  • the law was on their side, have conquered this mobbish opposition.
  • Feeding and fattening countries, besides, must always be highly improved,
  • whereas breeding countries are generally uncultivated. The high price of
  • lean cattle, by augmenting the value of uncultivated land, is like a
  • bounty against improvement. To any country which was highly improved
  • throughout, it would be more advantageous to import its lean cattle than
  • to breed them. The province of Holland, accordingly, is said to follow
  • this maxim at present. The mountains of Scotland, Wales, and
  • Northumberland, indeed, are countries not capable of much improvement, and
  • seem destined by nature to be the breeding countries of Great Britain. The
  • freest importation of foreign cattle could have no other effect than to
  • hinder those breeding countries from taking advantage of the increasing
  • population and improvement of the rest of the kingdom, from raising their
  • price to an exorbitant height, and from laying a real tax upon all the
  • more improved and cultivated parts of the country.
  • The freest importation of salt provisions, in the same manner, could have
  • as little effect upon the interest of the graziers of Great Britain as
  • that of live cattle. Salt provisions are not only a very bulky commodity,
  • but when compared with fresh meat they are a commodity both of worse
  • quality, and, as they cost more labour and expense, of higher price. They
  • could never, therefore, come into competition with the fresh meat, though
  • they might with the salt provisions of the country. They might be used for
  • victualling ships for distant voyages, and such like uses, but could never
  • make any considerable part of the food of the people. The small quantity
  • of salt provisions imported from Ireland since their importation was
  • rendered free, is an experimental proof that our graziers have nothing to
  • apprehend from it. It does not appear that the price of butcher’s meat has
  • ever been sensibly affected by it.
  • Even the free importation of foreign corn could very little affect the
  • interest of the farmers of Great Britain. Corn is a much more bulky
  • commodity than butcher’s meat. A pound of wheat at a penny is as dear as a
  • pound of butcher’s meat at fourpence. The small quantity of foreign corn
  • imported even in times of the greatest scarcity, may satisfy our farmers
  • that they can have nothing to fear from the freest importation. The
  • average quantity imported, one year with another, amounts only, according
  • to the very well informed author of the Tracts upon the Corn Trade, to
  • 23,728 quarters of all sorts of grain, and does not exceed the five
  • hundredth and seventy-one part of the annual consumption. But as the
  • bounty upon corn occasions a greater exportation in years of plenty, so it
  • must, of consequence, occasion a greater importation in years of scarcity,
  • than in the actual state of tillage would otherwise take place. By means
  • of it, the plenty of one year does not compensate the scarcity of another;
  • and as the average quantity exported is necessarily augmented by it, so
  • must likewise, in the actual state of tillage, the average quantity
  • imported. If there were no bounty, as less corn would be exported, suit is
  • probable that, one year with another, less would be imported than at
  • present. The corn-merchants, the fetchers and carriers of corn between
  • Great Britain and foreign countries, would have much less employment, and
  • might suffer considerably; but the country gentlemen and farmers could
  • suffer very little. It is in the corn-merchants, accordingly, rather than
  • the country gentlemen and farmers, that I have observed the greatest
  • anxiety for the renewal and continuation of the bounty.
  • Country gentlemen and farmers are, to their great honour, of all people,
  • the least subject to the wretched spirit of monopoly. The undertaker of a
  • great manufactory is sometimes alarmed if another work of the same kind is
  • established within twenty miles of him; the Dutch undertaker of the
  • woollen manufacture at Abbeville, stipulated that no work of the same kind
  • should be established within thirty leagues of that city. Farmers and
  • country gentlemen, on the contrary, are generally disposed rather to
  • promote, than to obstruct, the cultivation and improvement of their
  • neighbours farms and estates. They have no secrets, such as those of the
  • greater part of manufacturers, but are generally rather fond of
  • communicating to their neighbours, and of extending as far as possible any
  • new practice which they may have found to be advantageous. “Pius
  • quaestus”, says old Cato, “stabilissimusque, minimeque invidiosus;
  • minimeque male cogitantes sunt, qui in eo studio occupati sunt.” Country
  • gentlemen and farmers, dispersed in different parts of the country, cannot
  • so easily combine as merchants and manufacturers, who being collected into
  • towns, and accustomed to that exclusive corporation spirit which prevails
  • in them, naturally endeavour to obtain, against all their countrymen, the
  • same exclusive privilege which they generally possess against the
  • inhabitants of their respective towns. They accordingly seem to have been
  • the original inventors of those restraints upon the importation of foreign
  • goods, which secure to them the monopoly of the home market. It was
  • probably in imitation of them, and to put themselves upon a level with
  • those who, they found, were disposed to oppress them, that the country
  • gentlemen and farmers of Great Britain so far forgot the generosity which
  • is natural to their station, as to demand the exclusive privilege of
  • supplying their countrymen with corn and butcher’s meat. They did not,
  • perhaps, take time to consider how much less their interest could be
  • affected by the freedom of trade, than that of the people whose example
  • they followed.
  • To prohibit, by a perpetual law, the importation of foreign corn and
  • cattle, is in reality to enact, that the population and industry of the
  • country shall, at no time, exceed what the rude produce of its own soil
  • can maintain.
  • There seem, however, to be two cases, in which it will generally be
  • advantageous to lay some burden upon foreign, for the encouragement of
  • domestic industry.
  • The first is, when some particular sort of industry is necessary for the
  • defence of the country. The defence of Great Britain, for example, depends
  • very much upon the number of its sailors and shipping. The act of
  • navigation, therefore, very properly endeavours to give the sailors and
  • shipping of Great Britain the monopoly of the trade of their own country,
  • in some cases, by absolute prohibitions, and in others, by heavy burdens
  • upon the shipping of foreign countries. The following are the principal
  • dispositions of this act.
  • First, All ships, of which the owners, masters, and three-fourths of the
  • mariners, are not British subjects, are prohibited, upon pain of
  • forfeiting ship and cargo, from trading to the British settlements and
  • plantations, or from being employed in the coasting trade of Great
  • Britain.
  • Secondly, A great variety of the most bulky articles of importation can be
  • brought into Great Britain only, either in such ships as are above
  • described, or in ships of the country where those goods are produced, and
  • of which the owners, masters, and three-fourths of the mariners, are of
  • that particular country; and when imported even in ships of this latter
  • kind, they are subject to double aliens duty. If imported in ships of any
  • other country, the penalty is forfeiture of ship and goods. When this act
  • was made, the Dutch were, what they still are, the great carriers of
  • Europe; and by this regulation they were entirely excluded from being the
  • carriers to Great Britain, or from importing to us the goods of any other
  • European country.
  • Thirdly, A great variety of the most bulky articles of importation are
  • prohibited from being imported, even in British ships, from any country
  • but that in which they are produced, under pain of forfeiting ship and
  • cargo. This regulation, too, was probably intended against the Dutch.
  • Holland was then, as now, the great emporium for all European goods; and
  • by this regulation, British ships were hindered from loading in Holland
  • the goods of any other European country.
  • Fourthly, Salt fish of all kinds, whale fins, whalebone, oil, and blubber,
  • not caught by and cured on board British vessels, when imported into Great
  • Britain, are subject to double aliens duty. The Dutch, as they are still
  • the principal, were then the only fishers in Europe that attempted to
  • supply foreign nations with fish. By this regulation, a very heavy burden
  • was laid upon their supplying Great Britain.
  • When the act of navigation was made, though England and Holland were not
  • actually at war, the most violent animosity subsisted between the two
  • nations. It had begun during the government of the long parliament, which
  • first framed this act, and it broke out soon after in the Dutch wars,
  • during that of the Protector and of Charles II. It is not impossible,
  • therefore, that some of the regulations of this famous act may have
  • proceeded from national animosity. They are as wise, however, as if they
  • had all been dictated by the most deliberate wisdom. National animosity,
  • at that particular time, aimed at the very same object which the most
  • deliberate wisdom would have recommended, the diminution of the naval
  • power of Holland, the only naval power which could endanger the security
  • of England.
  • The act of navigation is not favourable to foreign commerce, or to the
  • growth of that opulence which can arise from it. The interest of a nation,
  • in its commercial relations to foreign nations, is, like that of a
  • merchant with regard to the different people with whom he deals, to buy as
  • cheap, and to sell as dear as possible. But it will be most likely to buy
  • cheap, when, by the most perfect freedom of trade, it encourages all
  • nations to bring to it the goods which it has occasion to purchase; and,
  • for the same reason, it will be most likely to sell dear, when its markets
  • are thus filled with the greatest number of buyers. The act of navigation,
  • it is true, lays no burden upon foreign ships that come to export the
  • produce of British industry. Even the ancient aliens duty, which used to
  • be paid upon all goods, exported as well as imported, has, by several
  • subsequent acts, been taken off from the greater part of the articles of
  • exportation. But if foreigners, either by prohibitions or high duties, are
  • hindered from coming to sell, they cannot always afford to come to buy;
  • because, coming without a cargo, they must lose the freight from their own
  • country to Great Britain. By diminishing the number of sellers, therefore,
  • we necessarily diminish that of buyers, and are thus likely not only to
  • buy foreign goods dearer, but to sell our own cheaper, than if there was a
  • more perfect freedom of trade. As defence, however, is of much more
  • importance than opulence, the act of navigation is, perhaps, the wisest of
  • all the commercial regulations of England.
  • The second case, in which it will generally be advantageous to lay some
  • burden upon foreign for the encouragement of domestic industry, is when
  • some tax is imposed at home upon the produce of the latter. In this case,
  • it seems reasonable that an equal tax should be imposed upon the like
  • produce of the former. This would not give the monopoly of the borne
  • market to domestic industry, nor turn towards a particular employment a
  • greater share of the stock and labour of the country, than what would
  • naturally go to it. It would only hinder any part of what would naturally
  • go to it from being turned away by the tax into a less natural direction,
  • and would leave the competition between foreign and domestic industry,
  • after the tax, as nearly as possible upon the same footing as before it.
  • In Great Britain, when any such tax is laid upon the produce of domestic
  • industry, it is usual, at the same time, in order to stop the clamorous
  • complaints of our merchants and manufacturers, that they will be undersold
  • at home, to lay a much heavier duty upon the importation of all foreign
  • goods of the same kind.
  • This second limitation of the freedom of trade, according to some people,
  • should, upon most occasions, be extended much farther than to the precise
  • foreign commodities which could come into competition with those which had
  • been taxed at home. When the necessaries of life have been taxed in any
  • country, it becomes proper, they pretend, to tax not only the like
  • necessaries of life imported from other countries, but all sorts of
  • foreign goods which can come into competition with any thing that is the
  • produce of domestic industry. Subsistence, they say, becomes necessarily
  • dearer in consequence of such taxes; and the price of labour must always
  • rise with the price of the labourer’s subsistence. Every commodity,
  • therefore, which is the produce of domestic industry, though not
  • immediately taxed itself, becomes dearer in consequence of such taxes,
  • because the labour which produces it becomes so. Such taxes, therefore,
  • are really equivalent, they say, to a tax upon every particular commodity
  • produced at home. In order to put domestic upon the same footing with
  • foreign industry, therefore, it becomes necessary, they think, to lay some
  • duty upon every foreign commodity, equal to this enhancement of the price
  • of the home commodities with which it can come into competition.
  • Whether taxes upon the necessaries of life, such as those in Great Britain
  • upon soap, salt, leather, candles, etc. necessarily raise the price of
  • labour, and consequently that of all other commodities, I shall consider
  • hereafter, when I come to treat of taxes. Supposing, however, in the mean
  • time, that they have this effect, and they have it undoubtedly, this
  • general enhancement of the price of all commodities, in consequence of
  • that labour, is a case which differs in the two following respects from
  • that of a particular commodity, of which the price was enhanced by a
  • particular tax immediately imposed upon it.
  • First, It might always be known with great exactness, how far the price of
  • such a commodity could be enhanced by such a tax; but how far the general
  • enhancement of the price of labour might affect that of every different
  • commodity about which labour was employed, could never be known with any
  • tolerable exactness. It would be impossible, therefore, to proportion,
  • with any tolerable exactness, the tax of every foreign, to the enhancement
  • of the price of every home commodity.
  • Secondly, Taxes upon the necessaries of life have nearly the same effect
  • upon the circumstances of the people as a poor soil and a bad climate.
  • Provisions are thereby rendered dearer, in the same manner as if it
  • required extraordinary labour and expense to raise them. As, in the
  • natural scarcity arising from soil and climate, it would be absurd to
  • direct the people in what manner they ought to employ their capitals and
  • industry, so is it likewise in the artificial scarcity arising from such
  • taxes. To be left to accommodate, as well as they could, their industry to
  • their situation, and to find out those employments in which,
  • notwithstanding their unfavourable circumstances, they might have some
  • advantage either in the home or in the foreign market, is what, in both
  • cases, would evidently be most for their advantage. To lay a new-tax upon
  • them, because they are already overburdened with taxes, and because they
  • already pay too dear for the necessaries of life, to make them likewise
  • pay too dear for the greater part of other commodities, is certainly a
  • most absurd way of making amends.
  • Such taxes, when they have grown up to a certain height, are a curse equal
  • to the barrenness of the earth, and the inclemency of the heavens, and yet
  • it is in the richest and most industrious countries that they have been
  • most generally imposed. No other countries could support so great a
  • disorder. As the strongest bodies only can live and enjoy health under an
  • unwholesome regimen, so the nations only, that in every sort of industry
  • have the greatest natural and acquired advantages, can subsist and prosper
  • under such taxes. Holland is the country in Europe in which they abound
  • most, and which, from peculiar circumstances, continues to prosper, not by
  • means of them, as has been most absurdly supposed, but in spite of them.
  • As there are two cases in which it will generally be advantageous to lay
  • some burden upon foreign for the encouragement of domestic industry, so
  • there are two others in which it may sometimes be a matter of
  • deliberation, in the one, how far it is proper to continue the free
  • importation of certain foreign goods; and, in the other, how far, or in
  • what manner, it may be proper to restore that free importation, after it
  • has been for some time interrupted.
  • The case in which it may sometimes be a matter of deliberation how far it
  • is proper to continue the free importation of certain foreign goods, is
  • when some foreign nation restrains, by high duties or prohibitions, the
  • importation of some of our manufactures into their country. Revenge, in
  • this case, naturally dictates retaliation, and that we should impose the
  • like duties and prohibitions upon the importation of some or all of their
  • manufactures into ours. Nations, accordingly, seldom fail to retaliate in
  • this manner. The French have been particularly forward to favour their own
  • manufactures, by restraining the importation of such foreign goods as
  • could come into competition with them. In this consisted a great part of
  • the policy of Mr Colbert, who, notwithstanding his great abilities, seems
  • in this case to have been imposed upon by the sophistry of merchants and
  • manufacturers, who are always demanding a monopoly against their
  • countrymen. It is at present the opinion of the most intelligent men in
  • France, that his operations of this kind have not been beneficial to his
  • country. That minister, by the tariff of 1667, imposed very high duties
  • upon a great number of foreign manufactures. Upon his refusing to moderate
  • them in favour of the Dutch, they, in 1671, prohibited the importation of
  • the wines, brandies, and manufactures of France. The war of 1672 seems to
  • have been in part occasioned by this commercial dispute. The peace of
  • Nimeguen put an end to it in 1678, by moderating some of those duties in
  • favour of the Dutch, who in consequence took off their prohibition. It was
  • about the same time that the French and English began mutually to oppress
  • each other’s industry, by the like duties and prohibitions, of which the
  • French, however, seem to have set the first example, The spirit of
  • hostility which has subsisted between the two nations ever since, has
  • hitherto hindered them from being moderated on either side. In 1697, the
  • Ehglish prohibited the importation of bone lace, the manufacture of
  • Flanders. The government of that country, at that time under the dominion
  • of Spain, prohibited, in return, the importation of English woollens. In
  • 1700, the prohibition of importing bone lace into England was taken oft;
  • upon condition that the importation of English woollens into Flanders
  • should be put on the same footing as before.
  • There may be good policy in retaliations of this kind, when there is a
  • probability that they will procure the repeal of the high duties or
  • prohibitions complained of. The recovery of a great foreign market will
  • generally more than compensate the transitory inconveniency of paying
  • dearer during a short time for some sorts of goods. To judge whether such
  • retaliations are likely to produce such an effect, does not, perhaps,
  • belong so much to the science of a legislator, whose deliberations ought
  • to be governed by general principles, which are always the same, as to the
  • skill of that insidious and crafty animal vulgarly called a statesman or
  • politician, whose councils are directed by the momentary fluctuations of
  • affairs. When there is no probability that any such repeal can be
  • procured, it seems a bad method of compensating the injury done to certain
  • classes of our people, to do another injury ourselves, not only to those
  • classes, but to almost all the other classes of them. When our neighbours
  • prohibit some manufacture of ours, we generally prohibit, not only the
  • same, for that alone would seldom affect them considerably, but some other
  • manufacture of theirs. This may, no doubt, give encouragement to some
  • particular class of workmen among ourselves, and, by excluding some of
  • their rivals, may enable them to raise their price in the home market.
  • Those workmen however, who suffered by our neighbours prohibition, will
  • not be benefited by ours. On the contrary, they, and almost all the other
  • classes of our citizens, will thereby be obliged to pay dearer than before
  • for certain goods. Every such law, therefore, imposes a real tax upon the
  • whole country, not in favour of that particular class of workmen who were
  • injured by our neighbours prohibitions, but of some other class.
  • The case in which it may sometimes be a matter of deliberation, how far,
  • or in what manner, it is proper to restore the free importation of foreign
  • goods, after it has been for some time interrupted, is when particular
  • manufactures, by means of high duties or prohibitions upon all foreign
  • goods which can come into competition with them, have been so far extended
  • as to employ a great multitude of hands. Humanity may in this case require
  • that the freedom of trade should be restored only by slow gradations, and
  • with a good deal of reserve and circumspection. Were those high duties and
  • prohibitions taken away all at once, cheaper foreign goods of the same
  • kind might be poured so fast into the home market, as to deprive all at
  • once many thousands of our people of their ordinary employment and means
  • of subsistence. The disorder which this would occasion might no doubt be
  • very considerable. It would in all probability, however, be much less than
  • is commonly imagined, for the two following reasons.
  • First, All those manufactures of which any part is commonly exported to
  • other European countries without a bounty, could be very little affected
  • by the freest importation of foreign goods. Such manufactures must be sold
  • as cheap abroad as any other foreign goods of the same quality and kind,
  • and consequently must be sold cheaper at home. They would still,
  • therefore, keep possession of the home market; and though a capricious man
  • of fashion might sometimes prefer foreign wares, merely because they were
  • foreign, to cheaper and better goods of the same kind that were made at
  • home, this folly could, from the nature of things, extend to so few, that
  • it could make no sensible impression upon the general employment of the
  • people. But a great part of all the different branches of our woollen
  • manufacture, of our tanned leather, and of our hardware, are annually
  • exported to other European countries without any bounty, and these are the
  • manufactures which employ the greatest number of hands. The silk, perhaps,
  • is the manufacture which would suffer the most by this freedom of trade,
  • and after it the linen, though the latter much less than the former.
  • Secondly, Though a great number of people should, by thus restoring the
  • freedom of trade, be thrown all at once out of their ordinary employment
  • and common method of subsistence, it would by no means follow that they
  • would thereby be deprived either of employment or subsistence. By the
  • reduction of the army and navy at the end of the late war, more than
  • 100,000 soldiers and seamen, a number equal to what is employed in the
  • greatest manufactures, were all at once thrown out of their ordinary
  • employment: but though they no doubt suffered some inconveniency, they
  • were not thereby deprived of all employment and subsistence. The greater
  • part of the seamen, it is probable, gradually betook themselves to the
  • merchant service as they could find occasion, and in the mean time both
  • they and the soldiers were absorbed in the great mass of the people, and
  • employed in a great variety of occupations. Not only no great convulsion,
  • but no sensible disorder, arose from so great a change in the situation of
  • more than 100,000 men, all accustomed to the use of arms, and many of them
  • to rapine and plunder. The number of vagrants was scarce anywhere sensibly
  • increased by it; even the wages of labour were not reduced by it in any
  • occupation, so far as I have been able to learn, except in that of seamen
  • in the merchant service. But if we compare together the habits of a
  • soldier and of any sort of manufacturer, we shall find that those of the
  • latter do not tend so much to disqualify him from being employed in a new
  • trade, as those of the former from being employed in any. The manufacturer
  • has always been accustomed to look for his subsistence from his labour
  • only; the soldier to expect it from his pay. Application and industry have
  • been familiar to the one; idleness and dissipation to the other. But it is
  • surely much easier to change the direction of industry from one sort of
  • labour to another, than to turn idleness and dissipation to any. To the
  • greater part of manufactures, besides, it has already been observed, there
  • are other collateral manufactures of so similar a nature, that a workman
  • can easily transfer his industry from one of them to another. The greater
  • part of such workmen, too, are occasionally employed in country labour.
  • The stock which employed them in a particular manufacture before, will
  • still remain in the country, to employ an equal number of people in some
  • other way. The capital of the country remaining the same, the demand for
  • labour will likewise be the same, or very nearly the same, though it may
  • be exerted in different places, and for different occupations. Soldiers
  • and seamen, indeed, when discharged from the king’s service, are at
  • liberty to exercise any trade within any town or place of Great Britain or
  • Ireland. Let the same natural liberty of exercising what species of
  • industry they please, be restored to all his Majesty’s subjects, in the
  • same manner as to soldiers and seamen; that is, break down the exclusive
  • privileges of corporations, and repeal the statute of apprenticeship, both
  • which are really encroachments upon natural Liberty, and add to those the
  • repeal of the law of settlements, so that a poor workman, when thrown out
  • of employment, either in one trade or in one place, may seek for it in
  • another trade or in another place, without the fear either of a
  • prosecution or of a removal; and neither the public nor the individuals
  • will suffer much more from the occasional disbanding some particular
  • classes of manufacturers, than from that of the soldiers. Our
  • manufacturers have no doubt great merit with their country, but they
  • cannot have more than those who defend it with their blood, nor deserve to
  • be treated with more delicacy.
  • To expect, indeed, that the freedom of trade should ever be entirely
  • restored in Great Britain, is as absurd as to expect that an Oceana or
  • Utopia should ever be established in it. Not only the prejudices of the
  • public, but, what is much more unconquerable, the private interests of
  • many individuals, irresistibly oppose it. Were the officers of the army to
  • oppose, with the same zeal and unanimity, any reduction in the number of
  • forces, with which master manufacturers set themselves against every law
  • that is likely to increase the number of their rivals in the home market;
  • were the former to animate their soldiers. In the same manner as the
  • latter inflame their workmen, to attack with violence and outrage the
  • proposers of any such regulation; to attempt to reduce the army would be
  • as dangerous as it has now become to attempt to diminish, in any respect,
  • the monopoly which our manufacturers have obtained against us. This
  • monopoly has so much increased the number of some particular tribes of
  • them, that, like an overgrown standing army, they have become formidable
  • to the government, and, upon many occasions, intimidate the legislature.
  • The member of parliament who supports every proposal for strengthening
  • this monopoly, is sure to acquire not only the reputation of understanding
  • trade, but great popularity and influence with an order of men whose
  • numbers and wealth render them of great importance. If he opposes them, on
  • the contrary, and still more, if he has authority enough to be able to
  • thwart them, neither the most acknowledged probity, nor the highest rank,
  • nor the greatest public services, can protect him from the most infamous
  • abuse and detraction, from personal insults, nor sometimes from real
  • danger, arising from the insolent outrage of furious and disappointed
  • monopolists.
  • The undertaker of a great manufacture, who, by the home markets being
  • suddenly laid open to the competition of foreigners, should be obliged to
  • abandon his trade, would no doubt suffer very considerably. That part of
  • his capital which had usually been employed in purchasing materials, and
  • in paying his workmen, might, without much difficulty, perhaps, find
  • another employment; but that part of it which was fixed in workhouses, and
  • in the instruments of trade, could scarce be disposed of without
  • considerable loss. The equitable regard, therefore, to his interest,
  • requires that changes of this kind should never be introduced suddenly,
  • but slowly, gradually, and after a very long warning. The legislature,
  • were it possible that its deliberations could be always directed, not by
  • the clamorous importunity of partial interests, but by an extensive view
  • of the general good, ought, upon this very account, perhaps, to be
  • particularly careful, neither to establish any new monopolies of this
  • kind, nor to extend further those which are already established. Every
  • such regulation introduces some degree of real disorder into the
  • constitution of the state, which it will be difficult afterwards to cure
  • without occasioning another disorder.
  • How far it may be proper to impose taxes upon the importation of foreign
  • goods, in order not to prevent their importation, but to raise a revenue
  • for government, I shall consider hereafter when I come to treat of taxes.
  • Taxes imposed with a view to prevent, or even to diminish importation, are
  • evidently as destructive of the revenue of the customs as of the freedom
  • of trade.
  • CHAPTER III.
  • OF THE EXTRAORDINARY RESTRAINTS UPON
  • THE IMPORTATION OF GOODS OF ALMOST ALL KINDS, FROM THOSE COUNTRIES WITH WHICH
  • THE BALANCE IS SUPPOSED TO BE DISADVANTAGEOUS.
  • Part I—Of the Unreasonableness of those Restraints, even upon the
  • Principles of the Commercial System.
  • To lay extraordinary restraints upon the importation of goods of almost
  • all kinds, from those particular countries with which the balance of trade
  • is supposed to be disadvantageous, is the second expedient by which the
  • commercial system proposes to increase the quantity of gold and silver.
  • Thus, in Great Britain, Silesia lawns may be imported for home
  • consumption, upon paying certain duties; but French cambrics and lawns are
  • prohibited to be imported, except into the port of London, there to be
  • warehoused for exportation. Higher duties are imposed upon the wines of
  • France than upon those of Portugal, or indeed of any other country. By
  • what is called the impost 1692, a duty of five and-twenty per cent. of the
  • rate or value, was laid upon all French goods; while the goods of other
  • nations were, the greater part of them, subjected to much lighter duties,
  • seldom exceeding five per cent. The wine, brandy, salt, and vinegar of
  • France, were indeed excepted; these commodities being subjected to other
  • heavy duties, either by other laws, or by particular clauses of the same
  • law. In 1696, a second duty of twenty-five per cent. the first not having
  • been thought a sufficient discouragement, was imposed upon all French
  • goods, except brandy; together with a new duty of five-and-twenty pounds
  • upon the ton of French wine, and another of fifteen pounds upon the ton of
  • French vinegar. French goods have never been omitted in any of those
  • general subsidies or duties of five per cent. which have been imposed upon
  • all, or the greater part, of the goods enumerated in the book of rates. If
  • we count the one-third and two-third subsidies as making a complete
  • subsidy between them, there have been five of these general subsidies; so
  • that, before the commencement of the present war, seventy-five per cent.
  • may be considered as the lowest duty to which the greater part of the
  • goods of the growth, produce, or manufacture of France, were liable. But
  • upon the greater part of goods, those duties are equivalent to a
  • prohibition. The French, in their turn, have, I believe, treated our goods
  • and manufactures just as hardly; though I am not so well acquainted with
  • the particular hardships which they have imposed upon them. Those mutual
  • restraints have put an end to almost all fair commerce between the two
  • nations; and smugglers are now the principal importers, either of British
  • goods into France, or of French goods into Great Britain. The principles
  • which I have been examining, in the foregoing chapter, took their origin
  • from private interest and the spirit of monopoly; those which I am going
  • te examine in this, from national prejudice and animosity. They are,
  • accordingly, as might well be expected, still more unreasonable. They are
  • so, even upon the principles of the commercial system.
  • First, Though it were certain that in the case of a free trade between
  • France and England, for example, the balance would be in favour of France,
  • it would by no means follow that such a trade would be disadvantageous to
  • England, or that the general balance of its whole trade would thereby be
  • turned more against it. If the wines of France are better and cheaper than
  • those of Portugal, or its linens than those of Germany, it would be more
  • advantageous for Great Britain to purchase both the wine and the foreign
  • linen which it had occasion for of France, than of Portugal and Germany.
  • Though the value of the annual importations from France would thereby be
  • greatly augmented, the value of the whole annual importations would be
  • diminished, in proportion as the French goods of the same quality were
  • cheaper than those of the other two countries. This would be the case,
  • even upon the supposition that the whole French goods imported were to be
  • consumed in Great Britain.
  • But, Secondly, A great part of them might be re-exported to other
  • countries, where, being sold with profit, they might bring back a return,
  • equal in value, perhaps, to the prime cost of the whole French goods
  • imported. What has frequently been said of the East India trade, might
  • possibly be true of the French; that though the greater part of East India
  • goods were bought with gold and silver, the re-exportation of a part of
  • them to other countries brought back more gold and silver to that which
  • carried on the trade, than the prime cost of the whole amounted to. One of
  • the most important branches of the Dutch trade at present, consists in the
  • carriage of French goods to other European countries. Some part even of
  • the French wine drank in Great Britain, is clandestinely imported from
  • Holland and Zealand. If there was either a free trade between France and
  • England, or if French goods could be imported upon paying only the same
  • duties as those of other European nations, to be drawn back upon
  • exportation, England might have some share of a trade which is found so
  • advantageous to Holland.
  • Thirdly, and lastly, There is no certain criterion by which we can
  • determine on which side what is called the balance between any two
  • countries lies, or which of them exports to the greatest value. National
  • prejudice and animosity, prompted always by the private interest of
  • particular traders, are the principles which generally direct our judgment
  • upon all questions concerning it. There are two criterions, however, which
  • have frequently been appealed to upon such occasions, the custom-house
  • books and the course of exchange. The custom-house books, I think, it is
  • now generally acknowledged, are a very uncertain criterion, on account of
  • the inaccuracy of the valuation at which the greater part of goods are
  • rated in them. The course of exchange is, perhaps, almost equally so.
  • When the exchange between two places, such as London and Paris, is at par,
  • it is said to be a sign that the debts due from London to Paris are
  • compensated by those due from Paris to London. On the contrary, when a
  • premium is paid at London for a bill upon Paris, it is said to be a sign
  • that the debts due from London to Paris are not compensated by those due
  • from Paris to London, but that a balance in money must be sent out from
  • the latter place; for the risk, trouble, and expense, of exporting which,
  • the premium is both demanded and given. But the ordinary state of debt and
  • credit between those two cities must necessarily be regulated, it is said,
  • by the ordinary course of their dealings with one another. When neither of
  • them imports from from other to a greater amount than it exports to that
  • other, the debts and credits of each may compensate one another. But when
  • one of them imports from the other to a greater value than it exports to
  • that other, the former necessarily becomes indebted to the latter in a
  • greater sum than the latter becomes indebted to it: the debts and credits
  • of each do not compensate one another, and money must be sent out from
  • that place of which the debts overbalance the credits. The ordinary course
  • of exchange, therefore, being an indication of the ordinary state of debt
  • and credit between two places, must likewise be an indication of the
  • ordinary course of their exports and imports, as these necessarily
  • regulate that state.
  • But though the ordinary course of exchange shall be allowed to be a
  • sufficient indication of the ordinary state of debt and credit between any
  • two places, it would not from thence follow, that the balance of trade was
  • in favour of that place which had the ordinary state of debt and credit in
  • its favour. The ordinary state of debt and credit between any two places
  • is not always entirely regulated by the ordinary course of their dealings
  • with one another, but is often influenced by that of the dealings of
  • either with many other places. If it is usual, for example, for the
  • merchants of England to pay for the goods which they buy of Hamburg,
  • Dantzic, Riga, etc. by bills upon Holland, the ordinary state of debt and
  • credit between England and Holland will not be regulated entirely by the
  • ordinary course of the dealings of those two countries with one another,
  • but will be influenced by that of the dealings in England with those other
  • places. England may be obliged to send out every year money to Holland,
  • though its annual exports to that country may exceed very much the annual
  • value of its imports from thence, and though what is called the balance of
  • trade may be very much in favour of England.
  • In the way, besides, in which the par of exchange has hitherto been
  • computed, the ordinary course of exchange can afford no sufficient
  • indication that the ordinary state of debt and credit is in favour of that
  • country which seems to have, or which is supposed to have, the ordinary
  • course of exchange in its favour; or, in other words, the real exchange
  • may be, and in fact often is, so very different from the computed one,
  • that, from the course of the latter, no certain conclusion can, upon many
  • occasions, be drawn concerning that of the former.
  • When for a sum or money paid in England, containing, according to the
  • standard of the English mint, a certain number of ounces of pure silver,
  • you receive a bill for a sum of money to be paid in France, containing,
  • according to the standard of the French mint, an equal number of ounces of
  • pure silver, exchange is said to be at par between England and France.
  • When you pay more, you are supposed to give a premium, and exchange is
  • said to be against England, and in favour of France. When you pay less,
  • you are supposed to get a premium, and exchange is said to be against
  • France, and in favour of England.
  • But, first, We cannot always judge of the value of the current money of
  • different countries by the standard of their respective mints. In some it
  • is more, in others it is less worn, clipt, and otherwise degenerated from
  • that standard. But the value of the current coin of every country,
  • compared with that of any other country, is in proportion, not to the
  • quantity of pure silver which it ought to contain, but to that which it
  • actually does contain. Before the reformation of the silver coin in King
  • William’s time, exchange between England and Holland, computed in the
  • usual manner, according to the standard of their respective mints, was
  • five-and twenty per cent. against England. But the value of the current
  • coin of England, as we learn from Mr Lowndes, was at that time rather more
  • than five-and-twenty per cent. below its standard value. The real
  • exchange, therefore, may even at that time have been in favour of England,
  • notwithstanding the computed exchange was so much against it; a smaller
  • number or ounces of pure silver, actually paid in England, may have
  • purchased a bill for a greater number of ounces of pure silver to be paid
  • in Holland, and the man who was supposed to give, may in reality have got
  • the premium. The French coin was, before the late reformation of the
  • English gold coin, much less wore than the English, and was perhaps two or
  • three per cent. nearer its standard. If the computed exchange with France,
  • therefore, was not more than two or three per cent. against England, the
  • real exchange might have been in its favour. Since the reformation of the
  • gold coin, the exchange has been constantly in favour of England, and
  • against France.
  • Secondly, In some countries the expense of coinage is defrayed by the
  • government; in others, it is defrayed by the private people, who carry
  • their bullion to the mint, and the government even derives some revenue
  • from the coinage. In England it is defrayed by the government; and if you
  • carry a pound weight of standard silver to the mint, you get back
  • sixty-two shillings, containing a pound weight of the like standard
  • silver. In France a duty of eight per cent. is deducted for the coinage,
  • which not only defrays the expense of it, but affords a small revenue to
  • the government. In England, as the coinage costs nothing, the current coin
  • can never be much more valuable than the quantity of bullion which it
  • actually contains. In France, the workmanship, as you pay for it, adds to
  • the value, in the same manner as to that of wrought plate. A sum of French
  • money, therefore, containing an equal weight of pure silver, is more
  • valuable than a sum of English money containing an equal weight of pure
  • silver, and must require more bullion, or other commodities, to purchase
  • it. Though the current coin of the two countries, therefore, were equally
  • near the standards of their respective mints, a sum of English money could
  • not well purchase a sum of French money containing an equal number of
  • ounces of pure silver, nor, consequently, a bill upon France for such a
  • sum. If, for such a bill, no more additional money was paid than what was
  • sufficient to compensate the expense of the French coinage, the real
  • exchange might be at par between the two countries; their debts and
  • credits might mutually compensate one another, while the computed exchange
  • was considerably in favour of France. If less than this was paid, the real
  • exchange might be in favour of England, while the computed was in favour
  • of France.
  • Thirdly, and lastly, In some places, as at Amsterdam, Hamburg, Venice,
  • etc. foreign bills of exchange are paid in what they call bank money;
  • while in others, as at London, Lisbon, Antwerp, Leghorn, etc. they are
  • paid in the common currency of the country. What is called bank money, is
  • always of more value than the same nominal sum of common currency. A
  • thousand guilders in the bank of Amsterdam, for example, are of more value
  • than a thousand guilders of Amsterdam currency. The difference between
  • them is called the agio of the bank, which at Amsterdam is generally about
  • five per cent. Supposing the current money of the two countries equally
  • near to the standard of their respective mints, and that the one pays
  • foreign bills in this common currency, while the other pays them in bank
  • money, it is evident that the computed exchange may be in favour of that
  • which pays in bank money, though the real exchange should be in favour of
  • that which pays in current money; for the same reason that the computed
  • exchange may be in favour of that which pays in better money, or in money
  • nearer to its own standard, though the real exchange should be in favour
  • of that which pays in worse. The computed exchange, before the late
  • reformation of the gold coin, was generally against London with Amsterdam,
  • Hamburg, Venice, and, I believe, with all other places which pay in what
  • is called bank money. It will by no means follow, however, that the real
  • exchange was against it. Since the reformation of the gold coin, it has
  • been in favour of London, even with those places. The computed exchange
  • has generally been in favour of London with Lisbon, Antwerp, Leghorn, and,
  • if you except France, I believe with most other parts of Europe that pay
  • in common currency; and it is not improbable that the real exchange was so
  • too.
  • Digression concerning Banks of Deposit, particularly concerning that of
  • Amsterdam.
  • The currency of a great state, such as France or England, generally
  • consists almost entirely of its own coin. Should this currency, therefore,
  • be at any time worn, clipt, or otherwise degraded below its standard
  • value, the state, by a reformation of its coin, can effectually
  • re-establish its currency. But the currency of a small state, such as
  • Genoa or Hamburg, can seldom consist altogether in its own coin, but must
  • be made up, in a great measure, of the coins of all the neighbouring
  • states with which its inhabitants have a continual intercourse. Such a
  • state, therefore, by reforming its coin, will not always be able to reform
  • its currency. If foreign bills of exchange are paid in this currency, the
  • uncertain value of any sum, of what is in its own nature so uncertain,
  • must render the exchange always very much against such a state, its
  • currency being in all foreign states necessarily valued even below what it
  • is worth.
  • In order to remedy the inconvenience to which this disadvantageous
  • exchange must have subjected their merchants, such small states, when they
  • began to attend to the interest of trade, have frequently enacted that
  • foreign bills of exchange of a certain value should be paid, not in common
  • currency, but by an order upon, or by a transfer in the books of a certain
  • bank, established upon the credit, and under the protection of the state,
  • this bank being always obliged to pay, in good and true money, exactly
  • according to the standard of the state. The banks of Venice, Genoa,
  • Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Nuremberg, seem to have been all originally
  • established with this view, though some of them may have afterwards been
  • made subservient to other purposes. The money of such banks, being better
  • than the common currency of the country, necessarily bore an agio, which
  • was greater or smaller, according as the currency was supposed to be more
  • or less degraded below the standard of the state. The agio of the bank of
  • Hamburg, for example, which is said to be commonly about fourteen per
  • cent. is the supposed difference between the good standard money of the
  • state, and the clipt, worn, and diminished currency, poured into it from
  • all the neighbouring states.
  • Before 1609, the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign coin which the
  • extensive trade of Amsterdam brought from all parts of Europe, reduced the
  • value of its currency about nine per cent. below that of good money fresh
  • from the mint. Such money no sooner appeared, than it was melted down or
  • carried away, as it always is in such circumstances. The merchants, with
  • plenty of currency, could not always find a sufficient quantity of good
  • money to pay their bills of exchange; and the value of those bills, in
  • spite of several regulations which were made to prevent it, became in a
  • great measure uncertain.
  • In order to remedy these inconveniencies, a bank was established in 1609,
  • under the guarantee of the city. This bank received both foreign coin, and
  • the light and worn coin of the country, at its real intrinsic value in the
  • good standard money of the country, deducting only so much as was
  • necessary for defraying the expense of coinage and the other necessary
  • expense of management. For the value which remained after this small
  • deduction was made, it gave a credit in its books. This credit was called
  • bank money, which, as it represented money exactly according to the
  • standard of the mint, was always of the same real value, and intrinsically
  • worth more than current money. It was at the same time enacted, that all
  • bills drawn upon or negotiated at Amsterdam, of the value of 600 guilders
  • and upwards, should be paid in bank money, which at once took away all
  • uncertainty in the value of those bills. Every merchant, in consequence of
  • this regulation, was obliged to keep an account with the bank, in order to
  • pay his foreign bills of exchange, which necessarily occasioned a certain
  • demand for bank money.
  • Bank money, over and above both its intrinsic superiority to currency, and
  • the additional value which this demand necessarily gives it, has likewise
  • some other advantages, It is secure from fire, robbery, and other
  • accidents; the city of Amsterdam is bound for it; it can be paid away by a
  • simple transfer, without the trouble of counting, or the risk of
  • transporting it from one place to another. In consequence of those
  • different advantages, it seems from the beginning to have borne an agio;
  • and it is generally believed that all the money originally deposited in
  • the bank, was allowed to remain there, nobody caring to demand payment of
  • a debt which he could sell for a premium in the market. By demanding
  • payment of the bank, the owner of a bank credit would lose this premium.
  • As a shilling fresh from the mint will buy no more goods in the market
  • than one of our common worn shillings, so the good and true money which
  • might be brought from the coffers of the bank into those of a private
  • person, being mixed and confounded with the common currency of the
  • country, would be of no more value than that currency, from which it could
  • no longer be readily distinguished. While it remained in the coffers of
  • the bank, its superiority was known and ascertained. When it had come into
  • those of a private person, its superiority could not well be ascertained
  • without more trouble than perhaps the difference was worth. By being
  • brought from the coffers of the bank, besides, it lost all the other
  • advantages of bank money; its security, its easy and safe transferability,
  • its use in paying foreign bills of exchange. Over and above all this, it
  • could not be brought from those coffers, as will appear by and by, without
  • previously paying for the keeping.
  • Those deposits of coin, or those deposits which the bank was bound to
  • restore in coin, constituted the original capital of the bank, or the
  • whole value of what was represented by what is called bank money. At
  • present they are supposed to constitute but a very small part of it. In
  • order to facilitate the trade in bullion, the bank has been for these many
  • years in the practice of giving credit in its books, upon deposits of gold
  • and silver bullion. This credit is generally about five per cent. below
  • the mint price of such bullion. The bank grants at the same time what is
  • called a recipice or receipt, entitling the person who makes the deposit,
  • or the bearer, to take out the bullion again at any time within six
  • months, upon transferring to the bank a quantity of bank money equal to
  • that for which credit had been given in its books when the deposit was
  • made, and upon paying one-fourth per cent. for the keeping, if the deposit
  • was in silver; and one-half per cent. if it was in gold; but at the same
  • time declaring, that in default of such payment, and upon the expiration
  • of this term, the deposit should belong to the bank, at the price at which
  • it had been received, or for which credit had been given in the transfer
  • books. What is thus paid for the keeping of the deposit may be considered
  • as a sort of warehouse rent; and why this warehouse rent should be so much
  • dearer for gold than for silver, several different reasons have been
  • assigned. The fineness of gold, it has been said, is more difficult to be
  • ascertained than that of silver. Frauds are more easily practised, and
  • occasion a greater loss in the most precious metal. Silver, besides, being
  • the standard metal, the state, it has been said, wishes to encourage more
  • the making of deposits of silver than those of gold.
  • Deposits of bullion are most commonly made when the price is somewhat
  • lower than ordinary, and they are taken out again when it happens to rise.
  • In Holland the market price of bullion is generally above the mint price,
  • for the same reason that it was so in England before the late reformation
  • of the gold coin. The difference is said to be commonly from about six to
  • sixteen stivers upon the mark, or eight ounces of silver, of eleven parts
  • of fine and one part alloy. The bank price, or the credit which the bank
  • gives for the deposits of such silver (when made in foreign coin, of which
  • the fineness is well known and ascertained, such as Mexico dollars), is
  • twenty-two guilders the mark: the mint price is about twenty-three
  • guilders, and the market price is from twenty-three guilders six, to
  • twenty-three guilders sixteen stivers, or from two to three per cent.
  • above the mint price.
  • The following are the prices at which the bank of Amsterdam at present
  • {September 1775} receives bullion and coin of different kinds:
  • SILVER
  • Mexico dollars ................. 22 Guilders / mark
  • French crowns .................. 22
  • English silver coin............. 22
  • Mexico dollars, new coin........ 21 10
  • Ducatoons....................... 3 0
  • Rix-dollars..................... 2 8
  • Bar silver, containing 11-12ths fine silver, 21 Guilders / mark, and in
  • this proportion down to 1-4th fine, on which 5 guilders are given. Fine
  • bars,................. 28 Guilders / mark.
  • GOLD
  • Portugal coin................. 310 Guilders / mark
  • Guineas....................... 310
  • Louis d’ors, new.............. 310
  • Ditto old.............. 300
  • New ducats.................... 4 19 8 per ducat
  • Bar or ingot gold is received in proportion to its fineness, compared with
  • the above foreign gold coin. Upon fine bars the bank gives 340 per mark.
  • In general, however, something more is given upon coin of a known
  • fineness, than upon gold and silver bars, of which the fineness cannot be
  • ascertained but by a process of melting and assaying.
  • The proportions between the bank price, the mint price, and the market
  • price of gold bullion, are nearly the same. A person can generally sell
  • his receipt for the difference between the mint price of bullion and the
  • market price. A receipt for bullion is almost always worth something, and
  • it very seldom happens, therefore, that anybody suffers his receipts to
  • expire, or allows his bullion to fall to the bank at the price at which it
  • had been received, either by not taking it out before the end of the six
  • months, or by neglecting to pay one fourth or one half per cent. in order
  • to obtain a new receipt for another six months. This, however, though it
  • happens seldom, is said to happen sometimes, and more frequently with
  • regard to gold than with regard to silver, on account of the higher
  • warehouse rent which is paid for the keeping of the more precious metal.
  • The person who, by making a deposit of bullion, obtains both a bank credit
  • and a receipt, pays his bills of exchange as they become due, with his
  • bank credit; and either sells or keeps his receipt, according as he judges
  • that the price of bullion is likely to rise or to fall. The receipt and
  • the bank credit seldom keep long together, and there is no occasion that
  • they should. The person who has a receipt, and who wants to take out
  • bullion, finds always plenty of bank credits, or bank money, to buy at the
  • ordinary price, and the person who has bank money, and wants to take out
  • bullion, finds receipts always in equal abundance.
  • The owners of bank credits, and the holders of receipts, constitute two
  • different sorts of creditors against the bank. The holder of a receipt
  • cannot draw out the bullion for which it is granted, without re-assigning
  • to the bank a sum of bank money equal to the price at which the bullion
  • had been received. If he has no bank money of his own, he must purchase it
  • of those who have it. The owner of bank money cannot draw out bullion,
  • without producing to the bank receipts for the quantity which he wants. If
  • he has none of his own, he must buy them of those who have them. The
  • holder of a receipt, when he purchases bank money, purchases the power of
  • taking out a quantity of bullion, of which the mint price is five per
  • cent. above the bank price. The agio of five per cent. therefore, which he
  • commonly pays for it, is paid, not for an imaginary, but for a real value.
  • The owner of bank money, when he purchases a receipt, purchases the power
  • of taking out a quantity of bullion, of which the market price is commonly
  • from two to three per cent. above the mint price. The price which he pays
  • for it, therefore, is paid likewise for a real value. The price of the
  • receipt, and the price of the bank money, compound or make up between them
  • the full value or price of the bullion.
  • Upon deposits of the coin current in the country, the bank grant receipts
  • likewise, as well as bank credits; but those receipts are frequently of no
  • value and will bring no price in the market. Upon ducatoons, for example,
  • which in the currency pass for three guilders three stivers each, the bank
  • gives a credit of three guilders only, or five per cent. below their
  • current value. It grants a receipt likewise, entitling the bearer to take
  • out the number of ducatoons deposited at any time within six months, upon
  • paying one fourth per cent. for the keeping. This receipt will frequently
  • bring no price in the market. Three guilders, bank money, generally sell
  • in the market for three guilders three stivers, the full value of the
  • ducatoons, if they were taken out of the bank; and before they can be
  • taken out, one-fourth per cent. must be paid for the keeping, which would
  • be mere loss to the holder of the receipt. If the agio of the bank,
  • however, should at any time fall to three per cent. such receipts might
  • bring some price in the market, and might sell for one and three-fourths
  • per cent. But the agio of the bank being now generally about five per
  • cent. such receipts are frequently allowed to expire, or, as they express
  • it, to fall to the bank. The receipts which are given for deposits of gold
  • ducats fall to it yet more frequently, because a higher warehouse rent, or
  • one half per cent. must be paid for the keeping of them, before they can
  • be taken out again. The five per cent. which the bank gains, when deposits
  • either of coin or bullion are allowed to fall to it, maybe considered as
  • the warehouse rent for the perpetual keeping of such deposits.
  • The sum of bank money, for which the receipts are expired, must be very
  • considerable. It must comprehend the whole original capital of the bank,
  • which, it is generally supposed, has been allowed to remain there from the
  • time it was first deposited, nobody caring either to renew his receipt, or
  • to take out his deposit, as, for the reasons already assigned, neither the
  • one nor the other could be done without loss. But whatever may be the
  • amount of this sum, the proportion which it bears to the whole mass of
  • bank money is supposed to be very small. The bank of Amsterdam has, for
  • these many years past, been the great warehouse of Europe for bullion, for
  • which the receipts are very seldom allowed to expire, or, as they express
  • it, to fall to the bank. The far greater part of the bank money, or of the
  • credits upon the books of the bank, is supposed to have been created, for
  • these many years past, by such deposits, which the dealers in bullion are
  • continually both making and withdrawing.
  • No demand can be made upon the bank, but by means of a recipice or
  • receipt. The smaller mass of bank money, for which the receipts are
  • expired, is mixed and confounded with the much greater mass for which they
  • are still in force; so that, though there may be a considerable sum of
  • bank money, for which there are no receipts, there is no specific sum or
  • portion of it which may not at any time be demanded by one. The bank
  • cannot be debtor to two persons for the same thing; and the owner of bank
  • money who has no receipt, cannot demand payment of the bank till he buys
  • one. In ordinary and quiet times, he can find no difficulty in getting one
  • to buy at the market price, which generally corresponds with the price at
  • which he can sell the coin or bullion it entitles him to take out of the
  • bank.
  • It might be otherwise during a public calamity; an invasion, for example,
  • such as that of the French in 1672. The owners of bank money being then
  • all eager to draw it out of the bank, in order to have it in their own
  • keeping, the demand for receipts might raise their price to an exorbitant
  • height. The holders of them might form extravagant expectations, and,
  • instead of two or three per cent. demand half the bank money for which
  • credit had been given upon the deposits that the receipts had respectively
  • been granted for. The enemy, informed of the constitution of the bank,
  • might even buy them up, in order to prevent the carrying away of the
  • treasure. In such emergencies, the bank, it is supposed, would break
  • through its ordinary rule of making payment only to the holders of
  • receipts. The holders of receipts, who had no bank money, must have
  • received within two or three per cent. of the value of the deposit for
  • which their respective receipts had been granted. The bank, therefore, it
  • is said, would in this case make no scruple of paying, either with money
  • or bullion, the full value of what the owners of bank money, who could get
  • no receipts, were credited for in its books; paying, at the same time, two
  • or three per cent. to such holders of receipts as had no bank money, that
  • being the whole value which, in this state of things, could justly be
  • supposed due to them.
  • Even in ordinary and quiet times, it is the interest of the holders of
  • receipts to depress the agio, in order either to buy bank money (and
  • consequently the bullion which their receipts would then enable them to
  • take out of the bank ) so much cheaper, or to sell their receipts to those
  • who have bank money, and who want to take out bullion, so much dearer; the
  • price of a receipt being generally equal to the difference between the
  • market price of bank money and that of the coin or bullion for which the
  • receipt had been granted. It is the interest of the owners of bank money,
  • on the contrary, to raise the agio, in order either to sell their bank
  • money so much dearer, or to buy a receipt so much cheaper. To prevent the
  • stock-jobbing tricks which those opposite interests might sometimes
  • occasion, the bank has of late years come to the resolution, to sell at
  • all times bank money for currency at five per cent. agio, and to buy it in
  • again at four per cent. agio. In consequence of this resolution, the agio
  • can never either rise above five, or sink below four per cent.; and the
  • proportion between the market price of bank and that of current money is
  • kept at all times very near the proportion between their intrinsic values.
  • Before this resolution was taken, the market price of bank money used
  • sometimes to rise so high as nine per cent. agio, and sometimes to sink so
  • low as par, according as opposite interests happened to influence the
  • market.
  • The bank of Amsterdam professes to lend out no part of what is deposited
  • with it, but for every guilder for which it gives credit in its books, to
  • keep in its repositories the value of a guilder either in money or
  • bullion. That it keeps in its repositories all the money or bullion for
  • which there are receipts in force for which it is at all times liable to
  • be called upon, and which in reality is continually going from it, and
  • returning to it again, cannot well be doubted. But whether it does so
  • likewise with regard to that part of its capital for which the receipts
  • are long ago expired, for which, in ordinary and quiet times, it cannot be
  • called upon, and which, in reality, is very likely to remain with it for
  • ever, or as long as the states of the United Provinces subsist, may
  • perhaps appear more uncertain. At Amsterdam, however, no point of faith is
  • better established than that, for every guilder circulated as bank money,
  • there is a correspondent guilder in gold or silver to be found in the
  • treasures of the bank. The city is guarantee that it should be so. The
  • bank is under the direction of the four reigning burgomasters who are
  • changed every year. Each new set of burgomasters visits the treasure,
  • compares it with the books, receives it upon oath, and delivers it over,
  • with the same awful solemnity to the set which succeeds; and in that sober
  • and religious country, oaths are not yet disregarded. A rotation of this
  • kind seems alone a sufficient security against any practices which cannot
  • be avowed. Amidst all the revolutions which faction has ever occasioned in
  • the government of Amsterdam, the prevailing party has at no time accused
  • their predecessors of infidelity in the administration of the bank. No
  • accusation could have affected more deeply the reputation and fortune of
  • the disgraced party; and if such an accusation could have been supported,
  • we may be assured that it would have been brought. In 1672, when the
  • French king was at Utrecht, the bank of Amsterdam paid so readily, as left
  • no doubt of the fidelity with which it had observed its engagements. Some
  • of the pieces which were then brought from its repositories, appeared to
  • have been scorched with the fire which happened in the town-house soon
  • after the bank was established. Those pieces, therefore, must have lain
  • there from that time.
  • What may be the amount of the treasure in the bank, is a question which
  • has long employed the speculations of the curious. Nothing but conjecture
  • can be offered concerning it. It is generally reckoned, that there are
  • about 2000 people who keep accounts with the bank; and allowing them to
  • have, one with another, the value of £1500 sterling lying upon their
  • respective accounts (a very large allowance), the whole quantity of bank
  • money, and consequently of treasure in the bank, will amount to about
  • £3,000,000 sterling, or, at eleven guilders the pound sterling, 33,000,000
  • of guilders; a great sum, and sufficient to carry on a very extensive
  • circulation, but vastly below the extravagant ideas which some people have
  • formed of this treasure.
  • The city of Amsterdam derives a considerable revenue from the bank.
  • Besides what may be called the warehouse rent above mentioned, each
  • person, upon first opening an account with the bank, pays a fee of ten
  • guilders; and for every new account, three guilders three stivers; for
  • every transfer, two stivers; and if the transfer is for less than 300
  • guilders, six stivers, in order to discourage the multiplicity of small
  • transactions. The person who neglects to balance his account twice in the
  • year, forfeits twenty-five guilders. The person who orders a transfer for
  • more than is upon his account, is obliged to pay three per cent. for the
  • sum overdrawn, and his order is set aside into the bargain. The bank is
  • supposed, too, to make a considerable profit by the sale of the foreign
  • coin or bullion which sometimes falls to it by the expiring of receipts,
  • and which is always kept till it can be sold with advantage. It makes a
  • profit, likewise, by selling bank money at five per cent. agio, and buying
  • it in at four. These different emoluments amount to a good deal more than
  • what is necessary for paying the salaries of officers, and defraying the
  • expense of management. What is paid for the keeping of bullion upon
  • receipts, is alone supposed to amount to a neat annual revenue of between
  • 150,000 and 200,000 guilders. Public utility, however, and not revenue,
  • was the original object of this institution. Its object was to relieve the
  • merchants from the inconvenience of a disadvantageous exchange. The
  • revenue which has arisen from it was unforeseen, and may be considered as
  • accidental. But it is now time to return from this long digression, into
  • which I have been insensibly led, in endeavouring to explain the reasons
  • why the exchange between the countries which pay in what is called bank
  • money, and those which pay in common currency, should generally appear to
  • be in favour of the former, and against the latter. The former pay in a
  • species of money, of which the intrinsic value is always the same, and
  • exactly agreeable to the standard of their respective mints; the latter is
  • a species of money, of which the intrinsic value is continually varying,
  • and is almost always more or less below that standard.
  • PART II.—Of the Unreasonableness of those extraordinary Restraints,
  • upon other Principles.
  • In the foregoing part of this chapter, I have endeavoured to show, even
  • upon the principles of the commercial system, how unnecessary it is to lay
  • extraordinary restraints upon the importation of goods from those
  • countries with which the balance of trade is supposed to be
  • disadvantageous.
  • Nothing, however, can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the
  • balance of trade, upon which, not only these restraints, but almost all
  • the other regulations of commerce, are founded. When two places trade with
  • one another, this doctrine supposes that, if the balance be even, neither
  • of them either loses or gains; but if it leans in any degree to one side,
  • that one of them loses, and the other gains, in proportion to its
  • declension from the exact equilibrium. Both suppositions are false. A
  • trade, which is forced by means of bounties and monopolies, may be, and
  • commonly is, disadvantageous to the country in whose favour it is meant to
  • be established, as I shall endeavour to show hereafter. But that trade
  • which, without force or constraint, is naturally and regularly carried on
  • between any two places, is always advantageous, though not always equally
  • so, to both.
  • By advantage or gain, I understand, not the increase of the quantity of
  • gold and silver, but that of the exchangeable value of the annual produce
  • of the land and labour of the country, or the increase of the annual
  • revenue of its inhabitants.
  • If the balance be even, and if the trade between the two places consist
  • altogether in the exchange of their native commodities, they will, upon
  • most occasions, not only both gain, but they will gain equally, or very
  • nearly equally; each will, in this case, afford a market for a part of the
  • surplus produce of the other; each will replace a capital which had been
  • employed in raising and preparing for the market this part of the surplus
  • produce of the other, and which had been distributed among, and given
  • revenue and maintenance to, a certain number of its inhabitants. Some part
  • of the inhabitants of each, therefore, will directly derive their revenue
  • and maintenance from the other. As the commodities exchanged, too, are
  • supposed to be of equal value, so the two capitals employed in the trade
  • will, upon most occasions, be equal, or very nearly equal; and both being
  • employed in raising the native commodities of the two countries, the
  • revenue and maintenance which their distribution will afford to the
  • inhabitants of each will be equal, or very nearly equal. This revenue and
  • maintenance, thus mutually afforded, will be greater or smaller, in
  • proportion to the extent of their dealings. If these should annually
  • amount to £100,000, for example, or to £1,000,000, on each side, each of
  • them will afford an annual revenue, in the one case, of £100,000, and, in
  • the other, of £1,000,000, to the inhabitants of the other.
  • If their trade should be of such a nature, that one of them exported to
  • the other nothing but native commodities, while the returns of that other
  • consisted altogether in foreign goods; the balance, in this case, would
  • still be supposed even, commodities being paid for with commodities. They
  • would, in this case too, both gain, but they would not gain equally; and
  • the inhabitants of the country which exported nothing but native
  • commodities, would derive the greatest revenue from the trade. If England,
  • for example, should import from France nothing but the native commodities
  • of that country, and not having such commodities of its own as were in
  • demand there, should annually repay them by sending thither a large
  • quantity of foreign goods, tobacco, we shall suppose, and East India
  • goods; this trade, though it would give some revenue to the inhabitants of
  • both countries, would give more to those of France than to those of
  • England. The whole French capital annually employed in it would annually
  • be distributed among the people of France; but that part of the English
  • capital only, which was employed in producing the English commodities with
  • which those foreign goods were purchased, would be annually distributed
  • among the people of England. The greater part of it would replace the
  • capitals which had been employed in Virginia, Indostan, and China, and
  • which had given revenue and maintenance to the inhabitants of those
  • distant countries. If the capitals were equal, or nearly equal, therefore,
  • this employment of the French capital would augment much more the revenue
  • of the people of France, than that of the English capital would the
  • revenue of the people of England. France would, in this case, carry on a
  • direct foreign trade of consumption with England; whereas England would
  • carry on a round-about trade of the same kind with France. The different
  • effects of a capital employed in the direct, and of one employed in the
  • round-about foreign trade of consumption, have already been fully
  • explained.
  • There is not, probably, between any two countries, a trade which consists
  • altogether in the exchange, either of native commodities on both sides, or
  • of native commodities on one side, and of foreign goods on the other.
  • Almost all countries exchange with one another, partly native and partly
  • foreign goods. That country, however, in whose cargoes there is the
  • greatest proportion of native, and the least of foreign goods, will always
  • be the principal gainer.
  • If it was not with tobacco and East India goods, but with gold and silver,
  • that England paid for the commodities annually imported from France, the
  • balance, in this case, would be supposed uneven, commodities not being
  • paid for with commodities, but with gold and silver. The trade, however,
  • would in this case, as in the foregoing, give some revenue to the
  • inhabitants of both countries, but more to those of France than to those
  • of England. It would give some revenue to those of England. The capital
  • which had been employed in producing the English goods that purchased this
  • gold and silver, the capital which had been distributed among, and given
  • revenue to, certain inhabitants of England, would thereby be replaced, and
  • enabled to continue that employment. The whole capital of England would no
  • more be diminished by this exportation of gold and silver, than by the
  • exportation of an equal value of any other goods. On the contrary, it
  • would, in most cases, be augmented. No goods are sent abroad but those for
  • which the demand is supposed to be greater abroad than at home, and of
  • which the returns, consequently, it is expected, will be of more value at
  • home than the commodities exported. If the tobacco which in England is
  • worth only £100,000, when sent to France, will purchase wine which is in
  • England worth £110,000, the exchange will augment the capital of England
  • by £10,000. If £100,000 of English gold, in the same manner, purchase
  • French wine, which in England is worth £110,000, this exchange will
  • equally augment the capital of England by £10,000. As a merchant, who has
  • £110,000 worth of wine in his cellar, is a richer man than he who has only
  • £100,000 worth of tobacco in his warehouse, so is he likewise a richer man
  • than he who has only £100,000 worth of gold in his coffers. He can put
  • into motion a greater quantity of industry, and give revenue, maintenance,
  • and employment, to a greater number of people, than either of the other
  • two. But the capital of the country is equal to the capital of all its
  • different inhabitants; and the quantity of industry which can be annually
  • maintained in it is equal to what all those different capitals can
  • maintain. Both the capital of the country, therefore, and the quantity of
  • industry which can be annually maintained in it, must generally be
  • augmented by this exchange. It would, indeed, be more advantageous for
  • England that it could purchase the wines of France with its own hardware
  • and broad cloth, than with either the tobacco of Virginia, or the gold and
  • silver of Brazil and Peru. A direct foreign trade of consumption is always
  • more advantageous than a round-about one. But a round-about foreign trade
  • of consumption, which is carried on with gold and silver, does not seem to
  • be less advantageous than any other equally round-about one. Neither is a
  • country which has no mines, more likely to be exhausted of gold and silver
  • by this annual exportation of those metals, than one which does not grow
  • tobacco by the like annual exportation of that plant. As a country which
  • has wherewithal to buy tobacco will never be long in want of it, so
  • neither will one be long in want of gold and silver which has wherewithal
  • to purchase those metals.
  • It is a losing trade, it is said, which a workman carries on with the
  • alehouse; and the trade which a manufacturing nation would naturally carry
  • on with a wine country, may be considered as a trade of the same nature. I
  • answer, that the trade with the alehouse is not necessarily a losing
  • trade. In its own nature it is just as advantageous as any other, though,
  • perhaps, somewhat more liable to be abused. The employment of a brewer,
  • and even that of a retailer of fermented liquors, are as necessary
  • divisions of labour as any other. It will generally be more advantageous
  • for a workman to buy of the brewer the quantity he has occasion for, than
  • to brew it himself; and if he is a poor workman, it will generally be more
  • advantageous for him to buy it by little and little of the retailer, than
  • a large quantity of the brewer. He may no doubt buy too much of either, as
  • he may of any other dealers in his neighbourhood; of the butcher, if he is
  • a glutton; or of the draper, if he affects to be a beau among his
  • companions. It is advantageous to the great body of workmen,
  • notwithstanding, that all these trades should be free, though this freedom
  • may be abused in all of them, and is more likely to be so, perhaps, in
  • some than in others. Though individuals, besides, may sometimes ruin their
  • fortunes by an excessive consumption of fermented liquors, there seems to
  • be no risk that a nation should do so. Though in every country there are
  • many people who spend upon such liquors more than they can afford, there
  • are always many more who spend less. It deserves to be remarked, too, that
  • if we consult experience, the cheapness of wine seems to be a cause, not
  • of drunkenness, but of sobriety. The inhabitants of the wine countries are
  • in general the soberest people of Europe; witness the Spaniards, the
  • Italians, and the inhabitants of the southern provinces of France. People
  • are seldom guilty of excess in what is their daily fare. Nobody affects
  • the character of liberality and good fellowship, by being profuse of a
  • liquor which is as cheap as small beer. On the contrary, in the countries
  • which, either from excessive heat or cold, produce no grapes, and where
  • wine consequently is dear and a rarity, drunkenness is a common vice, as
  • among the northern nations, and all those who live between the tropics,
  • the negroes, for example on the coast of Guinea. When a French regiment
  • comes from some of the northern provinces of France, where wine is
  • somewhat dear, to be quartered in the southern, where it is very cheap,
  • the soldiers, I have frequently heard it observed, are at first debauched
  • by the cheapness and novelty of good wine; but after a few months
  • residence, the greater part of them become as sober as the rest of the
  • inhabitants. Were the duties upon foreign wines, and the excises upon
  • malt, beer, and ale, to be taken away all at once, it might, in the same
  • manner, occasion in Great Britain a pretty general and temporary
  • drunkenness among the middling and inferior ranks of people, which would
  • probably be soon followed by a permanent and almost universal sobriety. At
  • present, drunkenness is by no means the vice of people of fashion, or of
  • those who can easily afford the most expensive liquors. A gentleman drunk
  • with ale has scarce ever been seen among us. The restraints upon the wine
  • trade in Great Britain, besides, do not so much seem calculated to hinder
  • the people from going, if I may say so, to the alehouse, as from going
  • where they can buy the best and cheapest liquor. They favour the wine
  • trade of Portugal, and discourage that of France. The Portuguese, it is
  • said, indeed, are better customers for our manufactures than the French,
  • and should therefore be encouraged in preference to them. As they give us
  • their custom, it is pretended we should give them ours. The sneaking arts
  • of underling tradesmen are thus erected into political maxims for the
  • conduct of a great empire; for it is the most underling tradesmen only who
  • make it a rule to employ chiefly their own customers. A great trader
  • purchases his goods always where they are cheapest and best, without
  • regard to any little interest of this kind.
  • By such maxims as these, however, nations have been taught that their
  • interest consisted in beggaring all their neighbours. Each nation has been
  • made to look with an invidious eye upon the prosperity of all the nations
  • with which it trades, and to consider their gain as its own loss.
  • Commerce, which ought naturally to be, among nations as among individuals,
  • a bond of union and friendship, has become the most fertile source of
  • discord and animosity. The capricious ambition of kings and ministers has
  • not, during the present and the preceding century, been more fatal to the
  • repose of Europe, than the impertinent jealousy of merchants and
  • manufacturers. The violence and injustice of the rulers of mankind is an
  • ancient evil, for which, I am afraid, the nature of human affairs can
  • scarce admit of a remedy: but the mean rapacity, the monopolizing spirit,
  • of merchants and manufacturers, who neither are, nor ought to be, the
  • rulers of mankind, though it cannot, perhaps, be corrected, may very
  • easily be prevented from disturbing the tranquillity of anybody but
  • themselves.
  • That it was the spirit of monopoly which originally both invented and
  • propagated this doctrine, cannot be doubted and they who first taught it,
  • were by no means such fools as they who believed it. In every country it
  • always is, and must be, the interest of the great body of the people, to
  • buy whatever they want of those who sell it cheapest. The proposition is
  • so very manifest, that it seems ridiculous to take any pains to prove it;
  • nor could it ever have been called in question, had not the interested
  • sophistry of merchants and manufacturers confounded the common sense of
  • mankind. Their interest is, in this respect, directly opposite to that of
  • the great body of the people. As it is the interest of the freemen of a
  • corporation to hinder the rest of the inhabitants from employing any
  • workmen but themselves; so it is the interest of the merchants and
  • manufacturers of every country to secure to themselves the monopoly of the
  • home market. Hence, in Great Britain, and in most other European
  • countries, the extraordinary duties upon almost all goods imported by
  • alien merchants. Hence the high duties and prohibitions upon all those
  • foreign manufactures which can come into competition with our own. Hence,
  • too, the extraordinary restraints upon the importation of almost all sorts
  • of goods from those countries with which the balance of trade is supposed
  • to be disadvantageous; that is, from those against whom national animosity
  • happens ta be most violently inflamed.
  • The wealth of neighbouring nations, however, though dangerous in war and
  • politics, is certainly advantageous in trade. In a state of hostility, it
  • may enable our enemies to maintain fleets and armies superior to our own;
  • but in a state of peace and commerce it must likewise enable them to
  • exchange with us to a greater value, and to afford a better market, either
  • for the immediate produce of our own industry, or for whatever is
  • purchased with that produce. As a rich man is likely to be a better
  • customer to the industrious people in his neighbourhood, than a poor, so
  • is likewise a rich nation. A rich man, indeed, who is himself a
  • manufacturer, is a very dangerous neighbour to all those who deal in the
  • same way. All the rest of the neighbourhood, however, by far the greatest
  • number, profit by the good market which his expense affords them. They
  • even profit by his underselling the poorer workmen who deal in the same
  • way with him. The manufacturers of a rich nation, in the same manner, may
  • no doubt be very dangerous rivals to those of their neighbours. This very
  • competition, however, is advantageous to the great body of the people, who
  • profit greatly, besides, by the good market which the great expense of
  • such a nation affords them in every other way. Private people, who want to
  • make a fortune, never think of retiring to the remote and poor provinces
  • of the country, but resort either to the capital, or to some of the great
  • commercial towns. They know, that where little wealth circulates, there is
  • little to be got; but that where a great deal is in motion, some share of
  • it may fall to them. The same maxim which would in this manner direct the
  • common sense of one, or ten, or twenty individuals, should regulate the
  • judgment of one, or ten, or twenty millions, and should make a whole
  • nation regard the riches of its neighbours, as a probable cause and
  • occasion for itself to acquire riches. A nation that would enrich itself
  • by foreign trade, is certainly most likely to do so, when its neighbours
  • are all rich, industrious and commercial nations. A great nation,
  • surrounded on all sides by wandering savages and poor barbarians, might,
  • no doubt, acquire riches by the cultivation of its own lands, and by its
  • own interior commerce, but not by foreign trade. It seems to have been in
  • this manner that the ancient Egyptians and the modern Chinese acquired
  • their great wealth. The ancient Egyptians, it is said, neglected foreign
  • commerce, and the modern Chinese, it is known, hold it in the utmost
  • contempt, and scarce deign to afford it the decent protection of the laws.
  • The modern maxims of foreign commerce, by aiming at the impoverishment of
  • all our neighbours, so far as they are capable of producing their intended
  • effect, tend to render that very commerce insignificant and contemptible.
  • It is in consequence of these maxims, that the commerce between France and
  • England has, in both countries, been subjected to so many discouragements
  • and restraints. If those two countries, however, were to consider their
  • real interest, without either mercantile jealousy or national animosity,
  • the commerce of France might be more advantageous to Great Britain than
  • that of any other country, and, for the same reason, that of Great Britain
  • to France. France is the nearest neighbour to Great Britain. In the trade
  • between the southern coast of England and the northern and north-western
  • coast of France, the returns might be expected, in the same manner as in
  • the inland trade, four, five, or six times in the year. The capital,
  • therefore, employed in this trade could, in each of the two countries,
  • keep in motion four, five, or six times the quantity of industry, and
  • afford employment and subsistence to four, five, or six times the number
  • of people, which all equal capital could do in the greater part of the
  • other branches of foreign trade. Between the parts of France and Great
  • Britain most remote from one another, the returns might be expected, at
  • least, once in the year; and even this trade would so far be at least
  • equally advantageous, as the greater part of the other branches of our
  • foreign European trade. It would be, at least, three times more
  • advantageous than the boasted trade with our North American colonies, in
  • which the returns were seldom made in less than three years, frequently
  • not in less than four or five years. France, besides, is supposed to
  • contain 24,000,000 of inhabitants. Our North American colonies were never
  • supposed to contain more than 3,000,000; and France is a much richer
  • country than North America; though, on account of the more unequal
  • distribution of riches, there is much more poverty and beggary in the one
  • country than in the other. France, therefore, could afford a market at
  • least eight times more extensive, and, on account of the superior
  • frequency of the returns, four-and-twenty times more advantageous than
  • that which our North American colonies ever afforded. The trade of Great
  • Britain would be just as advantageous to France, and, in proportion to the
  • wealth, population, and proximity of the respective countries, would have
  • the same superiority over that which France carries on with her own
  • colonies. Such is the very great difference between that trade which the
  • wisdom of both nations has thought proper to discourage, and that which it
  • has favoured the most.
  • But the very same circumstances which would have rendered an open and free
  • commerce between the two countries so advantageous to both, have
  • occasioned the principal obstructions to that commerce. Being neighbours,
  • they are necessarily enemies, and the wealth and power of each becomes,
  • upon that account, more formidable to the other; and what would increase
  • the advantage of national friendship, serves only to inflame the violence
  • of national animosity. They are both rich and industrious nations; and the
  • merchants and manufacturers of each dread the competition of the skill and
  • activity of those of the other. Mercantile jealousy is excited, and both
  • inflames, and is itself inflamed, by the violence of national animosity,
  • and the traders of both countries have announced, with all the passionate
  • confidence of interested falsehood, the certain ruin of each, in
  • consequence of that unfavourable balance of trade, which, they pretend,
  • would be the infallible effect of an unrestrained commerce with the other.
  • There is no commercial country in Europe, of which the approaching ruin
  • has not frequently been foretold by the pretended doctors of this system,
  • from all unfavourably balance of trade. After all the anxiety, however,
  • which they have excited about this, after all the vain attempts of almost
  • all trading nations to turn that balance in their own favour, and against
  • their neighbours, it does not appear that any one nation in Europe has
  • been, in any respect, impoverished by this cause. Every town and country,
  • on the contrary, in proportion as they have opened their ports to all
  • nations, instead of being ruined by this free trade, as the principles of
  • the commercial system would lead us to expect, have been enriched by it.
  • Though there are in Europe indeed, a few towns which, in same respects,
  • deserve the name of free ports, there is no country which does so.
  • Holland, perhaps, approaches the nearest to this character of any, though
  • still very remote from it; and Holland, it is acknowledged, not only
  • derives its whole wealth, but a great part of its necessary subsistence,
  • from foreign trade.
  • There is another balance, indeed, which has already been explained, very
  • different from the balance of trade, and which, according as it happens to
  • be either favourable or unfavourable, necessarily occasions the prosperity
  • or decay of every nation. This is the balance of the annual produce and
  • consumption. If the exchangeable value of the annual produce, it has
  • already been observed, exceeds that of the annual consumption, the capital
  • of the society must annually increase in proportion to this excess. The
  • society in this case lives within its revenue; and what is annually saved
  • out of its revenue, is naturally added to its capital, and employed so as
  • to increase still further the annual produce. If the exchangeable value of
  • the annual produce, on the contrary, fall short of the annual consumption,
  • the capital of the society must annually decay in proportion to this
  • deficiency. The expense of the society, in this case, exceeds its revenue,
  • and necessarily encroaches upon its capital. Its capital, therefore, must
  • necessarily decay, and, together with it, the exchangeable value of the
  • annual produce of its industry.
  • This balance of produce and consumption is entirely different from what is
  • called the balance of trade. It might take place in a nation which had no
  • foreign trade, but which was entirely separated from all the world. It may
  • take place in the whole globe of the earth, of which the wealth,
  • population, and improvement, may be either gradually increasing or
  • gradually decaying.
  • The balance of produce and consumption may be constantly in favour of a
  • nation, though what is called the balance of trade be generally against
  • it. A nation may import to a greater value than it exports for half a
  • century, perhaps, together; the gold and silver which comes into it during
  • all this time, may be all immediately sent out of it; its circulating coin
  • may gradually decay, different sorts of paper money being substituted in
  • its place, and even the debts, too, which it contracts in the principal
  • nations with whom it deals, may be gradually increasing; and yet its real
  • wealth, the exchangeable value of the annual produce of its lands and
  • labour, may, during the same period, have been increasing in a much
  • greater proportion. The state of our North American colonies, and of the
  • trade which they carried on with Great Britain, before the commencement of
  • the present disturbances, {This paragraph was written in the year 1775.}
  • may serve as a proof that this is by no means an impossible supposition.
  • CHAPTER IV.
  • OF DRAWBACKS.
  • Merchants and manufacturers are not contented with the monopoly of the
  • home market, but desire likewise the most extensive foreign sale for their
  • goods. Their country has no jurisdiction in foreign nations, and therefore
  • can seldom procure them any monopoly there. They are generally obliged,
  • therefore, to content themselves with petitioning for certain
  • encouragements to exportation.
  • Of these encouragements, what are called drawbacks seem to be the most
  • reasonable. To allow the merchant to draw back upon exportation, either
  • the whole, or a part of whatever excise or inland duty is imposed upon
  • domestic industry, can never occasion the exportation of a greater
  • quantity of goods than what would have been exported had no duty been
  • imposed. Such encouragements do not tend to turn towards any particular
  • employment a greater share of the capital of the country, than what would
  • go to that employment of its own accord, but only to hinder the duty from
  • driving away any part of that share to other employments. They tend not to
  • overturn that balance which naturally establishes itself among all the
  • various employments of the society, but to hinder it from being overturned
  • by the duty. They tend not to destroy, but to preserve, what it is in most
  • cases advantageous to preserve, the natural division and distribution of
  • labour in the society.
  • The same thing may be said of the drawbacks upon the re-exportation of
  • foreign goods imported, which, in Great Britain, generally amount to by
  • much the largest part of the duty upon importation. By the second of the
  • rules, annexed to the act of parliament, which imposed what is now called
  • the old subsidy, every merchant, whether English or alien. was allowed to
  • draw back half that duty upon exportation; the English merchant, provided
  • the exportation took place within twelve months; the alien, provided it
  • took place within nine months. Wines, currants, and wrought silks, were
  • the only goods which did not fall within this rule, having other and more
  • advantageous allowances. The duties imposed by this act of parliament
  • were, at that time, the only duties upon the importation of foreign goods.
  • The term within which this, and all other drawbacks could be claimed, was
  • afterwards (by 7 Geo. I. chap. 21. sect. 10.) extended to three years.
  • The duties which have been imposed since the old subsidy, are, the greater
  • part of them, wholly drawn back upon exportation. This general rule,
  • however, is liable to a great number of exceptions; and the doctrine of
  • drawbacks has become a much less simple matter than it was at their first
  • institution.
  • Upon the exportation of some foreign goods, of which it was expected that
  • the importation would greatly exceed what was necessary for the home
  • consumption, the whole duties are drawn back, without retaining even half
  • the old subsidy. Before the revolt of our North American colonies, we had
  • the monopoly of the tobacco of Maryland and Virginia. We imported about
  • ninety-six thousand hogsheads, and the home consumption was not supposed
  • to exceed fourteen thousand. To facilitate the great exportation which was
  • necessary, in order to rid us of the rest, the whole duties were drawn
  • back, provided the exportation took place within three years.
  • We still have, though not altogether, yet very nearly, the monopoly of the
  • sugars of our West Indian islands. If sugars are exported within a year,
  • therefore, all the duties upon importation are drawn back; and if exported
  • within three years, all the duties, except half the old subsidy, which
  • still continues to be retained upon the exportation of the greater part of
  • goods. Though the importation of sugar exceeds a good deal what is
  • necessary for the home consumption, the excess is inconsiderable, in
  • comparison of what it used to be in tobacco.
  • Some goods, the particular objects of the jealousy of our own
  • manufacturers, are prohibited to be imported for home consumption. They
  • may, however, upon paying certain duties, be imported and warehoused for
  • exportation. But upon such exportation no part of these duties is drawn
  • back. Our manufacturers are unwilling, it seems, that even this restricted
  • importation should be encouraged, and are afraid lest some part of these
  • goods should be stolen out of the warehouse, and thus come into
  • competition with their own. It is under these regulations only that we can
  • import wrought silks, French cambrics and lawns, calicoes, painted,
  • printed, stained, or dyed, etc.
  • We are unwilling even to be the carriers of French goods, and choose
  • rather to forego a profit to ourselves than to suffer those whom we
  • consider as our enemies to make any profit by our means. Not only half the
  • old subsidy, but the second twenty-five per cent. is retained upon the
  • exportation of all French goods.
  • By the fourth of the rules annexed to the old subsidy, the drawback
  • allowed upon the exportation of all wines amounted to a great deal more
  • than half the duties which were at that time paid upon their importation;
  • and it seems at that time to have been the object of the legislature to
  • give somewhat more than ordinary encouragement to the carrying trade in
  • wine. Several of the other duties, too which were imposed either at the
  • same time or subsequent to the old subsidy, what is called the additional
  • duty, the new subsidy, the one-third and two-thirds subsidies, the impost
  • 1692, the tonnage on wine, were allowed to be wholly drawn back upon
  • exportation. All those duties, however, except the additional duty and
  • impost 1692, being paid down in ready money upon importation, the interest
  • of so large a sum occasioned an expense, which made it unreasonable to
  • expect any profitable carrying trade in this article. Only a part,
  • therefore of the duty called the impost on wine, and no part of the
  • twenty-five pounds the ton upon French wines, or of the duties imposed in
  • 1745, in 1763, and in 1778, were allowed to be drawn back upon
  • exportation. The two imposts of five per cent. imposed in 1779 and 1781,
  • upon all the former duties of customs, being allowed to be wholly drawn
  • back upon the exportation of all other goods, were likewise allowed to be
  • drawn back upon that of wine. The last duty that has been particularly
  • imposed upon wine, that of 1780, is allowed to be wholly drawn back; an
  • indulgence which, when so many heavy duties are retained, most probably
  • could never occasion the exportation of a single ton of wine. These rules
  • took place with regard to all places of lawful exportation, except the
  • British colonies in America.
  • The 15th Charles II, chap. 7, called an act for the encouragement of
  • trade, had given Great Britain the monopoly of supplying the colonies with
  • all the commodities of the growth or manufacture of Europe, and
  • consequently with wines. In a country of so extensive a coast as our North
  • American and West Indian colonies, where our authority was always so very
  • slender, and where the inhabitants were allowed to carry out in their own
  • ships their non-enumerated commodities, at first to all parts of Europe,
  • and afterwards to all parts of Europe south of Cape Finisterre, it is not
  • very probable that this monopoly could ever be much respected; and they
  • probably at all times found means of bringing back some cargo from the
  • countries to which they were allowed to carry out one. They seem, however,
  • to have found some difficulty in importing European wines from the places
  • of their growth; and they could not well import them from Great Britain,
  • where they were loaded with many heavy duties, of which a considerable
  • part was not drawn back upon exportation. Madeira wine, not being an
  • European commodity, could be imported directly into America and the West
  • Indies, countries which, in all their non-enumerated commodities, enjoyed
  • a free trade to the island of Madeira. These circumstances had probably
  • introduced that general taste for Madeira wine, which our officers found
  • established in all our colonies at the commencement of the war which began
  • in 1755, and which they brought back with them to the mother country,
  • where that wine had not been much in fashion before. Upon the conclusion
  • of that war, in 1763 (by the 4th Geo. III, chap. 15, sect. 12), all the
  • duties except £3, 10s. were allowed to be drawn back upon the exportation
  • to the colonies of all wines, except French wines, to the commerce and
  • consumption of which national prejudice would allow no sort of
  • encouragement. The period between the granting of this indulgence and the
  • revolt of our North American colonies, was probably too short to admit of
  • any considerable change in the customs of those countries.
  • The same act which, in the drawbacks upon all wines, except French wines,
  • thus favoured the colonies so much more than other countries, in those
  • upon the greater part of other commodities, favoured them much less. Upon
  • the exportation of the greater part of commodities to other countries,
  • half the old subsidy was drawn back. But this law enacted, that no part of
  • that duty should be drawn back upon the exportation to the colonies of any
  • commodities of the growth or manufacture either of Europe or the East
  • Indies, except wines, white calicoes, and muslins.
  • Drawbacks were, perhaps, originally granted for the encouragement of the
  • carrying trade, which, as the freight of the ship is frequently paid by
  • foreigners in money, was supposed to be peculiarly fitted for bringing
  • gold and silver into the country. But though the carrying trade certainly
  • deserves no peculiar encouragement, though the motive of the institution
  • was, perhaps, abundantly foolish, the institution itself seems reasonable
  • enough. Such drawbacks cannot force into this trade a greater share of the
  • capital of the country than what would have gone to it of its own accord,
  • had there been no duties upon importation; they only prevent its being
  • excluded altogether by those duties. The carrying trade, though it
  • deserves no preference, ought not to be precluded, but to be left free,
  • like all other trades. It is a necessary resource to those capitals which
  • cannot find employment, either in the agriculture or in the manufactures
  • of the country, either in its home trade, or in its foreign trade of
  • consumption.
  • The revenue of the customs, instead of suffering, profits from such
  • drawbacks, by that part of the duty which is retained. If the whole duties
  • had been retained, the foreign goods upon which they are paid could seldom
  • have been exported, nor consequently imported, for want of a market. The
  • duties, therefore, of which a part is retained, would never have been
  • paid.
  • These reasons seem sufficiently to justify drawbacks, and would justify
  • them, though the whole duties, whether upon the produce of domestic
  • industry or upon foreign goods, were always drawn back upon exportation.
  • The revenue of excise would, in this case indeed, suffer a little, and
  • that of the customs a good deal more; but the natural balance of industry,
  • the natural division and distribution of labour, which is always more or
  • less disturbed by such duties, would be more nearly re-established by such
  • a regulation.
  • These reasons, however, will justify drawbacks only upon exporting goods
  • to those countries which are altogether foreign and independent, not to
  • those in which our merchants and manufacturers enjoy a monopoly. A
  • drawback, for example, upon the exportation of European goods to our
  • American colonies, will not always occasion a greater exportation than
  • what would have taken place without it. By means of the monopoly which our
  • merchants and manufacturers enjoy there, the same quantity might
  • frequently, perhaps, be sent thither, though the whole duties were
  • retained. The drawback, therefore, may frequently be pure loss to the
  • revenue of excise and customs, without altering the state of the trade, or
  • rendering it in any respect more extensive. How far such drawbacks can be
  • justified as a proper encouragement to the industry of our colonies, or
  • how far it is advantageous to the mother country that they should be
  • exempted from taxes which are paid by all the rest of their
  • fellow-subjects, will appear hereafter, when I come to treat of colonies.
  • Drawbacks, however, it must always be understood, are useful only in those
  • cases in which the goods, for the exportation of which they are given, are
  • really exported to some foreign country, and not clandestinely re-imported
  • into our own. That some drawbacks, particularly those upon tobacco, have
  • frequently been abused in this manner, and have given occasion to many
  • frauds, equally hurtful both to the revenue and to the fair trader, is
  • well known.
  • CHAPTER V.
  • OF BOUNTIES.
  • Bounties upon exportation are, in Great Britain, frequently petitioned
  • for, and sometimes granted, to the produce of particular branches of
  • domestic industry. By means of them, our merchants and manufacturers, it
  • is pretended, will be enabled to sell their goods as cheap or cheaper than
  • their rivals in the foreign market. A greater quantity, it is said, will
  • thus be exported, and the balance of trade consequently turned more in
  • favour of our own country. We cannot give our workmen a monopoly in the
  • foreign, as we have done in the home market. We cannot force foreigners to
  • buy their goods, as we have done our own countrymen. The next best
  • expedient, it has been thought, therefore, is to pay them for buying. It
  • is in this manner that the mercantile system proposes to enrich the whole
  • country, and to put money into all our pockets, by means of the balance of
  • trade.
  • Bounties, it is allowed, ought to be given to those branches of trade only
  • which cannot be carried on without them. But every branch of trade in
  • which the merchant can sell his goods for a price which replaces to him,
  • with the ordinary profits of stock, the whole capital employed in
  • preparing and sending them to market, can be carried on without a bounty.
  • Every such branch is evidently upon a level with all the other branches of
  • trade which are carried on without bounties, and cannot, therefore,
  • require one more than they. Those trades only require bounties, in which
  • the merchant is obliged to sell his goods for a price which does not
  • replace to him his capital, together with the ordinary profit, or in which
  • he is obliged to sell them for less than it really cost him to send them
  • to market. The bounty is given in order to make up this loss, and to
  • encourage him to continue, or, perhaps, to begin a trade, of which the
  • expense is supposed to be greater than the returns, of which every
  • operation eats up a part of the capital employed in it, and which is of
  • such a nature, that if all other trades resembled it, there would soon be
  • no capital left in the country.
  • The trades, it is to be observed, which are carried on by means of
  • bounties, are the only ones which can be carried on between two nations
  • for any considerable time together, in such a manner as that one of them
  • shall always and regularly lose, or sell its goods for less than it
  • really cost to send them to market. But if the bounty did not repay to the
  • merchant what he would otherwise lose upon the price of his goods, his own
  • interest would soon oblige him to employ his stock in another way, or to
  • find out a trade in which the price of the goods would replace to him,
  • with the ordinary profit, the capital employed in sending them to market.
  • The effect of bounties, like that of all the other expedients of the
  • mercantile system, can only be to force the trade of a country into a
  • channel much less advantageous than that in which it would naturally run
  • of its own accord.
  • The ingenious and well-informed author of the Tracts upon the Corn Trade
  • has shown very clearly, that since the bounty upon the exportation of corn
  • was first established, the price of the corn exported, valued moderately
  • enough, has exceeded that of the corn imported, valued very high, by a
  • much greater sum than the amount of the whole bounties which have been
  • paid during that period. This, he imagines, upon the true principles of
  • the mercantile system, is a clear proof that this forced corn trade is
  • beneficial to the nation, the value of the exportation exceeding that of
  • the importation by a much greater sum than the whole extraordinary expense
  • which the public has been at in order to get it exported. He does not
  • consider that this extraordinary expense, or the bounty, is the smallest
  • part of the expense which the exportation of corn really costs the
  • society. The capital which the farmer employed in raising it must likewise
  • be taken into the account. Unless the price of the corn, when sold in the
  • foreign markets, replaces not only the bounty, but this capital, together
  • with the ordinary profits of stock, the society is a loser by the
  • difference, or the national stock is so much diminished. But the very
  • reason for which it has been thought necessary to grant a bounty, is the
  • supposed insufficiency of the price to do this.
  • The average price of corn, it has been said, has fallen considerably since
  • the establishment of the bounty. That the average price of corn began to
  • fall somewhat towards the end of the last century, and has continued to do
  • so during the course of the sixty-four first years of the present, I have
  • already endeavoured to show. But this event, supposing it to be real, as I
  • believe it to be, must have happened in spite of the bounty, and cannot
  • possibly have happened in consequence of it. It has happened in France, as
  • well as in England, though in France there was not only no bounty, but,
  • till 1764, the exportation of corn was subjected to a general prohibition.
  • This gradual fall in the average price of grain, it is probable,
  • therefore, is ultimately owing neither to the one regulation nor to the
  • other, but to that gradual and insensible rise in the real value of
  • silver, which, in the first book of this discourse, I have endeavoured to
  • show, has taken place in the general market of Europe during the course of
  • the present century. It seems to be altogether impossible that the bounty
  • could ever contribute to lower the price of grain.
  • In years of plenty, it has already been observed, the bounty, by
  • occasioning an extraordinary exportation, necessarily keeps up the price
  • of corn in the home market above what it would naturally fall to. To do so
  • was the avowed purpose of the institution. In years of scarcity, though
  • the bounty is frequently suspended, yet the great exportation which it
  • occasions in years of plenty, must frequently hinder, more or less, the
  • plenty of one year from relieving the scarcity of another. Both in years
  • of plenty and in years of scarcity, therefore, the bounty necessarily
  • tends to raise the money price of corn somewhat higher than it otherwise
  • would be in the home market.
  • That in the actual state of tillage the bounty must necessarily have this
  • tendency, will not, I apprehend, be disputed by any reasonable person. But
  • it has been thought by many people, that it tends to encourage tillage,
  • and that in two different ways; first, by opening a more extensive foreign
  • market to the corn of the farmer, it tends, they imagine, to increase the
  • demand for, and consequently the production of, that commodity; and,
  • secondly by securing to him a better price than he could otherwise expect
  • in the actual state of tillage, it tends, they suppose, to encourage
  • tillage. This double encouragement must they imagine, in a long period of
  • years, occasion such an increase in the production of corn, as may lower
  • its price in the home market, much more than the bounty can raise it in
  • the actual state which tillage may, at the end of that period, happen to
  • be in.
  • I answer, that whatever extension of the foreign market can be occasioned
  • by the bounty must, in every particular year, be altogether at the expense
  • of the home market; as every bushel of corn, which is exported by means of
  • the bounty, and which would not have been exported without the bounty,
  • would have remained in the home market to increase the consumption, and to
  • lower the price of that commodity. The corn bounty, it is to be observed,
  • as well as every other bounty upon exportation, imposes two different
  • taxes upon the people; first, the tax which they are obliged to
  • contribute, in order to pay the bounty; and, secondly, the tax which
  • arises from the advanced price of the commodity in the home market, and
  • which, as the whole body of the people are purchasers of corn, must, in
  • this particular commodity, be paid by the whole body of the people. In
  • this particular commodity, therefore, this second tax is by much the
  • heaviest of the two. Let us suppose that, taking one year with another,
  • the bounty of 5s. upon the exportation of the quarter of wheat raises the
  • price of that commodity in the home market only 6d. the bushel, or 4s. the
  • quarter higher than it otherwise would have been in the actual state of
  • the crop. Even upon this very moderate supposition, the great body of the
  • people, over and above contributing the tax which pays the bounty of 5s.
  • upon every quarter of wheat exported, must pay another of 4s. upon every
  • quarter which they themselves consume. But according to the very well
  • informed author of the Tracts upon the Corn Trade, the average proportion
  • of the corn exported to that consumed at home, is not more than that of
  • one to thirty-one. For every 5s. therefore, which they contribute to the
  • payment of the first tax, they must contribute £6:4s. to the payment of
  • the second. So very heavy a tax upon the first necessary of life-must
  • either reduce the subsistence of the labouring poor, or it must occasion
  • some augmentation in their pecuniary wages, proportionable to that in the
  • pecuniary price of their subsistence. So far as it operates in the one
  • way, it must reduce the ability of the labouring poor to educate and bring
  • up their children, and must, so far, tend to restrain the population of
  • the country. So far as it operates in the other, it must reduce the
  • ability of the employers of the poor, to employ so great a number as they
  • otherwise might do, and must so far tend to restrain the industry of the
  • country. The extraordinary exportation of corn, therefore occasioned by
  • the bounty, not only in every particular year diminishes the home, just as
  • much as it extends the foreign market and consumption, but, by restraining
  • the population and industry of the country, its final tendency is to stint
  • and restrain the gradual extension of the home market; and thereby, in the
  • long-run, rather to diminish than to augment the whole market and
  • consumption of corn.
  • This enhancement of the money price of corn, however, it has been thought,
  • by rendering that commodity more profitable to the farmer, must
  • necessarily encourage its production.
  • I answer, that this might be the case, if the effect of the bounty was to
  • raise the real price of corn, or to enable the farmer, with an equal
  • quantity of it, to maintain a greater number of labourers in the same
  • manner, whether liberal, moderate, or scanty, than other labourers are
  • commonly maintained in his neighbourhood. But neither the bounty, it is
  • evident, nor any other human institution, can have any such effect. It is
  • not the real, but the nominal price of corn, which can in any considerable
  • degree be affected by the bounty. And though the tax, which that
  • institution imposes upon the whole body of the people, may be very
  • burdensome to those who pay it, it is of very little advantage to those
  • who receive it.
  • The real effect of the bounty is not so much to raise the real value of
  • corn, as to degrade the real value of silver; or to make an equal quantity
  • of it exchange for a smaller quantity, not only of corn, but of all other
  • home made commodities; for the money price of corn regulates that of all
  • other home made commodities.
  • It regulates the money price of labour, which must always be such as to
  • enable the labourer to purchase a quantity of corn sufficient to maintain
  • him and his family, either in the liberal, moderate, or scanty manner, in
  • which the advancing, stationary, or declining, circumstances of the
  • society, oblige his employers to maintain him.
  • It regulates the money price of all the other parts of the rude produce of
  • land, which, in every period of improvement, must bear a certain
  • proportion to that of corn, though this proportion is different in
  • different periods. It regulates, for example, the money price of grass and
  • hay, of butcher’s meat, of horses, and the maintenance of horses, of land
  • carriage consequently, or of the greater part of the inland commerce of
  • the country.
  • By regulating the money price of all the other parts of the rude produce
  • of land, it regulates that of the materials of almost all manufactures; by
  • regulating the money price of labour, it regulates that of manufacturing
  • art and industry; and by regulating both, it regulates that of the
  • complete manufacture. The money price of labour, and of every thing that
  • is the produce, either of land or labour, must necessarily either rise or
  • fall in proportion to the money price of corn.
  • Though in consequence of the bounty, therefore, the farmer should be
  • enabled to sell his corn for 4s. the bushel, instead of 3s:6d. and to pay
  • his landlord a money rent proportionable to this rise in the money price
  • of his produce; yet if, in consequence of this rise in the price of corn,
  • 4s. will purchase no more home made goods of any other kind than 3s. 6d.
  • would have done before, neither the circumstances of the farmer, nor those
  • of the landlord, will be much mended by this change. The farmer will not
  • be able to cultivate much better; the landlord will not be able to live
  • much better. In the purchase of foreign commodities, this enhancement in
  • the price of corn may give them some little advantage. In that of home
  • made commodities, it can give them none at all. And almost the whole
  • expense of the farmer, and the far greater part even of that of the
  • landlord, is in home made commodities.
  • That degradation in the value of silver, which is the effect of the
  • fertility of the mines, and which operates equally, or very nearly
  • equally, through the greater part of the commercial world, is a matter of
  • very little consequence to any particular country. The consequent rise of
  • all money prices, though it does not make those who receive them really
  • richer, does not make them really poorer. A service of plate becomes
  • really cheaper, and every thing else remains precisely of the same real
  • value as before.
  • But that degradation in the value of silver, which, being the effect
  • either of the peculiar situation or of the political institutions of a
  • particular country, takes place only in that country, is a matter of very
  • great consequence, which, far from tending to make anybody really richer,
  • tends to make every body really poorer. The rise in the money price of all
  • commodities, which is in this case peculiar to that country, tends to
  • discourage more or less every sort of industry which is carried on within
  • it, and to enable foreign nations, by furnishing almost all sorts of goods
  • for a smaller quantity of silver than its own workmen can afford to do, to
  • undersell them, not only in the foreign, but even in the home market.
  • It is the peculiar situation of Spain and Portugal, as proprietors of the
  • mines, to be the distributers of gold and silver to all the other
  • countries of Europe. Those metals ought naturally, therefore, to be
  • somewhat cheaper in Spain and Portugal than in any other part of Europe.
  • The difference, however, should be no more than the amount of the freight
  • and insurance; and, on account of the great value and small bulk of those
  • metals, their freight is no great matter, and their insurance is the same
  • as that of any other goods of equal value. Spain and Portugal, therefore,
  • could suffer very little from their peculiar situation, if they did not
  • aggravate its disadvantages by their political institutions.
  • Spain by taxing, and Portugal by prohibiting, the exportation of gold and
  • silver, load that exportation with the expense of smuggling, and raise the
  • value of those metals in other countries so much more above what it is in
  • their own, by the whole amount of this expense. When you dam up a stream
  • of water, as soon as the dam is full, as much water must run over the
  • dam-head as if there was no dam at all. The prohibition of exportation
  • cannot detain a greater quantity of gold and silver in Spain and Portugal,
  • than what they can afford to employ, than what the annual produce of their
  • land and labour will allow them to employ, in coin, plate, gilding, and
  • other ornaments of gold and silver. When they have got this quantity, the
  • dam is full, and the whole stream which flows in afterwards must run over.
  • The annual exportation of gold and silver from Spain and Portugal,
  • accordingly, is, by all accounts, notwithstanding these restraints, very
  • near equal to the whole annual importation. As the water, however, must
  • always be deeper behind the dam-head than before it, so the quantity of
  • gold and silver which these restraints detain in Spain and Portugal, must,
  • in proportion to the annual produce of their land and labour, be greater
  • than what is to be found in other countries. The higher and stronger the
  • dam-head, the greater must be the difference in the depth of water behind
  • and before it. The higher the tax, the higher the penalties with which the
  • prohibition is guarded, the more vigilant and severe the police which
  • looks after the execution of the law, the greater must be the difference
  • in the proportion of gold and silver to the annual produce of the land and
  • labour of Spain and Portugal, and to that of other countries. It is said,
  • accordingly, to be very considerable, and that you frequently find there a
  • profusion of plate in houses, where there is nothing else which would in
  • other countries be thought suitable or correspondent to this sort of
  • magnificence. The cheapness of gold and silver, or, what is the same
  • thing, the dearness of all commodities, which is the necessary effect of
  • this redundancy of the precious metals, discourages both the agriculture
  • and manufactures of Spain and Portugal, and enables foreign nations to
  • supply them with many sorts of rude, and with almost all sorts of
  • manufactured produce, for a smaller quantity of gold and silver than what
  • they themselves can either raise or make them for at home. The tax and
  • prohibition operate in two different ways. They not only lower very much
  • the value of the precious metals in Spain and Portugal, but by detaining
  • there a certain quantity of those metals which would otherwise flow over
  • other countries, they keep up their value in those other countries
  • somewhat above what it otherwise would be, and thereby give those
  • countries a double advantage in their commerce with Spain and Portugal.
  • Open the flood-gates, and there will presently be less water above, and
  • more below the dam-head, and it will soon come to a level in both places.
  • Remove the tax and the prohibition, and as the quantity of gold and silver
  • will diminish considerably in Spain and Portugal, so it will increase
  • somewhat in other countries; and the value of those metals, their
  • proportion to the annual produce of land and labour, will soon come to a
  • level, or very near to a level, in all. The loss which Spain and Portugal
  • could sustain by this exportation of their gold and silver, would be
  • altogether nominal and imaginary. The nominal value of their goods, and of
  • the annual produce of their land and labour, would fall, and would be
  • expressed or represented by a smaller quantity of silver than before; but
  • their real value would be the same as before, and would be sufficient to
  • maintain, command, and employ the same quantity of labour. As the nominal
  • value of their goods would fall, the real value of what remained of their
  • gold and silver would rise, and a smaller quantity of those metals would
  • answer all the same purposes of commerce and circulation which had
  • employed a greater quantity before. The gold and silver which would go
  • abroad would not go abroad for nothing, but would bring back an equal
  • value of goods of some kind or other. Those goods, too, would not be all
  • matters of mere luxury and expense, to be consumed by idle people, who
  • produce nothing in return for their consumption. As the real wealth and
  • revenue of idle people would not be augmented by this extraordinary
  • exportation of gold and silver, so neither would their consumption be much
  • augmented by it. Those goods would probably, the greater part of them, and
  • certainly some part of them, consist in materials, tools, and provisions,
  • for the employment and maintenance of industrious people, who would
  • reproduce, with a profit, the full value of their consumption. A part of
  • the dead stock of the society would thus be turned into active stock, and
  • would put into motion a greater quantity of industry than had been
  • employed before. The annual produce of their land and labour would
  • immediately be augmented a little, and in a few years would probably be
  • augmented a great deal; their industry being thus relieved from one of the
  • most oppressive burdens which it at present labours under.
  • The bounty upon the exportation of corn necessarily operates exactly in
  • the same way as this absurd policy of Spain and Portugal. Whatever be the
  • actual state of tillage, it renders our corn somewhat dearer in the home
  • market than it otherwise would be in that state, and somewhat cheaper in
  • the foreign; and as the average money price of corn regulates, more or
  • less, that of all other commodities, it lowers the value of silver
  • considerably in the one, and tends to raise it a little in the other. It
  • enables foreigners, the Dutch in particular, not only to eat our corn
  • cheaper than they otherwise could do, but sometimes to eat it cheaper than
  • even our own people can do upon the same occasions; as we are assured by
  • an excellent authority, that of Sir Matthew Decker. It hinders our own
  • workmen from furnishing their goods for so small a quantity of silver as
  • they otherwise might do, and enables the Dutch to furnish theirs for a
  • smaller. It tends to render our manufactures somewhat dearer in every
  • market, and theirs somewhat cheaper, than they otherwise would be, and
  • consequently to give their industry a double advantage over our own.
  • The bounty, as it raises in the home market, not so much the real, as the
  • nominal price of our corn; as it augments, not the quantity of labour
  • which a certain quantity of corn can maintain and employ, but only the
  • quantity of silver which it will exchange for; it discourages our
  • manufactures, without rendering any considerable service, either to our
  • farmers or country gentlemen. It puts, indeed, a little more money into
  • the pockets of both, and it will perhaps be somewhat difficult to persuade
  • the greater part of them that this is not rendering them a very
  • considerable service. But if this money sinks in its value, in the
  • quantity of labour, provisions, and home-made commodities of all different
  • kinds which it is capable of purchasing, as much as it rises in its
  • quantity, the service will be little more than nominal and imaginary.
  • There is, perhaps, but one set of men in the whole commonwealth to whom
  • the bounty either was or could be essentially serviceable. These were the
  • corn merchants, the exporters and importers of corn. In years of plenty,
  • the bounty necessarily occasioned a greater exportation than would
  • otherwise have taken place; and by hindering the plenty of the one year
  • from relieving the scarcity of another, it occasioned in years of scarcity
  • a greater importation than would otherwise have been necessary. It
  • increased the business of the corn merchant in both; and in the years of
  • scarcity, it not only enabled him to import a greater quantity, but to
  • sell it for a better price, and consequently with a greater profit, than
  • he could otherwise have made, if the plenty of one year had not been more
  • or less hindered from relieving the scarcity of another. It is in this set
  • of men, accordingly, that I have observed the greatest zeal for the
  • continuance or renewal of the bounty.
  • Our country gentlemen, when they imposed the high duties upon the
  • exportation of foreign corn, which in times of moderate plenty amount to a
  • prohibition, and when they established the bounty, seem to have imitated
  • the conduct of our manufacturers. By the one institution, they secured to
  • themselves the monopoly of the home market, and by the other they
  • endeavoured to prevent that market from ever being overstocked with their
  • commodity. By both they endeavoured to raise its real value, in the same
  • manner as our manufacturers had, by the like institutions, raised the real
  • value of many different sorts of manufactured goods. They did not,
  • perhaps, attend to the great and essential difference which nature has
  • established between corn and almost every other sort of goods. When,
  • either by the monopoly of the home market, or by a bounty upon
  • exportation, you enable our woollen or linen manufacturers to sell their
  • goods for somewhat a better price than they otherwise could get for them,
  • you raise, not only the nominal, but the real price of those goods; you
  • render them equivalent to a greater quantity of labour and subsistence;
  • you increase not only the nominal, but the real profit, the real wealth
  • and revenue of those manufacturers; and you enable them, either to live
  • better themselves, or to employ a greater quantity of labour in those
  • particular manufactures. You really encourage those manufactures, and
  • direct towards them a greater quantity of the industry of the country than
  • what would properly go to them of its own accord. But when, by the like
  • institutions, you raise the nominal or money price of corn, you do not
  • raise its real value; you do not increase the real wealth, the real
  • revenue, either of our farmers or country gentlemen; you do not encourage
  • the growth of corn, because you do not enable them to maintain and employ
  • more labourers in raising it. The nature of things has stamped upon corn a
  • real value, which cannot be altered by merely altering its money price. No
  • bounty upon exportation, no monopoly of the home market, can raise that
  • value. The freest competition cannot lower it, Through the world in
  • general, that value is equal to the quantity of labour which it can
  • maintain, and in every particular place it is equal to the quantity of
  • labour which it can maintain in the way, whether liberal, moderate, or
  • scanty, in which labour is commonly maintained in that place. Woollen or
  • linen cloth are not the regulating commodities by which the real value of
  • all other commodities must be finally measured and determined; corn is.
  • The real value of every other commodity is finally measured and determined
  • by the proportion which its average money price bears to the average money
  • price of corn. The real value of corn does not vary with those variations
  • in its average money price, which sometimes occur from one century to
  • another; it is the real value of silver which varies with them.
  • Bounties upon the exportation of any homemade commodity are liable, first,
  • to that general objection which may be made to all the different
  • expedients of the mercantile system; the objection of forcing some part of
  • the industry of the country into a channel less advantageous than that in
  • which it would run of its own accord; and, secondly, to the particular
  • objection of forcing it not only into a channel that is less advantageous,
  • but into one that is actually disadvantageous; the trade which cannot be
  • carried on but by means of a bounty being necessarily a losing trade. The
  • bounty upon the exportation of corn is liable to this further objection,
  • that it can in no respect promote the raising of that particular commodity
  • of which it was meant to encourage the production. When our country
  • gentlemen, therefore, demanded the establishment of the bounty, though
  • they acted in imitation of our merchants and manufacturers, they did not
  • act with that complete comprehension of their own interest, which commonly
  • directs the conduct of those two other orders of people. They loaded the
  • public revenue with a very considerable expense: they imposed a very heavy
  • tax upon the whole body of the people; but they did not, in any sensible
  • degree, increase the real value of their own commodity; and by lowering
  • somewhat the real value of silver, they discouraged, in some degree, the
  • general industry of the country, and, instead of advancing, retarded more
  • or less the improvement of their own lands, which necessarily depend upon
  • the general industry of the country.
  • To encourage the production of any commodity, a bounty upon production,
  • one should imagine, would have a more direct operation than one upon
  • exportation. It would, besides, impose only one tax upon the people, that
  • which they must contribute in order to pay the bounty. Instead of raising,
  • it would tend to lower the price of the commodity in the home market; and
  • thereby, instead of imposing a second tax upon the people, it might, at
  • least in part, repay them for what they had contributed to the first.
  • Bounties upon production, however, have been very rarely granted. The
  • prejudices established by the commercial system have taught us to believe,
  • that national wealth arises more immediately from exportation than from
  • production. It has been more favoured, accordingly, as the more immediate
  • means of bringing money into the country. Bounties upon production, it has
  • been said too, have been found by experience more liable to frauds than
  • those upon exportation. How far this is true, I know not. That bounties
  • upon exportation have been abused, to many fraudulent purposes, is very
  • well known. But it is not the interest of merchants and manufacturers, the
  • great inventors of all these expedients, that the home market should be
  • overstocked with their goods; an event which a bounty upon production
  • might sometimes occasion. A bounty upon exportation, by enabling them to
  • send abroad their surplus part, and to keep up the price of what remains
  • in the home market, effectually prevents this. Of all the expedients of
  • the mercantile system, accordingly, it is the one of which they are the
  • fondest. I have known the different undertakers of some particular works
  • agree privately among themselves to give a bounty out of their own pockets
  • upon the exportation of a certain proportion of the goods which they dealt
  • in. This expedient succeeded so well, that it more than doubled the price
  • of their goods in the home market, notwithstanding a very considerable
  • increase in the produce. The operation of the bounty upon corn must have
  • been wonderfully different, if it has lowered the money price of that
  • commodity.
  • Something like a bounty upon production, however, has been granted upon
  • some particular occasions. The tonnage bounties given to the white herring
  • and whale fisheries may, perhaps, be considered as somewhat of this
  • nature. They tend directly, it may be supposed, to render the goods
  • cheaper in the home market than they otherwise would be. In other
  • respects, their effects, it must be acknowledged, are the same as those of
  • bounties upon exportation. By means of them, a part of the capital of the
  • country is employed in bringing goods to market, of which the price does
  • not repay the cost, together with the ordinary profits of stock.
  • But though the tonnage bounties to those fisheries do not contribute to
  • the opulence of the nation, it may, perhaps, be thought that they
  • contribute to its defence, by augmenting the number of its sailors and
  • shipping. This, it may be alleged, may sometimes be done by means of such
  • bounties, at a much smaller expense than by keeping up a great standing
  • navy, if I may use such an expression, in the same way as a standing army.
  • Notwithstanding these favourable allegations, however, the following
  • considerations dispose me to believe, that in granting at least one of
  • these bounties, the legislature has been very grossly imposed upon:
  • First, The herring-buss bounty seems too large.
  • From the commencement of the winter fishing 1771, to the end of the winter
  • fishing 1781, the tonnage bounty upon the herring-buss fishery has been at
  • thirty shillings the ton. During these eleven years, the whole number of
  • barrels caught by the herring-buss fishery of Scotland amounted to
  • 378,347. The herrings caught and cured at sea are called sea-sticks. In
  • order to render them what are called merchantable herrings, it is
  • necessary to repack them with an additional quantity of salt; and in this
  • case, it is reckoned, that three barrels of sea-sticks are usually
  • repacked into two barrels of merchantable herrings. The number of barrels
  • of merchantable herrings, therefore, caught during these eleven years,
  • will amount only, according to this account, to 252,231¼. During these
  • eleven years, the tonnage bounties paid amounted to £155,463:11s. or
  • 8s:2¼d. upon every barrel of sea-sticks, and to 12s:3¾d. upon every barrel
  • of merchantable herrings.
  • The salt with which these herrings are cured is sometimes Scotch, and
  • sometimes foreign salt; both which are delivered, free of all excise duty,
  • to the fish-curers. The excise duty upon Scotch salt is at present 1s:6d.,
  • that upon foreign salt 10s. the bushel. A barrel of herrings is supposed
  • to require about one bushel and one-fourth of a bushel foreign salt. Two
  • bushels are the supposed average of Scotch salt. If the herrings are
  • entered for exportation, no part of this duty is paid up; if entered for
  • home consumption, whether the herrings were cured with foreign or with
  • Scotch salt, only one shilling the barrel is paid up. It was the old
  • Scotch duty upon a bushel of salt, the quantity which, at a low
  • estimation, had been supposed necessary for curing a barrel of herrings.
  • In Scotland, foreign salt is very little used for any other purpose but
  • the curing of fish. But from the 5th April 1771 to the 5th April 1782, the
  • quantity of foreign salt imported amounted to 936,974 bushels, at
  • eighty-four pounds the bushel; the quantity of Scotch salt delivered from
  • the works to the fish-curers, to no more than 168,226, at fifty-six pounds
  • the bushel only. It would appear, therefore, that it is principally
  • foreign salt that is used in the fisheries. Upon every barrel of herrings
  • exported, there is, besides, a bounty of 2s:8d. and more than two-thirds
  • of the buss-caught herrings are exported. Put all these things together,
  • and you will find that, during these eleven years, every barrel of
  • buss-caught herrings, cured with Scotch salt, when exported, has cost
  • government 17s:11¾d.; and, when entered for home consumption, 14s:3¾d.;
  • and that every barrel cured with foreign salt, when exported, has cost
  • government £1:7:5¾d.; and, when entered for home consumption, £1:3:9¾d.
  • The price of a barrel of good merchantable herrings runs from seventeen
  • and eighteen to four and five-and-twenty shillings; about a guinea at an
  • average. {See the accounts at the end of this Book.}
  • Secondly, The bounty to the white-herring fishery is a tonnage bounty, and
  • is proportioned to the burden of the ship, not to her diligence or success
  • in the fishery; and it has, I am afraid, been too common for the vessels
  • to fit out for the sole purpose of catching, not the fish but the bounty.
  • In the year 1759, when the bounty was at fifty shillings the ton, the
  • whole buss fishery of Scotland brought in only four barrels of sea-sticks.
  • In that year, each barrel of sea-sticks cost government, in bounties
  • alone, £113:15s.; each barrel of merchantable herrings £159:7:6.
  • Thirdly, The mode of fishing, for which this tonnage bounty in the white
  • herring fishery has been given (by busses or decked vessels from twenty to
  • eighty tons burden ), seems not so well adapted to the situation of
  • Scotland, as to that of Holland, from the practice of which country it
  • appears to have been borrowed. Holland lies at a great distance from the
  • seas to which herrings are known principally to resort, and can,
  • therefore, carry on that fishery only in decked vessels, which can carry
  • water and provisions sufficient for a voyage to a distant sea; but the
  • Hebrides, or Western Islands, the islands of Shetland, and the northern
  • and north-western coasts of Scotland, the countries in whose neighbourhood
  • the herring fishery is principally carried on, are everywhere intersected
  • by arms of the sea, which run up a considerable way into the land, and
  • which, in the language of the country, are called sea-lochs. It is to
  • these sea-lochs that the herrings principally resort during the seasons in
  • which they visit these seas; for the visits of this, and, I am assured, of
  • many other sorts of fish, are not quite regular and constant. A
  • boat-fishery, therefore, seems to be the mode of fishing best adapted to
  • the peculiar situation of Scotland, the fishers carrying the herrings on
  • shore as fast as they are taken, to be either cured or consumed fresh. But
  • the great encouragement which a bounty of 30s. the ton gives to the
  • buss-fishery, is necessarily a discouragement to the boat-fishery, which,
  • having no such bounty, cannot bring its cured fish to market upon the same
  • terms as the buss-fishery. The boat-fishery; accordingly, which, before
  • the establishment of the buss-bounty, was very considerable, and is said
  • to have employed a number of seamen, not inferior to what the buss-fishery
  • employs at present, is now gone almost entirely to decay. Of the former
  • extent, however, of this now ruined and abandoned fishery, I must
  • acknowledge that I cannot pretend to speak with much precision. As no
  • bounty was-paid upon the outfit of the boat-fishery, no account was taken
  • of it by the officers of the customs or salt duties.
  • Fourthly, In many parts of Scotland, during certain seasons of the year,
  • herrings make no inconsiderable part of the food of the common people. A
  • bounty which tended to lower their price in the home market, might
  • contribute a good deal to the relief of a great number of our
  • fellow-subjects, whose circumstances are by no means affluent. But the
  • herring-bus bounty contributes to no such good purpose. It has ruined the
  • boat fishery, which is by far the best adapted for the supply of the home
  • market; and the additional bounty of 2s:8d. the barrel upon exportation,
  • carries the greater part, more than two-thirds, of the produce of the
  • buss-fishery abroad. Between thirty and forty years ago, before the
  • establishment of the buss-bounty, 16s. the barrel, I have been assured,
  • was the common price of white herrings. Between ten and fifteen years ago,
  • before the boat-fishery was entirely ruined, the price was said to have
  • run from seventeen to twenty shillings the barrel. For these last five
  • years, it has, at an average, been at twenty-five shillings the barrel.
  • This high price, however, may have been owing to the real scarcity of the
  • herrings upon the coast of Scotland. I must observe, too, that the cask or
  • barrel, which is usually sold with the herrings, and of which the price is
  • included in all the foregoing prices, has, since the commencement of the
  • American war, risen to about double its former price, or from about 3s. to
  • about 6s. I must likewise observe, that the accounts I have received of
  • the prices of former times, have been by no means quite uniform and
  • consistent, and an old man of great accuracy and experience has assured
  • me, that, more than fifty years ago, a guinea was the usual price of a
  • barrel of good merchantable herrings; and this, I imagine, may still be
  • looked upon as the average price. All accounts, however, I think, agree
  • that the price has not been lowered in the home market in consequence of
  • the buss-bounty.
  • When the undertakers of fisheries, after such liberal bounties have been
  • bestowed upon them, continue to sell their commodity at the same, or even
  • at a higher price than they were accustomed to do before, it might be
  • expected that their profits should be very great; and it is not improbable
  • that those of some individuals may have been so. In general, however, I
  • have every reason to believe they have been quite otherwise. The usual
  • effect of such bounties is, to encourage rash undertakers to adventure in
  • a business which they do not understand; and what they lose by their own
  • negligence and ignorance, more than compensates all that they can gain by
  • the utmost liberality of government. In 1750, by the same act which first
  • gave the bounty of 30s. the ton for the encouragement of the white herring
  • fishery (the 23d Geo. II. chap. 24), a joint stock company was erected,
  • with a capital of £500,000, to which the subscribers (over and above all
  • other encouragements, the tonnage bounty just now mentioned, the
  • exportation bounty of 2s:8d. the barrel, the delivery of both British and
  • foreign salt duty free) were, during the space of fourteen years, for
  • every hundred pounds which they subscribed and paid into the stock of the
  • society, entitled to three pounds a-year, to be paid by the
  • receiver-general of the customs in equal half-yearly payments. Besides
  • this great company, the residence of whose governor and directors was to
  • be in London, it was declared lawful to erect different fishing chambers
  • in all the different out-ports of the kingdom, provided a sum not less
  • than £10,000 was subscribed into the capital of each, to be managed at its
  • own risk, and for its own profit and loss. The same annuity, and the same
  • encouragements of all kinds, were given to the trade of those inferior
  • chambers as to that of the great company. The subscription of the great
  • company was soon filled up, and several different fishing chambers were
  • erected in the different out-ports of the kingdom. In spite of all these
  • encouragements, almost all those different companies, both great and
  • small, lost either the whole or the greater part of their capitals; scarce
  • a vestige now remains of any of them, and the white-herring fishery is now
  • entirely, or almost entirely, carried on by private adventurers.
  • If any particular manufacture was necessary, indeed, for the defence of
  • the society, it might not always be prudent to depend upon our neighbours
  • for the supply; and if such manufacture could not otherwise be supported
  • at home, it might not be unreasonable that all the other branches of
  • industry should be taxed in order to support it. The bounties upon the
  • exportation of British made sail-cloth, and British made gunpowder, may,
  • perhaps, both be vindicated upon this principle.
  • But though it can very seldom be reasonable to tax the industry of the
  • great body of the people, in order to support that of some particular
  • class of manufacturers; yet, in the wantonness of great prosperity, when
  • the public enjoys a greater revenue than it knows well what to do with, to
  • give such bounties to favourite manufactures, may, perhaps, be as natural
  • as to incur any other idle expense. In public, as well as in private
  • expenses, great wealth, may, perhaps, frequently be admitted as an apology
  • for great folly. But there must surely be something more than ordinary
  • absurdity in continuing such profusion in times of general difficulty and
  • distress.
  • What is called a bounty, is sometimes no more than a drawback, and,
  • consequently, is not liable to the same objections as what is properly a
  • bounty. The bounty, for example, upon refined sugar exported, may be
  • considered as a drawback of the duties upon the brown and Muscovado
  • sugars, from which it is made; the bounty upon wrought silk exported, a
  • drawback of the duties upon raw and thrown silk imported; the bounty upon
  • gunpowder exported, a drawback of the duties upon brimstone and saltpetre
  • imported. In the language of the customs, those allowances only are called
  • drawbacks which are given upon goods exported in the same form in which
  • they are imported. When that form has been so altered by manufacture of
  • any kind as to come under a new denomination, they are called bounties.
  • Premiums given by the public to artists and manufacturers, who excel in
  • their particular occupations, are not liable to the same objections as
  • bounties. By encouraging extraordinary dexterity and ingenuity, they serve
  • to keep up the emulation of the workmen actually employed in those
  • respective occupations, and are not considerable enough to turn towards
  • any one of them a greater share of the capital of the country than what
  • would go to it of its own accord. Their tendency is not to overturn the
  • natural balance of employments, but to render the work which is done in
  • each as perfect and complete as possible. The expense of premiums,
  • besides, is very trifling, that of bounties very great. The bounty upon
  • corn alone has sometimes cost the public, in one year, more than £300,000.
  • Bounties are sometimes called premiums, as drawbacks are sometimes called
  • bounties. But we must, in all cases, attend to the nature of the thing,
  • without paying any regard to the word.
  • Digression concerning the Corn Trade and Corn Laws.
  • I cannot conclude this chapter concerning bounties, without observing,
  • that the praises which have been bestowed upon the law which establishes
  • the bounty upon the exportation of corn, and upon that system of
  • regulations which is connected with it, are altogether unmerited. A
  • particular examination of the nature of the corn trade, and of the
  • principal British laws which relate to it, will sufficiently demonstrate
  • the truth of this assertion. The great importance of this subject must
  • justify the length of the digression.
  • The trade of the corn merchant is composed of four different branches,
  • which, though they may sometimes be all carried on by the same person,
  • are, in their own nature, four separate and distinct trades. These are,
  • first, the trade of the inland dealer; secondly, that of the
  • merchant-importer for home consumption; thirdly, that of the
  • merchant-exporter of home produce for foreign consumption; and, fourthly,
  • that of the merchant-carrier, or of the importer of corn, in order to
  • export it again.
  • I. The interest of the inland dealer, and that of the great body of the
  • people, how opposite soever they may at first appear, are, even in years
  • of the greatest scarcity, exactly the same. It is his interest to raise
  • the price of his corn as high as the real scarcity of the season requires,
  • and it can never be his interest to raise it higher. By raising the price,
  • he discourages the consumption, and puts every body more or less, but
  • particularly the inferior ranks of people, upon thrift and good management
  • If, by raising it too high, he discourages the consumption so much that
  • the supply of the season is likely to go beyond the consumption of the
  • season, and to last for some time after the next crop begins to come in,
  • he runs the hazard, not only of losing a considerable part of his corn by
  • natural causes, but of being obliged to sell what remains of it for much
  • less than what he might have had for it several months before. If, by not
  • raising the price high enough, he discourages the consumption so little,
  • that the supply of the season is likely to fall short of the consumption
  • of the season, he not only loses a part of the profit which he might
  • otherwise have made, but he exposes the people to suffer before the end of
  • the season, instead of the hardships of a dearth, the dreadful horrors of
  • a famine. It is the interest of the people that their daily, weekly, and
  • monthly consumption should be proportioned as exactly as possible to the
  • supply of the season. The interest of the inland corn dealer is the same.
  • By supplying them, as nearly as he can judge, in this proportion, he is
  • likely to sell all his corn for the highest price, and with the greatest
  • profit; and his knowledge of the state of the crop, and of his daily,
  • weekly, and monthly sales, enables him to judge, with more or less
  • accuracy, how far they really are supplied in this manner. Without
  • intending the interest of the people, he is necessarily led, by a regard
  • to his own interest, to treat them, even in years of scarcity, pretty much
  • in the same manner as the prudent master of a vessel is sometimes obliged
  • to treat his crew. When he foresees that provisions are likely to run
  • short, he puts them upon short allowance. Though from excess of caution he
  • should sometimes do this without any real necessity, yet all the
  • inconveniencies which his crew can thereby suffer are inconsiderable, in
  • comparison of the danger, misery, and ruin, to which they might sometimes
  • be exposed by a less provident conduct. Though, from excess of avarice, in
  • the same manner, the inland corn merchant should sometimes raise the price
  • of his corn somewhat higher than the scarcity of the season requires, yet
  • all the inconveniencies which the people can suffer from this conduct,
  • which effectually secures them from a famine in the end of the season, are
  • inconsiderable, in comparison of what they might have been exposed to by a
  • more liberal way of dealing in the beginning of it the corn merchant
  • himself is likely to suffer the most by this excess of avarice; not only
  • from the indignation which it generally excites against him, but, though
  • he should escape the effects of this indignation, from the quantity of
  • corn which it necessarily leaves upon his hands in the end of the season,
  • and which, if the next season happens to prove favourable, he must always
  • sell for a much lower price than he might otherwise have had.
  • Were it possible, indeed, for one great company of merchants to possess
  • themselves of the whole crop of an extensive country, it might perhaps be
  • their interest to deal with it, as the Dutch are said to do with the
  • spiceries of the Moluccas, to destroy or throw away a considerable part of
  • it, in order to keep up the price of the rest. But it is scarce possible,
  • even by the violence of law, to establish such an extensive monopoly with
  • regard to corn; and wherever the law leaves the trade free, it is of all
  • commodities the least liable to be engrossed or monopolized by the forced
  • a few large capitals, which buy up the greater part of it. Not only its
  • value far exceeds what the capitals of a few private men are capable of
  • purchasing; but, supposing they were capable of purchasing it, the manner
  • in which it is produced renders this purchase altogether impracticable.
  • As, in every civilized country, it is the commodity of which the annual
  • consumption is the greatest; so a greater quantity of industry is annually
  • employed in producing corn than in producing any other commodity. When it
  • first comes from the ground, too, it is necessarily divided among a
  • greater number of owners than any other commodity; and these owners can
  • never be collected into one place, like a number of independent
  • manufacturers, but are necessarily scattered through all the different
  • corners of the country. These first owners either immediately supply the
  • consumers in their own neighbourhood, or they supply other inland dealers,
  • who supply those consumers. The inland dealers in corn, therefore,
  • including both the farmer and the baker, are necessarily more numerous
  • than the dealers in any other commodity; and their dispersed situation
  • renders it altogether impossible for them to enter into any general
  • combination. If, in a year of scarcity, therefore, any of them should find
  • that he had a good deal more corn upon hand than, at the current price, he
  • could hope to dispose of before the end of the season, he would never
  • think of keeping up this price to his own loss, and to the sole benefit of
  • his rivals and competitors, but would immediately lower it, in order to
  • get rid of his corn before the new crop began to come in. The same
  • motives, the same interests, which would thus regulate the conduct of any
  • one dealer, would regulate that of every other, and oblige them all in
  • general to sell their corn at the price which, according to the best of
  • their judgment, was most suitable to the scarcity or plenty of the season.
  • Whoever examines, with attention, the history of the dearths and famines
  • which have afflicted any part of Europe during either the course of the
  • present or that of the two preceding centuries, of several of which we
  • have pretty exact accounts, will find, I believe, that a dearth never has
  • arisen from any combination among the inland dealers in corn, nor from any
  • other cause but a real scarcity, occasioned sometimes, perhaps, and in
  • some particular places, by the waste of war, but in by far the greatest
  • number of cases by the fault of the seasons; and that a famine has never
  • arisen from any other cause but the violence of government attempting, by
  • improper means, to remedy the inconveniencies of a dearth.
  • In an extensive corn country, between all the different parts of which
  • there is a free commerce and communication, the scarcity occasioned by the
  • most unfavourable seasons can never be so great as to produce a famine;
  • and the scantiest crop, if managed with frugality and economy, will
  • maintain, through the year, the same number of people that are commonly
  • fed in a more affluent manner by one of moderate plenty. The seasons most
  • unfavourable to the crop are those of excessive drought or excessive rain.
  • But as corn grows equally upon high and low lands, upon grounds that are
  • disposed to be too wet, and upon those that are disposed to be too dry,
  • either the drought or the rain, which is hurtful to one part of the
  • country, is favourable to another; and though, both in the wet and in the
  • dry season, the crop is a good deal less than in one more properly
  • tempered; yet, in both, what is lost in one part of the country is in some
  • measure compensated by what is gained in the other. In rice countries,
  • where the crop not only requires a very moist soil, but where, in a
  • certain period of its growing, it must be laid under water, the effects of
  • a drought are much more dismal. Even in such countries, however, the
  • drought is, perhaps, scarce ever so universal as necessarily to occasion a
  • famine, if the government would allow a free trade. The drought in Bengal,
  • a few years ago, might probably have occasioned a very great dearth. Some
  • improper regulations, some injudicious restraints, imposed by the servants
  • of the East India Company upon the rice trade, contributed, perhaps, to
  • turn that dearth into a famine.
  • When the government, in order to remedy the inconveniencies of a dearth,
  • orders all the dealers to sell their corn at what it supposes a reasonable
  • price, it either hinders them from bringing it to market, which may
  • sometimes produce a famine even in the beginning of the season; or, if
  • they bring it thither, it enables the people, and thereby encourages them
  • to consume it so fast as must necessarily produce a famine before the end
  • of the season. The unlimited, unrestrained freedom of the corn trade, as
  • it is the only effectual preventive of the miseries of a famine, so it is
  • the best palliative of the inconveniencies of a dearth; for the
  • inconveniencies of a real scarcity cannot be remedied; they can only be
  • palliated. No trade deserves more the full protection of the law, and no
  • trade requires it so much; because no trade is so much exposed to popular
  • odium.
  • In years of scarcity, the inferior ranks of people impute their distress
  • to the avarice of the corn merchant, who becomes the object of their
  • hatred and indignation. Instead of making profit upon such occasions,
  • therefore, he is often in danger of being utterly ruined, and of having
  • his magazines plundered and destroyed by their violence. It is in years of
  • scarcity, however, when prices are high, that the corn merchant expects to
  • make his principal profit. He is generally in contract with some farmers
  • to furnish him, for a certain number of years, with a certain quantity of
  • corn, at a certain price. This contract price is settled according to what
  • is supposed to be the moderate and reasonable, that is, the ordinary or
  • average price, which, before the late years of scarcity, was commonly
  • about 28s. for the quarter of wheat, and for that of other grain in
  • proportion. In years of scarcity, therefore, the corn merchant buys a
  • great part of his corn for the ordinary price, and sells it for a much
  • higher. That this extraordinary profit, however, is no more than
  • sufficient to put his trade upon a fair level with other trades, and to
  • compensate the many losses which he sustains upon other occasions, both
  • from the perishable nature of the commodity itself, and from the frequent
  • and unforeseen fluctuations of its price, seems evident enough, from this
  • single circumstance, that great fortunes are as seldom made in this as in
  • any other trade. The popular odium, however, which attends it in years of
  • scarcity, the only years in which it can be very profitable, renders
  • people of character and fortune averse to enter into it. It is abandoned
  • to an inferior set of dealers; and millers, bakers, meal-men, and
  • meal-factors, together with a number of wretched hucksters, are almost the
  • only middle people that, in the home market, come between the grower and
  • the consumer.
  • The ancient policy of Europe, instead of discountenancing this popular
  • odium against a trade so beneficial to the public, seems, on the contrary,
  • to have authorised and encouraged it.
  • By the 5th and 6th of Edward VI cap. 14, it was enacted, that whoever
  • should buy any corn or grain, with intent to sell it again, should be
  • reputed an unlawful engrosser, and should, for the first fault, suffer two
  • months imprisonment, and forfeit the value of the corn; for the second,
  • suffer six months imprisonment, and forfeit double the value; and, for the
  • third, be set in the pillory, suffer imprisonment during the king’s
  • pleasure, and forfeit all his goods and chattels. The ancient policy of
  • most other parts of Europe was no better than that of England.
  • Our ancestors seem to have imagined, that the people would buy their corn
  • cheaper of the farmer than of the corn merchant, who, they were afraid,
  • would require, over and above the price which he paid to the farmer, an
  • exorbitant profit to himself. They endeavoured, therefore, to annihilate
  • his trade altogether. They even endeavoured to hinder, as much as
  • possible, any middle man of any kind from coming in between the grower and
  • the consumer; and this was the meaning of the many restraints which they
  • imposed upon the trade of those whom they called kidders, or carriers of
  • corn; a trade which nobody was allowed to exercise without a licence,
  • ascertaining his qualifications as a man of probity and fair dealing. The
  • authority of three justices of the peace was, by the statute of Edward VI.
  • necessary in order to grant this licence. But even this restraint was
  • afterwards thought insufficient, and, by a statute of Elizabeth, the
  • privilege of granting it was confined to the quarter-sessions.
  • The ancient policy of Europe endeavoured, in this manner, to regulate
  • agriculture, the great trade of the country, by maxims quite different
  • from those which it established with regard to manufactures, the great
  • trade of the towns. By leaving a farmer no other customers but either the
  • consumers or their immediate factors, the kidders and carriers of corn, it
  • endeavoured to force him to exercise the trade, not only of a farmer, but
  • of a corn merchant, or corn retailer. On the contrary, it, in many cases,
  • prohibited the manufacturer from exercising the trade of a shopkeeper, or
  • from selling his own goods by retail. It meant, by the one law, to promote
  • the general interest of the country, or to render corn cheap, without,
  • perhaps, its being well understood how this was to be done. By the other,
  • it meant to promote that of a particular order of men, the shopkeepers,
  • who would be so much undersold by the manufacturer, it was supposed, that
  • their trade would be ruined, if he was allowed to retail at all.
  • The manufacturer, however, though he had been allowed to keep a shop, and
  • to sell his own goods by retail, could not have undersold the common
  • shopkeeper. Whatever part of his capital he might have placed in his shop,
  • he must have withdrawn it from his manufacture. In order to carry on his
  • business on a level with that of other people, as he must have had the
  • profit of a manufacturer on the one part, so he must have had that of a
  • shopkeeper upon the other. Let us suppose, for example, that in the
  • particular town where he lived, ten per cent. was the ordinary profit both
  • of manufacturing and shopkeeping stock; he must in this case have charged
  • upon every piece of his own goods, which he sold in his shop, a profit of
  • twenty per cent. When he carried them from his workhouse to his shop, he
  • must have valued them at the price for which he could have sold them to a
  • dealer or shopkeeper, who would have bought them by wholesale. If he
  • valued them lower, he lost a part of the profit of his manufacturing
  • capital. When, again, he sold them from his shop, unless he got the same
  • price at which a shopkeeper would have sold them, he lost a part of the
  • profit of his shop-keeping capital. Though he might appear, therefore, to
  • make a double profit upon the same piece of goods, yet, as these goods
  • made successively a part of two distinct capitals, he made but a single
  • profit upon the whole capital employed about them; and if he made less
  • than his profit, he was a loser, and did not employ his whole capital with
  • the same advantage as the greater part of his neighbours.
  • What the manufacturer was prohibited to do, the farmer was in some measure
  • enjoined to do; to divide his capital between two different employments;
  • to keep one part of it in his granaries and stack-yard, for supplying the
  • occasional demands of the market, and to employ the other in the
  • cultivation of his land. But as he could not afford to employ the latter
  • for less than the ordinary profits of farming stock, so he could as little
  • afford to employ the former for less than the ordinary profits of
  • mercantile stock. Whether the stock which really carried on the business
  • of a corn merchant belonged to the person who was called a farmer, or to
  • the person who was called a corn merchant, an equal profit was in both
  • cases requisite, in order to indemnify its owner for employing it in this
  • manner, in order to put his business on a level with other trades, and in
  • order to hinder him from having an interest to change it as soon as
  • possible for some other. The farmer, therefore, who was thus forced to
  • exercise the trade of a corn merchant, could not afford to sell his corn
  • cheaper than any other corn merchant would have been obliged to do in the
  • case of a free competition.
  • The dealer who can employ his whole stock in one single branch of
  • business, has an advantage of the same kind with the workman who can
  • employ his whole labour in one single operation. As the latter acquires a
  • dexterity which enables him, with the same two hands, to perform a much
  • greater quantity of work, so the former acquires so easy and ready a
  • method of transacting his business, of buying and disposing of his goods,
  • that with the same capital he can transact a much greater quantity of
  • business. As the one can commonly afford his work a good deal cheaper, so
  • the other can commonly afford his goods somewhat cheaper, than if his
  • stock and attention were both employed about a greater variety of objects.
  • The greater part of manufacturers could not afford to retail their own
  • goods so cheap as a vigilant and active shopkeeper, whose sole business it
  • was to buy them by wholesale and to retail them again. The greater part of
  • farmers could still less afford to retail their own corn, to supply the
  • inhabitants of a town, at perhaps four or five miles distance from the
  • greater part of them, so cheap as a vigilant and active corn merchant,
  • whose sole business it was to purchase corn by wholesale, to collect it
  • into a great magazine, and to retail it again.
  • The law which prohibited the manufacturer from exercising the trade of a
  • shopkeeper, endeavoured to force this division in the employment of stock
  • to go on faster than it might otherwise have done. The law which obliged
  • the farmer to exercise the trade of a corn merchant, endeavoured to hinder
  • it from going on so fast. Both laws were evident violations of natural
  • liberty, and therefore unjust; and they were both, too, as impolitic as
  • they were unjust. It is the interest of every society, that things of this
  • kind should never either he forced or obstructed. The man who employs
  • either his labour or his stock in a greater variety of ways than his
  • situation renders necessary, can never hurt his neighbour by underselling
  • him. He may hurt himself, and he generally does so. Jack-of-all-trades
  • will never be rich, says the proverb. But the law ought always to trust
  • people with the care of their own interest, as in their local situations
  • they must generally be able to judge better of it than the legislature can
  • do. The law, however, which obliged the farmer to exercise the trade of a
  • corn merchant was by far the most pernicious of the two.
  • It obstructed not only that division in the employment of stock which is
  • so advantageous to every society, but it obstructed likewise the
  • improvement and cultivation of the land. By obliging the farmer to carry
  • on two trades instead of one, it forced him to divide his capital into two
  • parts, of which one only could be employed in cultivation. But if he had
  • been at liberty to sell his whole crop to a corn merchant as fast as he
  • could thresh it out, his whole capital might have returned immediately to
  • the land, and have been employed in buying more cattle, and hiring more
  • servants, in order to improve and cultivate it better. But by being
  • obliged to sell his corn by retail, he was obliged to keep a great part of
  • his capital in his granaries and stack-yard through the year, and could
  • not therefore cultivate so well as with the same capital he might
  • otherwise have done. This law, therefore, necessarily obstructed the
  • improvement of the land, and, instead of tending to render corn cheaper,
  • must have tended to render it scarcer, and therefore dearer, than it would
  • otherwise have been.
  • After the business of the farmer, that of the corn merchant is in reality
  • the trade which, if properly protected and encouraged, would contribute
  • the most to the raising of corn. It would support the trade of the farmer,
  • in the same manner as the trade of the wholesale dealer supports that of
  • the manufacturer.
  • The wholesale dealer, by affording a ready market to the manufacturer, by
  • taking his goods off his hand as fast as he can make them, and by
  • sometimes even advancing their price to him before he has made them,
  • enables him to keep his whole capital, and sometimes even more than his
  • whole capital, constantly employed in manufacturing, and consequently to
  • manufacture a much greater quantity of goods than if he was obliged to
  • dispose of them himself to the immediate consumers, or even to the
  • retailers. As the capital of the wholesale merchant, too, is generally
  • sufficient to replace that of many manufacturers, this intercourse between
  • him and them interests the owner of a large capital to support the owners
  • of a great number of small ones, and to assist them in those losses and
  • misfortunes which might otherwise prove ruinous to them.
  • An intercourse of the same kind universally established between the
  • farmers and the corn merchants, would be attended with effects equally
  • beneficial to the farmers. They would be enabled to keep their whole
  • capitals, and even more than their whole capitals constantly employed in
  • cultivation. In case of any of those accidents to which no trade is more
  • liable than theirs, they would find in their ordinary customer, the
  • wealthy corn merchant, a person who had both an interest to support them,
  • and the ability to do it; and they would not, as at present, be entirely
  • dependent upon the forbearance of their landlord, or the mercy of his
  • steward. Were it possible, as perhaps it is not, to establish this
  • intercourse universally, and all at once; were it possible to turn all at
  • once the whole farming stock of the kingdom to its proper business, the
  • cultivation of land, withdrawing it from every other employment into which
  • any part of it may be at present diverted; and were it possible, in order
  • to support and assist, upon occasion, the operations of this great stock,
  • to provide all at once another stock almost equally great; it is not,
  • perhaps, very easy to imagine how great, how extensive, and how sudden,
  • would be the improvement which this change of circumstances would alone
  • produce upon the whole face of the country.
  • The statute of Edward VI. therefore, by prohibiting as much as possible
  • any middle man from coming in between the grower and the consumer,
  • endeavoured to annihilate a trade, of which the free exercise is not only
  • the best palliative of the inconveniencies of a dearth, but the best
  • preventive of that calamity; after the trade of the farmer, no trade
  • contributing so much to the growing of corn as that of the corn merchant.
  • The rigour of this law was afterwards softened by several subsequent
  • statutes, which successively permitted the engrossing of corn when the
  • price of wheat should not exceed 20s. and 24s. 32s. and 40s. the quarter.
  • At last, by the 15th of Charles II. c.7, the engrossing or buying of corn,
  • in order to sell it again, as long as the price of wheat did not exceed
  • 48s. the quarter, and that of other grain in proportion, was declared
  • lawful to all persons not being forestallers, that is, not selling again
  • in the same market within three months. All the freedom which the trade of
  • the inland corn dealer has ever yet enjoyed was bestowed upon it by this
  • statute. The statute of the twelfth of the present king, which repeals
  • almost all the other ancient laws against engrossers and forestallers,
  • does not repeal the restrictions of this particular statute, which
  • therefore still continue in force.
  • This statute, however, authorises in some measure two very absurd popular
  • prejudices.
  • First, It supposes, that when the price of wheat has risen so high as 48s.
  • the quarter, and that of other grain in proportion, corn is likely to be
  • so engrossed as to hurt the people. But, from what has been already said,
  • it seems evident enough, that corn can at no price be so engrossed by the
  • inland dealers as to hurt the people; and 48s. the quarter, besides,
  • though it may be considered as a very high price, yet, in years of
  • scarcity, it is a price which frequently takes place immediately after
  • harvest, when scarce any part of the new crop can be sold off, and when it
  • is impossible even for ignorance to suppose that any part of it can be so
  • engrossed as to hurt the people.
  • Secondly, It supposes that there is a certain price at which corn is
  • likely to be forestalled, that is, bought up in order to be sold again
  • soon after in the same market, so as to hurt the people. But if a merchant
  • ever buys up corn, either going to a particular market, or in a particular
  • market, in order to sell it again soon after in the same market, it must
  • be because he judges that the market cannot be so liberally supplied
  • through the whole season as upon that particular occasion, and that the
  • price, therefore, must soon rise. If he judges wrong in this, and if the
  • price does not rise, he not only loses the whole profit of the stock which
  • he employs in this manner, but a part of the stock itself, by the expense
  • and loss which necessarily attend the storing and keeping of corn. He
  • hurts himself, therefore, much more essentially than he can hurt even the
  • particular people whom he may hinder from supplying themselves upon that
  • particular market day, because they may afterwards supply themselves just
  • as cheap upon any other market day. If he judges right, instead of hurting
  • the great body of the people, he renders them a most important service. By
  • making them feel the inconveniencies of a dearth somewhat earlier than
  • they otherwise might do, he prevents their feeling them afterwards so
  • severely as they certainly would do, if the cheapness of price encouraged
  • them to consume faster than suited the real scarcity of the season. When
  • the scarcity is real, the best thing that can be done for the people is,
  • to divide the inconvenience of it as equally as possible, through all the
  • different months and weeks and days of the year. The interest of the corn
  • merchant makes him study to do this as exactly as he can; and as no other
  • person can have either the same interest, or the same knowledge, or the
  • same abilities, to do it so exactly as he, this most important operation
  • of commerce ought to be trusted entirely to him; or, in other words, the
  • corn trade, so far at least as concerns the supply of the home market,
  • ought to be left perfectly free.
  • The popular fear of engrossing and forestalling may be compared to the
  • popular terrors and suspicions of witchcraft. The unfortunate wretches
  • accused of this latter crime were not more innocent of the misfortunes
  • imputed to them, than those who have been accused of the former. The law
  • which put an end to all prosecutions against witchcraft, which put it out
  • of any man’s power to gratify his own malice by accusing his neighbour of
  • that imaginary crime, seems effectually to have put an end to those fears
  • and suspicions, by taking away the great cause which encouraged and
  • supported them. The law which would restore entire freedom to the inland
  • trade of corn, would probably prove as effectual to put an end to the
  • popular fears of engrossing and forestalling.
  • The 15th of Charles II. c. 7, however, with all its imperfections, has,
  • perhaps, contributed more, both to the plentiful supply of the home
  • market, and to the increase of tillage, than any other law in the statute
  • book. It is from this law that the inland corn trade has derived all the
  • liberty and protection which it has ever yet enjoyed; and both the supply
  • of the home market and the interest of tillage are much more effectually
  • promoted by the inland, than either by the importation or exportation
  • trade.
  • The proportion of the average quantity of all sorts of grain imported into
  • Great Britain to that of all sorts of grain consumed, it has been computed
  • by the author of the Tracts upon the Corn Trade, does not exceed that of
  • one to five hundred and seventy. For supplying the home market, therefore,
  • the importance of the inland trade must be to that of the importation
  • trade as five hundred and seventy to one.
  • The average quantity of all sorts of grain exported from Great Britain
  • does not, according to the same author, exceed the one-and-thirtieth part
  • of the annual produce. For the encouragement of tillage, therefore, by
  • providing a market for the home produce, the importance of the inland
  • trade must be to that of the exportation trade as thirty to one.
  • I have no great faith in political arithmetic, and I mean not to warrant
  • the exactness of either of these computations. I mention them only in
  • order to show of how much less consequence, in the opinion of the most
  • judicious and experienced persons, the foreign trade of corn is than the
  • home trade. The great cheapness of corn in the years immediately preceding
  • the establishment of the bounty may, perhaps with reason, he ascribed in
  • some measure to the operation of this statute of Charles II. which had
  • been enacted about five-and-twenty years before, and which had, therefore,
  • full time to produce its effect.
  • A very few words will sufficiently explain all that I have to say
  • concerning the other three branches of the corn trade.
  • II. The trade of the merchant-importer of foreign corn for home
  • consumption, evidently contributes to the immediate supply of the home
  • market, and must so far be immediately beneficial to the great body of the
  • people. It tends, indeed, to lower somewhat the average money price of
  • corn, but not to diminish its real value, or the quantity of labour which
  • it is capable of maintaining. If importation was at all times free, our
  • farmers and country gentlemen would probably, one year with another, get
  • less money for their corn than they do at present, when importation is at
  • most times in effect prohibited; but the money which they got would be of
  • more value, would buy more goods of all other kinds, and would employ more
  • labour. Their real wealth, their real revenue, therefore, would be the
  • same as at present, though it might be expressed by a smaller quantity of
  • silver, and they would neither be disabled nor discouraged from
  • cultivating corn as much as they do at present. On the contrary, as the
  • rise in the real value of silver, in consequence of lowering the money
  • price of corn, lowers somewhat the money price of all other commodities,
  • it gives the industry of the country where it takes place some advantage
  • in all foreign markets and thereby tends to encourage and increase that
  • industry. But the extent of the home market for corn must be in proportion
  • to the general industry of the country where it grows, or to the number of
  • those who produce something else, and therefore, have something else, or,
  • what comes to the same thing, the price of something else, to give in
  • exchange for corn. But in every country, the home market, as it is the
  • nearest and most convenient, so is it likewise the greatest and most
  • important market for corn. That rise in the real value of silver,
  • therefore, which is the effect of lowering the average money price of
  • corn, tends to enlarge the greatest and most important market for corn,
  • and thereby to encourage, instead of discouraging its growth.
  • By the 22d of Charles II. c. 13, the importation of wheat, whenever the
  • price in the home market did not exceed 53s:4d. the quarter, was subjected
  • to a duty of 16s. the quarter; and to a duty of 8s. whenever the price did
  • not exceed £4. The former of these two prices has, for more than a century
  • past, taken place only in times of very great scarcity; and the latter
  • has, so far as I know, not taken place at all. Yet, till wheat has risen
  • above this latter price, it was, by this statute, subjected to a very high
  • duty; and, till it had risen above the former, to a duty which amounted to
  • a prohibition. The importation of other sorts of grain was restrained at
  • rates and by duties, in proportion to the value of the grain, almost
  • equally high. Before the 13th of the present king, the following were the
  • duties payable upon the importation of the different sorts of grain:
  • Grain. Duties. Duties Duties.
  • Beans to 28s. per qr. 19s:10d. after till 40s. 16s:8d. then 12d.
  • Barley to 28s. - 19s:10d. - 32s. 16s. - 12d.
  • Malt is prohibited by the annual malt-tax bill.
  • Oats to 16s. - 5s:10d. after - 9½d.
  • Pease to 40s. - 16s: 0d. after - 9¾d.
  • Rye to 36s. - 19s:10d. till 40s. 16s:8d - 12d.
  • Wheat to 44s. - 21s: 9d. till 53s:4d. 17s. - 8s.
  • till £4, and after that about 1s:4d.
  • Buck-wheat to 32s. per qr. to pay 16s.
  • These different duties were imposed, partly by the 22d of Charles II. in
  • place of the old subsidy, partly by the new subsidy, by the one-third and
  • two-thirds subsidy, and by the subsidy 1747. Subsequent laws still further
  • increased those duties.
  • The distress which, in years of scarcity, the strict execution of those
  • laws might have brought upon the people, would probably have been very
  • great; but, upon such occasions, its execution was generally suspended by
  • temporary statutes, which permitted, for a limited time, the importation
  • of foreign corn. The necessity of these temporary statutes sufficiently
  • demonstrates the impropriety of this general one.
  • These restraints upon importation, though prior to the establishment of
  • the bounty, were dictated by the same spirit, by the same principles,
  • which afterwards enacted that regulation. How hurtful soever in
  • themselves, these, or some other restraints upon importation, became
  • necessary in consequence of that regulation. If, when wheat was either
  • below 48s. the quarter, or not much above it, foreign corn could have been
  • imported, either duty free, or upon paying only a small duty, it might
  • have been exported again, with the benefit of the bounty, to the great
  • loss of the public revenue, and to the entire perversion of the
  • institution, of which the object was to extend the market for the home
  • growth, not that for the growth of foreign countries.
  • III. The trade of the merchant-exporter of corn for foreign consumption,
  • certainly does not contribute directly to the plentiful supply of the home
  • market. It does so, however, indirectly. From whatever source this supply
  • maybe usually drawn, whether from home growth, or from foreign
  • importation, unless more corn is either usually grown, or usually imported
  • into the country, than what is usually consumed in it, the supply of the
  • home market can never be very plentiful. But unless the surplus can, in
  • all ordinary cases, be exported, the growers will be careful never to grow
  • more, and the importers never to import more, than what the bare
  • consumption of the home market requires. That market will very seldom be
  • overstocked; but it will generally be understocked; the people, whose
  • business it is to supply it, being generally afraid lest their goods
  • should be left upon their hands. The prohibition of exportation limits the
  • improvement and cultivation of the country to what the supply of its own
  • inhabitants require. The freedom of exportation enables it to extend
  • cultivation for the supply of foreign nations.
  • By the 12th of Charles II. c.4, the exportation of corn was permitted
  • whenever the price of wheat did not exceed 40s. the quarter, and that of
  • other grain in proportion. By the 15th of the same prince, this liberty
  • was extended till the price of wheat exceeded 48s. the quarter; and by the
  • 22d, to all higher prices. A poundage, indeed, was to be paid to the king
  • upon such exportation; but all grain was rated so low in the book of
  • rates, that this poundage amounted only, upon wheat to 1s., upon oats to
  • 4d., and upon all other grain to 6d. the quarter. By the 1st of William
  • and Mary, the act which established this bounty, this small duty was
  • virtually taken off whenever the price of wheat did not exceed 48s. the
  • quarter; and by the 11th and 12th of William III. c. 20, it was expressly
  • taken off at all higher prices.
  • The trade of the merchant-exporter was, in this manner, not only
  • encouraged by a bounty, but rendered much more free than that of the
  • inland dealer. By the last of these statutes, corn could be engrossed at
  • any price for exportation; but it could not be engrossed for inland sale,
  • except when the price did not exceed 48s. the quarter. The interest of the
  • inland dealer, however, it has already been shown, can never be opposite
  • to that of the great body of the people. That of the merchant-exporter
  • may, and in fact sometimes is. If, while his own country labours under a
  • dearth, a neighbouring country should be afflicted with a famine, it might
  • be his interest to carry corn to the latter country, in such quantities as
  • might very much aggravate the calamities of the dearth. The plentiful
  • supply of the home market was not the direct object of those statutes;
  • but, under the pretence of encouraging agriculture, to raise the money
  • price of corn as high as possible, and thereby to occasion, as much as
  • possible, a constant dearth in the home market. By the discouragement of
  • importation, the supply of that market; even in times of great scarcity,
  • was confined to the home growth; and by the encouragement of exportation,
  • when the price was so high as 48s. the quarter, that market was not, even
  • in times of considerable scarcity, allowed to enjoy the whole of that
  • growth. The temporary laws, prohibiting, for a limited time, the
  • exportation of corn, and taking off, for a limited time, the duties upon
  • its importation, expedients to which Great Britain has been obliged so
  • frequently to have recourse, sufficiently demonstrate the impropriety of
  • her general system. Had that system been good, she would not so frequently
  • have been reduced to the necessity of departing from it.
  • Were all nations to follow the liberal system of free exportation and free
  • importation, the different states into which a great continent was
  • divided, would so far resemble the different provinces of a great empire.
  • As among the different provinces of a great empire, the freedom of the
  • inland trade appears, both from reason and experience, not only the best
  • palliative of a dearth, but the most effectual preventive of a famine; so
  • would the freedom of the exportation and importation trade be among the
  • different states into which a great continent was divided. The larger the
  • continent, the easier the communication through all the different parts of
  • it, both by land and by water, the less would any one particular part of
  • it ever be exposed to either of these calamities, the scarcity of any one
  • country being more likely to be relieved by the plenty of some other. But
  • very few countries have entirely adopted this liberal system. The freedom
  • of the corn trade is almost everywhere more or less restrained, and in
  • many countries is confined by such absurd regulations, as frequently
  • aggravate the unavoidable misfortune of a dearth into the dreadful
  • calamity of a famine. The demand of such countries for corn may frequently
  • become so great and so urgent, that a small state in their neighbourhood,
  • which happened at the same time to be labouring under some degree of
  • dearth, could not venture to supply them without exposing itself to the
  • like dreadful calamity. The very bad policy of one country may thus render
  • it, in some measure, dangerous and imprudent to establish what would
  • otherwise be the best policy in another. The unlimited freedom of
  • exportation, however, would be much less dangerous in great states, in
  • which the growth being much greater, the supply could seldom be much
  • affected by any quantity or corn that was likely to be exported. In a
  • Swiss canton, or in some of the little states in Italy, it may, perhaps,
  • sometimes be necessary to restrain the exportation of corn. In such great
  • countries as France or England, it scarce ever can. To hinder, besides,
  • the farmer from sending his goods at all times to the best market, is
  • evidently to sacrifice the ordinary laws of justice to an idea of public
  • utility, to a sort of reasons of state; an act or legislative authority
  • which ought to be exercised only, which can be pardoned only, in cases of
  • the most urgent necessity. The price at which exportation of corn is
  • prohibited, if it is ever to be prohibited, ought always to be a very high
  • price.
  • The laws concerning corn may everywhere be compared to the laws concerning
  • religion. The people feel themselves so much interested in what relates
  • either to their subsistence in this life, or to their happiness in a life
  • to come, that government must yield to their prejudices, and, in order to
  • preserve the public tranquillity, establish that system which they approve
  • of. It is upon this account, perhaps, that we so seldom find a reasonable
  • system established with regard to either of those two capital objects.
  • IV. The trade of the merchant-carrier, or of the importer of foreign corn,
  • in order to export it again, contributes to the plentiful supply of the
  • home market. It is not, indeed, the direct purpose of his trade to sell
  • his corn there; but he will generally be willing to do so, and even for a
  • good deal less money than he might expect in a foreign market; because he
  • saves in this manner the expense of loading and unloading, of freight and
  • insurance. The inhabitants of the country which, by means of the carrying
  • trade, becomes the magazine and storehouse for the supply of other
  • countries, can very seldom be in want themselves. Though the carrying
  • trade must thus contribute to reduce the average money price of corn in
  • the home market, it would not thereby lower its real value; it would only
  • raise somewhat the real value of silver.
  • The carrying trade was in effect prohibited in Great Britain, upon all
  • ordinary occasions, by the high duties upon the importation of foreign
  • corn, of the greater part of which there was no drawback; and upon
  • extraordinary occasions, when a scarcity made it necessary to suspend
  • those duties by temporary statutes, exportation was always prohibited. By
  • this system of laws, therefore, the carrying trade was in effect
  • prohibited.
  • That system of laws, therefore, which is connected with the establishment
  • of the bounty, seems to deserve no part of the praise which has been
  • bestowed upon it. The improvement and prosperity of Great Britain, which
  • has been so often ascribed to those laws, may very easily be accounted for
  • by other causes. That security which the laws in Great Britain give to
  • every man, that he shall enjoy the fruits of his own labour, is alone
  • sufficient to make any country flourish, notwithstanding these and twenty
  • other absurd regulations of commerce; and this security was perfected by
  • the Revolution, much about the same time that the bounty was established.
  • The natural effort of every individual to better his own condition, when
  • suffered to exert itself with freedom and security, is so powerful a
  • principle, that it is alone, and without any assistance, not only capable
  • of carrying on the society to wealth and prosperity, but of surmounting a
  • hundred impertinent obstructions, with which the folly of human laws too
  • often encumbers its operations: though the effect of those obstructions is
  • always, more or less, either to encroach upon its freedom, or to diminish
  • its security. In Great Britain industry is perfectly secure; and though it
  • is far from being perfectly free, it is as free or freer than in any other
  • part of Europe.
  • Though the period of the greatest prosperity and improvement of Great
  • Britain has been posterior to that system of laws which is connected with
  • the bounty, we must not upon that account, impute it to those laws. It has
  • been posterior likewise to the national debt; but the national debt has
  • most assuredly not been the cause of it.
  • Though the system of laws which is connected with the bounty, has exactly
  • the same tendency with the practice of Spain and Portugal, to lower
  • somewhat the value of the precious metals in the country where it takes
  • place; yet Great Britain is certainly one of the richest countries in
  • Europe, while Spain and Portugal are perhaps amongst the most beggarly.
  • This difference of situation, however, may easily be accounted for from
  • two different causes. First, the tax in Spain, the prohibition in Portugal
  • of exporting gold and silver, and the vigilant police which watches over
  • the execution of those laws, must, in two very poor countries, which
  • between them import annually upwards of six millions sterling, operate not
  • only more directly, but much more forcibly, in reducing the value of those
  • metals there, than the corn laws can do in Great Britain. And, secondly,
  • this bad policy is not in those countries counterbalanced by the general
  • liberty and security of the people. Industry is there neither free nor
  • secure; and the civil and ecclesiastical governments of both Spain and
  • Portugal are such as would alone be sufficient to perpetuate their present
  • state of poverty, even though their regulations of commerce were as wise
  • as the greatest part of them are absurd and foolish.
  • The 13th of the present king, c. 43, seems to have established a new
  • system with regard to the corn laws, in many respects better than the
  • ancient one, but in one or two respects perhaps not quite so good.
  • By this statute, the high duties upon importation for home consumption are
  • taken off, so soon as the price of middling wheat rises to 48s. the
  • quarter; that of middling rye, pease, or beans, to 32s.; that of barley to
  • 24s.; and that of oats to 16s.; and instead of them, a small duty is
  • imposed of only 6d upon the quarter of wheat, and upon that or other grain
  • in proportion. With regard to all those different sorts of grain, but
  • particularly with regard to wheat, the home market is thus opened to
  • foreign supplies, at prices considerably lower than before.
  • By the same statute, the old bounty of 5s. upon the exportation of wheat,
  • ceases so soon as the price rises to 44s. the quarter, instead of 48s. the
  • price at which it ceased before; that of 2s:6d. upon the exportation of
  • barley, ceases so soon as the price rises to 22s. instead of 24s. the
  • price at which it ceased before; that of 2s:6d. upon the exportation of
  • oatmeal, ceases so soon as the price rises to 14s. instead of 15s. the
  • price at which it ceased before. The bounty upon rye is reduced from
  • 3s:6d. to 3s. and it ceases so soon as the price rises to 28s. instead of
  • 32s. the price at which it ceased before. If bounties are as improper as I
  • have endeavoured to prove them to be, the sooner they cease, and the lower
  • they are, so much the better.
  • The same statute permits, at the lowest prices, the importation of corn in
  • order to be exported again, duty free, provided it is in the mean time
  • lodged in a warehouse under the joint locks of the king and the importer.
  • This liberty, indeed, extends to no more than twenty-five of the different
  • ports of Great Britain. They are, however, the principal ones; and there
  • may not, perhaps, be warehouses proper for this purpose in the greater
  • part of the others.
  • So far this law seems evidently an improvement upon the ancient system.
  • But by the same law, a bounty of 2s. the quarter is given for the
  • exportation of oats, whenever the price does not exceed fourteen
  • shillings. No bounty had ever been given before for the exportation of
  • this grain, no more than for that of pease or beans.
  • By the same law, too, the exportation of wheat is prohibited so soon as
  • the price rises to forty-four shillings the quarter; that of rye so soon
  • as it rises to twenty-eight shillings; that of barley so soon as it rises
  • to twenty-two shillings; and that of oats so soon as they rise to fourteen
  • shillings. Those several prices seem all of them a good deal too low; and
  • there seems to be an impropriety, besides, in prohibiting exportation
  • altogether at those precise prices at which that bounty, which was given
  • in order to force it, is withdrawn. The bounty ought certainly either to
  • have been withdrawn at a much lower price, or exportation ought to have
  • been allowed at a much higher.
  • So far, therefore, this law seems to be inferior to the ancient system.
  • With all its imperfections, however, we may perhaps say of it what was
  • said of the laws of Solon, that though not the best in itself, it is the
  • best which the interest, prejudices, and temper of the times, would admit
  • of. It may perhaps in due time prepare the way for a better.
  • CHAPTER VI.
  • OF TREATIES OF COMMERCE.
  • When a nation binds itself by treaty, either to permit the entry of
  • certain goods from one foreign country which it prohibits from all others,
  • or to exempt the goods of one country from duties to which it subjects
  • those of all others, the country, or at least the merchants and
  • manufacturers of the country, whose commerce is so favoured, must
  • necessarily derive great advantage from the treaty. Those merchants and
  • manufacturers enjoy a sort of monopoly in the country which is so
  • indulgent to them. That country becomes a market, both more extensive and
  • more advantageous for their goods: more extensive, because the goods of
  • other nations being either excluded or subjected to heavier duties, it
  • takes off a greater quantity of theirs; more advantageous, because the
  • merchants of the favoured country, enjoying a sort of monopoly there, will
  • often sell their goods for a better price than if exposed to the free
  • competition of all other nations.
  • Such treaties, however, though they may be advantageous to the merchants
  • and manufacturers of the favoured, are necessarily disadvantageous to
  • those of the favouring country. A monopoly is thus granted against them to
  • a foreign nation; and they must frequently buy the foreign goods they have
  • occasion for, dearer than if the free competition of other nations was
  • admitted. That part of its own produce with which such a nation purchases
  • foreign goods, must consequently be sold cheaper; because, when two things
  • are exchanged for one another, the cheapness of the one is a necessary
  • consequence, or rather is the same thing, with the dearness of the other.
  • The exchangeable value of its annual produce, therefore, is likely to be
  • diminished by every such treaty. This diminution, however, can scarce
  • amount to any positive loss, but only to a lessening of the gain which it
  • might otherwise make. Though it sells its goods cheaper than it otherwise
  • might do, it will not probably sell them for less than they cost; nor, as
  • in the case of bounties, for a price which will not replace the capital
  • employed in bringing them to market, together with the ordinary profits of
  • stock. The trade could not go on long if it did. Even the favouring
  • country, therefore, may still gain by the trade, though less than if there
  • was a free competition.
  • Some treaties of commerce, however, have been supposed advantageous, upon
  • principles very different from these; and a commercial country has
  • sometimes granted a monopoly of this kind, against itself, to certain
  • goods of a foreign nation, because it expected, that in the whole commerce
  • between them, it would annually sell more than it would buy, and that a
  • balance in gold and silver would be annually returned to it. It is upon
  • this principle that the treaty of commerce between England and Portugal,
  • concluded in 1703 by Mr Methuen, has been so much commended. The following
  • is a literal translation of that treaty, which consists of three articles
  • only.
  • ART. I. His sacred royal majesty of Portugal promises, both in his own
  • name and that of his successors, to admit for ever hereafter, into
  • Portugal, the woollen cloths, and the rest of the woollen manufactures of
  • the British, as was accustomed, till they were prohibited by the law;
  • nevertheless upon this condition:
  • ART. II. That is to say, that her sacred royal majesty of Great Britain
  • shall, in her own name, and that of her successors, be obliged, for ever
  • hereafter, to admit the wines of the growth of Portugal into Britain; so
  • that at no time, whether there shall be peace or war between the kingdoms
  • of Britain and France, any thing more shall be demanded for these wines by
  • the name of custom or duty, or by whatsoever other title, directly or
  • indirectly, whether they shall be imported into Great Britain in pipes or
  • hogsheads, or other casks, than what shall be demanded for the like
  • quantity or measure of French wine, deducting or abating a third part of
  • the custom or duty. But if, at any time, this deduction or abatement of
  • customs, which is to be made as aforesaid, shall in any manner be
  • attempted and prejudiced, it shall be just and lawful for his sacred royal
  • majesty of Portugal, again to prohibit the woollen cloths, and the rest of
  • the British woollen manufactures.
  • ART. III. The most excellent lords the plenipotentiaries promise and take
  • upon themselves, that their above named masters shall ratify this treaty;
  • and within the space of two months the ratification shall be exchanged.
  • By this treaty, the crown of Portugal becomes bound to admit the English
  • woollens upon the same footing as before the prohibition; that is, not to
  • raise the duties which had been paid before that time. But it does not
  • become bound to admit them upon any better terms than those of any other
  • nation, of France or Holland, for example. The crown of Great Britain, on
  • the contrary, becomes bound to admit the wines of Portugal, upon paying
  • only two-thirds of the duty which is paid for those of France, the wines
  • most likely to come into competition with them. So far this treaty,
  • therefore, is evidently advantageous to Portugal, and disadvantageous to
  • Great Britain.
  • It has been celebrated, however, as a masterpiece of the commercial policy
  • of England. Portugal receives annually from the Brazils a greater quantity
  • of gold than can be employed in its domestic commerce, whether in the
  • shape of coin or of plate. The surplus is too valuable to be allowed to
  • lie idle and locked up in coffers; and as it can find no advantageous
  • market at home, it must, notwithstanding; any prohibition, be sent abroad,
  • and exchanged for something for which there is a more advantageous market
  • at home. A large share of it comes annually to England, in return either
  • for English goods, or for those of other European nations that receive
  • their returns through England. Mr Barretti was informed, that the weekly
  • packet-boat from Lisbon brings, one week with another, more than £50,000
  • in gold to England. The sum had probably been exaggerated. It would amount
  • to more than £2,600,000 a year, which is more than the Brazils are
  • supposed to afford.
  • Our merchants were, some years ago, out of humour with the crown of
  • Portugal. Some privileges which had been granted them, not by treaty, but
  • by the free grace of that crown, at the solicitation, indeed, it is
  • probable, and in return for much greater favours, defence and protection
  • from the crown of Great Britain, had been either infringed or revoked. The
  • people, therefore, usually most interested in celebrating the Portugal
  • trade, were then rather disposed to represent it as less advantageous than
  • it had commonly been imagined. The far greater part, almost the whole,
  • they pretended, of this annual importation of gold, was not on account of
  • Great Britain, but of other European nations; the fruits and wines of
  • Portugal annually imported into Great Britain nearly compensating the
  • value of the British goods sent thither.
  • Let us suppose, however, that the whole was on account of Great Britain,
  • and that it amounted to a still greater sum than Mr Barretti seems to
  • imagine; this trade would not, upon that account, be more advantageous
  • than any other, in which, for the same value sent out, we received an
  • equal value of consumable goods in return.
  • It is but a very small part of this importation which, it can be supposed,
  • is employed as an annual addition, either to the plate or to the coin of
  • the kingdom. The rest must all be sent abroad, and exchanged for
  • consumable goods of some kind or other. But if those consumable goods were
  • purchased directly with the produce of English industry, it would be more
  • for the advantage of England, than first to purchase with that produce the
  • gold of Portugal, and afterwards to purchase with that gold those
  • consumable goods. A direct foreign trade of consumption is always more
  • advantageous than a round-about one; and to bring the same value of
  • foreign goods to the home market requires a much smaller capital in the
  • one way than in the ether. If a smaller share of its industry, therefore,
  • had been employed in producing goods fit for the Portugal market, and a
  • greater in producing those lit for the other markets, where those
  • consumable goods for which there is a demand in Great Britain are to be
  • had, it would have been more for the advantage of England. To procure both
  • the gold which it wants for its own use, and the consumable goods, would,
  • in this way, employ a much smaller capital than at present. There would be
  • a spare capital, therefore, to be employed for other purposes, in exciting
  • an additional quantity of industry, and in raising a greater annual
  • produce.
  • Though Britain were entirely excluded from the Portugal trade, it could
  • find very little difficulty in procuring all the annual supplies of gold
  • which it wants, either for the purposes of plate, or of coin, or of
  • foreign trade. Gold, like every other commodity, is always somewhere or
  • another to be got for its value by those who have that value to give for
  • it. The annual surplus of gold in Portugal, besides, would still be sent
  • abroad, and though not carried away by Great Britain, would be carried
  • away by some other nation, which would be glad to sell it again for its
  • price, in the same manner as Great Britain does at present. In buying gold
  • of Portugal, indeed, we buy it at the first hand; whereas, in buying it of
  • any other nation, except Spain, we should buy it at the second, and might
  • pay somewhat dearer. This difference, however, would surely be too
  • insignificant to deserve the public attention.
  • Almost all our gold, it is said, comes from Portugal. With other nations,
  • the balance of trade is either against as, or not much in our favour. But
  • we should remember, that the more gold we import from one country, the
  • less we must necessarily import from all others. The effectual demand for
  • gold, like that for every other commodity, is in every country limited to
  • a certain quantity. If nine-tenths of this quantity are imported from one
  • country, there remains a tenth only to be imported from all others. The
  • more gold, besides, that is annually imported from some particular
  • countries, over and above what is requisite for plate and for coin, the
  • more must necessarily be exported to some others: and the more that most
  • insignificant object of modern policy, the balance of trade, appears to be
  • in our favour with some particular countries, the more it must necessarily
  • appear to be against us with many others.
  • It was upon this silly notion, however, that England could not subsist
  • without the Portugal trade, that, towards the end of the late war, France
  • and Spain, without pretending either offence or provocation, required the
  • king of Portugal to exclude all British ships from his ports, and, for the
  • security of this exclusion, to receive into them French or Spanish
  • garrisons. Had the king of Portugal submitted to those ignominious terms
  • which his brother-in-law the king of Spain proposed to him, Britain would
  • have been freed from a much greater inconveniency than the loss of the
  • Portugal trade, the burden of supporting a very weak ally, so unprovided
  • of every thing for his own defence, that the whole power of England, had
  • it been directed to that single purpose, could scarce, perhaps, have
  • defended him for another campaign. The loss of the Portugal trade would,
  • no doubt, have occasioned a considerable embarrassment to the merchants at
  • that time engaged in it, who might not, perhaps, have found out, for a
  • year or two, any other equally advantageous method of employing their
  • capitals; and in this would probably have consisted all the inconveniency
  • which England could have suffered from this notable piece of commercial
  • policy.
  • The great annual importation of gold and silver is neither for the purpose
  • of plate nor of coin, but of foreign trade. A round-about foreign trade of
  • consumption can be carried on more advantageously by means of these metals
  • than of almost any other goods. As they are the universal instruments of
  • commerce, they are more readily received in return for all commodities
  • than any other goods; and, on account of their small bulk and great value,
  • it costs less to transport them backward and forward from one place to
  • another than almost any other sort of merchandize, and they lose less of
  • their value by being so transported. Of all the commodities, therefore,
  • which are bought in one foreign country, for no other purpose but to be
  • sold or exchanged again for some other goods in another, there are none so
  • convenient as gold and silver. In facilitating all the different
  • round-about foreign trades of consumption which are carried on in Great
  • Britain, consists the principal advantage of the Portugal trade; and
  • though it is not a capital advantage, it is, no doubt, a considerable one.
  • That any annual addition which, it can reasonably be supposed, is made
  • either to the plate or to the coin of the kingdom, could require but a
  • very small annual importation of gold and silver, seems evident enough;
  • and though we had no direct trade with Portugal, this small quantity could
  • always, somewhere or another, be very easily got.
  • Though the goldsmiths trade be very considerable in Great Britain, the far
  • greater part of the new plate which they annually sell, is made from other
  • old plate melted down; so that the addition annually made to the whole
  • plate of the kingdom cannot be very great, and could require but a very
  • small annual importation.
  • It is the same case with the coin. Nobody imagines, I believe, that even
  • the greater part of the annual coinage, amounting, for ten years together,
  • before the late reformation of the gold coin, to upwards of £800,000
  • a-year in gold, was an annual addition to the money before current in the
  • kingdom. In a country where the expense of the coinage is defrayed by the
  • government, the value of the coin, even when it contains its full standard
  • weight of gold and silver, can never be much greater than that of an equal
  • quantity of those metals uncoined, because it requires only the trouble of
  • going to the mint, and the delay, perhaps, of a few weeks, to procure for
  • any quantity of uncoined gold and silver an equal quantity of those metals
  • in coin; but in every country the greater part of the current coin is
  • almost always more or less worn, or otherwise degenerated from its
  • standard. In Great Britain it was, before the late reformation, a good
  • deal so, the gold being more than two per cent., and the silver more than
  • eight per cent. below its standard weight. But if forty-four guineas and
  • a-half, containing their full standard weight, a pound weight of gold,
  • could purchase very little more than a pound weight of uncoined gold;
  • forty-four guineas and a-half, wanting a part of their weight, could not
  • purchase a pound weight, and something was to be added, in order to make
  • up the deficiency. The current price of gold bullion at market, therefore,
  • instead of being the same with the mint price, or £46:14:6, was then about
  • £47:14s., and sometimes about £48. When the greater part of the coin,
  • however, was in this degenerate condition, forty four guineas and a-half,
  • fresh from the mint, would purchase no more goods in the market than any
  • other ordinary guineas; because, when they came into the coffers of the
  • merchant, being confounded with other money, they could not afterwards be
  • distinguished without more trouble than the difference was worth. Like
  • other guineas, they were worth no more than £46:14:6. If thrown into the
  • melting pot, however, they produced, without any sensible loss, a pound
  • weight of standard gold, which could be sold at any time for between
  • £47:14s. and £48, either in gold or silver, as fit for all the purposes of
  • coin as that which had been melted down. There was an evident profit,
  • therefore, in melting down new-coined money; and it was done so
  • instantaneously, that no precaution of government could prevent it. The
  • operations of the mint were, upon this account, somewhat like the web of
  • Penelope; the work that was done in the day was undone in the night. The
  • mint was employed, not so much in making daily additions to the coin, as
  • in replacing the very best part of it, which was daily melted down.
  • Were the private people who carry their gold and silver to the mint to pay
  • themselves for the coinage, it would add to the value of those metals, in
  • the same manner as the fashion does to that of plate. Coined gold and
  • silver would be more valuable than uncoined. The seignorage, if it was not
  • exorbitant, would add to the bullion the whole value of the duty; because,
  • the government having everywhere the exclusive privilege of coining, no
  • coin can come to market cheaper than they think proper to afford it. If
  • the duty was exorbitant, indeed, that is, if it was very much above the
  • real value of the labour and expense requisite for coinage, false coiners,
  • both at home and abroad, might be encouraged, by the great difference
  • between the value of bullion and that of coin, to pour in so great a
  • quantity of counterfeit money as might reduce the value of the government
  • money. In France, however, though the seignorage is eight per cent., no
  • sensible inconveniency of this kind is found to arise from it. The dangers
  • to which a false coiner is everywhere exposed, if he lives in the country
  • of which he counterfeits the coin, and to which his agents or
  • correspondents are exposed, if he lives in a foreign country, are by far
  • too great to be incurred for the sake of a profit of six or seven per
  • cent.
  • The seignorage in France raises the value of the coin higher than in
  • proportion to the quantity of pure gold which it contains. Thus, by the
  • edict of January 1726, the mint price of fine gold of twenty-four carats
  • was fixed at seven hundred and forty livres nine sous and one denier
  • one-eleventh the mark of eight Paris ounces. {See Dictionnaire des
  • Monnoies, tom. ii. article Seigneurage, p. 439, par 81. Abbot de
  • Bazinghen, Conseiller-Commissaire en la Cour des Monnoies à Paris.} The
  • gold coin of France, making an allowance for the remedy of the mint,
  • contains twenty-one carats and three-fourths of fine gold, and two carats
  • one-fourth of alloy. The mark of standard gold, therefore, is worth no
  • more than about six hundred and seventy-one livres ten deniers. But in
  • France this mark of standard gold is coined into thirty louis d’ors of
  • twenty-four livres each, or into seven hundred and twenty livres. The
  • coinage, therefore, increases the value of a mark of standard gold
  • bullion, by the difference between six hundred and seventy-one livres ten
  • deniers and seven hundred and twenty livres, or by forty-eight livres
  • nineteen sous and two deniers.
  • A seignorage will, in many cases, take away altogether, and will in all
  • cases diminish, the profit of melting down the new coin. This profit
  • always arises from the difference between the quantity of bullion which
  • the common currency ought to contain and that which it actually does
  • contain. If this difference is less than the seignorage, there will be
  • loss instead of profit. If it is equal to the seignorage, there will be
  • neither profit nor loss. If it is greater than the seignorage, there will,
  • indeed, be some profit, but less than if there was no seignorage. If,
  • before the late reformation of the gold coin, for example, there had been
  • a seignorage of five per cent. upon the coinage, there would have been a
  • loss of three per cent. upon the melting down of the gold coin. If the
  • seignorage had been two per cent., there would have been neither profit
  • nor loss. If the seignorage had been one per cent., there would have been
  • a profit but of one per cent. only, instead of two per cent. Wherever
  • money is received by tale, therefore, and not by weight, a seignorage is
  • the most effectual preventive of the melting down of the coin, and, for
  • the same reason, of its exportation. It is the best and heaviest pieces
  • that are commonly either melted down or exported, because it is upon such
  • that the largest profits are made.
  • The law for the encouragement of the coinage, by rendering it duty-free,
  • was first enacted during the reign of Charles II. for a limited time, and
  • afterwards continued, by different prolongations, till 1769, when it was
  • rendered perpetual. The bank of England, in order to replenish their
  • coffers with money, are frequently obliged to carry bullion to the mint;
  • and it was more for their interest, they probably imagined, that the
  • coinage should be at the expense of the government than at their own. It
  • was probably out of complaisance to this great company, that the
  • government agreed to render this law perpetual. Should the custom of
  • weighing gold, however, come to be disused, as it is very likely to be on
  • account of its inconveniency; should the gold coin of England come to be
  • received by tale, as it was before the late recoinage this great company
  • may, perhaps, find that they have, upon this, as upon some other
  • occasions, mistaken their own interest not a little.
  • Before the late recoinage, when the gold currency of England was two per
  • cent. below its standard weight, as there was no seignorage, it was two
  • per cent. below the value of that quantity of standard gold bullion which
  • it ought to have contained. When this great company, therefore, bought
  • gold bullion in order to have it coined, they were obliged to pay for it
  • two per cent. more than it was worth after the coinage. But if there had
  • been a seignorage of two per cent. upon the coinage, the common gold
  • currency, though two per cent. below its standard weight, would,
  • notwithstanding, have been equal in value to the quantity of standard gold
  • which it ought to have contained; the value of the fashion compensating in
  • this case the diminution of the weight. They would, indeed, have had the
  • seignorage to pay, which being two per cent., their loss upon the whole
  • transaction would have been two per cent., exactly the same, but no
  • greater than it actually was.
  • If the seignorage had been five per cent. and the gold currency only two
  • per cent. below its standard weight, the bank would, in this case, have
  • gained three per cent. upon the price of the bullion; but as they would
  • have had a seignorage of five per cent. to pay upon the coinage, their
  • loss upon the whole transaction would, in the same manner, have been
  • exactly two per cent.
  • If the seignorage had been only one per cent., and the gold currency two
  • per cent. below its standard weight, the bank would, in this case, have
  • lost only one per cent. upon the price of the bullion; but as they would
  • likewise have had a seignorage of one per cent. to pay, their loss upon
  • the whole transaction would have been exactly two per cent., in the same
  • manner as in all other cases.
  • If there was a reasonable seignorage, while at the same time the coin
  • contained its full standard weight, as it has done very nearly since the
  • late recoinage, whatever the bank might lose by the seignorage, they would
  • gain upon the price of the bullion; and whatever they might gain upon the
  • price of the bullion, they would lose by the seignorage. They would
  • neither lose nor gain, therefore, upon the whole transaction, and they
  • would in this, as in all the foregoing cases, be exactly in the same
  • situation as if there was no seignorage.
  • When the tax upon a commodity is so moderate as not to encourage
  • smuggling, the merchant who deals in it, though he advances, does not
  • properly pay the tax, as he gets it back in the price of the commodity.
  • The tax is finally paid by the last purchaser or consumer. But money is a
  • commodity, with regard to which every man is a merchant. Nobody buys it
  • but in order to sell it again; and with regard to it there is, in ordinary
  • cases, no last purchaser or consumer. When the tax upon coinage,
  • therefore, is so moderate as not to encourage false coining, though every
  • body advances the tax, nobody finally pays it; because every body gets it
  • back in the advanced value of the coin.
  • A moderate seignorage, therefore, would not, in any case, augment the
  • expense of the bank, or of any other private persons who carry their
  • bullion to the mint in order to be coined; and the want of a moderate
  • seignorage does not in any case diminish it. Whether there is or is not a
  • seignorage, if the currency contains its full standard weight, the coinage
  • costs nothing to anybody; and if it is short of that weight, the coinage
  • must always cost the difference between the quantity of bullion which
  • ought to be contained in it, and that which actually is contained in it.
  • The government, therefore, when it defrays the expense of coinage, not
  • only incurs some small expense, but loses some small revenue which it
  • might get by a proper duty; and neither the bank, nor any other private
  • persons, are in the smallest degree benefited by this useless piece of
  • public generosity.
  • The directors of the bank, however, would probably be unwilling to agree
  • to the imposition of a seignorage upon the authority of a speculation
  • which promises them no gain, but only pretends to insure them from any
  • loss. In the present state of the gold coin, and as long as it continues
  • to be received by weight, they certainly would gain nothing by such a
  • change. But if the custom of weighing the gold coin should ever go into
  • disuse, as it is very likely to do, and if the gold coin should ever fall
  • into the same state of degradation in which it was before the late
  • recoinage, the gain, or more properly the savings, of the bank,
  • inconsequence of the imposition of a seignorage, would probably be very
  • considerable. The bank of England is the only company which sends any
  • considerable quantity of bullion to the mint, and the burden of the annual
  • coinage falls entirely, or almost entirely, upon it. If this annual
  • coinage had nothing to do but to repair the unavoidable losses and
  • necessary wear and tear of the coin, it could seldom exceed fifty
  • thousand, or at most a hundred thousand pounds. But when the coin is
  • degraded below its standard weight, the annual coinage must, besides this,
  • fill up the large vacuities which exportation and the melting pot are
  • continually making in the current coin. It was upon this account, that
  • during the ten or twelve years immediately preceding the late reformation
  • of the gold coin, the annual coinage amounted, at an average, to more than
  • £850,000. But if there had been a seignorage of four or five per cent.
  • upon the gold coin, it would probably, even in the state in which things
  • then were, have put an effectual stop to the business both of exportation
  • and of the melting pot. The bank, instead of losing every year about two
  • and a half per cent. upon the bullion which was to be coined into more
  • than eight hundred and fifty thousand pounds, or incurring an annual loss
  • of more than £21,250 pounds, would not probably have incurred the tenth
  • part of that loss.
  • The revenue allotted by parliament for defraying the expense of the
  • coinage is but fourteen thousand pounds a-year; and the real expense which
  • it costs the government, or the fees of the officers of the mint, do not,
  • upon ordinary occasions, I am assured, exceed the half of that sum. The
  • saving of so very small a sum, or even the gaining of another, which could
  • not well be much larger, are objects too inconsiderable, it may be
  • thought, to deserve the serious attention of government. But the saving of
  • eighteen or twenty thousand pounds a-year, in case of an event which is
  • not improbable, which has frequently happened before, and which is very
  • likely to happen again, is surely an object which well deserves the
  • serious attention, even of so great a company as the bank of England.
  • Some of the foregoing reasonings and observations might, perhaps, have
  • been more properly placed in those chapters of the first book which treat
  • of the origin and use of money, and of the difference between the real and
  • the nominal price of commodities. But as the law for the encouragement of
  • coinage derives its origin from those vulgar prejudices which have been
  • introduced by the mercantile system, I judged it more proper to reserve
  • them for this chapter. Nothing could be more agreeable to the spirit of
  • that system than a sort of bounty upon the production of money, the very
  • thing which, it supposes, constitutes the wealth of every nation. It is
  • one of its many admirable expedients for enriching the country.
  • CHAPTER VII.
  • OF COLONIES.
  • PART I. Of the Motives for Establishing New Colonies.
  • The interest which occasioned the first settlement of the different
  • European colonies in America and the West Indies, was not altogether so
  • plain and distinct as that which directed the establishment of those of
  • ancient Greece and Rome.
  • All the different states of ancient Greece possessed, each of them, but a
  • very small territory; and when the people in anyone of them multiplied
  • beyond what that territory could easily maintain, a part of them were sent
  • in quest of a new habitation, in some remote and distant part of the
  • world; the warlike neighbours who surrounded them on all sides, rendering
  • it difficult for any of them to enlarge very much its territory at home.
  • The colonies of the Dorians resorted chiefly to Italy and Sicily, which,
  • in the times preceding the foundation of Rome, were inhabited by barbarous
  • and uncivilized nations; those of the Ionians and Aeolians, the two other
  • great tribes of the Greeks, to Asia Minor and the islands of the Aegean
  • sea, of which the inhabitants sewn at that time to have been pretty much
  • in the same state as those of Sicily and Italy. The mother city, though
  • she considered the colony as a child, at all times entitled to great
  • favour and assistance, and owing in return much gratitude and respect, yet
  • considered it as an emancipated child, over whom she pretended to claim no
  • direct authority or jurisdiction. The colony settled its own form of
  • government, enacted its own laws, elected its own magistrates, and made
  • peace or war with its neighbours, as an independent state, which had no
  • occasion to wait for the approbation or consent of the mother city.
  • Nothing can be more plain and distinct than the interest which directed
  • every such establishment.
  • Rome, like most of the other ancient republics, was originally founded
  • upon an agrarian law, which divided the public territory, in a certain
  • proportion, among the different citizens who composed the state. The
  • course of human affairs, by marriage, by succession, and by alienation,
  • necessarily deranged this original division, and frequently threw the
  • lands which had been allotted for the maintenance of many different
  • families, into the possession of a single person. To remedy this disorder,
  • for such it was supposed to be, a law was made, restricting the quantity
  • of land which any citizen could possess to five hundred jugera; about 350
  • English acres. This law, however, though we read of its having been
  • executed upon one or two occasions, was either neglected or evaded, and
  • the inequality of fortunes went on continually increasing. The greater
  • part of the citizens had no land; and without it the manners and customs
  • of those times rendered it difficult for a freeman to maintain his
  • independency. In the present times, though a poor man has no land of his
  • own, if he has a little stock, he may either farm the lands of another, or
  • he may carry on some little retail trade; and if he has no stock, he may
  • find employment either as a country labourer, or as an artificer. But
  • among the ancient Romans, the lands of the rich were all cultivated by
  • slaves, who wrought under an overseer, who was likewise a slave; so that a
  • poor freeman had little chance of being employed either as a farmer or as
  • a labourer. All trades and manufactures, too, even the retail trade, were
  • carried on by the slaves of the rich for the benefit of their masters,
  • whose wealth, authority, and protection, made it difficult for a poor
  • freeman to maintain the competition against them. The citizens, therefore,
  • who had no land, had scarce any other means of subsistence but the
  • bounties of the candidates at the annual elections. The tribunes, when
  • they had a mind to animate the people against the rich and the great, put
  • them in mind of the ancient divisions of lands, and represented that law
  • which restricted this sort of private property as the fundamental law of
  • the republic. The people became clamorous to get land, and the rich and
  • the great, we may believe, were perfectly determined not to give them any
  • part of theirs. To satisfy them in some measure, therefore, they
  • frequently proposed to send out a new colony. But conquering Rome was,
  • even upon such occasions, under no necessity of turning out her citizens
  • to seek their fortune, if one may so, through the wide world, without
  • knowing where they were to settle. She assigned them lands generally in
  • the conquered provinces of Italy, where, being within the dominions of the
  • republic, they could never form any independent state, but were at best
  • but a sort of corporation, which, though it had the power of enacting
  • bye-laws for its own government, was at all times subject to the
  • correction, jurisdiction, and legislative authority of the mother city.
  • The sending out a colony of this kind not only gave some satisfaction to
  • the people, but often established a sort of garrison, too, in a newly
  • conquered province, of which the obedience might otherwise have been
  • doubtful. A Roman colony, therefore, whether we consider the nature of the
  • establishment itself, or the motives for making it, was altogether
  • different from a Greek one. The words, accordingly, which in the original
  • languages denote those different establishments, have very different
  • meanings. The Latin word (colonia) signifies simply a plantation. The
  • Greek word (apoixia), on the contrary, signifies a separation of dwelling,
  • a departure from home, a going out of the house. But though the Roman
  • colonies were, in many respects, different from the Greek ones, the
  • interest which prompted to establish them was equally plain and distinct.
  • Both institutions derived their origin, either from irresistible
  • necessity, or from clear and evident utility.
  • The establishment of the European colonies in America and the West Indies
  • arose from no necessity; and though the utility which has resulted from
  • them has been very great, it is not altogether so clear and evident. It
  • was not understood at their first establishment, and was not the motive,
  • either of that establishment, or of the discoveries which gave occasion to
  • it; and the nature, extent, and limits of that utility, are not, perhaps,
  • well understood at this day.
  • The Venetians, during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, carried on a
  • very advantageous commerce in spiceries and other East India goods, which
  • they distributed among the other nations of Europe. They purchased them
  • chiefly in Egypt, at that time under the dominion of the Mamelukes, the
  • enemies of the Turks, of whom the Venetians were the enemies; and this
  • union of interest, assisted by the money of Venice, formed such a
  • connexion as gave the Venetians almost a monopoly of the trade.
  • The great profits of the Venetians tempted the avidity of the Portuguese.
  • They had been endeavouring, during the course of the fifteenth century, to
  • find out by sea a way to the countries from which the Moors brought them
  • ivory and gold dust across the desert. They discovered the Madeiras, the
  • Canaries, the Azores, the Cape de Verd islands, the coast of Guinea, that
  • of Loango, Congo, Angola, and Benguela, and, finally, the Cape of Good
  • Hope. They had long wished to share in the profitable traffic of the
  • Venetians, and this last discovery opened to them a probable prospect of
  • doing so. In 1497, Vasco de Gamo sailed from the port of Lisbon with a
  • fleet of four ships, and, after a navigation of eleven months, arrived
  • upon the coast of Indostan; and thus completed a course of discoveries
  • which had been pursued with great steadiness, and with very little
  • interruption, for near a century together.
  • Some years before this, while the expectations of Europe were in suspense
  • about the projects of the Portuguese, of which the success appeared yet to
  • be doubtful, a Genoese pilot formed the yet more daring project of sailing
  • to the East Indies by the west. The situation of those countries was at
  • that time very imperfectly known in Europe. The few European travellers
  • who had been there, had magnified the distance, perhaps through simplicity
  • and ignorance; what was really very great, appearing almost infinite to
  • those who could not measure it; or, perhaps, in order to increase somewhat
  • more the marvellous of their own adventures in visiting regions so
  • immensely remote from Europe. The longer the way was by the east, Columbus
  • very justly concluded, the shorter it would be by the west. He proposed,
  • therefore, to take that way, as both the shortest and the surest, and he
  • had the good fortune to convince Isabella of Castile of the probability of
  • his project. He sailed from the port of Palos in August 1492, near five
  • years before the expedition of Vasco de Gamo set out from Portugal; and,
  • after a voyage of between two and three months, discovered first some of
  • the small Bahama or Lucyan islands, and afterwards the great island of St.
  • Domingo.
  • But the countries which Columbus discovered, either in this or in any of
  • his subsequent voyages, had no resemblance to those which he had gone in
  • quest of. Instead of the wealth, cultivation, and populousness of China
  • and Indostan, he found, in St. Domingo, and in all the other parts of the
  • new world which he ever visited, nothing but a country quite covered with
  • wood, uncultivated, and inhabited only by some tribes of naked and
  • miserable savages. He was not very willing, however, to believe that they
  • were not the same with some of the countries described by Marco Polo, the
  • first European who had visited, or at least had left behind him any
  • description of China or the East Indies; and a very slight resemblance,
  • such as that which he found between the name of Cibao, a mountain in St.
  • Domingo, and that of Cipange, mentioned by Marco Polo, was frequently
  • sufficient to make him return to this favourite prepossession, though
  • contrary to the clearest evidence. In his letters to Ferdinand and
  • Isabella, he called the countries which he had discovered the Indies. He
  • entertained no doubt but that they were the extremity of those which had
  • been described by Marco Polo, and that they were not very distant from the
  • Ganges, or from the countries which had been conquered by Alexander. Even
  • when at last convinced that they were different, he still flattered
  • himself that those rich countries were at no great distance; and in a
  • subsequent voyage, accordingly, went in quest of them along the coast of
  • Terra Firma, and towards the Isthmus of Darien.
  • In consequence of this mistake of Columbus, the name of the Indies has
  • stuck to those unfortunate countries ever since; and when it was at last
  • clearly discovered that the new were altogether different from the old
  • Indies, the former were called the West, in contradistinction to the
  • latter, which were called the East Indies.
  • It was of importance to Columbus, however, that the countries which he had
  • discovered, whatever they were, should be represented to the court of
  • Spain as of very great consequence; and, in what constitutes the real
  • riches of every country, the animal and vegetable productions of the soil,
  • there was at that time nothing which could well justify such a
  • representation of them.
  • The cori, something between a rat and a rabbit, and supposed by Mr Buffon
  • to be the same with the aperea of Brazil, was the largest viviparous
  • quadruped in St. Domingo. This species seems never to have been very
  • numerous; and the dogs and cats of the Spaniards are said to have long ago
  • almost entirely extirpated it, as well as some other tribes of a still
  • smaller size. These, however, together with a pretty large lizard, called
  • the ivana or iguana, constituted the principal part of the animal food
  • which the land afforded.
  • The vegetable food of the inhabitants, though, from their want of
  • industry, not very abundant, was not altogether so scanty. It consisted in
  • Indian corn, yams, potatoes, bananas, etc., plants which were then
  • altogether unknown in Europe, and which have never since been very much
  • esteemed in it, or supposed to yield a sustenance equal to what is drawn
  • from the common sorts of grain and pulse, which have been cultivated in
  • this part of the world time out of mind.
  • The cotton plant, indeed, afforded the material of a very important
  • manufacture, and was at that time, to Europeans, undoubtedly the most
  • valuable of all the vegetable productions of those islands. But though, in
  • the end of the fifteenth century, the muslins and other cotton goods of
  • the East Indies were much esteemed in every part of Europe, the cotton
  • manufacture itself was not cultivated in any part of it. Even this
  • production, therefore, could not at that time appear in the eyes of
  • Europeans to be of very great consequence.
  • Finding nothing, either in the animals or vegetables of the newly
  • discovered countries which could justify a very advantageous
  • representation of them, Columbus turned his view towards their minerals;
  • and in the richness of their productions of this third kingdom, he
  • flattered himself he had found a full compensation for the insignificancy
  • of those of the other two. The little bits of gold with which the
  • inhabitants ornamented their dress, and which, he was informed, they
  • frequently found in the rivulets and torrents which fell from the
  • mountains, were sufficient to satisfy him that those mountains abounded
  • with the richest gold mines. St. Domingo, therefore, was represented as a
  • country abounding with gold, and upon that account (according to the
  • prejudices not only of the present times, but of those times), an
  • inexhaustible source of real wealth to the crown and kingdom of Spain.
  • When Columbus, upon his return from his first voyage, was introduced with
  • a sort of triumphal honours to the sovereigns of Castile and Arragon, the
  • principal productions of the countries which he had discovered were
  • carried in solemn procession before him. The only valuable part of them
  • consisted in some little fillets, bracelets, and other ornaments of gold,
  • and in some bales of cotton. The rest were mere objects of vulgar wonder
  • and curiosity; some reeds of an extraordinary size, some birds of a very
  • beautiful plumage, and some stuffed skins of the huge alligator and
  • manati; all of which were preceded by six or seven of the wretched
  • natives, whose singular colour and appearance added greatly to the novelty
  • of the show.
  • In consequence of the representations of Columbus, the council of Castile
  • determined to take possession of the countries of which the inhabitants
  • were plainly incapable of defending themselves. The pious purpose of
  • converting them to Christianity sanctified the injustice of the project.
  • But the hope of finding treasures of gold there was the sole motive which
  • prompted to undertake it; and to give this motive the greater weight, it
  • was proposed by Columbus, that the half of all the gold and silver that
  • should be found there, should belong to the crown. This proposal was
  • approved of by the council.
  • As long as the whole, or the greater part of the gold which the first
  • adventurers imported into Europe was got by so very easy a method as the
  • plundering of the defenceless natives, it was not perhaps very difficult
  • to pay even this heavy tax; but when the natives were once fairly stript
  • of all that they had, which, in St. Domingo, and in all the other
  • countries discovered by Columbus, was done completely in six or eight
  • years, and when, in order to find more, it had become necessary to dig for
  • it in the mines, there was no longer any possibility of paying this tax.
  • The rigorous exaction of it, accordingly, first occasioned, it is said,
  • the total abandoning of the mines of St. Domingo, which have never been
  • wrought since. It was soon reduced, therefore, to a third; then to a
  • fifth; afterwards to a tenth; and at last to a twentieth part of the gross
  • produce of the gold mines. The tax upon silver continued for a long time
  • to be a fifth of the gross produce. It was reduced to a tenth only in the
  • course of the present century. But the first adventurers do not appear to
  • have been much interested about silver. Nothing less precious than gold
  • seemed worthy of their attention.
  • All the other enterprizes of the Spaniards in the New World, subsequent to
  • those of Columbus, seem to have been prompted by the same motive. It was
  • the sacred thirst of gold that carried Ovieda, Nicuessa, and Vasco Nugnes
  • de Balboa, to the Isthmus of Darien; that carried Cortes to Mexico,
  • Almagro and Pizarro to Chili and Peru. When those adventurers arrived upon
  • any unknown coast, their first inquiry was always if there was any gold to
  • be found there; and according to the information which they received
  • concerning this particular, they determined either to quit the country or
  • to settle in it.
  • Of all those expensive and uncertain projects, however, which bring
  • bankruptcy upon the greater part of the people who engage in them, there
  • is none, perhaps, more perfectly ruinous than the search after new silver
  • and gold mines. It is, perhaps, the most disadvantageous lottery in the
  • world, or the one in which the gain of those who draw the prizes bears the
  • least proportion to the loss of those who draw the blanks; for though the
  • prizes are few, and the blanks many, the common price of a ticket is the
  • whole fortune of a very rich man. Projects of mining, instead of replacing
  • the capital employed in them, together with the ordinary profits of stock,
  • commonly absorb both capital and profit. They are the projects, therefore,
  • to which, of all others, a prudent lawgiver, who desired to increase the
  • capital of his nation, would least choose to give any extraordinary
  • encouragement, or to turn towards them a greater share of that capital
  • than what would go to them of its own accord. Such, in reality, is the
  • absurd confidence which almost all men have in their own good fortune,
  • that wherever there is the least probability of success, too great a share
  • of it is apt to go to them of its own accord.
  • But though the judgment of sober reason and experience concerning such
  • projects has always been extremely unfavourable, that of human avidity has
  • commonly been quite otherwise. The same passion which has suggested to so
  • many people the absurd idea of the philosopher’s stone, has suggested to
  • others the equally absurd one of immense rich mines of gold and silver.
  • They did not consider that the value of those metals has, in all ages and
  • nations, arisen chiefly from their scarcity, and that their scarcity has
  • arisen from the very small quantities of them which nature has anywhere
  • deposited in one place, from the hard and intractable substances with
  • which she has almost everywhere surrounded those small quantities, and
  • consequently from the labour and expense which are everywhere necessary in
  • order to penetrate, and get at them. They flattered themselves that veins
  • of those metals might in many places be found, as large and as abundant as
  • those which are commonly found of lead, or copper, or tin, or iron. The
  • dream of Sir Waiter Raleigh, concerning the golden city and country of El
  • Dorado, may satisfy us, that even wise men are not always exempt from such
  • strange delusions. More than a hundred years after the death of that great
  • man, the Jesuit Gumila was still convinced of the reality of that
  • wonderful country, and expressed, with great warmth, and, I dare say, with
  • great sincerity, how happy he should be to carry the light of the gospel
  • to a people who could so well reward the pious labours of their
  • missionary.
  • In the countries first discovered by the Spaniards, no gold and silver
  • mines are at present known which are supposed to be worth the working. The
  • quantities of those metals which the first adventurers are said to have
  • found there, had probably been very much magnified, as well as the
  • fertility of the mines which were wrought immediately after the first
  • discovery. What those adventurers were reported to have found, however,
  • was sufficient to inflame the avidity of all their countrymen. Every
  • Spaniard who sailed to America expected to find an El Dorado. Fortune,
  • too, did upon this what she has done upon very few other occasions. She
  • realized in some measure the extravagant hopes of her votaries; and in the
  • discovery and conquest of Mexico and Peru (of which the one happened about
  • thirty, and the other about forty, years after the first expedition of
  • Columbus), she presented them with something not very unlike that
  • profusion of the precious metals which they sought for.
  • A project of commerce to the East Indies, therefore, gave occasion to the
  • first discovery of the West. A project of conquest gave occasion to all
  • the establishments of the Spaniards in those newly discovered countries.
  • The motive which excited them to this conquest was a project of gold and
  • silver mines; and a course of accidents which no human wisdom could
  • foresee, rendered this project much more successful than the undertakers
  • had any reasonable grounds for expecting.
  • The first adventurers of all the other nations of Europe who attempted to
  • make settlements in America, were animated by the like chimerical views;
  • but they were not equally successful. It was more than a hundred years
  • after the first settlement of the Brazils, before any silver, gold, or
  • diamond mines, were discovered there. In the English, French, Dutch, and
  • Danish colonies, none have ever yet been discovered, at least none that
  • are at present supposed to be worth the working. The first English
  • settlers in North America, however, offered a fifth of all the gold and
  • silver which should be found there to the king, as a motive for granting
  • them their patents. In the patents of Sir Waiter Raleigh, to the London
  • and Plymouth companies, to the council of Plymouth, etc. this fifth was
  • accordingly reserved to the crown. To the expectation of finding gold and
  • silver mines, those first settlers, too, joined that of discovering a
  • north-west passage to the East Indies. They have hitherto been
  • disappointed in both.
  • PART II. Causes of the Prosperity of New Colonies.
  • The colony of a civilized nation which takes possession either of a waste
  • country, or of one so thinly inhabited that the natives easily give place
  • to the new settlers, advances more rapidly to wealth and greatness than
  • any other human society.
  • The colonies carry out with them a knowledge of agriculture and of other
  • useful arts, superior to what can grow up of its own accord, in the course
  • of many centuries, among savage and barbarous nations. They carry out with
  • them, too, the habit of subordination, some notion of the regular
  • government which takes place in their own country, of the system of laws
  • which support it, and of a regular administration of justice; and they
  • naturally establish something of the same kind in the new settlement. But
  • among savage and barbarous nations, the natural progress of law and
  • government is still slower than the natural progress of arts, after law
  • and government have been so far established as is necessary for their
  • protection. Every colonist gets more land than he can possibly cultivate.
  • He has no rent, and scarce any taxes, to pay. No landlord shares with him
  • in its produce, and, the share of the sovereign is commonly but a trifle.
  • He has every motive to render as great as possible a produce which is thus
  • to be almost entirely his own. But his land is commonly so extensive,
  • that, with all his own industry, and with all the industry of other people
  • whom he can get to employ, he can seldom make it produce the tenth part of
  • what it is capable of producing. He is eager, therefore, to collect
  • labourers from all quarters, and to reward them with the most liberal
  • wages. But those liberal wages, joined to the plenty and cheapness of
  • land, soon make those labourers leave him, in order to become landlords
  • themselves, and to reward with equal liberality other labourers, who soon
  • leave them for the same reason that they left their first master. The
  • liberal reward of labour encourages marriage. The children, during the
  • tender years of infancy, are well fed and properly taken care of; and when
  • they are grown up, the value of their labour greatly overpays their
  • maintenance. When arrived at maturity, the high price of labour, and the
  • low price of land, enable them to establish themselves in the same manner
  • as their fathers did before them.
  • In other countries, rent and profit eat up wages, and the two superior
  • orders of people oppress the inferior one; but in new colonies, the
  • interest of the two superior orders obliges them to treat the inferior one
  • with more generosity and humanity, at least where that inferior one is not
  • in a state of slavery. Waste lands, of the greatest natural fertility, are
  • to be had for a trifle. The increase of revenue which the proprietor, who
  • is always the undertaker, expects from their improvement, constitutes his
  • profit, which, in these circumstances, is commonly very great; but this
  • great profit cannot be made, without employing the labour of other people
  • in clearing and cultivating the land; and the disproportion between the
  • great extent of the land and the small number of the people, which
  • commonly takes place in new colonies, makes it difficult for him to get
  • this labour. He does not, therefore, dispute about wages, but is willing
  • to employ labour at any price. The high wages of labour encourage
  • population. The cheapness and plenty of good land encourage improvement,
  • and enable the proprietor to pay those high wages. In those wages consists
  • almost the whole price of the land; and though they are high, considered
  • as the wages of labour, they are low, considered as the price of what is
  • so very valuable. What encourages the progress of population and
  • improvement, encourages that of real wealth and greatness.
  • The progress of many of the ancient Greek colonies towards wealth and
  • greatness seems accordingly to have been very rapid. In the course of a
  • century or two, several of them appear to have rivalled, and even to have
  • surpassed, their mother cities. Syracuse and Agrigentum in Sicily,
  • Tarentum and Locri in Italy, Ephesus and Miletus in Lesser Asia, appear,
  • by all accounts, to have been at least equal to any of the cities of
  • ancient Greece. Though posterior in their establishment, yet all the arts
  • of refinement, philosophy, poetry, and eloquence, seem to have been
  • cultivated as early, and to have been improved as highly in them as in any
  • part of the mother country. The schools of the two oldest Greek
  • philosophers, those of Thales and Pythagoras, were established, it is
  • remarkable, not in ancient Greece, but the one in an Asiatic, the other in
  • an Italian colony. All those colonies had established themselves in
  • countries inhabited by savage and barbarous nations, who easily gave place
  • to the new settlers. They had plenty of good land; and as they were
  • altogether independent of the mother city, they were at liberty to manage
  • their own affairs in the way that they judged was most suitable to their
  • own interest.
  • The history of the Roman colonies is by no means so brilliant. Some of
  • them, indeed, such as Florence, have, in the course of many ages, and
  • after the fall of the mother city, grown up to be considerable states. But
  • the progress of no one of them seems ever to have been very rapid. They
  • were all established in conquered provinces, which in most cases had been
  • fully inhabited before. The quantity of land assigned to each colonist was
  • seldom very considerable, and, as the colony was not independent, they
  • were not always at liberty to manage their own affairs in the way that
  • they judged was most suitable to their own interest.
  • In the plenty of good land, the European colonies established in America
  • and the West Indies resemble, and even greatly surpass, those of ancient
  • Greece. In their dependency upon the mother state, they resemble those of
  • ancient Rome; but their great distance from Europe has in all of them
  • alleviated more or less the effects of this dependency. Their situation
  • has placed them less in the view, and less in the power of their mother
  • country. In pursuing their interest their own way, their conduct has upon
  • many occasions been overlooked, either because not known or not understood
  • in Europe; and upon some occasions it has been fairly suffered and
  • submitted to, because their distance rendered it difficult to restrain it.
  • Even the violent and arbitrary government of Spain has, upon many
  • occasions, been obliged to recall or soften the orders which had been
  • given for the government of her colonies, for fear of a general
  • insurrection. The progress of all the European colonies in wealth,
  • population, and improvement, has accordingly been very great.
  • The crown of Spain, by its share of the gold and silver, derived some
  • revenue from its colonies from the moment of their first establishment. It
  • was a revenue, too, of a nature to excite in human avidity the most
  • extravagant expectation of still greater riches. The Spanish colonies,
  • therefore, from the moment of their first establishment, attracted very
  • much the attention of their mother country; while those of the other
  • European nations were for a long time in a great measure neglected. The
  • former did not, perhaps, thrive the better in consequence of this
  • attention, nor the latter the worse in consequence of this neglect. In
  • proportion to the extent of the country which they in some measure
  • possess, the Spanish colonies are considered as less populous and thriving
  • than those of almost any other European nation. The progress even of the
  • Spanish colonies, however, in population and improvement, has certainly
  • been very rapid and very great. The city of Lima, founded since the
  • conquest, is represented by Ulloa as containing fifty thousand inhabitants
  • near thirty years ago. Quito, which had been but a miserable hamlet of
  • Indians, is represented by the same author as in his time equally
  • populous. Gemel i Carreri, a pretended traveller, it is said, indeed, but
  • who seems everywhere to have written upon extreme good information,
  • represents the city of Mexico as containing a hundred thousand
  • inhabitants; a number which, in spite of all the exaggerations of the
  • Spanish writers, is probably more than five times greater than what it
  • contained in the time of Montezuma. These numbers exceed greatly those of
  • Boston, New York, and Philadelphia, the three greatest cities of the
  • English colonies. Before the conquest of the Spaniards, there were no
  • cattle fit for draught, either in Mexico or Peru. The lama was their only
  • beast of burden, and its strength seems to have been a good deal inferior
  • to that of a common ass. The plough was unknown among them. They were
  • ignorant of the use of iron. They had no coined money, nor any established
  • instrument of commerce of any kind. Their commerce was carried on by
  • barter. A sort of wooden spade was their principal instrument of
  • agriculture. Sharp stones served them for knives and hatchets to cut with;
  • fish bones, and the hard sinews of certain animals, served them with
  • needles to sew with; and these seem to have been their principal
  • instruments of trade. In this state of things, it seems impossible that
  • either of those empires could have been so much improved or so well
  • cultivated as at present, when they are plentifully furnished with all
  • sorts of European cattle, and when the use of iron, of the plough, and of
  • many of the arts of Europe, have been introduced among them. But the
  • populousness of every country must be in proportion to the degree of its
  • improvement and cultivation. In spite of the cruel destruction of the
  • natives which followed the conquest, these two great empires are probably
  • more populous now than they ever were before; and the people are surely
  • very different; for we must acknowledge, I apprehend, that the Spanish
  • creoles are in many respects superior to the ancient Indians.
  • After the settlements of the Spaniards, that of the Portuguese in Brazil
  • is the oldest of any European nation in America. But as for a long time
  • after the first discovery neither gold nor silver mines were found in it,
  • and as it afforded upon that account little or no revenue to the crown, it
  • was for a long time in a great measure neglected; and during this state of
  • neglect, it grew up to be a great and powerful colony. While Portugal was
  • under the dominion of Spain, Brazil was attacked by the Dutch, who got
  • possession of seven of the fourteen provinces into which it is divided.
  • They expected soon to conquer the other seven, when Portugal recovered its
  • independency by the elevation of the family of Braganza to the throne. The
  • Dutch, then, as enemies to the Spaniards, became friends to the
  • Portuguese, who were likewise the enemies of the Spaniards. They agreed,
  • therefore, to leave that part of Brazil which they had not conquered to
  • the king of Portugal, who agreed to leave that part which they had
  • conquered to them, as a matter not worth disputing about, with such good
  • allies. But the Dutch government soon began to oppress the Portuguese
  • colonists, who, instead of amusing themselves with complaints, took arms
  • against their new masters, and by their own valour and resolution, with
  • the connivance, indeed, but without any avowed assistance from the mother
  • country, drove them out of Brazil. The Dutch, therefore, finding it
  • impossible to keep any part of the country to themselves, were contented
  • that it should be entirely restored to the crown of Portugal. In this
  • colony there are said to be more than six hundred thousand people, either
  • Portuguese or descended from Portuguese, creoles, mulattoes, and a mixed
  • race between Portuguese and Brazilians. No one colony in America is
  • supposed to contain so great a number of people of European extraction.
  • Towards the end of the fifteenth, and during the greater part of the
  • sixteenth century, Spain and Portugal were the two great naval powers upon
  • the ocean; for though the commerce of Venice extended to every part of
  • Europe, its fleet had scarce ever sailed beyond the Mediterranean. The
  • Spaniards, in virtue of the first discovery, claimed all America as their
  • own; and though they could not hinder so great a naval power as that of
  • Portugal from settling in Brazil, such was at that time the terror of
  • their name, that the greater part of the other nations of Europe were
  • afraid to establish themselves in any other part of that great continent.
  • The French, who attempted to settle in Florida, were all murdered by the
  • Spaniards. But the declension of the naval power of this latter nation, in
  • consequence of the defeat or miscarriage of what they called their
  • invincible armada, which happened towards the end of the sixteenth
  • century, put it out of their power to obstruct any longer the settlements
  • of the other European nations. In the course of the seventeenth century,
  • therefore, the English, French, Dutch, Danes, and Swedes, all the great
  • nations who had any ports upon the ocean, attempted to make some
  • settlements in the new world.
  • The Swedes established themselves in New Jersey; and the number of Swedish
  • families still to be found there sufficiently demonstrates, that this
  • colony was very likely to prosper, had it been protected by the mother
  • country. But being neglected by Sweden, it was soon swallowed up by the
  • Dutch colony of New York, which again, in 1674, fell under the dominion of
  • the English.
  • The small islands of St. Thomas and Santa Cruz, are the only countries in
  • the new world that have ever been possessed by the Danes. These little
  • settlements, too, were under the government of an exclusive company, which
  • had the sole right, both of purchasing the surplus produce of the
  • colonies, and of supplying them with such goods of other countries as they
  • wanted, and which, therefore, both in its purchases and sales, had not
  • only the power of oppressing them, but the greatest temptation to do so.
  • The government of an exclusive company of merchants is, perhaps, the worst
  • of all governments for any country whatever. It was not, however, able to
  • stop altogether the progress of these colonies, though it rendered it more
  • slow and languid. The late king of Denmark dissolved this company, and
  • since that time the prosperity of these colonies has been very great.
  • The Dutch settlements in the West, as well as those in the East Indies,
  • were originally put under the government of an exclusive company. The
  • progress of some of them, therefore, though it has been considerable in
  • comparison with that of almost any country that has been long peopled and
  • established, has been languid and slow in comparison with that of the
  • greater part of new colonies. The colony of Surinam, though very
  • considerable, is still inferior to the greater part of the sugar colonies
  • of the other European nations. The colony of Nova Belgia, now divided into
  • the two provinces of New York and New Jersey, would probably have soon
  • become considerable too, even though it had remained under the government
  • of the Dutch. The plenty and cheapness of good land are such powerful
  • causes of prosperity, that the very worst government is scarce capable of
  • checking altogether the efficacy of their operation. The great distance,
  • too, from the mother country, would enable the colonists to evade more or
  • less, by smuggling, the monopoly which the company enjoyed against them.
  • At present, the company allows all Dutch ships to trade to Surinam, upon
  • paying two and a-half per cent. upon the value of their cargo for a
  • license; and only reserves to itself exclusively, the direct trade from
  • Africa to America, which consists almost entirely in the slave trade. This
  • relaxation in the exclusive privileges of the company, is probably the
  • principal cause of that degree of prosperity which that colony at present
  • enjoys. Curacoa and Eustatia, the two principal islands belonging to the
  • Dutch, are free ports, open to the ships of all nations; and this freedom,
  • in the midst of better colonies, whose ports are open to those of one
  • nation only, has been the great cause of the prosperity of those two
  • barren islands.
  • The French colony of Canada was, during the greater part of the last
  • century, and some part of the present, under the government of an
  • exclusive company. Under so unfavourable an administration, its progress
  • was necessarily very slow, in comparison with that of other new colonies;
  • but it became much more rapid when this company was dissolved, after the
  • fall of what is called the Mississippi scheme. When the English got
  • possession of this country, they found in it near double the number of
  • inhabitants which father Charlevoix had assigned to it between twenty and
  • thirty years before. That jesuit had travelled over the whole country, and
  • had no inclination to represent it as less inconsiderable than it really
  • was.
  • The French colony of St. Domingo was established by pirates and
  • freebooters, who, for a long time, neither required the protection, nor
  • acknowledged the authority of France; and when that race of banditti
  • became so far citizens as to acknowledge this authority, it was for a long
  • time necessary to exercise it with very great gentleness. During this
  • period, the population and improvement of this colony increased very fast.
  • Even the oppression of the exclusive company, to which it was for some
  • time subjected with all the other colonies of France, though it no doubt
  • retarded, had not been able to stop its progress altogether. The course of
  • its prosperity returned as soon as it was relieved from that oppression.
  • It is now the most important of the sugar colonies of the West Indies, and
  • its produce is said to be greater than that of all the English sugar
  • colonies put together. The other sugar colonies of France are in general
  • all very thriving.
  • But there are no colonies of which the progress has been more rapid than
  • that of the English in North America.
  • Plenty of good land, and liberty to manage their own affairs their own
  • way, seem to be the two great causes of the prosperity of all new
  • colonies.
  • In the plenty of good land, the English colonies of North America, though
  • no doubt very abundantly provided, are, however, inferior to those of the
  • Spaniards and Portuguese, and not superior to some of those possessed by
  • the French before the late war. But the political institutions of the
  • English colonies have been more favourable to the improvement and
  • cultivation of this land, than those of the other three nations.
  • First, The engrossing of uncultivated land, though it has by no means been
  • prevented altogether, has been more restrained in the English colonies
  • than in any other. The colony law, which imposes upon every proprietor the
  • obligation of improving and cultivating, within a limited time, a certain
  • proportion of his lands, and which, in case of failure, declares those
  • neglected lands grantable to any other person; though it has not perhaps
  • been very strictly executed, has, however, had some effect.
  • Secondly, In Pennsylvania there is no right of primogeniture, and lands,
  • like moveables, are divided equally among all the children of the family.
  • In three of the provinces of New England, the oldest has only a double
  • share, as in the Mosaical law. Though in those provinces, therefore, too
  • great a quantity of land should sometimes be engrossed by a particular
  • individual, it is likely, in the course of a generation or two, to be
  • sufficiently divided again. In the other English colonies, indeed, the
  • right of primogeniture takes place, as in the law of England: But in all
  • the English colonies, the tenure of the lands, which are all held by free
  • soccage, facilitates alienation; and the grantee of an extensive tract of
  • land generally finds it for his interest to alienate, as fast as he can,
  • the greater part of it, reserving only a small quit-rent. In the Spanish
  • and Portuguese colonies, what is called the right of majorazzo takes place
  • in the succession of all those great estates to which any title of honour
  • is annexed. Such estates go all to one person, and are in effect entailed
  • and unalienable. The French colonies, indeed, are subject to the custom of
  • Paris, which, in the inheritance of land, is much more favourable to the
  • younger children than the law of England. But, in the French colonies, if
  • any part of an estate, held by the noble tenure of chivalry and homage, is
  • alienated, it is, for a limited time, subject to the right of redemption,
  • either by the heir of the superior, or by the heir of the family; and all
  • the largest estates of the country are held by such noble tenures, which
  • necessarily embarrass alienation. But, in a new colony, a great
  • uncultivated estate is likely to be much more speedily divided by
  • alienation than by succession. The plenty and cheapness of good land, it
  • has already been observed, are the principal causes of the rapid
  • prosperity of new colonies. The engrossing of land, in effect, destroys
  • this plenty and cheapness. The engrossing of uncultivated land, besides,
  • is the greatest obstruction to its improvement; but the labour that is
  • employed in the improvement and cultivation of land affords the greatest
  • and most valuable produce to the society. The produce of labour, in this
  • case, pays not only its own wages and the profit of the stock which
  • employs it, but the rent of the land too upon which it is employed. The
  • labour of the English colonies, therefore, being more employed in the
  • improvement and cultivation of land, is likely to afford a greater and
  • more valuable produce than that of any of the other three nations, which,
  • by the engrossing of land, is more or less diverted towards other
  • employments.
  • Thirdly, The labour of the English colonists is not only likely to afford
  • a greater and more valuable produce, but, in consequence of the moderation
  • of their taxes, a greater proportion of this produce belongs to
  • themselves, which they may store up and employ in putting into motion a
  • still greater quantity of labour. The English colonists have never yet
  • contributed any thing towards the defence of the mother country, or
  • towards the support of its civil government. They themselves, on the
  • contrary, have hitherto been defended almost entirely at the expense of
  • the mother country; but the expense of fleets and armies is out of all
  • proportion greater than the necessary expense of civil government. The
  • expense of their own civil government has always been very moderate. It
  • has generally been confined to what was necessary for paying competent
  • salaries to the governor, to the judges, and to some other officers of
  • police, and for maintaining a few of the most useful public works. The
  • expense of the civil establishment of Massachusetts Bay, before the
  • commencement of the present disturbances, used to be but about £18;000
  • a-year; that of New Hampshire and Rhode Island, £3500 each; that of
  • Connecticut, £4000; that of New York and Pennsylvania, £4500 each; that of
  • New Jersey, £1200; that of Virginia and South Carolina, £8000 each. The
  • civil establishments of Nova Scotia and Georgia are partly supported by an
  • annual grant of parliament; but Nova Scotia pays, besides, about £7000
  • a-year towards the public expenses of the colony, and Georgia about £2500
  • a-year. All the different civil establishments in North America, in short,
  • exclusive of those of Maryland and North Carolina, of which no exact
  • account has been got, did not, before the commencement of the present
  • disturbances, cost the inhabitants about £64,700 a-year; an ever memorable
  • example, at how small an expense three millions of people may not only be
  • governed but well governed. The most important part of the expense of
  • government, indeed, that of defence and protection, has constantly fallen
  • upon the mother country. The ceremonial, too, of the civil government in
  • the colonies, upon the reception of a new governor, upon the opening of a
  • new assembly, etc. though sufficiently decent, is not accompanied with any
  • expensive pomp or parade. Their ecclesiastical government is conducted
  • upon a plan equally frugal. Tithes are unknown among them; and their
  • clergy, who are far from being numerous, are maintained either by moderate
  • stipends, or by the voluntary contributions of the people. The power of
  • Spain and Portugal, on the contrary, derives some support from the taxes
  • levied upon their colonies. France, indeed, has never drawn any
  • considerable revenue from its colonies, the taxes which it levies upon
  • them being generally spent among them. But the colony government of all
  • these three nations is conducted upon a much more extensive plan, and is
  • accompanied with a much more expensive ceremonial. The sums spent upon the
  • reception of a new viceroy of Peru, for example, have frequently been
  • enormous. Such ceremonials are not only real taxes paid by the rich
  • colonists upon those particular occasions, but they serve to introduce
  • among them the habit of vanity and expense upon all other occasions. They
  • are not only very grievous occasional taxes, but they contribute to
  • establish perpetual taxes, of the same kind, still more grievous; the
  • ruinous taxes of private luxury and extravagance. In the colonies of all
  • those three nations, too, the ecclesiastical government is extremely
  • oppressive. Tithes take place in all of them, and are levied with the
  • utmost rigour in those of Spain and Portugal. All of them, besides, are
  • oppressed with a numerous race of mendicant friars, whose beggary being
  • not only licensed but consecrated by religion, is a most grievous tax upon
  • the poor people, who are most carefully taught that it is a duty to give,
  • and a very great sin to refuse them their charity. Over and above all
  • this, the clergy are, in all of them, the greatest engrossers of land.
  • Fourthly, In the disposal of their surplus produce, or of what is over and
  • above their own consumption, the English colonies have been more favoured,
  • and have been allowed a more extensive market, than those of any other
  • European nation. Every European nation has endeavoured, more or less, to
  • monopolize to itself the commerce of its colonies, and, upon that account,
  • has prohibited the ships of foreign nations from trading to them, and has
  • prohibited them from importing European goods from any foreign nation. But
  • the manner in which this monopoly has been exercised in different nations,
  • has been very different.
  • Some nations have given up the whole commerce of their colonies to an
  • exclusive company, of whom the colonists were obliged to buy all such
  • European goods as they wanted, and to whom they were obliged to sell the
  • whole of their surplus produce. It was the interest of the company,
  • therefore, not only to sell the former as dear, and to buy the latter as
  • cheap as possible, but to buy no more of the latter, even at this low
  • price, than what they could dispose of for a very high price in Europe. It
  • was their interest not only to degrade in all cases the value of the
  • surplus produce of the colony, but in many cases to discourage and keep
  • down the natural increase of its quantity. Of all the expedients that can
  • well be contrived to stunt the natural growth of a new colony, that of an
  • exclusive company is undoubtedly the most effectual. This, however, has
  • been the policy of Holland, though their company, in the course of the
  • present century, has given up in many respects the exertion of their
  • exclusive privilege. This, too, was the policy of Denmark, till the reign
  • of the late king. It has occasionally been the policy of France; and of
  • late, since 1755, after it had been abandoned by all other nations on
  • account of its absurdity, it has become the policy of Portugal, with
  • regard at least to two of the principal provinces of Brazil, Pernambucco,
  • and Marannon.
  • Other nations, without establishing an exclusive company, have confined
  • the whole commerce of their colonies to a particular port of the mother
  • country, from whence no ship was allowed to sail, but either in a fleet
  • and at a particular season, or, if single, in consequence of a particular
  • license, which in most cases was very well paid for. This policy opened,
  • indeed, the trade of the colonies to all the natives of the mother
  • country, provided they traded from the proper port, at the proper season,
  • and in the proper vessels. But as all the different merchants, who joined
  • their stocks in order to fit out those licensed vessels, would find it for
  • their interest to act in concert, the trade which was carried on in this
  • manner would necessarily be conducted very nearly upon the same principles
  • as that of an exclusive company. The profit of those merchants would be
  • almost equally exorbitant and oppressive. The colonies would be ill
  • supplied, and would be obliged both to buy very dear, and to sell very
  • cheap. This, however, till within these few years, had always been the
  • policy of Spain; and the price of all European goods, accordingly, is said
  • to have been enormous in the Spanish West Indies. At Quito, we are told by
  • Ulloa, a pound of iron sold for about 4s:6d., and a pound of steel for
  • about 6s:9d. sterling. But it is chiefly in order to purchase European
  • goods that the colonies part with their own produce. The more, therefore,
  • they pay for the one, the less they really get for the other, and the
  • dearness of the one is the same thing with the cheapness of the other. The
  • policy of Portugal is, in this respect, the same as the ancient policy of
  • Spain, with regard to all its colonies, except Pernambucco and Marannon;
  • and with regard to these it has lately adopted a still worse.
  • Other nations leave the trade of their colonies free to all their
  • subjects, who may carry it on from all the different ports of the mother
  • country, and who have occasion for no other license than the common
  • despatches of the custom-house. In this case the number and dispersed
  • situation of the different traders renders it impossible for them to enter
  • into any general combination, and their competition is sufficient to
  • hinder them from making very exorbitant profits. Under so liberal a
  • policy, the colonies are enabled both to sell their own produce, and to
  • buy the goods of Europe at a reasonable price; but since the dissolution
  • of the Plymouth company, when our colonies were but in their infancy, this
  • has always been the policy of England. It has generally, too, been that of
  • France, and has been uniformly so since the dissolution of what in England
  • is commonly called their Mississippi company. The profits of the trade,
  • therefore, which France and England carry on with their colonies, though
  • no doubt somewhat higher than if the competition were free to all other
  • nations, are, however, by no means exorbitant; and the price of European
  • goods, accordingly, is not extravagantly high in the greater past of the
  • colonies of either of those nations.
  • In the exportation of their own surplus produce, too, it is only with
  • regard to certain commodities that the colonies of Great Britain are
  • confined to the market of the mother country. These commodities having
  • been enumerated in the act of navigation, and in some other subsequent
  • acts, have upon that account been called enumerated commodities. The rest
  • are called non-enumerated, and may be exported directly to other
  • countries, provided it is in British or plantation ships, of which the
  • owners and three fourths of the mariners are British subjects.
  • Among the non-enumerated commodities are some of the most important
  • productions of America and the West Indies, grain of all sorts, lumber,
  • salt provisions, fish, sugar, and rum.
  • Grain is naturally the first and principal object of the culture of all
  • new colonies. By allowing them a very extensive market for it, the law
  • encourages them to extend this culture much beyond the consumption of a
  • thinly inhabited country, and thus to provide beforehand an ample
  • subsistence for a continually increasing population.
  • In a country quite covered with wood, where timber consequently is of
  • little or no value, the expense of clearing the ground is the principal
  • obstacle to improvement. By allowing the colonies a very extensive market
  • for their lumber, the law endeavours to facilitate improvement by raising
  • the price of a commodity which would otherwise be of little value, and
  • thereby enabling them to make some profit of what would otherwise be mere
  • expense.
  • In a country neither half peopled nor half cultivated, cattle naturally
  • multiply beyond the consumption of the inhabitants, and are often, upon
  • that account, of little or no value. But it is necessary, it has already
  • been shown, that the price of cattle should bear a certain proportion to
  • that of corn, before the greater part of the lands of any country can be
  • improved. By allowing to American cattle, in all shapes, dead and alive, a
  • very extensive market, the law endeavours to raise the value of a
  • commodity, of which the high price is so very essential to improvement.
  • The good effects of this liberty, however, must be somewhat diminished by
  • the 4th of Geo. III. c. 15, which puts hides and skins among the
  • enumerated commodities, and thereby tends to reduce the value of American
  • cattle.
  • To increase the shipping and naval power of Great Britain by the extension
  • of the fisheries of our colonies, is an object which the legislature seems
  • to have had almost constantly in view. Those fisheries, upon this account,
  • have had all the encouragement which freedom can give them, and they have
  • flourished accordingly. The New England fishery, in particular, was,
  • before the late disturbances, one of the most important, perhaps, in the
  • world. The whale fishery which, notwithstanding an extravagant bounty, is
  • in Great Britain carried on to so little purpose, that in the opinion of
  • many people ( which I do not, however, pretend to warrant), the whole
  • produce does not much exceed the value of the bounties which are annually
  • paid for it, is in New England carried on, without any bounty, to a very
  • great extent. Fish is one of the principal articles with which the North
  • Americans trade to Spain, Portugal, and the Mediterranean.
  • Sugar was originally an enumerated commodity, which could only be exported
  • to Great Britain; but in 1751, upon a representation of the
  • sugar-planters, its exportation was permitted to all parts of the world.
  • The restrictions, however, with which this liberty was granted, joined to
  • the high price of sugar in Great Britain, have rendered it in a great
  • measure ineffectual. Great Britain and her colonies still continue to be
  • almost the sole market for all sugar produced in the British plantations.
  • Their consumption increases so fast, that, though in consequence of the
  • increasing improvement of Jamaica, as well as of the ceded islands, the
  • importation of sugar has increased very greatly within these twenty years,
  • the exportation to foreign countries is said to be not much greater than
  • before.
  • Rum is a very important article in the trade which the Americans carry on
  • to the coast of Africa, from which they bring back negro slaves in return.
  • If the whole surplus produce of America, in grain of all sorts, in salt
  • provisions, and in fish, had been put into the enumeration, and thereby
  • forced into the market of Great Britain, it would have interfered too much
  • with the produce of the industry of our own people. It was probably not so
  • much from any regard to the interest of America, as from a jealousy of
  • this interference, that those important commodities have not only been
  • kept out of the enumeration, but that the importation into Great Britain
  • of all grain, except rice, and of all salt provisions, has, in the
  • ordinary state of the law, been prohibited.
  • The non-enumerated commodities could originally be exported to all parts
  • of the world. Lumber and rice having been once put into the enumeration,
  • when they were afterwards taken out of it, were confined, as to the
  • European market, to the countries that lie south of Cape Finisterre. By
  • the 6th of George III. c. 52, all non-enumerated commodities were
  • subjected to the like restriction. The parts of Europe which lie south of
  • Cape Finisterre are not manufacturing countries, and we are less jealous
  • of the colony ships carrying home from them any manufactures which could
  • interfere with our own.
  • The enumerated commodities are of two sorts; first, such as are either the
  • peculiar produce of America, or as cannot be produced, or at least are not
  • produced in the mother country. Of this kind are molasses, coffee,
  • cocoa-nuts, tobacco, pimento, ginger, whalefins, raw silk, cotton, wool,
  • beaver, and other peltry of America, indigo, fustick, and other dyeing
  • woods; secondly, such as are not the peculiar produce of America, but
  • which are, and may be produced in the mother country, though not in such
  • quantities as to supply the greater part of her demand, which is
  • principally supplied from foreign countries. Of this kind are all naval
  • stores, masts, yards, and bowsprits, tar, pitch, and turpentine, pig and
  • bar iron, copper ore, hides and skins, pot and pearl ashes. The largest
  • importation of commodities of the first kind could not discourage the
  • growth, or interfere with the sale, of any part of the produce of the
  • mother country. By confining them to the home market, our merchants, it
  • was expected, would not only be enabled to buy them cheaper in the
  • plantations, and consequently to sell them with a better profit at home,
  • but to establish between the plantations and foreign countries an
  • advantageous carrying trade, of which Great Britain was necessarily to be
  • the centre or emporium, as the European country into which those
  • commodities were first to be imported. The importation of commodities of
  • the second kind might be so managed too, it was supposed, as to interfere,
  • not with the sale of those of the same kind which were produced at home,
  • but with that of those which were imported from foreign countries;
  • because, by means of proper duties, they might be rendered always somewhat
  • dearer than the former, and yet a good deal cheaper than the latter. By
  • confining such commodities to the home market, therefore, it was proposed
  • to discourage the produce, not of Great Britain, but of some foreign
  • countries with which the balance of trade was believed to be unfavourable
  • to Great Britain.
  • The prohibition of exporting from the colonies to any other country but
  • Great Britain, masts, yards, and bowsprits, tar, pitch, and turpentine,
  • naturally tended to lower the price of timber in the colonies, and
  • consequently to increase the expense of clearing their lands, the
  • principal obstacle to their improvement. But about the beginning of the
  • present century, in 1703, the pitch and tar company of Sweden endeavoured
  • to raise the price of their commodities to Great Britain, by prohibiting
  • their exportation, except in their own ships, at their own price, and in
  • such quantities as they thought proper. In order to counteract this
  • notable piece of mercantile policy, and to render herself as much as
  • possible independent, not only of Sweden, but of all the other northern
  • powers, Great Britain gave a bounty upon the importation of naval stores
  • from America; and the effect of this bounty was to raise the price of
  • timber in America much more than the confinement to the home market could
  • lower it; and as both regulations were enacted at the same time, their
  • joint effect was rather to encourage than to discourage the clearing of
  • land in America.
  • Though pig and bar iron, too, have been put among the enumerated
  • commodities, yet as, when imported from America, they are exempted from
  • considerable duties to which they are subject when imported front any
  • other country, the one part of the regulation contributes more to
  • encourage the erection of furnaces in America than the other to discourage
  • it. There is no manufacture which occasions so great a consumption of wood
  • as a furnace, or which can contribute so much to the clearing of a country
  • overgrown with it.
  • The tendency of some of these regulations to raise the value of timber in
  • America, and thereby to facilitate the clearing of the land, was neither,
  • perhaps, intended nor understood by the legislature. Though their
  • beneficial effects, however, have been in this respect accidental, they
  • have not upon that account been less real.
  • The most perfect freedom of trade is permitted between the British
  • colonies of America and the West Indies, both in the enumerated and in the
  • non-enumerated commodities Those colonies are now become so populous and
  • thriving, that each of them finds in some of the others a great and
  • extensive market for every part of its produce. All of them taken
  • together, they make a great internal market for the produce of one
  • another.
  • The liberality of England, however, towards the trade of her colonies, has
  • been confined chiefly to what concerns the market for their produce,
  • either in its rude state, or in what may be called the very first stage of
  • manufacture. The more advanced or more refined manufactures, even of the
  • colony produce, the merchants and manufacturers of Great Britain chuse to
  • reserve to themselves, and have prevailed upon the legislature to prevent
  • their establishment in the colonies, sometimes by high duties, and
  • sometimes by absolute prohibitions.
  • While, for example, Muscovado sugars from the British plantations pay,
  • upon importation, only 6s:4d. the hundred weight, white sugars pay £1:1:1;
  • and refined, either double or single, in loaves, £4:2:5 8/20ths. When
  • those high duties were imposed, Great Britain was the sole, and she still
  • continues to be, the principal market, to which the sugars of the British
  • colonies could be exported. They amounted, therefore, to a prohibition, at
  • first of claying or refining sugar for any foreign market, and at present
  • of claying or refining it for the market which takes off, perhaps, more
  • than nine-tenths of the whole produce. The manufacture of claying or
  • refining sugar, accordingly, though it has flourished in all the sugar
  • colonies of France, has been little cultivated in any of those of England,
  • except for the market of the colonies themselves. While Grenada was in the
  • hands of the French, there was a refinery of sugar, by claying, at least
  • upon almost every plantation. Since it fell into those of the English,
  • almost all works of this kind have been given up; and there are at present
  • (October 1773), I am assured, not above two or three remaining in the
  • island. At present, however, by an indulgence of the custom-house, clayed
  • or refined sugar, if reduced from loaves into powder, is commonly imported
  • as Muscovado.
  • While Great Britain encourages in America the manufacturing of pig and bar
  • iron, by exempting them from duties to which the like commodities are
  • subject when imported from any other country, she imposes an absolute
  • prohibition upon the erection of steel furnaces and slit-mills in any of
  • her American plantations. She will not suffer her colonies to work in
  • those more refined manufactures, even for their own consumption; but
  • insists upon their purchasing of her merchants and manufacturers all goods
  • of this kind which they have occasion for.
  • She prohibits the exportation from one province to another by water, and
  • even the carriage by land upon horseback, or in a cart, of hats, of wools,
  • and woollen goods, of the produce of America; a regulation which
  • effectually prevents the establishment of any manufacture of such
  • commodities for distant sale, and confines the industry of her colonists
  • in this way to such coarse and household manufactures as a private family
  • commonly makes for its own use, or for that of some of its neighbours in
  • the same province.
  • To prohibit a great people, however, from making all that they can of
  • every part of their own produce, or from employing their stock and
  • industry in the way that they judge most advantageous to themselves, is a
  • manifest violation of the most sacred rights of mankind. Unjust, however,
  • as such prohibitions may be, they have not hitherto been very hurtful to
  • the colonies. Land is still so cheap, and, consequently, labour so dear
  • among them, that they can import from the mother country almost all the
  • more refined or more advanced manufactures cheaper than they could make
  • them for themselves. Though they had not, therefore, been prohibited from
  • establishing such manufactures, yet, in their present state of
  • improvement, a regard to their own interest would probably have prevented
  • them from doing so. In their present state of improvement, those
  • prohibitions, perhaps, without cramping their industry, or restraining it
  • from any employment to which it would have gone of its own accord, are
  • only impertinent badges of slavery imposed upon them, without any
  • sufficient reason, by the groundless jealousy of the merchants and
  • manufacturers of the mother country. In a more advanced state, they might
  • be really oppressive and insupportable.
  • Great Britain, too, as she confines to her own market some of the most
  • important productions of the colonies, so, in compensation, she gives to
  • some of them an advantage in that market, sometimes by imposing higher
  • duties upon the like productions when imported from other countries, and
  • sometimes by giving bounties upon their importation from the colonies. In
  • the first way, she gives an advantage in the home market to the sugar,
  • tobacco, and iron of her own colonies; and, in the second, to their raw
  • silk, to their hemp and flax, to their indigo, to their naval stores, and
  • to their building timber. This second way of encouraging the colony
  • produce, by bounties upon importation, is, so far as I have been able to
  • learn, peculiar to Great Britain: the first is not. Portugal does not
  • content herself with imposing higher duties upon the importation of
  • tobacco from any other country, but prohibits it under the severest
  • penalties.
  • With regard to the importation of goods from Europe, England has likewise
  • dealt more liberally with her colonies than any other nation.
  • Great Britain allows a part, almost always the half, generally a larger
  • portion, and sometimes the whole, of the duty which is paid upon the
  • importation of foreign goods, to be drawn back upon their exportation to
  • any foreign country. No independent foreign country, it was easy to
  • foresee, would receive them, if they came to it loaded with the heavy
  • duties to which almost all foreign goods are subjected on their
  • importation into Great Britain. Unless, therefore, some part of those
  • duties was drawn back upon exportation, there was an end of the carrying
  • trade; a trade so much favoured by the mercantile system.
  • Our colonies, however, are by no means independent foreign countries; and
  • Great Britain having assumed to herself the exclusive right of supplying
  • them with all goods from Europe, might have forced them (in the same
  • manner as other countries have done their colonies) to receive such goods
  • loaded with all the same duties which they paid in the mother country.
  • But, on the contrary, till 1763, the same drawbacks were paid upon the
  • exportation of the greater part of foreign goods to our colonies, as to
  • any independent foreign country. In 1763, indeed, by the 4th of Geo. III.
  • c. 15, this indulgence was a good deal abated, and it was enacted, “That
  • no part of the duty called the old subsidy should be drawn back for any
  • goods of the growth, production, or manufacture of Europe or the East
  • Indies, which should be exported from this kingdom to any British colony
  • or plantation in America; wines, white calicoes, and muslins, excepted.”
  • Before this law, many different sorts of foreign goods might have been
  • bought cheaper in the plantations than in the mother country, and some may
  • still.
  • Of the greater part of the regulations concerning the colony trade, the
  • merchants who carry it on, it must be observed, have been the principal
  • advisers. We must not wonder, therefore, if, in a great part of them,
  • their interest has been more considered than either that of the colonies
  • or that of the mother country. In their exclusive privilege of supplying
  • the colonies with all the goods which they wanted from Europe, and of
  • purchasing all such parts of their surplus produce as could not interfere
  • with any of the trades which they themselves carried on at home, the
  • interest of the colonies was sacrificed to the interest of those
  • merchants. In allowing the same drawbacks upon the re-exportation of the
  • greater part of European and East India goods to the colonies, as upon
  • their re-exportation to any independent country, the interest of the
  • mother country was sacrificed to it, even according to the mercantile
  • ideas of that interest. It was for the interest of the merchants to pay as
  • little as possible for the foreign goods which they sent to the colonies,
  • and, consequently, to get back as much as possible of the duties which
  • they advanced upon their importation into Great Britain. They might
  • thereby be enabled to sell in the colonies, either the same quantity of
  • goods with a greater profit, or a greater quantity with the same profit,
  • and, consequently, to gain something either in the one way or the other.
  • It was likewise for the interest of the colonies to get all such goods as
  • cheap, and in as great abundance as possible. But this might not always be
  • for the interest of the mother country. She might frequently suffer, both
  • in her revenue, by giving back a great part of the duties which had been
  • paid upon the importation of such goods; and in her manufactures, by being
  • undersold in the colony market, in consequence of the easy terms upon
  • which foreign manufactures could be carried thither by means of those
  • drawbacks. The progress of the linen manufacture of Great Britain, it is
  • commonly said, has been a good deal retarded by the drawbacks upon the
  • re-exportation of German linen to the American colonies.
  • But though the policy of Great Britain, with regard to the trade of her
  • colonies, has been dictated by the same mercantile spirit as that of other
  • nations, it has, however, upon the whole, been less illiberal and
  • oppressive than that of any of them.
  • In every thing except their foreign trade, the liberty of the English
  • colonists to manage their own affairs their own way, is complete. It is in
  • every respect equal to that of their fellow-citizens at home, and is
  • secured in the same manner, by an assembly of the representatives of the
  • people, who claim the sole right of imposing taxes for the support of the
  • colony government. The authority of this assembly overawes the executive
  • power; and neither the meanest nor the most obnoxious colonist, as long as
  • he obeys the law, has any thing to fear from the resentment, either of the
  • governor, or of any other civil or military officer in the province. The
  • colony assemblies, though, like the house of commons in England, they are
  • not always a very equal representation of the people, yet they approach
  • more nearly to that character; and as the executive power either has not
  • the means to corrupt them, or, on account of the support which it receives
  • from the mother country, is not under the necessity of doing so, they are,
  • perhaps, in general more influenced by the inclinations of their
  • constituents. The councils, which, in the colony legislatures, correspond
  • to the house of lords in Great Britain, are not composed of a hereditary
  • nobility. In some of the colonies, as in three of the governments of New
  • England, those councils are not appointed by the king, but chosen by the
  • representatives of the people. In none of the English colonies is there
  • any hereditary nobility. In all of them, indeed, as in all other free
  • countries, the descendant of an old colony family is more respected than
  • an upstart of equal merit and fortune; but he is only more respected, and
  • he has no privileges by which he can be troublesome to his neighbours.
  • Before the commencement of the present disturbances, the colony assemblies
  • had not only the legislative, but a part of the executive power. In
  • Connecticut and Rhode Island, they elected the governor. In the other
  • colonies, they appointed the revenue officers, who collected the taxes
  • imposed by those respective assemblies, to whom those officers were
  • immediately responsible. There is more equality, therefore, among the
  • English colonists than among the inhabitants of the mother country. Their
  • manners are more re publican; and their governments, those of three of the
  • provinces of New England in particular, have hitherto been more republican
  • too.
  • The absolute governments of Spain, Portugal, and France, on the contrary,
  • take place in their colonies; and the discretionary powers which such
  • governments commonly delegate to all their inferior officers are, on
  • account of the great distance, naturally exercised there with more than
  • ordinary violence. Under all absolute governments, there is more liberty
  • in the capital than in any other part of the country. The sovereign
  • himself can never have either interest or inclination to pervert the order
  • of justice, or to oppress the great body of the people. In the capital,
  • his presence overawes, more or less, all his inferior officers, who, in
  • the remoter provinces, from whence the complaints of the people are less
  • likely to reach him, can exercise their tyranny with much more safety. But
  • the European colonies in America are more remote than the most distant
  • provinces of the greatest empires which had ever been known before. The
  • government of the English colonies is, perhaps, the only one which, since
  • the world began, could give perfect security to the inhabitants of so very
  • distant a province. The administration of the French colonies, however,
  • has always been conducted with much more gentleness and moderation than
  • that of the Spanish and Portuguese. This superiority of conduct is
  • suitable both to the character of the French nation, and to what forms the
  • character of every nation, the nature of their government, which, though
  • arbitrary and violent in comparison with that of Great Britain, is legal
  • and free in comparison with those of Spain and Portugal.
  • It is in the progress of the North American colonies, however, that the
  • superiority of the English policy chiefly appears. The progress of the
  • sugar colonies of France has been at least equal, perhaps superior, to
  • that of the greater part of those of England; and yet the sugar colonies
  • of England enjoy a free government, nearly of the same kind with that
  • which takes place in her colonies of North America. But the sugar colonies
  • of France are not discouraged, like those of England, from refining their
  • own sugar; and what is still of greater importance, the genius of their
  • government naturally introduces a better management of their negro slaves.
  • In all European colonies, the culture of the sugar-cane is carried on by
  • negro slaves. The constitution of those who have been born in the
  • temperate climate of Europe could not, it is supposed, support the labour
  • of digging the ground under the burning sun of the West Indies; and the
  • culture of the sugar-cane, as it is managed at present, is all hand
  • labour; though, in the opinion of many, the drill plough might be
  • introduced into it with great advantage. But, as the profit and success of
  • the cultivation which is carried on by means of cattle, depend very much
  • upon the good management of those cattle; so the profit and success of
  • that which is carried on by slaves must depend equally upon the good
  • management of those slaves; and in the good management of their slaves the
  • French planters, I think it is generally allowed, are superior to the
  • English. The law, so far as it gives some weak protection to the slave
  • against the violence of his master, is likely to be better executed in a
  • colony where the government is in a great measure arbitrary, than in one
  • where it is altogether free. In ever country where the unfortunate law of
  • slavery is established, the magistrate, when he protects the slave,
  • intermeddles in some measure in the management of the private property of
  • the master; and, in a free country, where the master is, perhaps, either a
  • member of the colony assembly, or an elector of such a member, he dares
  • not do this but with the greatest caution and circumspection. The respect
  • which he is obliged to pay to the master, renders it more difficult for
  • him to protect the slave. But in a country where the government is in a
  • great measure arbitrary, where it is usual for the magistrate to
  • intermeddle even in the management of the private property of individuals,
  • and to send them, perhaps, a lettre de cachet, if they do not manage it
  • according to his liking, it is much easier for him to give some protection
  • to the slave; and common humanity naturally disposes him to do so. The
  • protection of the magistrate renders the slave less contemptible in the
  • eyes of his master, who is thereby induced to consider him with more
  • regard, and to treat him with more gentleness. Gentle usage renders the
  • slave not only more faithful, but more intelligent, and, therefore, upon a
  • double account, more useful. He approaches more to the condition of a free
  • servant, and may possess some degree of integrity and attachment to his
  • master’s interest; virtues which frequently belong to free servants, but
  • which never can belong to a slave, who is treated as slaves commonly are
  • in countries where the master is perfectly free and secure.
  • That the condition of a slave is better under an arbitrary than under a
  • free government, is, I believe, supported by the history of all ages and
  • nations. In the Roman history, the first time we read of the magistrate
  • interposing to protect the slave from the violence of his master, is under
  • the emperors. When Vidius Pollio, in the presence of Augustus, ordered one
  • of his slaves, who had committed a slight fault, to be cut into pieces and
  • thrown into his fish-pond, in order to feed his fishes, the emperor
  • commanded him, with indignation, to emancipate immediately, not only that
  • slave, but all the others that belonged to him. Under the republic no
  • magistrate could have had authority enough to protect the slave, much less
  • to punish the master.
  • The stock, it is to be observed, which has improved the sugar colonies of
  • France, particularly the great colony of St Domingo, has been raised
  • almost entirely from the gradual improvement and cultivation of those
  • colonies. It has been almost altogether the produce of the soil and of the
  • industry of the colonists, or, what comes to the same thing, the price of
  • that produce, gradually accumulated by good management, and employed in
  • raising a still greater produce. But the stock which has improved and
  • cultivated the sugar colonies of England, has, a great part of it, been
  • sent out from England, and has by no means been altogether the produce of
  • the soil and industry of the colonists. The prosperity of the English
  • sugar colonies has been in a great measure owing to the great riches of
  • England, of which a part has overflowed, if one may say so, upon these
  • colonies. But the prosperity of the sugar colonies of France has been
  • entirely owing to the good conduct of the colonists, which must therefore
  • have had some superiority over that of the English; and this superiority
  • has been remarked in nothing so much as in the good management of their
  • slaves.
  • Such have been the general outlines of the policy of the different
  • European nations with regard to their colonies.
  • The policy of Europe, therefore, has very little to boast of, either in
  • the original establishment, or, so far as concerns their internal
  • government, in the subsequent prosperity of the colonies of America.
  • Folly and injustice seem to have been the principles which presided over
  • and directed the first project of establishing those colonies; the folly
  • of hunting after gold and silver mines, and the injustice of coveting the
  • possession of a country whose harmless natives, far from having ever
  • injured the people of Europe, had received the first adventurers with
  • every mark of kindness and hospitality.
  • The adventurers, indeed, who formed some of the latter establishments,
  • joined to the chimerical project of finding gold and silver mines, other
  • motives more reasonable and more laudable; but even these motives do very
  • little honour to the policy of Europe.
  • The English puritans, restrained at home, fled for freedom to America, and
  • established there the four governments of New England. The English
  • catholics, treated with much greater injustice, established that of
  • Maryland; the quakers, that of Pennsylvania. The Portuguese Jews,
  • persecuted by the inquisition, stript of their fortunes, and banished to
  • Brazil, introduced, by their example, some sort of order and industry
  • among the transported felons and strumpets by whom that colony was
  • originally peopled, and taught them the culture of the sugar-cane. Upon
  • all these different occasions, it was not the wisdom and policy, but the
  • disorder and injustice of the European governments, which peopled and
  • cultivated America.
  • In effectuation some of the most important of these establishments, the
  • different governments of Europe had as little merit as in projecting them.
  • The conquest of Mexico was the project, not of the council of Spain, but
  • of a governor of Cuba; and it was effectuated by the spirit of the bold
  • adventurer to whom it was entrusted, in spite of every thing which that
  • governor, who soon repented of having trusted such a person, could do to
  • thwart it. The conquerors of Chili and Peru, and of almost all the other
  • Spanish settlements upon the continent of America, carried out with them
  • no other public encouragement, but a general permission to make
  • settlements and conquests in the name of the king of Spain. Those
  • adventures were all at the private risk and expense of the adventurers.
  • The government of Spain contributed scarce any thing to any of them. That
  • of England contributed as little towards effectuating the establishment of
  • some of its most important colonies in North America.
  • When those establishments were effectuated, and had become so considerable
  • as to attract the attention of the mother country, the first regulations
  • which she made with regard to them, had always in view to secure to
  • herself the monopoly of their commerce; to confine their market, and to
  • enlarge her own at their expense, and, consequently, rather to damp and
  • discourage, than to quicken and forward the course of their prosperity. In
  • the different ways in which this monopoly has been exercised, consists one
  • of the most essential differences in the policy of the different European
  • nations with regard to their colonies. The best of them all, that of
  • England, is only somewhat less illiberal and oppressive than that of any
  • of the rest.
  • In what way, therefore, has the policy of Europe contributed either to the
  • first establishment, or to the present grandeur of the colonies of
  • America? In one way, and in one way only, it has contributed a good deal.
  • Magna virum mater! It bred and formed the men who were capable of
  • achieving such great actions, and of laying the foundation of so great an
  • empire; and there is no other quarter of the world; of which the policy is
  • capable of forming, or has ever actually, and in fact, formed such men.
  • The colonies owe to the policy of Europe the education and great views of
  • their active and enterprizing founders; and some of the greatest and most
  • important of them, so far as concerns their internal government, owe to it
  • scarce anything else.
  • PART III. Of the Advantages which Europe has derived From the Discovery of
  • America, and from that of a Passage to the East Indies by the Cape of Good
  • Hope.
  • Such are the advantages which the colonies of America have derived from
  • the policy of Europe.
  • What are those which Europe has derived from the discovery and
  • colonization of America?
  • Those advantages may be divided, first, into the general advantages which
  • Europe, considered as one great country, has derived from those great
  • events; and, secondly, into the particular advantages which each
  • colonizing country has derived from the colonies which particularly belong
  • to it, in consequence of the authority or dominion which it exercises over
  • them.
  • The general advantages which Europe, considered as one great country, has
  • derived from the discovery and colonization of America, consist, first, in
  • the increase of its enjoyments; and, secondly, in the augmentation of its
  • industry.
  • The surplus produce of America imported into Europe, furnishes the
  • inhabitants of this great continent with a variety of commodities which
  • they could not otherwise have possessed; some for conveniency and use,
  • some for pleasure, and some for ornament; and thereby contributes to
  • increase their enjoyments.
  • The discovery and colonization of America, it will readily be allowed,
  • have contributed to augment the industry, first, of all the countries
  • which trade to it directly, such as Spain, Portugal, France, and England;
  • and, secondly, of all those which, without trading to it directly, send,
  • through the medium of other countries, goods to it of their own produce,
  • such as Austrian Flanders, and some provinces of Germany, which, through
  • the medium of the countries before mentioned, send to it a considerable
  • quantity of linen and other goods. All such countries have evidently
  • gained a more extensive market for their surplus produce, and must
  • consequently have been encouraged to increase its quantity.
  • But that those great events should likewise have contributed to encourage
  • the industry of countries such as Hungary and Poland, which may never,
  • perhaps, have sent a single commodity of their own produce to America, is
  • not, perhaps, altogether so evident. That those events have done so,
  • however, cannot be doubted. Some part of the produce of America is
  • consumed in Hungary and Poland, and there is some demand there for the
  • sugar, chocolate, and tobacco, of that new quarter of the world. But those
  • commodities must be purchased with something which is either the produce
  • of the industry of Hungary and Poland, or with something which had been
  • purchased with some part of that produce. Those commodities of America are
  • new values, new equivalents, introduced into Hungary and Poland, to be
  • exchanged there for the surplus produce of these countries. By being
  • carried thither, they create a new and more extensive market for that
  • surplus produce. They raise its value, and thereby contribute to encourage
  • its increase. Though no part of it may ever be carried to America, it may
  • be carried to other countries, which purchase it with a part of their
  • share of the surplus produce of America, and it may find a market by means
  • of the circulation of that trade which was originally put into motion by
  • the surplus produce of America.
  • Those great events may even have contributed to increase the enjoyments,
  • and to augment the industry, of countries which not only never sent any
  • commodities to America, but never received any from it. Even such
  • countries may have received a greater abundance of other commodities from
  • countries, of which the surplus produce had been augmented by means of the
  • American trade. This greater abundance, as it must necessarily have
  • increased their enjoyments, so it must likewise have augmented their
  • industry. A greater number of new equivalents, of some kind or other, must
  • have been presented to them to be exchanged for the surplus produce of
  • that industry. A more extensive market must have been created for that
  • surplus produce, so as to raise its value, and thereby encourage its
  • increase. The mass of commodities annually thrown into the great circle of
  • European commerce, and by its various revolutions annually distributed
  • among all the different nations comprehended within it, must have been
  • augmented by the whole surplus produce of America. A greater share of this
  • greater mass, therefore, is likely to have fallen to each of those
  • nations, to have increased their enjoyments, and augmented their industry.
  • The exclusive trade of the mother countries tends to diminish, or at least
  • to keep down below what they would otherwise rise to, both the enjoyments
  • and industry of all those nations in general, and of the American colonies
  • in particular. It is a dead weight upon the action of one of the great
  • springs which puts into motion a great part of the business of mankind. By
  • rendering the colony produce dearer in all other countries, it lessens its
  • consumption, and thereby cramps the industry of the colonies, and both the
  • enjoyments and the industry of all other countries, which both enjoy less
  • when they pay more for what they enjoy, and produce less when they get
  • less for what they produce. By rendering the produce of all other
  • countries dearer in the colonies, it cramps in the same manner the
  • industry of all other colonies, and both the enjoyments and the industry
  • of the colonies. It is a clog which, for the supposed benefit of some
  • particular countries, embarrasses the pleasures and encumbers the industry
  • of all other countries, but of the colonies more than of any other. It not
  • only excludes as much as possible all other countries from one particular
  • market, but it confines as much as possible the colonies to one particular
  • market; and the difference is very great between being excluded from one
  • particular market when all others are open, and being confined to one
  • particular market when all others are shut up. The surplus produce of the
  • colonies, however, is the original source of all that increase of
  • enjoyments and industry which Europe derives from the discovery and
  • colonization of America, and the exclusive trade of the mother countries
  • tends to render this source much less abundant than it otherwise would be.
  • The particular advantages which each colonizing country derives from the
  • colonies which particularly belong to it, are of two different kinds;
  • first, those common advantages which every empire derives from the
  • provinces subject to its dominion; and, secondly, those peculiar
  • advantages which are supposed to result from provinces of so very peculiar
  • a nature as the European colonies of America.
  • The common advantages which every empire derives from the provinces
  • subject to its dominion consist, first, in the military force which they
  • furnish for its defence; and, secondly, in the revenue which they furnish
  • for the support of its civil government. The Roman colonies furnished
  • occasionally both the one and the other. The Greek colonies sometimes
  • furnished a military force, but seldom any revenue. They seldom
  • acknowledged themselves subject to the dominion of the mother city. They
  • were generally her allies in war, but very seldom her subjects in peace.
  • The European colonies of America have never yet furnished any military
  • force for the defence of the mother country. The military force has never
  • yet been sufficient for their own defence; and in the different wars in
  • which the mother countries have been engaged, the defence of their
  • colonies has generally occasioned a very considerable distraction of the
  • military force of those countries. In this respect, therefore, all the
  • European colonies have, without exception, been a cause rather of weakness
  • than of strength to their respective mother countries.
  • The colonies of Spain and Portugal only have contributed any revenue
  • towards the defence of the mother country, or the support of her civil
  • government. The taxes which have been levied upon those of other European
  • nations, upon those of England in particular, have seldom been equal to
  • the expense laid out upon them in time of peace, and never sufficient to
  • defray that which they occasioned in time of war. Such colonies,
  • therefore, have been a source of expense, and not of revenue, to their
  • respective mother countries.
  • The advantages of such colonies to their respective mother countries,
  • consist altogether in those peculiar advantages which are supposed to
  • result from provinces of so very peculiar a nature as the European
  • colonies of America; and the exclusive trade, it is acknowledged, is the
  • sole source of all those peculiar advantages.
  • In consequence of this exclusive trade, all that part of the surplus
  • produce of the English colonies, for example, which consists in what are
  • called enumerated commodities, can be sent to no other country but
  • England. Other countries must afterwards buy it of her. It must be
  • cheaper, therefore, in England than it can be in any other country, and
  • must contribute more to increase the enjoyments of England than those of
  • any other country. It must likewise contribute more to encourage her
  • industry. For all those parts of her own surplus produce which England
  • exchanges for those enumerated commodities, she must get a better price
  • than any other countries can get for the like parts of theirs, when they
  • exchange them for the same commodities. The manufactures of England, for
  • example, will purchase a greater quantity of the sugar and tobacco of her
  • own colonies than the like manufactures of other countries can purchase of
  • that sugar and tobacco. So far, therefore, as the manufactures of England
  • and those of other countries are both to be exchanged for the sugar and
  • tobacco of the English colonies, this superiority of price gives an
  • encouragement to the former beyond what the latter can, in these
  • circumstances, enjoy. The exclusive trade of the colonies, therefore, as
  • it diminishes, or at least keeps down below what they would otherwise rise
  • to, both the enjoyments and the industry of the countries which do not
  • possess it, so it gives an evident advantage to the countries which do
  • possess it over those other countries.
  • This advantage, however, will, perhaps, be found to be rather what may be
  • called a relative than an absolute advantage, and to give a superiority to
  • the country which enjoys it, rather by depressing the industry and produce
  • of other countries, than by raising those of that particular country above
  • what they would naturally rise to in the case of a free trade.
  • The tobacco of Maryland and Virginia, for example, by means of the
  • monopoly which England enjoys of it, certainly comes cheaper to England
  • than it can do to France to whom England commonly sells a considerable
  • part of it. But had France and all other European countries been at all
  • times allowed a free trade to Maryland and Virginia, the tobacco of those
  • colonies might by this time have come cheaper than it actually does, not
  • only to all those other countries, but likewise to England. The produce of
  • tobacco, in consequence of a market so much more extensive than any which
  • it has hitherto enjoyed, might, and probably would, by this time have been
  • so much increased as to reduce the profits of a tobacco plantation to
  • their natural level with those of a corn plantation, which it is supposed
  • they are still somewhat above. The price of tobacco might, and probably
  • would, by this time have fallen somewhat lower than it is at present. An
  • equal quantity of the commodities, either of England or of those other
  • countries, might have purchased in Maryland and Virginia a greater
  • quantity of tobacco than it can do at present, and consequently have been
  • sold there for so much a better price. So far as that weed, therefore,
  • can, by its cheapness and abundance, increase the enjoyments, or augment
  • the industry, either of England or of any other country, it would
  • probably, in the case of a free trade, have produced both these effects in
  • somewhat a greater degree than it can do at present. England, indeed,
  • would not, in this case, have had any advantage over other countries. She
  • might have bought the tobacco of her colonies somewhat cheaper, and
  • consequently have sold some of her own commodities somewhat dearer, than
  • she actually does; but she could neither have bought the one cheaper, nor
  • sold the other dearer, than any other country might have done. She might,
  • perhaps, have gained an absolute, but she would certainly have lost a
  • relative advantage.
  • In order, however, to obtain this relative advantage in the colony trade,
  • in order to execute the invidious and malignant project of excluding, as
  • much as possible, other nations from any share in it, England, there are
  • very probable reasons for believing, has not only sacrificed a part of the
  • absolute advantage which she, as well as every other nation, might have
  • derived from that trade, but has subjected herself both to an absolute and
  • to a relative disadvantage in almost every other branch of trade.
  • When, by the act of navigation, England assumed to herself the monopoly of
  • the colony trade, the foreign capitals which had before been employed in
  • it, were necessarily withdrawn from it. The English capital, which had
  • before carried on but a part of it, was now to carry on the whole. The
  • capital which had before supplied the colonies with but a part of the
  • goods which they wanted from Europe, was now all that was employed to
  • supply them with the whole. But it could not supply them with the whole;
  • and the goods with which it did supply them were necessarily sold very
  • dear. The capital which had before bought but a part of the surplus
  • produce of the colonies, was now all that was employed to buy the whole.
  • But it could not buy the whole at any thing near the old price; and
  • therefore, whatever it did buy, it necessarily bought very cheap. But in
  • an employment of capital, in which the merchant sold very dear, and bought
  • very cheap, the profit must have been very great, and much above the
  • ordinary level of profit in other branches of trade. This superiority of
  • profit in the colony trade could not fail to draw from other branches of
  • trade a part of the capital which had before been employed in them. But
  • this revulsion of capital, as it must have gradually increased the
  • competition of capitals in the colony trade, so it must have gradually
  • diminished that competition in all those other branches of trade; as it
  • must have gradually lowered the profits of the one, so it must have
  • gradually raised those of the other, till the profits of all came to a new
  • level, different from, and somewhat higher, than that at which they had
  • been before.
  • This double effect of drawing capital from all other trades, and of
  • raising the rate of profit somewhat higher than it otherwise would have
  • been in all trades, was not only produced by this monopoly upon its first
  • establishment, but has continued to be produced by it ever since.
  • First, This monopoly has been continually drawing capital from all other
  • trades, to be employed in that of the colonies.
  • Though the wealth of Great Britain has increased very much since the
  • establishment of the act of navigation, it certainly has not increased in
  • the same proportion as that or the colonies. But the foreign trade of
  • every country naturally increases in proportion to its wealth, its surplus
  • produce in proportion to its whole produce; and Great Britain having
  • engrossed to herself almost the whole of what may be called the foreign
  • trade of the colonies, and her capital not having increased in the same
  • proportion as the extent of that trade, she could not carry it on without
  • continually withdrawing from other branches of trade some part of the
  • capital which had before been employed in them, as well as withholding
  • from them a great deal more which would otherwise have gone to them. Since
  • the establishment of the act of navigation, accordingly, the colony trade
  • has been continually increasing, while many other branches of foreign
  • trade, particularly of that to other parts of Europe, have been
  • continually decaying. Our manufactures for foreign sale, instead of being
  • suited, as before the act of navigation, to the neighbouring market of
  • Europe, or to the more distant one of the countries which lie round the
  • Mediterranean sea, have the greater part of them, been accommodated to the
  • still more distant one of the colonies; to the market in which they have
  • the monopoly, rather than to that in which they have many competitors. The
  • causes of decay in other branches of foreign trade, which, by Sir Matthew
  • Decker and other writers, have been sought for in the excess and improper
  • mode of taxation, in the high price of labour, in the increase of luxury,
  • etc. may all be found in the overgrowth of the colony trade. The
  • mercantile capital of Great Britain, though very great, yet not being
  • infinite, and though greatly increased since the act of navigation, yet
  • not being increased in the same proportion as the colony trade, that trade
  • could not possibly be carried on without withdrawing some part of that
  • capital from other branches of trade, nor consequently without some decay
  • of those other branches.
  • England, it must be observed, was a great trading country, her mercantile
  • capital was very great, and likely to become still greater and greater
  • every day, not only before the act of navigation had established the
  • monopoly of the corn trade, but before that trade was very considerable.
  • In the Dutch war, during the government of Cromwell, her navy was superior
  • to that of Holland; and in that which broke out in the beginning of the
  • reign of Charles II., it was at least equal, perhaps superior to the
  • united navies of France and Holland. Its superiority, perhaps, would
  • scarce appear greater in the present times, at least if the Dutch navy
  • were to bear the same proportion to the Dutch commerce now which it did
  • then. But this great naval power could not, in either of those wars, be
  • owing to the act of navigation. During the first of them, the plan of that
  • act had been but just formed; and though, before the breaking out of the
  • second, it had been fully enacted by legal authority, yet no part of it
  • could have had time to produce any considerable effect, and least of all
  • that part which established the exclusive trade to the colonies. Both the
  • colonies and their trade were inconsiderable then, in comparison of what
  • they are how. The island of Jamaica was an unwholesome desert, little
  • inhabited, and less cultivated. New York and New Jersey were in the
  • possession of the Dutch, the half of St. Christopher’s in that of the
  • French. The island of Antigua, the two Carolinas, Pennsylvania, Georgia,
  • and Nova Scotia, were not planted. Virginia, Maryland, and New England
  • were planted; and though they were very thriving colonies, yet there was
  • not perhaps at that time, either in Europe or America, a single person who
  • foresaw, or even suspected, the rapid progress which they have since made
  • in wealth, population, and improvement. The island of Barbadoes, in short,
  • was the only British colony of any consequence, of which the condition at
  • that time bore any resemblance to what it is at present. The trade of the
  • colonies, of which England, even for some time after the act of
  • navigation, enjoyed but a part (for the act of navigation was not very
  • strictly executed till several years after it was enacted), could not at
  • that time be the cause of the great trade of England, nor of the great
  • naval power which was supported by that trade. The trade which at that
  • time supported that great naval power was the trade of Europe, and of the
  • countries which lie round the Mediterranean sea. But the share which Great
  • Britain at present enjoys of that trade could not support any such great
  • naval power. Had the growing trade of the colonies been left free to all
  • nations, whatever share of it might have fallen to Great Britain, and a
  • very considerable share would probably have fallen to her, must have been
  • all an addition to this great trade of which she was before in possession.
  • In consequence of the monopoly, the increase of the colony trade has not
  • so much occasioned an addition to the trade which Great Britain had
  • before, as a total change in its direction.
  • Secondly, This monopoly has necessarily contributed to keep up the rate of
  • profit, in all the different branches of British trade, higher than it
  • naturally would have been, had all nations been allowed a free trade to
  • the British colonies.
  • The monopoly of the colony trade, as it necessarily drew towards that
  • trade a greater proportion of the capital of Great Britain than what would
  • have gone to it of its own accord, so, by the expulsion of all foreign
  • capitals, it necessarily reduced the whole quantity of capital employed in
  • that trade below what it naturally would have been in the case of a free
  • trade. But, by lessening the competition of capitals in that branch of
  • trade, it necessarily raised the rate of profit in that branch. By
  • lessening, too, the competition of British capitals in all other branches
  • of trade, it necessarily raised the rate of British profit in all those
  • other branches. Whatever may have been, at any particular period since the
  • establishment of the act of navigation, the state or extent of the
  • mercantile capital of Great Britain, the monopoly of the colony trade
  • must, during the continuance of that state, have raised the ordinary rate
  • of British profit higher than it otherwise would have been, both in that
  • and in all the other branches of British trade. If, since the
  • establishment of the act of navigation, the ordinary rate of British
  • profit has fallen considerably, as it certainly has, it must have fallen
  • still lower, had not the monopoly established by that act contributed to
  • keep it up.
  • But whatever raises, in any country, the ordinary rate of profit higher
  • than it otherwise would be, necessarily subjects that country both to an
  • absolute, and to a relative disadvantage in every branch of trade of which
  • she has not the monopoly.
  • It subjects her to an absolute disadvantage; because, in such branches of
  • trade, her merchants cannot get this greater profit without selling dearer
  • than they otherwise would do, both the goods of foreign countries which
  • they import into their own, and the goods of their own country which they
  • export to foreign countries. Their own country must both buy dearer and
  • sell dearer; must both buy less, and sell less; must both enjoy less and
  • produce less, than she otherwise would do.
  • It subjects her to a relative disadvantage; because, in such branches of
  • trade, it sets other countries, which are not subject to the same absolute
  • disadvantage, either more above her or less below her, than they otherwise
  • would be. It enables them both to enjoy more and to produce more, in
  • proportion to what she enjoys and produces. It renders their superiority
  • greater, or their inferiority less, than it otherwise would be. By raising
  • the price of her produce above what it otherwise would be, it enables the
  • merchants of other countries to undersell her in foreign markets, and
  • thereby to justle her out of almost all those branches of trade, of which
  • she has not the monopoly.
  • Our merchants frequently complain of the high wages of British labour, as
  • the cause of their manufactures being undersold in foreign markets; but
  • they are silent about the high profits of stock. They complain of the
  • extravagant gain of other people; but they say nothing of their own. The
  • high profits of British stock, however, may contribute towards raising the
  • price of British manufactures, in many cases, as much, and in some perhaps
  • more, than the high wages of British labour.
  • It is in this manner that the capital of Great Britain, one may justly
  • say, has partly been drawn and partly been driven from the greater part of
  • the different branches of trade of which she has not the monopoly; from
  • the trade of Europe, in particular, and from that of the countries which
  • lie round the Mediterranean sea.
  • It has partly been drawn from those branches of trade, by the attraction
  • of superior profit in the colony trade, in consequence of the continual
  • increase of that trade, and of the continual insufficiency of the capital
  • which had carried it on one year to carry it on the next.
  • It has partly been driven from them, by the advantage which the high rate
  • of profit established in Great Britain gives to other countries, in all
  • the different branches of trade of which Great Britain has not the
  • monopoly.
  • As the monopoly of the colony trade has drawn from those other branches a
  • part of the British capital, which would otherwise have been employed in
  • them, so it has forced into them many foreign capitals which would never
  • have gone to them, had they not been expelled from the colony trade. In
  • those other branches of trade, it has diminished the competition of
  • British capitals, and thereby raised the rate of British profit higher
  • than it otherwise would have been. On the contrary, it has increased the
  • competition of foreign capitals, and thereby sunk the rate of foreign
  • profit lower than it otherwise would have been. Both in the one way and in
  • the other, it must evidently have subjected Great Britain to a relative
  • disadvantage in all those other branches of trade.
  • The colony trade, however, it may perhaps be said, is more advantageous to
  • Great Britain than any other; and the monopoly, by forcing into that trade
  • a greater proportion of the capital of Great Britain than what would
  • otherwise have gone to it, has turned that capital into an employment,
  • more advantageous to the country than any other which it could have found.
  • The most advantageous employment of any capital to the country to which it
  • belongs, is that which maintains there the greatest quantity of productive
  • labour, and increases the most the annual produce of the land and labour
  • of that country. But the quantity of productive labour which any capital
  • employed in the foreign trade of consumption can maintain, is exactly in
  • proportion, it has been shown in the second book, to the frequency of its
  • returns. A capital of a thousand pounds, for example, employed in a
  • foreign trade of consumption, of which the returns are made regularly once
  • in the year, can keep in constant employment, in the country to which it
  • belongs, a quantity of productive labour, equal to what a thousand pounds
  • can maintain there for a year. If the returns are made twice or thrice in
  • the year, it can keep in constant employment a quantity of productive
  • labour, equal to what two or three thousand pounds can maintain there for
  • a year. A foreign trade of consumption carried on with a neighbouring, is,
  • upon that account, in general, more advantageous than one carried on with
  • a distant country; and, for the same reason, a direct foreign trade of
  • consumption, as it has likewise been shown in the second book, is in
  • general more advantageous than a round-about one.
  • But the monopoly of the colony trade, so far as it has operated upon the
  • employment of the capital of Great Britain, has, in all cases, forced some
  • part of it from a foreign trade of consumption carried on with a
  • neighbouring, to one carried on with a more distant country, and in many
  • cases from a direct foreign trade of consumption to a round-about one.
  • First, The monopoly of the colony trade has, in all cases, forced some
  • part of the capital of Great Britain from a foreign trade of consumption
  • carried on with a neighbouring, to one carried on with a more distant
  • country.
  • It has, in all cases, forced some part of that capital from the trade with
  • Europe, and with the countries which lie round the Mediterranean sea, to
  • that with the more distant regions of America and the West Indies; from
  • which the returns are necessarily less frequent, not only on account of
  • the greater distance, but on account of the peculiar circumstances of
  • those countries. New colonies, it has already been observed, are always
  • understocked. Their capital is always much less than what they could
  • employ with great profit and advantage in the improvement and cultivation
  • of their land. They have a constant demand, therefore, for more capital
  • than they have of their own; and, in order to supply the deficiency of
  • their own, they endeavour to borrow as much as they can of the mother
  • country, to whom they are, therefore, always in debt. The most common way
  • in which the colonies contract this debt, is not by borrowing upon bond of
  • the rich people of the mother country, though they sometimes do this too,
  • but by running as much in arrear to their correspondents, who supply them
  • with goods from Europe, as those correspondents will allow them. Their
  • annual returns frequently do not amount to more than a third, and
  • sometimes not to so great a proportion of what they owe. The whole
  • capital, therefore, which their correspondents advance to them, is seldom
  • returned to Britain in less than three, and sometimes not in less than
  • four or five years. But a British capital of a thousand pounds, for
  • example, which is returned to Great Britain only once in five years, can
  • keep in constant employment only one-fifth part of the British industry
  • which it could maintain, if the whole was returned once in the year; and,
  • instead of the quantity of industry which a thousand pounds could maintain
  • for a year, can keep in constant employment the quantity only which two
  • hundred pounds can maintain for a year. The planter, no doubt, by the high
  • price which he pays for the goods from Europe, by the interest upon the
  • bills which he grants at distant dates, and by the commission upon the
  • renewal of those which he grants at near dates, makes up, and probably
  • more than makes up, all the loss which his correspondent can sustain by
  • this delay. But, though he make up the loss of his correspondent, he
  • cannot make up that of Great Britain. In a trade of which the returns are
  • very distant, the profit of the merchant may be as great or greater than
  • in one in which they are very frequent and near; but the advantage of the
  • country in which he resides, the quantity of productive labour constantly
  • maintained there, the annual produce of the land and labour, must always
  • be much less. That the returns of the trade to America, and still more
  • those of that to the West Indies, are, in general, not only more distant,
  • but more irregular and more uncertain, too, than those of the trade to any
  • part of Europe, or even of the countries which lie round the Mediterranean
  • sea, will readily be allowed, I imagine, by everybody who has any
  • experience of those different branches of trade.
  • Secondly, The monopoly of the colony trade, has, in many cases, forced
  • some part of the capital of Great Britain from a direct foreign trade of
  • consumption, into a round-about one.
  • Among the enumerated commodities which can be sent to no other market but
  • Great Britain, there are several of which the quantity exceeds very much
  • the consumption of Great Britain, and of which, a part, therefore, must be
  • exported to other countries. But this cannot be done without forcing some
  • part of the capital of Great Britain into a round-about foreign trade of
  • consumption. Maryland, and Virginia, for example, send annually to Great
  • Britain upwards of ninety-six thousand hogsheads of tobacco, and the
  • consumption of Great Britain is said not to exceed fourteen thousand.
  • Upwards of eighty-two thousand hogsheads, therefore, must be exported to
  • other countries, to France, to Holland, and, to the countries which lie
  • round the Baltic and Mediterranean seas. But that part of the capital of
  • Great Britain which brings those eighty-two thousand hogsheads to Great
  • Britain, which re-exports them from thence to those other countries, and
  • which brings back from those other countries to Great Britain either goods
  • or money in return, is employed in a round-about foreign trade of
  • consumption; and is necessarily forced into this employment, in order to
  • dispose of this great surplus. If we would compute in how many years the
  • whole of this capital is likely to come back to Great Britain, we must add
  • to the distance of the American returns that of the returns from those
  • other countries. If, in the direct foreign trade of consumption which we
  • carry on with America, the whole capital employed frequently does not come
  • back in less than three or four years, the whole capital employed in this
  • round-about one is not likely to come back in less than four or five. If
  • the one can keep in constant employment but a third or a fourth part of
  • the domestic industry which could be maintained by a capital returned once
  • in the year, the other can keep in constant employment but a fourth or a
  • fifth part of that industry. At some of the outports a credit is commonly
  • given to those foreign correspondents to whom they export them tobacco. At
  • the port of London, indeed, it is commonly sold for ready money: the rule
  • is Weigh and pay. At the port of London, therefore, the final returns of
  • the whole round-about trade are more distant than the returns from
  • America, by the time only which the goods may lie unsold in the warehouse;
  • where, however, they may sometimes lie long enough. But, had not the
  • colonies been confined to the market of Great Britain for the sale of
  • their tobacco, very little more of it would probably have come to us than
  • what was necessary for the home consumption. The goods which Great Britain
  • purchases at present for her own consumption with the great surplus of
  • tobacco which she exports to other countries, she would, in this case,
  • probably have purchased with the immediate produce of her own industry, or
  • with some part of her own manufactures. That produce, those manufactures,
  • instead of being almost entirely suited to one great market, as at
  • present, would probably have been fitted to a great number of smaller
  • markets. Instead of one great round-about foreign trade of consumption,
  • Great Britain would probably have carried on a great number of small
  • direct foreign trades of the same kind. On account of the frequency of the
  • returns, a part, and probably but a small part, perhaps not above a third
  • or a fourth of the capital which at present carries on this great
  • round-about trade, might have been sufficient to carry on all those small
  • direct ones; might have kept inconstant employment an equal quantity of
  • British industry; and have equally supported the annual produce of the
  • land and labour of Great Britain. All the purposes of this trade being, in
  • this manner, answered by a much smaller capital, there would have been a
  • large spare capital to apply to other purposes; to improve the lands, to
  • increase the manufactures, and to extend the commerce of Great Britain; to
  • come into competition at least with the other British capitals employed in
  • all those different ways, to reduce the rate of profit in them all, and
  • thereby to give to Great Britain, in all of them, a superiority over other
  • countries, still greater than what she at present enjoys.
  • The monopoly of the colony trade, too, has forced some part of the capital
  • of Great Britain from all foreign trade of consumption to a carrying
  • trade; and, consequently from supporting more or less the industry of
  • Great Britain, to be employed altogether in supporting partly that of the
  • colonies, and partly that of some other countries.
  • The goods, for example, which are annually purchased with the great
  • surplus of eighty-two thousand hogsheads of tobacco annually re-exported
  • from Great Britain, are not all consumed in Great Britain. Part of them,
  • linen from Germany and Holland, for example, is returned to the colonies
  • for their particular consumption. But that part of the capital of Great
  • Britain which buys the tobacco with which this linen is afterwards bought,
  • is necessarily withdrawn from supporting the industry of Great Britain, to
  • be employed altogether in supporting, partly that of the colonies, and
  • partly that of the particular countries who pay for this tobacco with the
  • produce of their own industry.
  • The monopoly of the colony trade, besides, by forcing towards it a much
  • greater proportion of the capital of Great Britain than what would
  • naturally have gone to it, seems to have broken altogether that natural
  • balance which would otherwise have taken place among all the different
  • branches of British industry. The industry of Great Britain, instead of
  • being accommodated to a great number of small markets, has been
  • principally suited to one great market. Her commerce, instead of running
  • in a great number of small channels, has been taught to run principally in
  • one great channel. But the whole system of her industry and commerce has
  • thereby been rendered less secure; the whole state of her body politic
  • less healthful than it otherwise would have been. In her present
  • condition, Great Britain resembles one of those unwholesome bodies in
  • which some of the vital parts are overgrown, and which, upon that account,
  • are liable to many dangerous disorders, scarce incident to those in which
  • all the parts are more properly proportioned. A small stop in that great
  • blood-vessel, which has been artificially swelled beyond its natural
  • dimensions, and through which an unnatural proportion of the industry and
  • commerce of the country has been forced to circulate, is very likely to
  • bring on the most dangerous disorders upon the whole body politic. The
  • expectation of a rupture with the colonies, accordingly, has struck the
  • people of Great Britain with more terror than they ever felt for a Spanish
  • armada, or a French invasion. It was this terror, whether well or ill
  • grounded, which rendered the repeal of the stamp act, among the merchants
  • at least, a popular measure. In the total exclusion from the colony
  • market, was it to last only for a few years, the greater part of our
  • merchants used to fancy that they foresaw an entire stop to their trade;
  • the greater part of our master manufacturers, the entire ruin of their
  • business; and the greater part of our workmen, an end of their employment.
  • A rupture with any of our neighbours upon the continent, though likely,
  • too, to occasion some stop or interruption in the employments of some of
  • all these different orders of people, is foreseen, however, without any
  • such general emotion. The blood, of which the circulation is stopt in some
  • of the smaller vessels, easily disgorges itself into the greater, without
  • occasioning any dangerous disorder; but, when it is stopt in any of the
  • greater vessels, convulsions, apoplexy, or death, are the immediate and
  • unavoidable consequences. If but one of those overgrown manufactures,
  • which, by means either of bounties or of the monopoly of the home and
  • colony markets, have been artificially raised up to any unnatural height,
  • finds some small stop or interruption in its employment, it frequently
  • occasions a mutiny and disorder alarming to government, and embarrassing
  • even to the deliberations of the legislature. How great, therefore, would
  • be the disorder and confusion, it was thought, which must necessarily be
  • occasioned by a sudden and entire stop in the employment of so great a
  • proportion of our principal manufacturers?
  • Some moderate and gradual relaxation of the laws which give to Great
  • Britain the exclusive trade to the colonies, till it is rendered in a
  • great measure free, seems to be the only expedient which can, in all
  • future times, deliver her from this danger; which can enable her, or even
  • force her, to withdraw some part of her capital from this overgrown
  • employment, and to turn it, though with less profit, towards other
  • employments; and which, by gradually diminishing one branch of her
  • industry, and gradually increasing all the rest, can, by degrees, restore
  • all the different branches of it to that natural, healthful, and proper
  • proportion, which perfect liberty necessarily establishes, and which
  • perfect liberty can alone preserve. To open the colony trade all at once
  • to all nations, might not only occasion some transitory inconveniency, but
  • a great permanent loss, to the greater part of those whose industry or
  • capital is at present engaged in it. The sudden loss of the employment,
  • even of the ships which import the eighty-two thousand hogsheads of
  • tobacco, which are over and above the consumption of Great Britain, might
  • alone be felt very sensibly. Such are the unfortunate effects of all the
  • regulations of the mercantile system. They not only introduce very
  • dangerous disorders into the state of the body politic, but disorders
  • which it is often difficult to remedy, without occasioning, for a time at
  • least, still greater disorders. In what manner, therefore, the colony
  • trade ought gradually to be opened; what are the restraints which ought
  • first, and what are those which ought last, to be taken away; or in what
  • manner the natural system of perfect liberty and justice ought gradually
  • to be restored, we must leave to the wisdom of future statesmen and
  • legislators to determine.
  • Five different events, unforeseen and unthought of, have very fortunately
  • concurred to hinder Great Britain from feeling, so sensibly as it was
  • generally expected she would, the total exclusion which has now taken
  • place for more than a year (from the first of December 1774) from a very
  • important branch of the colony trade, that of the twelve associated
  • provinces of North America. First, those colonies, in preparing themselves
  • for their non-importation agreement, drained Great Britain completely of
  • all the commodities which were fit for their market; secondly, the extra
  • ordinary demand of the Spanish flota has, this year, drained Germany and
  • the north of many commodities, linen in particular, which used to come
  • into competition, even in the British market, with the manufactures of
  • Great Britain; thirdly, the peace between Russia and Turkey has occasioned
  • an extraordinary demand from the Turkey market, which, during the distress
  • of the country, and while a Russian fleet was cruizing in the Archipelago,
  • had been very poorly supplied; fourthly, the demand of the north of Europe
  • for the manufactures of Great Britain has been increasing from year to
  • year, for some time past; and, fifthly, the late partition, and
  • consequential pacification of Poland, by opening the market of that great
  • country, have, this year, added an extraordinary demand from thence to the
  • increasing demand of the north. These events are all, except the fourth,
  • in their nature transitory and accidental; and the exclusion from so
  • important a branch of the colony trade, if unfortunately it should
  • continue much longer, may still occasion some degree of distress. This
  • distress, however, as it will come on gradually, will be felt much less
  • severely than if it had come on all at once; and, in the mean time, the
  • industry and capital of the country may find a new employment and
  • direction, so as to prevent this distress from ever rising to any
  • considerable height.
  • The monopoly of the colony trade, therefore, so far as it has turned
  • towards that trade a greater proportion of the capital of Great Britain
  • than what would otherwise have gone to it, has in all cases turned it,
  • from a foreign trade of consumption with a neighbouring, into one with a
  • more distant country; in many cases from a direct foreign trade of
  • consumption into a round-about one; and, in some cases, from all foreign
  • trade of consumption into a carrying trade. It has, in all cases,
  • therefore, turned it from a direction in which it would have maintained a
  • greater quantity of productive labour, into one in which it can maintain a
  • much smaller quantity. By suiting, besides, to one particular market only,
  • so great a part of the industry and commerce of Great Britain, it has
  • rendered the whole state of that industry and commerce more precarious and
  • less secure, than if their produce had been accommodated to a greater
  • variety of markets.
  • We must carefully distinguish between the effects of the colony trade and
  • those of the monopoly of that trade. The former are always and necessarily
  • beneficial; the latter always and necessarily hurtful. But the former are
  • so beneficial, that the colony trade, though subject to a monopoly, and,
  • notwithstanding the hurtful effects of that monopoly, is still, upon the
  • whole, beneficial, and greatly beneficial, though a good deal less so than
  • it otherwise would be.
  • The effect of the colony trade, in its natural and free state, is to open
  • a great though distant market, for such parts of the produce of British
  • industry as may exceed the demand of the markets nearer home, of those of
  • Europe, and of the countries which lie round the Mediterranean sea. In its
  • natural and free state, the colony trade, without drawing from those
  • markets any part of the produce which had ever been sent to them,
  • encourages Great Britain to increase the surplus continually, by
  • continually presenting new equivalents to be exchanged for it. In its
  • natural and free state, the colony trade tends to increase the quantity of
  • productive labour in Great Britain, but without altering in any respect
  • the direction of that which had been employed there before. In the natural
  • and free state of the colony trade, the competition of all other nations
  • would hinder the rate of profit from rising above the common level, either
  • in the new market, or in the new employment. The new market, without
  • drawing any thing from the old one, would create, if one may say so, a new
  • produce for its own supply; and that new produce would constitute a new
  • capital for carrying on the new employment, which, in the same manner,
  • would draw nothing from the old one.
  • The monopoly of the colony trade, on the contrary, by excluding the
  • competition of other nations, and thereby raising the rate of profit, both
  • in the new market and in the new employment, draws produce from the old
  • market, and capital from the old employment. To augment our share of the
  • colony trade beyond what it otherwise would be, is the avowed purpose of
  • the monopoly. If our share of that trade were to be no greater with, than
  • it would have been without the monopoly, there could have been no reason
  • for establishing the monopoly. But whatever forces into a branch of trade,
  • of which the returns are slower and more distant than those of the greater
  • part of other trades, a greater proportion of the capital of any country,
  • than what of its own accord would go to that branch, necessarily renders
  • the whole quantity of productive labour annually maintained there, the
  • whole annual produce of the land and labour of that country, less than
  • they otherwise would be. It keeps down the revenue of the inhabitants of
  • that country below what it would naturally rise to, and thereby diminishes
  • their power of accumulation. It not only hinders, at all times, their
  • capital from maintaining so great a quantity of productive labour as it
  • would otherwise maintain, but it hinders it from increasing so fast as it
  • would otherwise increase, and, consequently, from maintaining a still
  • greater quantity of productive labour.
  • The natural good effects of the colony trade, however, more than
  • counterbalance to Great Britain the bad effects of the monopoly; so that,
  • monopoly and altogether, that trade, even as it is carried on at present,
  • is not only advantageous, but greatly advantageous. The new market and the
  • new employment which are opened by the colony trade, are of much greater
  • extent than that portion of the old market and of the old employment which
  • is lost by the monopoly. The new produce and the new capital which has
  • been created, if one may say so, by the colony trade, maintain in Great
  • Britain a greater quantity of productive labour than what can have been
  • thrown out of employment by the revulsion of capital from other trades of
  • which the returns are more frequent. If the colony trade, however, even as
  • it is carried on at present, is advantageous to Great Britain, it is not
  • by means of the monopoly, but in spite of the monopoly.
  • It is rather for the manufactured than for the rude produce of Europe,
  • that the colony trade opens a new market. Agriculture is the proper
  • business of all new colonies; a business which the cheapness of land
  • renders more advantageous than any other. They abound, therefore, in the
  • rude produce of land; and instead of importing it from other countries,
  • they have generally a large surplus to export. In new colonies,
  • agriculture either draws hands from all other employments, or keeps them
  • from going to any other employment. There are few hands to spare for the
  • necessary, and none for the ornamental manufactures. The greater part of
  • the manufactures of both kinds they find it cheaper to purchase of other
  • countries than to make for themselves. It is chiefly by encouraging the
  • manufactures of Europe, that the colony trade indirectly encourages its
  • agriculture. The manufacturers of Europe, to whom that trade gives
  • employment, constitute a new market for the produce of the land, and the
  • most advantageous of all markets; the home market for the corn and cattle,
  • for the bread and butcher’s meat of Europe, is thus greatly extended by
  • means of the trade to America.
  • But that the monopoly of the trade of populous and thriving colonies is
  • not alone sufficient to establish, or even to maintain, manufactures in
  • any country, the examples of Spain and Portugal sufficiently demonstrate.
  • Spain and Portugal were manufacturing countries before they had any
  • considerable colonies. Since they had the richest and most fertile in the
  • world, they have both ceased to be so.
  • In Spain and Portugal, the bad effects of the monopoly, aggravated by
  • other causes, have, perhaps, nearly overbalanced the natural good effects
  • of the colony trade. These causes seem to be other monopolies of different
  • kinds: the degradation of the value of gold and silver below what it is in
  • most other countries; the exclusion from foreign markets by improper taxes
  • upon exportation, and the narrowing of the home market, by still more
  • improper taxes upon the transportation of goods from one part of the
  • country to another; but above all, that irregular and partial
  • administration of justice which often protects the rich and powerful
  • debtor from the pursuit of his injured creditor, and which makes the
  • industrious part of the nation afraid to prepare goods for the consumption
  • of those haughty and great men, to whom they dare not refuse to sell upon
  • credit, and from whom they are altogether uncertain of repayment.
  • In England, on the contrary, the natural good effects of the colony trade,
  • assisted by other causes, have in a great measure conquered the bad
  • effects of the monopoly. These causes seem to be, the general liberty of
  • trade, which, notwithstanding some restraints, is at least equal, perhaps
  • superior, to what it is in any other country; the liberty of exporting,
  • duty free, almost all sorts of goods which are the produce of domestic
  • industry, to almost any foreign country; and what, perhaps, is of still
  • greater importance, the unbounded liberty of transporting them from one
  • part of our own country to any other, without being obliged to give any
  • account to any public office, without being liable to question or
  • examination of any kind; but, above all, that equal and impartial
  • administration of justice, which renders the rights of the meanest British
  • subject respectable to the greatest, and which, by securing to every man
  • the fruits of his own industry, gives the greatest and most effectual
  • encouragement to every sort of industry.
  • If the manufactures of Great Britain, however, have been advanced, as they
  • certainly have, by the colony trade, it has not been by means of the
  • monopoly of that trade, but in spite of the monopoly. The effect of the
  • monopoly has been, not to augment the quantity, but to alter the quality
  • and shape of a part of the manufactures of Great Britain, and to
  • accommodate to a market, from which the returns are slow and distant, what
  • would otherwise have been accommodated to one from which the returns are
  • frequent and near. Its effect has consequently been, to turn a part of the
  • capital of Great Britain from an employment in which it would have
  • maintained a greater quantity of manufacturing industry, to one in which
  • it maintains a much smaller, and thereby to diminish, instead of
  • increasing, the whole quantity of manufacturing industry maintained in
  • Great Britain.
  • The monopoly of the colony trade, therefore, like all the other mean and
  • malignant expedients of the mercantile system, depresses the industry of
  • all other countries, but chiefly that of the colonies, without in the
  • least increasing, but on the contrary diminishing, that of the country in
  • whose favour it is established.
  • The monopoly hinders the capital of that country, whatever may, at any
  • particular time, be the extent of that capital, from maintaining so great
  • a quantity of productive labour as it would otherwise maintain, and from
  • affording so great a revenue to the industrious inhabitants as it would
  • otherwise afford. But as capital can be increased only by savings from
  • revenue, the monopoly, by hindering it from affording so great a revenue
  • as it would otherwise afford, necessarily hinders it from increasing so
  • fast as it would otherwise increase, and consequently from maintaining a
  • still greater quantity of productive labour, and affording a still greater
  • revenue to the industrious inhabitants of that country. One great original
  • source of revenue, therefore, the wages of labour, the monopoly must
  • necessarily have rendered, at all times, less abundant than it otherwise
  • would have been.
  • By raising the rate of mercantile profit, the monopoly discourages the
  • improvement of land. The profit of improvement depends upon the difference
  • between what the land actually produces, and what, by the application of a
  • certain capital, it can be made to produce. If this difference affords a
  • greater profit than what can be drawn from an equal capital in any
  • mercantile employment, the improvement of land will draw capital from all
  • mercantile employments. If the profit is less, mercantile employments will
  • draw capital from the improvement of land. Whatever, therefore, raises the
  • rate of mercantile profit, either lessens the superiority, or increases
  • the inferiority of the profit of improvement: and, in the one case,
  • hinders capital from going to improvement, and in the other draws capital
  • from it; but by discouraging improvement, the monopoly necessarily retards
  • the natural increase of another great original source of revenue, the rent
  • of land. By raising the rate of profit, too, the monopoly necessarily
  • keeps up the market rate of interest higher than it otherwise would be.
  • But the price of land, in proportion to the rent which it affords, the
  • number of years purchase which is commonly paid for it, necessarily falls
  • as the rate of interest rises, and rises as the rate of interest falls.
  • The monopoly, therefore, hurts the interest of the landlord two different
  • ways, by retarding the natural increase, first, of his rent, and,
  • secondly, of the price which he would get for his land, in proportion to
  • the rent which it affords.
  • The monopoly, indeed, raises the rate of mercantile profit and thereby
  • augments somewhat the gain of our merchants. But as it obstructs the
  • natural increase of capital, it tends rather to diminish than to increase
  • the sum total of the revenue which the inhabitants of the country derive
  • from the profits of stock; a small profit upon a great capital generally
  • affording a greater revenue than a great profit upon a small one. The
  • monopoly raises the rate of profit, but it hinders the sum of profit from
  • rising so high as it otherwise would do.
  • All the original sources of revenue, the wages of labour, the rent of
  • land, and the profits of stock, the monopoly renders much less abundant
  • than they otherwise would be. To promote the little interest of one little
  • order of men in one country, it hurts the interest of all other orders of
  • men in that country, and of all the men in all other countries.
  • It is solely by raising the ordinary rate of profit, that the monopoly
  • either has proved, or could prove, advantageous to any one particular
  • order of men. But besides all the bad effects to the country in general,
  • which have already been mentioned as necessarily resulting from a higher
  • rate of profit, there is one more fatal, perhaps, than all these put
  • together, but which, if we may judge from experience, is inseparably
  • connected with it. The high rate of profit seems everywhere to destroy
  • that parsimony which, in other circumstances, is natural to the character
  • of the merchant. When profits are high, that sober virtue seems to be
  • superfluous, and expensive luxury to suit better the affluence of his
  • situation. But the owners of the great mercantile capitals are necessarily
  • the leaders and conductors of the whole industry of every nation; and
  • their example has a much greater influence upon the manners of the whole
  • industrious part of it than that of any other order of men. If his
  • employer is attentive and parsimonious, the workman is very likely to be
  • so too; but if the master is dissolute and disorderly, the servant, who
  • shapes his work according to the pattern which his master prescribes to
  • him, will shape his life, too, according to the example which he sets him.
  • Accumulation is thus prevented in the hands of all those who are naturally
  • the most disposed to accumulate; and the funds destined for the
  • maintenance of productive labour, receive no augmentation from the revenue
  • of those who ought naturally to augment them the most. The capital of the
  • country, instead of increasing, gradually dwindles away, and the quantity
  • of productive labour maintained in it grows every day less and less. Have
  • the exorbitant profits of the merchants of Cadiz and Lisbon augmented the
  • capital of Spain and Portugal? Have they alleviated the poverty, have they
  • promoted the industry, of those two beggarly countries? Such has been the
  • tone of mercantile expense in those two trading cities, that those
  • exorbitant profits, far from augmenting the general capital of the
  • country, seem scarce to have been sufficient to keep up the capitals upon
  • which they were made. Foreign capitals are every day intruding themselves,
  • if I may say so, more and more into the trade of Cadiz and Lisbon. It is
  • to expel those foreign capitals from a trade which their own grows every
  • day more and more insufficient for carrying on, that the Spaniards and
  • Portuguese endeavour every day to straiten more and more the galling bands
  • of their absurd monopoly. Compare the mercantile manners of Cadiz and
  • Lisbon with those of Amsterdam, and you will be sensible how differently
  • the conduct and character of merchants are affected by the high and by the
  • low profits of stock. The merchants of London, indeed, have not yet
  • generally become such magnificent lords as those of Cadiz and Lisbon; but
  • neither are they in general such attetitive and parsimonious burghers as
  • those of Amsterdam. They are supposed, however, many of them, to be a good
  • deal richer than the greater part of the former, and not quire so rich as
  • many of the latter: but the rate of their profit is commonly much lower
  • than that of the former, and a good deal higher than that of the latter.
  • Light come, light go, says the proverb; and the ordinary tone of expense
  • seems everywhere to be regulated, not so much according to the real
  • ability of spending, as to the supposed facility of getting money to
  • spend.
  • It is thus that the single advantage which the monopoly procures to a
  • single order of men, is in many different ways hurtful to the general
  • interest of the country.
  • To found a great empire for the sole purpose of raising up a people of
  • customers, may at first sight, appear a project fit only for a nation of
  • shopkeepers. It is, however, a project altogether unfit for a nation of
  • shopkeepers, but extremely fit for a nation whose government is influenced
  • by shopkeepers. Such statesmen, and such statesmen only, are capable of
  • fancying that they will find some advantage in employing the blood and
  • treasure of their fellow-citizens, to found and maintain such an empire.
  • Say to a shopkeeper, Buy me a good estate, and I shall always buy my
  • clothes at your shop, even though I should pay somewhat dearer than what I
  • can have them for at other shops; and you will not find him very forward
  • to embrace your proposal. But should any other person buy you such an
  • estate, the shopkeeper will be much obliged to your benefactor if he would
  • enjoin you to buy all your clothes at his shop. England purchased for some
  • of her subjects, who found themselves uneasy at home, a great estate in a
  • distant country. The price, indeed, was very small, and instead of thirty
  • years purchase, the ordinary price of land in the present times, it
  • amounted to little more than the expense of the different equipments which
  • made the first discovery, reconnoitered the coast, and took a fictitious
  • possession of the country. The land was good, and of great extent; and the
  • cultivators having plenty of good ground to work upon, and being for some
  • time at liberty to sell their produce where they pleased, became, in the
  • course of little more than thirty or forty years (between 1620 and 1660),
  • so numerous and thriving a people, that the shopkeepers and other traders
  • of England wished to secure to themselves the monopoly of their custom.
  • Without pretending, therefore, that they had paid any part, either of the
  • original purchase money, or of the subsequent expense of improvement, they
  • petitioned the parliament, that the cultivators of America might for the
  • future be confined to their shop; first, for buying all the goods which
  • they wanted from Europe; and, secondly, for selling all such parts of
  • their own produce as those traders might find it convenient to buy. For
  • they did not find it convenient to buy every part of it. Some parts of it
  • imported into England, might have interfered with some of the trades which
  • they themselves carried on at home. Those particular parts of it,
  • therefore, they were willing that the colonists should sell where they
  • could; the farther off the better; and upon that account proposed that
  • their market should be confined to the countries south of Cape Finisterre.
  • A clause in the famous act of navigation established this truly shopkeeper
  • proposal into a law.
  • The maintenance of this monopoly has hitherto been the principal, or more
  • properly, perhaps, the sole end and purpose of the dominion which Great
  • Britain assumes over her colonies. In the exclusive trade, it is supposed,
  • consists the great advantage of provinces, which have never yet afforded
  • either revenue or military force for the support of the civil government,
  • or the defence of the mother country. The monopoly is the principal badge
  • of their dependency, and it is the sole fruit which has hitherto been
  • gathered from that dependency. Whatever expense Great Britain has hitherto
  • laid out in maintaining this dependency, has really been laid out in order
  • to support this monopoly. The expense of the ordinary peace establishment
  • of the colonies amounted, before the commencement of the present
  • disturbances to the pay of twenty regiments of foot; to the expense of the
  • artillery, stores, and extraordinary provisions, with which it was
  • necessary to supply them; and to the expense of a very considerable naval
  • force, which was constantly kept up, in order to guard from the smuggling
  • vessels of other nations, the immense coast of North America, and that of
  • our West Indian islands. The whole expense of this peace establishment was
  • a charge upon the revenue of Great Britain, and was, at the same time, the
  • smallest part of what the dominion of the colonies has cost the mother
  • country. If we would know the amount of the whole, we must add to the
  • annual expense of this peace establishment, the interest of the sums
  • which, in consequence of their considering her colonies as provinces
  • subject to her dominion, Great Britain has, upon different occasions, laid
  • out upon their defence. We must add to it, in particular, the whole
  • expense of the late war, and a great part of that of the war which
  • preceded it. The late war was altogether a colony quarrel; and the whole
  • expense of it, in whatever part of the world it might have been laid out,
  • whether in Germany or the East Indies, ought justly to be stated to the
  • account of the colonies. It amounted to more than ninety millions
  • sterling, including not only the new debt which was contracted, but the
  • two shillings in the pound additional land tax, and the sums which were
  • every year borrowed from the sinking fund. The Spanish war which began in
  • 1739 was principally a colony quarrel. Its principal object was to prevent
  • the search of the colony ships, which carried on a contraband trade with
  • the Spanish Main. This whole expense is, in reality, a bounty which has
  • been given in order to support a monopoly. The pretended purpose of it was
  • to encourage the manufactures, and to increase the commerce of Great
  • Britain. But its real effect has been to raise the rate of mercantile
  • profit, and to enable our merchants to turn into a branch of trade, of
  • which the returns are more slow and distant than those of the greater part
  • of other trades, a greater proportion of their capital than they otherwise
  • would have done; two events which, if a bounty could have prevented, it
  • might perhaps have been very well worth while to give such a bounty.
  • Under the present system of management, therefore, Great Britain derives
  • nothing but loss from the dominion which she assumes over her colonies.
  • To propose that Great Britain should voluntarily give up all authority
  • over her colonies, and leave them to elect their own magistrates, to enact
  • their own laws, and to make peace and war, as they might think proper,
  • would be to propose such a measure as never was, and never will be,
  • adopted by any nation in the world. No nation ever voluntarily gave up the
  • dominion of any province, how troublesome soever it might be to govern it,
  • and how small soever the revenue which it afforded might be in proportion
  • to the expense which it occasioned. Such sacrifices, though they might
  • frequently be agreeable to the interest, are always mortifying to the
  • pride of every nation; and, what is perhaps of still greater consequence,
  • they are always contrary to the private interest of the governing part of
  • it, who would thereby be deprived of the disposal of many places of trust
  • and profit, of many opportunities of acquiring wealth and distinction,
  • which the possession of the most turbulent, and, to the great body of the
  • people, the most unprofitable province, seldom fails to afford. The most
  • visionary enthusiasts would scarce be capable of proposing such a measure,
  • with any serious hopes at least of its ever being adopted. If it was
  • adopted, however, Great Britain would not only be immediately freed from
  • the whole annual expense of the peace establishment of the colonies, but
  • might settle with them such a treaty of commerce as would effectually
  • secure to her a free trade, more advantageous to the great body of the
  • people, though less so to the merchants, than the monopoly which she at
  • present enjoys. By thus parting good friends, the natural affection of the
  • colonies to the mother country, which, perhaps, our late dissensions have
  • well nigh extinguished, would quickly revive. It might dispose them not
  • only to respect, for whole centuries together, that treaty of commerce
  • which they had concluded with us at parting, but to favour us in war as
  • well as in trade, and instead of turbulent and factious subjects, to
  • become our most faithful, affectionate, and generous allies; and the same
  • sort of parental affection on the one side, and filial respect on the
  • other, might revive between Great Britain and her colonies, which used to
  • subsist between those of ancient Greece and the mother city from which
  • they descended.
  • In order to render any province advantageous to the empire to which it
  • belongs, it ought to afford, in time of peace, a revenue to the public,
  • sufficient not only for defraying the whole expense of its own peace
  • establishment, but for contributing its proportion to the support of the
  • general government of the empire. Every province necessarily contributes,
  • more or less, to increase the expense of that general government. If any
  • particular province, therefore, does not contribute its share towards
  • defraying this expense, an unequal burden must be thrown upon some other
  • part of the empire. The extraordinary revenue, too, which every province
  • affords to the public in time of war, ought, from parity of reason, to
  • bear the same proportion to the extraordinary revenue of the whole empire,
  • which its ordinary revenue does in time of peace. That neither the
  • ordinary nor extraordinary revenue which Great Britain derives from her
  • colonies, bears this proportion to the whole revenue of the British
  • empire, will readily be allowed. The monopoly, it has been supposed,
  • indeed, by increasing the private revenue of the people of Great Britain,
  • and thereby enabling them to pay greater taxes, compensates the deficiency
  • of the public revenue of the colonies. But this monopoly, I have
  • endeavoured to show, though a very grievous tax upon the colonies, and
  • though it may increase the revenue of a particular order of men in Great
  • Britain, diminishes, instead of increasing, that of the great body of the
  • people, and consequently diminishes, instead of increasing, the ability of
  • the great body of the people to pay taxes. The men, too, whose revenue the
  • monopoly increases, constitute a particular order, which it is both
  • absolutely impossible to tax beyond the proportion of other orders, and
  • extremely impolitic even to attempt to tax beyond that proportion, as I
  • shall endeavour to show in the following book. No particular resource,
  • therefore, can be drawn from this particular order.
  • The colonies may be taxed either by their own assemblies, or by the
  • parliament of Great Britain.
  • That the colony assemblies can never be so managed as to levy upon their
  • constituents a public revenue, sufficient, not only to maintain at all
  • times their own civil and military establishment, but to pay their proper
  • proportion of the expense of the general government of the British empire,
  • seems not very probable. It was a long time before even the parliament of
  • England, though placed immediately under the eye of the sovereign, could
  • be brought under such a system of management, or could be rendered
  • sufficiently liberal in their grants for supporting the civil and military
  • establishments even of their own country. It was only by distributing
  • among the particular members of parliament a great part either of the
  • offices, or of the disposal of the offices arising from this civil and
  • military establishment, that such a system of management could be
  • established, even with regard to the parliament of England. But the
  • distance of the colony assemblies from the eye of the sovereign, their
  • number, their dispersed situation, and their various constitutions, would
  • render it very difficult to manage them in the same manner, even though
  • the sovereign had the same means of doing it; and those means are wanting.
  • It would be absolutely impossible to distribute among all the leading
  • members of all the colony assemblies such a share, either of the offices,
  • or of the disposal of the offices, arising from the general government of
  • the British empire, as to dispose them to give up their popularity at
  • home, and to tax their constituents for the support of that general
  • government, of which almost the whole emoluments were to be divided among
  • people who were strangers to them. The unavoidable ignorance of
  • administration, besides, concerning the relative importance of the
  • different members of those different assemblies, the offences which must
  • frequently be given, the blunders which must constantly be committed, in
  • attempting to manage them in this manner, seems to render such a system of
  • management altogether impracticable with regard to them.
  • The colony assemblies, besides, cannot be supposed the proper judges of
  • what is necessary for the defence and support of the whole empire. The
  • care of that defence and support is not entrusted to them. It is not their
  • business, and they have no regular means of information concerning it. The
  • assembly of a province, like the vestry of a parish, may judge very
  • properly concerning the affairs of its own particular district, but can
  • have no proper means of judging concerning those of the whole empire. It
  • cannot even judge properly concerning the proportion which its own
  • province bears to the whole empire, or concerning the relative degree of
  • its wealth and importance, compared with the other provinces; because
  • those other provinces are not under the inspection and superintendency of
  • the assembly of a particular province. What is necessary for the defence
  • and support of the whole empire, and in what proportion each part ought to
  • contribute, can be judged of only by that assembly which inspects and
  • super-intends the affairs of the whole empire.
  • It has been proposed, accordingly, that the colonies should be taxed by
  • requisition, the parliament of Great Britain determining the sum which
  • each colony ought to pay, and the provincial assembly assessing and
  • levying it in the way that suited best the circumstances of the province.
  • What concerned the whole empire would in this way be determined by the
  • assembly which inspects and superintends the affairs of the whole empire;
  • and the provincial affairs of each colony might still be regulated by its
  • own assembly. Though the colonies should, in this case, have no
  • representatives in the British parliament, yet, if we may judge by
  • experience, there is no probability that the parliamentary requisition
  • would be unreasonable. The parliament of England has not, upon any
  • occasion, shewn the smallest disposition to overburden those parts of the
  • empire which are not represented in parliament. The islands of Guernsey
  • and Jersey, without any means of resisting the authority of parliament,
  • are more lightly taxed than any part of Great Britain. Parliament, in
  • attempting to exercise its supposed right, whether well or ill grounded,
  • of taxing the colonies, has never hitherto demanded of them anything which
  • even approached to a just proportion to what was paid by their fellow
  • subjects at home. If the contribution of the colonies, besides, was to
  • rise or fall in proportion to the rise or fall of the land-tax, parliament
  • could not tax them without taxing, at the same time, its own constituents,
  • and the colonies might, in this case, be considered as virtually
  • represented in parliament.
  • Examples are not wanting of empires in which all the different provinces
  • are not taxed, if I may be allowed the expression, in one mass; but in
  • which the sovereign regulates the sum which each province ought to pay,
  • and in some provinces assesses and levies it as he thinks proper; while in
  • others he leaves it to be assessed and levied as the respective states of
  • each province shall determine. In some provinces of France, the king not
  • only imposes what taxes he thinks proper, but assesses and levies them in
  • the way he thinks proper. From others he demands a certain sum, but leaves
  • it to the states of each province to assess and levy that sum as they
  • think proper. According to the scheme of taxing by requisition, the
  • parliament of Great Britain would stand nearly in the same situation
  • towards the colony assemblies, as the king of France does towards the
  • states of those provinces which still enjoy the privilege of having states
  • of their own, the provinces of France which are supposed to be the best
  • governed.
  • But though, according to this scheme, the colonies could have no just
  • reason to fear that their share of the public burdens should ever exceed
  • the proper proportion to that of their fellow-citizens at home, Great
  • Britain might have just reason to fear that it never would amount to that
  • proper proportion. The parliament of Great Britain has not, for some time
  • past, had the same established authority in the colonies, which the French
  • king has in those provinces of France which still enjoy the privilege of
  • having states of their own. The colony assemblies, if they were not very
  • favourably disposed (and unless more skilfully managed than they ever have
  • been hitherto, they are not very likely to be so), might still find many
  • pretences for evading or rejecting the most reasonable requisitions of
  • parliament. A French war breaks out, we shall suppose; ten millions must
  • immediately be raised, in order to defend the seat of the empire. This sum
  • must be borrowed upon the credit of some parliamentary fund mortgaged for
  • paying the interest. Part of this fund parliament proposes to raise by a
  • tax to be levied in Great Britain; and part of it by a requisition to all
  • the different colony assemblies of America and the West Indies. Would
  • people readily advance their money upon the credit of a fund which partly
  • depended upon the good humour of all those assemblies, far distant from
  • the seat of the war, and sometimes, perhaps, thinking themselves not much
  • concerned in the event of it? Upon such a fund, no more money would
  • probably be advanced than what the tax to be levied in Great Britain might
  • be supposed to answer for. The whole burden of the debt contracted on
  • account of the war would in this manner fall, as it always has done
  • hitherto, upon Great Britain; upon a part of the empire, and not upon the
  • whole empire. Great Britain is, perhaps, since the world began, the only
  • state which, as it has extended its empire, has only increased its
  • expense, without once augmenting its resources. Other states have
  • generally disburdened themselves, upon their subject and subordinate
  • provinces, of the most considerable part of the expense of defending the
  • empire. Great Britain has hitherto suffered her subject and subordinate
  • provinces to disburden themselves upon her of almost this whole expense.
  • In order to put Great Britain upon a footing of equality with her own
  • colonies, which the law has hitherto supposed to be subject and
  • subordinate, it seems necessary, upon the scheme of taxing them by
  • parliamentary requisition, that parliament should have some means of
  • rendering its requisitions immediately effectual, in case the colony
  • assemblies should attempt to evade or reject them; and what those means
  • are, it is not very easy to conceive, and it has not yet been explained.
  • Should the parliament of Great Britain, at the same time, be ever fully
  • established in the right of taxing the colonies, even independent of the
  • consent of their own assemblies, the importance of those assemblies would,
  • from that moment, be at an end, and with it, that of all the leading men
  • of British America. Men desire to have some share in the management of
  • public affairs, chiefly on account of the importance which it gives them.
  • Upon the power which the greater part of the leading men, the natural
  • aristocracy of every country, have of preserving or defending their
  • respective importance, depends the stability and duration of every system
  • of free government. In the attacks which those leading men are continually
  • making upon the importance of one another, and in the defence of their
  • own, consists the whole play of domestic faction and ambition. The leading
  • men of America, like those of all other countries, desire to preserve
  • their own importance. They feel, or imagine, that if their assemblies,
  • which they are fond of calling parliaments, and of considering as equal in
  • authority to the parliament of Great Britain, should be so far degraded as
  • to become the humble ministers and executive officers of that parliament,
  • the greater part of their own importance would be at an end. They have
  • rejected, therefore, the proposal of being taxed by parliamentary
  • requisition, and, like other ambitious and high-spirited men, have rather
  • chosen to draw the sword in defence of their own importance.
  • Towards the declension of the Roman republic, the allies of Rome, who had
  • borne the principal burden of defending the state and extending the
  • empire, demanded to be admitted to all the privileges of Roman citizens.
  • Upon being refused, the social war broke out. During the course of that
  • war, Rome granted those privileges to the greater part of them, one by
  • one, and in proportion as they detached themselves from the general
  • confederacy. The parliament of Great Britain insists upon taxing the
  • colonies; and they refuse to be taxed by a parliament in which they are
  • not represented. If to each colony which should detach itself from the
  • general confederacy, Great Britain should allow such a number of
  • representatives as suited the proportion of what it contributed to the
  • public revenue of the empire, in consequence of its being subjected to the
  • same taxes, and in compensation admitted to the same freedom of trade with
  • its fellow-subjects at home; the number of its representatives to be
  • augmented as the proportion of its contribution might afterwards augment;
  • a new method of acquiring importance, a new and more dazzling object of
  • ambition, would be presented to the leading men of each colony. Instead of
  • piddling for the little prizes which are to be found in what may be called
  • the paltry raffle of colony faction, they might then hope, from the
  • presumption which men naturally have in their own ability and good
  • fortune, to draw some of the great prizes which sometimes come from the
  • wheel of the great state lottery of British politics. Unless this or some
  • other method is fallen upon, and there seems to be none more obvious than
  • this, of preserving the importance and of gratifying the ambition of the
  • leading men of America, it is not very probable that they will ever
  • voluntarily submit to us; and we ought to consider, that the blood which
  • must be shed in forcing them to do so, is, every drop of it, the blood
  • either of those who are, or of those whom we wish to have for our fellow
  • citizens. They are very weak who flatter themselves that, in the state to
  • which things have come, our colonies will be easily conquered by force
  • alone. The persons who now govern the resolutions of what they call their
  • continental congress, feel in themselves at this moment a degree of
  • importance which, perhaps, the greatest subjects in Europe scarce feel.
  • From shopkeepers, trades men, and attorneys, they are become statesmen and
  • legislators, and are employed in contriving a new form of government for
  • an extensive empire, which, they flatter themselves, will become, and
  • which, indeed, seems very likely to become, one of the greatest and most
  • formidable that ever was in the world. Five hundred different people,
  • perhaps, who, in different ways, act immediately under the continental
  • congress, and five hundred thousand, perhaps, who act under those five
  • hundred, all feel, in the same manner, a proportionable rise in their own
  • importance. Almost every individual of the governing party in America
  • fills, at present, in his own fancy, a station superior, not only to what
  • he had ever filled before, but to what he had ever expected to fill; and
  • unless some new object of ambition is presented either to him or to his
  • leaders, if he has the ordinary spirit of a man, he will die in defence of
  • that station.
  • It is a remark of the President Heynaut, that we now read with pleasure
  • the account of many little transactions of the Ligue, which, when they
  • happened, were not, perhaps, considered as very important pieces of news.
  • But everyman then, says he, fancied himself of some importance; and the
  • innumerable memoirs which have come down to us from those times, were the
  • greater part of them written by people who took pleasure in recording and
  • magnifying events, in which they flattered themselves they had been
  • considerable actors. How obstinately the city of Paris, upon that
  • occasion, defended itself, what a dreadful famine it supported, rather
  • than submit to the best, and afterwards the most beloved of all the French
  • kings, is well known. The greater part of the citizens, or those who
  • governed the greater part of them, fought in defence of their own
  • importance, which, they foresaw, was to be at an end whenever the ancient
  • government should be re-established. Our colonies, unless they can be
  • induced to consent to a union, are very likely to defend themselves,
  • against the best of all mother countries, as obstinately as the city of
  • Paris did against one of the best of kings.
  • The idea of representation was unknown in ancient times. When the people
  • of one state were admitted to the right of citizenship in another, they
  • had no other means of exercising that right, but by coming in a body to
  • vote and deliberate with the people of that other state. The admission of
  • the greater part of the inhabitants of Italy to the privileges of Roman
  • citizens, completely ruined the Roman republic. It was no longer possible
  • to distinguish between who was, and who was not, a Roman citizen. No tribe
  • could know its own members. A rabble of any kind could be introduced into
  • the assemblies of the people, could drive out the real citizens, and
  • decide upon the affairs of the republic, as if they themselves had been
  • such. But though America were to send fifty or sixty new representatives
  • to parliament, the door-keeper of the house of commons could not find any
  • great difficulty in distinguishing between who was and who was not a
  • member. Though the Roman constitution, therefore, was necessarily ruined
  • by the union of Rome with the allied states of Italy, there is not the
  • least probability that the British constitution would be hurt by the union
  • of Great Britain with her colonies. That constitution, on the contrary,
  • would be completed by it, and seems to be imperfect without it. The
  • assembly which deliberates and decides concerning the affairs of every
  • part of the empire, in order to be properly informed, ought certainly to
  • have representatives from every part of it. That this union, however,
  • could be easily effectuated, or that difficulties, and great difficulties,
  • might not occur in the execution, I do not pretend. I have yet heard of
  • none, however, which appear insurmountable. The principal, perhaps, arise,
  • not from the nature of things, but from the prejudices and opinions of the
  • people, both on this and on the other side of the Atlantic.
  • We on this side the water are afraid lest the multitude of American
  • representatives should overturn the balance of the constitution, and
  • increase too much either the influence of the crown on the one hand, or
  • the force of the democracy on the other. But if the number of American
  • representatives were to be in proportion to the produce of American
  • taxation, the number of people to be managed would increase exactly in
  • proportion to the means of managing them, and the means of managing to the
  • number of people to be managed. The monarchical and democratical parts of
  • the constitution would, after the union, stand exactly in the same degree
  • of relative force with regard to one another as they had done before.
  • The people on the other side of the water are afraid lest their distance
  • from the seat of government might expose them to many oppressions; but
  • their representatives in parliament, of which the number ought from the
  • first to be considerable, would easily be able to protect them from all
  • oppression. The distance could not much weaken the dependency of the
  • representative upon the constituent, and the former would still feel that
  • he owed his seat in parliament, and all the consequence which he derived
  • from it, to the good-will of the latter. It would be the interest of the
  • former, therefore, to cultivate that good-will, by complaining, with all
  • the authority of a member of the legislature, of every outrage which any
  • civil or military officer might be guilty of in those remote parts of the
  • empire. The distance of America from the seat of government, besides, the
  • natives of that country might flatter themselves, with some appearance of
  • reason too, would not be of very long continuance. Such has hitherto been
  • the rapid progress of that country in wealth, population, and improvement,
  • that in the course of little more than a century, perhaps, the produce of
  • the American might exceed that of the British taxation. The seat of the
  • empire would then naturally remove itself to that part of the empire which
  • contributed most to the general defence and support of the whole.
  • The discovery of America, and that of a passage to the East Indies by the
  • Cape of Good Hope, are the two greatest and most important events recorded
  • in the history of mankind. Their consequences have already been great;
  • but, in the short period of between two and three centuries which has
  • elapsed since these discoveries were made, it is impossible that the whole
  • extent of their consequences can have been seen. What benefits or what
  • misfortunes to mankind may hereafter result from those great events, no
  • human wisdom can foresee. By uniting in some measure the most distant
  • parts of the world, by enabling them to relieve one another’s wants, to
  • increase one another’s enjoyments, and to encourage one another’s
  • industry, their general tendency would seem to be beneficial. To the
  • natives, however, both of the East and West Indies, all the commercial
  • benefits which can have resulted from those events have been sunk and lost
  • in the dreadful misfortunes which they have occasioned. These misfortunes,
  • however, seem to have arisen rather from accident than from any thing in
  • the nature of those events themselves. At the particular time when these
  • discoveries were made, the superiority of force happened to be so great on
  • the side of the Europeans, that they were enabled to commit with impunity
  • every sort of injustice in those remote countries. Hereafter, perhaps, the
  • natives of those countries may grow stronger, or those of Europe may grow
  • weaker; and the inhabitants of all the different quarters of the world may
  • arrive at that equality of courage and force which, by inspiring mutual
  • fear, can alone overawe the injustice of independent nations into some
  • sort of respect for the rights of one another. But nothing seems more
  • likely to establish this equality of force, than that mutual communication
  • of knowledge, and of all sorts of improvements, which an extensive
  • commerce from all countries to all countries naturally, or rather
  • necessarily, carries along with it.
  • In the mean time, one of the principal effects of those discoveries has
  • been, to raise the mercantile system to a degree of splendour and glory
  • which it could never otherwise have attained to. It is the object of that
  • system to enrich a great nation, rather by trade and manufactures than by
  • the improvement and cultivation of land, rather by the industry of the
  • towns than by that of the country. But in consequence of those
  • discoveries, the commercial towns of Europe, instead of being the
  • manufacturers and carriers for but a very small part of the world (that
  • part of Europe which is washed by the Atlantic ocean, and the countries
  • which lie round the Baltic and Mediterranean seas), have now become the
  • manufacturers for the numerous and thriving cultivators of America, and
  • the carriers, and in some respects the manufacturers too, for almost all
  • the different nations of Asia, Africa, and America. Two new worlds have
  • been opened to their industry, each of them much greater and more
  • extensive than the old one, and the market of one of them growing still
  • greater and greater every day.
  • The countries which possess the colonies of America, and which trade
  • directly to the East Indies, enjoy indeed the whole show and splendour of
  • this great commerce. Other countries, however, notwithstanding all the
  • invidious restraints by which it is meant to exclude them, frequently
  • enjoy a greater share of the real benefit of it. The colonies of Spain and
  • Portugal, for example, give more real encouragement to the industry of
  • other countries than to that of Spain and Portugal. In the single article
  • of linen alone, the consumption of those colonies amounts, it is said (but
  • I do not pretend to warrant the quantity ), to more than three millions
  • sterling a-year. But this great consumption is almost entirely supplied by
  • France, Flanders, Holland, and Germany. Spain and Portugal furnish but a
  • small part of it. The capital which supplies the colonies with this great
  • quantity of linen, is annually distributed among, and furnishes a revenue
  • to, the inhabitants of those other countries. The profits of it only are
  • spent in Spain and Portugal, where they help to support the sumptuous
  • profusion of the merchants of Cadiz and Lisbon.
  • Even the regulations by which each nation endeavours to secure to itself
  • the exclusive trade of its own colonies, are frequently more hurtful to
  • the countries in favour of which they are established, than to those
  • against which they are established. The unjust oppression of the industry
  • of other countries falls back, if I may say so, upon the heads of the
  • oppressors, and crushes their industry more than it does that of those
  • other countries. By those regulations, for example, the merchant of
  • Hamburg must send the linen which he destines for the American market to
  • London, and he must bring back from thence the tobacco which he destines
  • for the German market; because he can neither send the one directly to
  • America, nor bring the other directly from thence. By this restraint he is
  • probably obliged to sell the one somewhat cheaper, and to buy the other
  • somewhat dearer, than he otherwise might have done; and his profits are
  • probably somewhat abridged by means of it. In this trade, however, between
  • Hamburg and London, he certainly receives the returns of his capital much
  • more quickly than he could possibly have done in the direct trade to
  • America, even though we should suppose, what is by no means the case, that
  • the payments of America were as punctual as those of London. In the trade,
  • therefore, to which those regulations confine the merchant of Hamburg, his
  • capital can keep in constant employment a much greater quantity of German
  • industry than he possibly could have done in the trade from which he is
  • excluded. Though the one employment, therefore, may to him perhaps be less
  • profitable than the other, it cannot be less advantageous to his country.
  • It is quite otherwise with the employment into which the monopoly
  • naturally attracts, if I may say so, the capital of the London merchant.
  • That employment may, perhaps, be more profitable to him than the greater
  • part of other employments; but on account of the slowness of the returns,
  • it cannot be more advantageous to his country.
  • After all the unjust attempts, therefore, of every country in Europe to
  • engross to itself the whole advantage of the trade of its own colonies, no
  • country has yet been able to engross to itself any thing but the expense
  • of supporting in time of peace, and of defending in time of war, the
  • oppressive authority which it assumes over them. The inconveniencies
  • resulting from the possession of its colonies, every country has engrossed
  • to itself completely. The advantages resulting from their trade, it has
  • been obliged to share with many other countries.
  • At first sight, no doubt, the monopoly of the great commerce of America
  • naturally seems to be an acquisition of the highest value. To the
  • undiscerning eye of giddy ambition it naturally presents itself, amidst
  • the confused scramble of politics and war, as a very dazzling object to
  • fight for. The dazzling splendour of the object, however, the immense
  • greatness of the commerce, is the very quality which renders the monopoly
  • of it hurtful, or which makes one employment, in its own nature
  • necessarily less advantageous to the country than the greater part of
  • other employments, absorb a much greater proportion of the capital of the
  • country than what would otherwise have gone to it.
  • The mercantile stock of every country, it has been shown in the second
  • book, naturally seeks, if one may say so, the employment most advantageous
  • to that country. If it is employed in the carrying trade, the country to
  • which it belongs becomes the emporium of the goods of all the countries
  • whose trade that stock carries on. But the owner of that stock necessarily
  • wishes to dispose of as great a part of those goods as he can at home. He
  • thereby saves himself the trouble, risk, and expense of exportation; and
  • he will upon that account be glad to sell them at home, not only for a
  • much smaller price, but with somewhat a smaller profit, than he might
  • expect to make by sending them abroad. He naturally, therefore, endeavours
  • as much as he can to turn his carrying trade into a foreign trade of
  • consumption, If his stock, again, is employed in a foreign trade of
  • consumption, he will, for the same reason, be glad to dispose of, at home,
  • as great a part as he can of the home goods which he collects in order to
  • export to some foreign market, and he will thus endeavour, as much as he
  • can, to turn his foreign trade of consumption into a home trade. The
  • mercantile stock of every country naturally courts in this manner the
  • near, and shuns the distant employment: naturally courts the employment in
  • which the returns are frequent, and shuns that in which they are distant
  • and slow; naturally courts the employment in which it can maintain the
  • greatest quantity of productive labour in the country to which it belongs,
  • or in which its owner resides, and shuns that in which it can maintain
  • there the smallest quantity. It naturally courts the employment which in
  • ordinary cases is most advantageous, and shuns that which in ordinary
  • cases is least advantageous to that country.
  • But if, in any one of those distant employments, which in ordinary cases
  • are less advantageous to the country, the profit should happen to rise
  • somewhat higher than what is sufficient to balance the natural preference
  • which is given to nearer employments, this superiority of profit will draw
  • stock from those nearer employments, till the profits of all return to
  • their proper level. This superiority of profit, however, is a proof that,
  • in the actual circumstances of the society, those distant employments are
  • somewhat understocked in proportion to other employments, and that the
  • stock of the society is not distributed in the properest manner among all
  • the different employments carried on in it. It is a proof that something
  • is either bought cheaper or sold dearer than it ought to be, and that some
  • particular class of citizens is more or less oppressed, either by paying
  • more, or by getting less than what is suitable to that equality which
  • ought to take place, and which naturally does take place, among all the
  • different classes of them. Though the same capital never will maintain the
  • same quantity of productive labour in a distant as in a near employment,
  • yet a distant employment maybe as necessary for the welfare of the society
  • as a near one; the goods which the distant employment deals in being
  • necessary, perhaps, for carrying on many of the nearer employments. But if
  • the profits of those who deal in such goods are above their proper level,
  • those goods will be sold dearer than they ought to be, or somewhat above
  • their natural price, and all those engaged in the nearer employments will
  • be more or less oppressed by this high price. Their interest, therefore,
  • in this case, requires, that some stock should be withdrawn from those
  • nearer employments, and turned towards that distant one, in order to
  • reduce its profits to their proper level, and the price of the goods which
  • it deals in to their natural price. In this extraordinary case, the public
  • interest requires that some stock should be withdrawn from those
  • employments which, in ordinary cases, are more advantageous, and turned
  • towards one which, in ordinary cases, is less advantageous to the public;
  • and, in this extraordinary case, the natural interests and inclinations of
  • men coincide as exactly with the public interests as in all other ordinary
  • cases, and lead them to withdraw stock from the near, and to turn it
  • towards the distant employments.
  • It is thus that the private interests and passions of individuals
  • naturally dispose them to turn their stock towards the employments which
  • in ordinary cases, are most advantageous to the society. But if from this
  • natural preference they should turn too much of it towards those
  • employments, the fall of profit in them, and the rise of it in all others,
  • immediately dispose them to alter this faulty distribution. Without any
  • intervention of law, therefore, the private interests and passions of men
  • naturally lead them to divide and distribute the stock of every society
  • among all the different employments carried on in it; as nearly as
  • possible in the proportion which is most agreeable to the interest of the
  • whole society.
  • All the different regulations of the mercantile system necessarily derange
  • more or less this natural and most advantageous distribution of stock. But
  • those which concern the trade to America and the East Indies derange it,
  • perhaps, more than any other; because the trade to those two great
  • continents absorbs a greater quantity of stock than any two other branches
  • of trade. The regulations, however, by which this derangement is effected
  • in those two different branches of trade, are not altogether the same.
  • Monopoly is the great engine of both; but it is a different sort of
  • monopoly. Monopoly of one kind or another, indeed, seems to be the sole
  • engine of the mercantile system.
  • In the trade to America, every nation endeavours to engross as much as
  • possible the whole market of its own colonies, by fairly excluding all
  • other nations from any direct trade to them. During the greater part of
  • the sixteenth century, the Portuguese endeavoured to manage the trade to
  • the East Indies in the same manner, by claiming the sole right of sailing
  • in the Indian seas, on account of the merit of having first found out the
  • road to them. The Dutch still continue to exclude all other European
  • nations from any direct trade to their spice islands. Monopolies of this
  • kind are evidently established against all other European nations, who are
  • thereby not only excluded from a trade to which it might be convenient for
  • them to turn some part of their stock, but are obliged to buy the goods
  • which that trade deals in, somewhat dearer than if they could import them
  • themselves directly from the countries which produced them.
  • But since the fall of the power of Portugal, no European nation has
  • claimed the exclusive right of sailing in the Indian seas, of which the
  • principal ports are now open to the ships of all European nations. Except
  • in Portugal, however, and within these few years in France, the trade to
  • the East Indies has, in every European country, been subjected to an
  • exclusive company. Monopolies of this kind are properly established
  • against the very nation which erects them. The greater part of that nation
  • are thereby not only excluded from a trade to which it might be convenient
  • for them to turn some part of their stock, but are obliged to buy the
  • goods which that trade deals in somewhat dearer than if it was open and
  • free to all their countrymen. Since the establishment of the English East
  • India company, for example, the other inhabitants of England, over and
  • above being excluded from the trade, must have paid, in the price of the
  • East India goods which they have consumed, not only for all the
  • extraordinary profits which the company may have made upon those goods in
  • consequence of their monopoly, but for all the extraordinary waste which
  • the fraud and abuse inseparable from the management of the affairs of so
  • great a company must necessarily have occasioned. The absurdity of this
  • second kind of monopoly, therefore, is much more manifest than that of the
  • first.
  • Both these kinds of monopolies derange more or less the natural
  • distribution of the stock of the society; but they do not always derange
  • it in the same way.
  • Monopolies of the first kind always attract to the particular trade in
  • which they are established a greater proportion of the stock of the
  • society than what would go to that trade of its own accord.
  • Monopolies of the second kind may sometimes attract stock towards the
  • particular trade in which they are established, and sometimes repel it
  • from that trade, according to different circumstances. In poor countries,
  • they naturally attract towards that trade more stock than would otherwise
  • go to it. In rich countries, they naturally repel from it a good deal of
  • stock which would otherwise go to it.
  • Such poor countries as Sweden and Denmark, for example, would probably
  • have never sent a single ship to the East Indies, had not the trade been
  • subjected to an exclusive company. The establishment of such a company
  • necessarily encourages adventurers. Their monopoly secures them against
  • all competitors in the home market, and they have the same chance for
  • foreign markets with the traders of other nations. Their monopoly shows
  • them the certainty of a great profit upon a considerable quantity of
  • goods, and the chance of a considerable profit upon a great quantity.
  • Without such extraordinary encouragement, the poor traders of such poor
  • countries would probably never have thought of hazarding their small
  • capitals in so very distant and uncertain an adventure as the trade to the
  • East Indies must naturally have appeared to them.
  • Such a rich country as Holland, on the contrary, would probably, in the
  • case of a free trade, send many more ships to the East Indies than it
  • actually does. The limited stock of the Dutch East India company probably
  • repels from that trade many great mercantile capitals which would
  • otherwise go to it. The mercantile capital of Holland is so great, that it
  • is, as it were, continually overflowing, sometimes into the public funds
  • of foreign countries, sometimes into loans to private traders and
  • adventurers of foreign countries, sometimes into the most round-about
  • foreign trades of consumption, and sometimes into the carrying trade. All
  • near employments being completely filled up, all the capital which can be
  • placed in them with any tolerable profit being already placed in them, the
  • capital of Holland necessarily flows towards the most distant employments.
  • The trade to the East Indies, if it were altogether free, would probably
  • absorb the greater part of this redundant capital. The East Indies offer a
  • market both for the manufactures of Europe, and for the gold and silver,
  • as well as for the several other productions of America, greater and more
  • extensive than both Europe and America put together.
  • Every derangement of the natural distribution of stock is necessarily
  • hurtful to the society in which it takes place; whether it be by repelling
  • from a particular trade the stock which would otherwise go to it, or by
  • attracting towards a particular trade that which would not otherwise come
  • to it. If, without any exclusive company, the trade of Holland to the East
  • Indies would be greater than it actually is, that country must suffer a
  • considerable loss, by part of its capital being excluded from the
  • employment most convenient for that port. And, in the same manner, if,
  • without an exclusive company, the trade of Sweden and Denmark to the East
  • Indies would be less than it actually is, or, what perhaps is more
  • probable, would not exist at all, those two countries must likewise suffer
  • a considerable loss, by part of their capital being drawn into an
  • employment which must be more or less unsuitable to their present
  • circumstances. Better for them, perhaps, in the present circumstances, to
  • buy East India goods of other nations, even though they should pay
  • somewhat dearer, than to turn so great a part of their small capital to so
  • very distant a trade, in which the returns are so very slow, in which that
  • capital can maintain so small a quantity of productive labour at home,
  • where productive labour is so much wanted, where so little is done, and
  • where so much is to do.
  • Though without an exclusive company, therefore, a particular country
  • should not be able to carry on any direct trade to the East Indies, it
  • will not from thence follow, that such a company ought to be established
  • there, but only that such a country ought not, in these circumstances, to
  • trade directly to the East Indies. That such companies are not in general
  • necessary for carrying on the East India trade, is sufficiently
  • demonstrated by the experience of the Portuguese, who enjoyed almost the
  • whole of it for more than a century together, without any exclusive
  • company.
  • No private merchant, it has been said, could well have capital sufficient
  • to maintain factors and agents in the different ports of the East Indies,
  • in order to provide goods for the ships which he might occasionally send
  • thither; and yet, unless he was able to do this, the difficulty of finding
  • a cargo might frequently make his ships lose the season for returning; and
  • the expense of so long a delay would not only eat up the whole profit of
  • the adventure, but frequently occasion a very considerable loss. This
  • argument, however, if it proved any thing at all, would prove that no one
  • great branch of trade could be carried on without an exclusive company,
  • which is contrary to the experience of all nations. There is no great
  • branch of trade, in which the capital of any one private merchant is
  • sufficient for carrying on all the subordinate branches which must be
  • carried on, in order to carry on the principal one. But when a nation is
  • ripe for any great branch of trade, some merchants naturally turn their
  • capitals towards the principal, and some towards the subordinate branches
  • of it; and though all the different branches of it are in this manner
  • carried on, yet it very seldom happens that they are all carried on by the
  • capital of one private merchant. If a nation, therefore, is ripe for the
  • East India trade, a certain portion of its capital will naturally divide
  • itself among all the different branches of that trade. Some of its
  • merchants will find it for their interest to reside in the East Indies,
  • and to employ their capitals there in providing goods for the ships which
  • are to be sent out by other merchants who reside in Europe. The
  • settlements which different European nations have obtained in the East
  • Indies, if they were taken from the exclusive companies to which they at
  • present belong, and put under the immediate protection of the sovereign,
  • would render this residence both safe and easy, at least to the merchants
  • of the particular nations to whom those settlements belong. If, at any
  • particular time, that part of the capital of any country which of its own
  • accord tended and inclined, if I may say so, towards the East India trade,
  • was not sufficient for carrying on all those different branches of it, it
  • would be a proof that, at that particular time, that country was not ripe
  • for that trade, and that it would do better to buy for some time, even at
  • a higher price, from other European nations, the East India goods it had
  • occasion for, than to import them itself directly from the East Indies.
  • What it might lose by the high price of those goods, could seldom be equal
  • to the loss which it would sustain by the distraction of a large portion
  • of its capital from other employments more necessary, or more useful, or
  • more suitable to its circumstances and situation, than a direct trade to
  • the East Indies.
  • Though the Europeans possess many considerable settlements both upon the
  • coast of Africa and in the East Indies, they have not yet established, in
  • either of those countries, such numerous and thriving colonies as those in
  • the islands and continent of America. Africa, however, as well as several
  • of the countries comprehended under the general name of the East Indies,
  • is inhabited by barbarous nations. But those nations were by no means so
  • weak and defenceless as the miserable and helpless Americans; and in
  • proportion to the natural fertility of the countries which they inhabited,
  • they were, besides, much more populous. The most barbarous nations either
  • of Africa or of the East Indies, were shepherds; even the Hottentots were
  • so. But the natives of every part of America, except Mexico and Peru, were
  • only hunters and the difference is very great between the number of
  • shepherds and that of hunters whom the same extent of equally fertile
  • territory can maintain. In Africa and the East Indies, therefore, it was
  • more difficult to displace the natives, and to extend the European
  • plantations over the greater part of the lands of the original
  • inhabitants. The genius of exclusive companies, besides, is unfavourable,
  • it has already been observed, to the growth of new colonies, and has
  • probably been the principal cause of the little progress which they have
  • made in the East Indies. The Portuguese carried on the trade both to
  • Africa and the East Indies, without any exclusive companies; and their
  • settlements at Congo, Angola, and Benguela, on the coast of Africa, and at
  • Goa in the East Indies though much depressed by superstition and every
  • sort of bad government, yet bear some resemblance to the colonies of
  • America, and are partly inhabited by Portuguese who have been established
  • there for several generations. The Dutch settlements at the Cape of Good
  • Hope and at Batavia, are at present the most considerable colonies which
  • the Europeans have established, either in Africa or in the East Indies;
  • and both those settlements an peculiarly fortunate in their situation. The
  • Cape of Good Hope was inhabited by a race of people almost as barbarous,
  • and quite as incapable of defending themselves, as the natives of America.
  • It is, besides, the half-way house, if one may say so, between Europe and
  • the East Indies, at which almost every European ship makes some stay, both
  • in going and returning. The supplying of those ships with every sort of
  • fresh provisions, with fruit, and sometimes with wine, affords alone a
  • very extensive market for the surplus produce of the colonies. What the
  • Cape of Good Hope is between Europe and every part of the East Indies,
  • Batavia is between the principal countries of the East Indies. It lies
  • upon the most frequented road from Indostan to China and Japan, and is
  • nearly about mid-way upon that road. Almost all the ships too, that sail
  • between Europe and China, touch at Batavia; and it is, over and above all
  • this, the centre and principal mart of what is called the country trade of
  • the East Indies; not only of that part of it which is carried on by
  • Europeans, but of that which is carried on by the native Indians; and
  • vessels navigated by the inhabitants of China and Japan, of Tonquin,
  • Malacca, Cochin-China, and the island of Celebes, are frequently to be
  • seen in its port. Such advantageous situations have enabled those two
  • colonies to surmount all the obstacles which the oppressive genius of an
  • exclusive company may have occasionally opposed to their growth. They have
  • enabled Batavia to surmount the additional disadvantage of perhaps the
  • most unwholesome climate in the world.
  • The English and Dutch companies, though they have established no
  • considerable colonies, except the two above mentioned, have both made
  • considerable conquests in the East Indies. But in the manner in which they
  • both govern their new subjects, the natural genius of an exclusive company
  • has shewn itself most distinctly. In the spice islands, the Dutch are said
  • to burn all the spiceries which a fertile season produces, beyond what
  • they expect to dispose of in Europe with such a profit as they think
  • sufficient. In the islands where they have no settlements, they give a
  • premium to those who collect the young blossoms and green leaves of the
  • clove and nutmeg trees, which naturally grow there, but which this savage
  • policy has now, it is said, almost completely extirpated. Even in the
  • islands where they have settlements, they have very much reduced, it is
  • said, the number of those trees. If the produce even of their own islands
  • was much greater than what suited their market, the natives, they suspect,
  • might find means to convey some part of it to other nations; and the best
  • way, they imagine, to secure their own monopoly, is to take care that no
  • more shall grow than what they themselves carry to market. By different
  • arts of oppression, they have reduced the population of several of the
  • Moluccas nearly to the number which is sufficient to supply with fresh
  • provisions, and other necessaries of life, their own insignificant
  • garrisons, and such of their ships as occasionally come there for a cargo
  • of spices. Under the government even of the Portuguese, however, those
  • islands are said to have been tolerably well inhabited. The English
  • company have not yet had time to establish in Bengal so perfectly
  • destructive a system. The plan of their government, however, has had
  • exactly the same tendency. It has not been uncommon, I am well assured,
  • for the chief, that is, the first clerk or a factory, to order a peasant
  • to plough up a rich field of poppies, and sow it with rice, or some other
  • grain. The pretence was, to prevent a scarcity of provisions; but the real
  • reason, to give the chief an opportunity of selling at a better price a
  • large quantity of opium which he happened then to have upon hand. Upon
  • other occasions, the order has been reversed; and a rich field of rice or
  • other grain has been ploughed up, in order to make room for a plantation
  • of poppies, when the chief foresaw that extraordinary profit was likely to
  • be made by opium. The servants of the company have, upon several
  • occasions, attempted to establish in their own favour the monopoly of some
  • of the most important branches, not only of the foreign, but of the inland
  • trade of the country. Had they been allowed to go on, it is impossible
  • that they should not, at some time or another, have attempted to restrain
  • the production of the particular articles of which they had thus usurped
  • the monopoly, not only to the quantity which they themselves could
  • purchase, but to that which they could expect to sell with such a profit
  • as they might think sufficient. In the course of a century or two, the
  • policy of the English company would, in this manner, have probably proved
  • as completely destructive as that of the Dutch.
  • Nothing, however, can be more directly contrary to the real interest of
  • those companies, considered as the sovereigns of the countries which they
  • have conquered, than this destructive plan. In almost all countries, the
  • revenue of the sovereign is drawn from that of the people. The greater the
  • revenue of the people, therefore, the greater the annual produce of their
  • land and labour, the more they can afford to the sovereign. It is his
  • interest, therefore, to increase as much as possible that annual produce.
  • But if this is the interest of every sovereign, it is peculiarly so of one
  • whose revenue, like that of the sovereign of Bengal, arises chiefly from a
  • land-rent. That rent must necessarily be in proportion to the quantity and
  • value of the produce; and both the one and the other must depend upon the
  • extent of the market. The quantity will always be suited, with more or
  • less exactness, to the consumption of those who can afford to pay for it;
  • and the price which they will pay will always be in proportion to the
  • eagerness of their competition. It is the interest of such a sovereign,
  • therefore, to open the most extensive market for the produce of his
  • country, to allow the most perfect freedom of commerce, in order to
  • increase as much as possible the number and competition of buyers; and
  • upon this account to abolish, not only all monopolies, but all restraints
  • upon the transportation of the home produce from one part of the country
  • to mother, upon its exportation to foreign countries, or upon the
  • importation of goods of any kind for which it can be exchanged. He is in
  • this manner most likely to increase both the quantity and value of that
  • produce, and consequently of his own share of it, or of his own revenue.
  • But a company of merchants, are, it seems, incapable of considering
  • themselves as sovereigns, even after they have become such. Trade, or
  • buying in order to sell again, they still consider as their principal
  • business, and by a strange absurdity, regard the character of the
  • sovereign as but an appendix to that of the merchant; as something which
  • ought to be made subservient to it, or by means of which they may be
  • enabled to buy cheaper in India, and thereby to sell with a better profit
  • in Europe. They endeavour, for this purpose, to keep out as much as
  • possible all competitors from the market of the countries which are
  • subject to their government, and consequently to reduce, at least, some
  • part of the surplus produce of those countries to what is barely
  • sufficient for supplying their own demand, or to what they can expect to
  • sell in Europe, with such a profit as they may think reasonable. Their
  • mercantile habits draw them in this manner, almost necessarily, though
  • perhaps insensibly, to prefer, upon all ordinary occasions, the little and
  • transitory profit of the monopolist to the great and permanent revenue of
  • the sovereign; and would gradually lead them to treat the countries
  • subject to their government nearly as the Dutch treat the Moluccas. It is
  • the interest of the East India company, considered as sovereigns, that the
  • European goods which are carried to their Indian dominions should be sold
  • there as cheap as possible; and that the Indian goods which are brought
  • from thence should bring there as good a price, or should be sold there as
  • dear as possible. But the reverse of this is their interest as merchants.
  • As sovereigns, their interest is exactly the same with that of the country
  • which they govern. As merchants, their interest is directly opposite to
  • that interest.
  • But if the genius of such a government, even as to what concerns its
  • direction in Europe, is in this manner essentially, and perhaps incurably
  • faulty, that of its administration in India is still more so. That
  • administration is necessarily composed of a council of merchants, a
  • profession no doubt extremely respectable, but which in no country in the
  • world carries along with it that sort of authority which naturally
  • overawes the people, and without force commands their willing obedience.
  • Such a council can command obedience only by the military force with which
  • they are accompanied; and their government is, therefore, necessarily
  • military and despotical. Their proper business, however, is that of
  • merchants. It is to sell, upon their master’s account, the European goods
  • consigned to them, and to buy, in return, Indian goods for the European
  • market. It is to sell the one as dear, and to buy the other as cheap as
  • possible, and consequently to exclude, as much as possible, all rivals
  • from the particular market where they keep their shop. The genius of the
  • administration, therefore, so far as concerns the trade of the company, is
  • the same as that of the direction. It tends to make government subservient
  • to the interest of monopoly, and consequently to stunt the natural growth
  • of some parts, at least, of the surplus produce of the country, to what is
  • barely sufficient for answering the demand of the company.
  • All the members of the administration besides, trade more or less upon
  • their own account; and it is in vain to prohibit them from doing so.
  • Nothing can be more completely foolish than to expect that the clerk of a
  • great counting-house, at ten thousand miles distance, and consequently
  • almost quite out of sight, should, upon a simple order from their master,
  • give up at once doing any sort of business upon their own account abandon
  • for ever all hopes of making a fortune, of which they have the means in
  • their hands; and content themselves with the moderate salaries which those
  • masters allow them, and which, moderate as they are, can seldom be
  • augmented, being commonly as large as the real profits of the company
  • trade can afford. In such circumstances, to prohibit the servants of the
  • company from trading upon their own account, can have scarce any other
  • effect than to enable its superior servants, under pretence of executing
  • their master’s order, to oppress such of the inferior ones as have had the
  • misfortune to fall under their displeasure. The servants naturally
  • endeavour to establish the same monopoly in favour of their own private
  • trade as of the public trade of the company. If they are suffered to act
  • as they could wish, they will establish this monopoly openly and directly,
  • by fairly prohibiting all other people from trading in the articles in
  • which they choose to deal; and this, perhaps, is the best and least
  • oppressive way of establishing it. But if, by an order from Europe, they
  • are prohibited from doing this, they will, notwithstanding, endeavour to
  • establish a monopoly of the same kind secretly and indirectly, in a way
  • that is much more destructive to the country. They will employ the whole
  • authority of government, and pervert the administration of Justice, in
  • order to harass and ruin those who interfere with them in any branch of
  • commerce, which by means of agents, either concealed, or at least not
  • publicly avowed, they may choose to carry on. But the private trade of the
  • servants will naturally extend to a much greater variety of articles than
  • the public trade of the company. The public trade of the company extends
  • no further than the trade with Europe, and comprehends a part only of the
  • foreign trade of the country. But the private trade of the servants may
  • extend to all the different branches both of its inland and foreign trade.
  • The monopoly of the company can tend only to stunt the natural growth of
  • that part of the surplus produce which, in the case of a free trade, would
  • be exported to Europe. That of the servants tends to stunt the natural
  • growth of every part of the produce in which they choose to deal; of what
  • is destined for home consumption, as well as of what is destined for
  • exportation; and consequently to degrade the cultivation of the whole
  • country, and to reduce the number of its inhabitants. It tends to reduce
  • the quantity of every sort of produce, even that of the necessaries of
  • life, whenever the servants of the country choose to deal in them, to what
  • those servants can both afford to buy and expect to sell with such a
  • profit as pleases them.
  • From the nature of their situation, too, the servants must be more
  • disposed to support with rigourous severity their own interest, against
  • that of the country which they govern, than their masters can be to
  • support theirs. The country belongs to their masters, who cannot avoid
  • having some regard for the interest of what belongs to them; but it does
  • not belong to the servants. The real interest of their masters, if they
  • were capable of understanding it, is the same with that of the country;
  • {The interest of every proprietor of India stock, however, is by no means
  • the same with that of the country in the government of which his vote
  • gives him some influence.—See book v, chap. 1, part ii.}and it is
  • from ignorance chiefly, and the meanness of mercantile prejudice, that
  • they ever oppress it. But the real interest of the servants is by no means
  • the same with that of the country, and the most perfect information would
  • not necessarily put an end to their oppressions. The regulations,
  • accordingly, which have been sent out from Europe, though they have been
  • frequently weak, have upon most occasions been well meaning. More
  • intelligence, and perhaps less good meaning, has sometimes appeared in
  • those established by the servants in India. It is a very singular
  • government in which every member of the administration wishes to get out
  • of the country, and consequently to have done with the government, as soon
  • as he can, and to whose interest, the day after he has left it, and
  • carried his whole fortune with him, it is perfectly indifferent though the
  • whole country was swallowed up by an earthquake.
  • I mean not, however, by any thing which I have here said, to throw any
  • odious imputation upon the general character of the servants of the East
  • India company, and touch less upon that of any particular persons. It is
  • the system of government, the situation in which they are placed, that I
  • mean to censure, not the character of those who have acted in it. They
  • acted as their situation naturally directed, and they who have clamoured
  • the loudest against them would probably not have acted better themselves.
  • In war and negotiation, the councils of Madras and Calcutta, have upon
  • several occasions, conducted themselves with a resolution and decisive
  • wisdom, which would have done honour to the senate of Rome in the best
  • days of that republic. The members of those councils, however, had been
  • bred to professions very different from war and politics. But their
  • situation alone, without education, experience, or even example, seems to
  • have formed in them all at once the great qualities which it required, and
  • to have inspired them both with abilities and virtues which they
  • themselves could not well know that they possessed. If upon some
  • occasions, therefore, it has animated them to actions of magnanimity which
  • could not well have been expected from them, we should not wonder if, upon
  • others, it has prompted them to exploits of somewhat a different nature.
  • Such exclusive companies, therefore, are nuisances in every respect;
  • always more or less inconvenient to the countries in which they are
  • established, and destructive to those which have the misfortune to fall
  • under their government.
  • CHAPTER VIII.
  • CONCLUSION OF THE MERCANTILE SYSTEM.
  • Though the encouragement of exportation, and the discouragement of
  • importation, are the two great engines by which the mercantile system
  • proposes to enrich every country, yet, with regard to some particular
  • commodities, it seems to follow an opposite plan: to discourage
  • exportation, and to encourage importation. Its ultimate object, however,
  • it pretends, is always the same, to enrich the country by an advantageous
  • balance of trade. It discourages the exportation of the materials of
  • manufacture, and of the instruments of trade, in order to give our own
  • workmen an advantage, and to enable them to undersell those of other
  • nations in all foreign markets; and by restraining, in this manner, the
  • exportation of a few commodities, of no great price, it proposes to
  • occasion a much greater and more valuable exportation of others. It
  • encourages the importation of the materials of manufacture, in order that
  • our own people may be enabled to work them up more cheaply, and thereby
  • prevent a greater and more valuable importation of the manufactured
  • commodities. I do not observe, at least in our statute book, any
  • encouragement given to the importation of the instruments of trade. When
  • manufactures have advanced to a certain pitch of greatness, the
  • fabrication of the instruments of trade becomes itself the object of a
  • great number of very important manufactures. To give any particular
  • encouragement to the importation of such instruments, would interfere too
  • much with the interest of those manufactures. Such importation, therefore,
  • instead of being encouraged, has frequently been prohibited. Thus the
  • importation of wool cards, except from Ireland, or when brought in as
  • wreck or prize goods, was prohibited by the 3rd of Edward IV.; which
  • prohibition was renewed by the 39th of Elizabeth, and has been continued
  • and rendered perpetual by subsequent laws.
  • The importation of the materials of manufacture has sometimes been
  • encouraged by an exemption from the duties to which other goods are
  • subject, and sometimes by bounties.
  • The importation of sheep’s wool from several different countries, of
  • cotton wool from all countries, of undressed flax, of the greater part of
  • dyeing drugs, of the greater part of undressed hides from Ireland, or the
  • British colonies, of seal skins from the British Greenland fishery, of pig
  • and bar iron from the British colonies, as well as of several other
  • materials of manufacture, has been encouraged by an exemption from all
  • duties, if properly entered at the custom-house. The private interest of
  • our merchants and manufacturers may, perhaps, have extorted from the
  • legislature these exemptions, as well as the greater part of our other
  • commercial regulations. They are, however, perfectly just and reasonable;
  • and if, consistently with the necessities of the state, they could be
  • extended to all the other materials of manufacture, the public would
  • certainly be a gainer.
  • The avidity of our great manufacturers, however, has in some cases
  • extended these exemptions a good deal beyond what can justly be considered
  • as the rude materials of their work. By the 24th Geo. II. chap. 46, a
  • small duty of only 1d. the pound was imposed upon the importation of
  • foreign brown linen yarn, instead of much higher duties, to which it had
  • been subjected before, viz. of 6d. the pound upon sail yarn, of 1s. the
  • pound upon all French and Dutch yarn, and of £2:13:4 upon the hundred
  • weight of all spruce or Muscovia yarn. But our manufacturers were not long
  • satisfied with this reduction: by the 29th of the same king, chap. 15, the
  • same law which gave a bounty upon the exportation of British and Irish
  • linen, of which the price did not exceed 18d. the yard, even this small
  • duty upon the importation of brown linen yarn was taken away. In the
  • different operations, however, which are necessary for the preparation of
  • linen yarn, a good deal more industry is employed, than in the subsequent
  • operation of preparing linen cloth from linen yarn. To say nothing of the
  • industry of the flax-growers and flaxdressers, three or four spinners at
  • least are necessary in order to keep one weaver in constant employment;
  • and more than four-fifths of the whole quantity of labour necessary for
  • the preparation of linen cloth, is employed in that of linen yarn; but our
  • spinners are poor people; women commonly scattered about in all different
  • parts of the country, without support or protection. It is not by the sale
  • of their work, but by that of the complete work of the weavers, that our
  • great master manufacturers make their profits. As it is their interest to
  • sell the complete manufacture as dear, so it is to buy the materials as
  • cheap as possible. By extorting from the legislature bounties upon the
  • exportation of their own linen, high duties upon the importation of all
  • foreign linen, and a total prohibition of the home consumption of some
  • sorts of French linen, they endeavour to sell their own goods as dear as
  • possible. By encouraging the importation of foreign linen yarn, and
  • thereby bringing it into competition with that which is made by our own
  • people, they endeavour to buy the work of the poor spinners as cheap as
  • possible. They are as intent to keep down the wages of their own weavers,
  • as the earnings of the poor spinners; and it is by no means for the
  • benefit of the workmen that they endeavour either to raise the price of
  • the complete work, or to lower that of the rude materials. It is the
  • industry which is carried on for the benefit of the rich and the powerful,
  • that is principally encouraged by our mercantile system. That which is
  • carried on for the benefit of the poor and the indigent is too often
  • either neglected or oppressed.
  • Both the bounty upon the exportation of linen, and the exemption from the
  • duty upon the importation of foreign yarn, which were granted only for
  • fifteen years, but continued by two different prolongations, expire with
  • the end of the session of parliament which shall immediately follow the
  • 24th of June 1786.
  • The encouragement given to the importation of the materials of manufacture
  • by bounties, has been principally confined to such as were imported from
  • our American plantations.
  • The first bounties of this kind were those granted about the beginning of
  • the present century, upon the importation of naval stores from America.
  • Under this denomination were comprehended timber fit for masts, yards, and
  • bowsprits; hemp, tar, pitch, and turpentine. The bounty, however, of £1
  • the ton upon masting-timber, and that of £6 the ton upon hemp, were
  • extended to such as should be imported into England from Scotland. Both
  • these bounties continued, without any variation, at the same rate, till
  • they were severally allowed to expire; that upon hemp on the 1st of
  • January 1741, and that upon masting-timber at the end of the session of
  • parliament immediately following the 24th June 1781.
  • The bounties upon the importation of tar, pitch, and turpentine,
  • underwent, during their continuance, several alterations. Originally, that
  • upon tar was £4 the ton; that upon pitch the same; and that upon
  • turpentine £3 the ton. The bounty of £4 the ton upon tar was afterwards
  • confined to such as had been prepared in a particular manner; that upon
  • other good, clean, and merchantable tar was reduced to £2:4s. the ton. The
  • bounty upon pitch was likewise reduced to £1, and that upon turpentine to
  • £1:10s. the ton.
  • The second bounty upon the importation of any of the materials of
  • manufacture, according to the order of time, was that granted by the 21st
  • Geo. II. chap.30, upon the importation of indigo from the British
  • plantations. When the plantation indigo was worth three-fourths of the
  • price of the best French indigo, it was, by this act, entitled to a bounty
  • of 6d. the pound. This bounty, which, like most others, was granted only
  • for a limited time, was continued by several prolongations, but was
  • reduced to 4d. the pound. It was allowed to expire with the end of the
  • session of parliament which followed the 25th March 1781.
  • The third bounty of this kind was that granted (much about the time that
  • we were beginning sometimes to court, and sometimes to quarrel with our
  • American colonies), by the 4th. Geo. III. chap. 26, upon the importation
  • of hemp, or undressed flax, from the British plantations. This bounty was
  • granted for twenty-one years, from the 24th June 1764 to the 24th June
  • 1785. For the first seven years, it was to be at the rate of £8 the ton;
  • for the second at £6; and for the third at £4. It was not extended to
  • Scotland, of which the climate (although hemp is sometimes raised there in
  • small quantities, and of an inferior quality) is not very fit for that
  • produce. Such a bounty upon the importation of Scotch flax in England
  • would have been too great a discouragement to the native produce of the
  • southern part of the united kingdom.
  • The fourth bounty of this kind was that granted by the 5th Geo. III. chap.
  • 45, upon the importation of wood from America. It was granted for nine
  • years from the 1st January 1766 to the 1st January 1775. During the first
  • three years, it was to be for every hundred-and-twenty good deals, at the
  • rate of £1, and for every load containing fifty cubic feet of other square
  • timber, at the rate of 12s. For the second three years, it was for deals,
  • to be at the rate of 15s., and for other squared timber at the rate of
  • 8s.; and for the third three years, it was for deals, to be at the rate of
  • 10s.; and for every other squared timber at the rate of 5s.
  • The fifth bounty of this kind was that granted by the 9th Geo. III. chap.
  • 38, upon the importation of raw silk from the British plantations. It was
  • granted for twenty-one years, from the 1st January 1770, to the 1st
  • January 1791. For the first seven years, it was to be at the rate of £25
  • for every hundred pounds value; for the second, at £20; and for the third,
  • at £15. The management of the silk-worm, and the preparation of silk,
  • requires so much hand-labour, and labour is so very dear in America, that
  • even this great bounty, I have been informed, was not likely to produce
  • any considerable effect.
  • The sixth Bounty of this kind was that granted by 11th Geo. III. chap. 50,
  • for the importation of pipe, hogshead, and barrelstaves and leading from
  • the British plantations. It was granted for nine years, from 1st January
  • 1772 to the 1st January 1781. For the first three years, it was, for a
  • certain quantity of each, to be at the rate of £6; for the second three
  • years at £4; and for the third three years at £2.
  • The seventh and last bounty of this kind was that granted by the 19th Geo.
  • III chap. 37, upon the importation of hemp from Ireland. It was granted in
  • the same manner as that for the importation of hemp and undressed flax
  • from America, for twenty-one years, from the 24th June 1779 to the 24th
  • June 1800. The term is divided likewise into three periods, of seven years
  • each; and in each of those periods, the rate of the Irish bounty is the
  • same with that of the American. It does not, however, like the American
  • bounty, extend to the importation of undressed flax. It would have been
  • too great a discouragement to the cultivation of that plant in Great
  • Britain. When this last bounty was granted, the British and Irish
  • legislatures were not in much better humour with one another, than the
  • British and American had been before. But this boon to Ireland, it is to
  • be hoped, has been granted under more fortunate auspices than all those to
  • America. The same commodities, upon which we thus gave bounties, when
  • imported from America, were subjected to considerable duties when imported
  • from any other country. The interest of our American colonies was regarded
  • as the same with that of the mother country. Their wealth was considered
  • as our wealth. Whatever money was sent out to them, it was said, came all
  • back to us by the balance of trade, and we could never become a farthing
  • the poorer by any expense which we could lay out upon them. They were our
  • own in every respect, and it was an expense laid out upon the improvement
  • of our own property, and for the profitable employment of our own people.
  • It is unnecessary, I apprehend, at present to say anything further, in
  • order to expose the folly of a system which fatal experience has now
  • sufficiently exposed. Had our American colonies really been a part of
  • Great Britain, those bounties might have been considered as bounties upon
  • production, and would still have been liable to all the objections to
  • which such bounties are liable, but to no other.
  • The exportation of the materials of manufacture is sometimes discouraged
  • by absolute prohibitions, and sometimes by high duties.
  • Our woollen manufacturers have been more successful than any other class
  • of workmen, in persuading the legislature that the prosperity of the
  • nation depended upon the success and extension of their particular
  • business. They have not only obtained a monopoly against the consumers, by
  • an absolute prohibition of importing woollen cloths from any foreign
  • country; but they have likewise obtained another monopoly against the
  • sheep farmers and growers of wool, by a similar prohibition of the
  • exportation of live sheep and wool. The severity of many of the laws which
  • have been enacted for the security of the revenue is very justly
  • complained of, as imposing heavy penalties upon actions which, antecedent
  • to the statutes that declared them to be crimes, had always been
  • understood to be innocent. But the cruellest of our revenue laws, I will
  • venture to affirm, are mild and gentle, in comparison to some of those
  • which the clamour of our merchants and manufacturers has extorted from the
  • legislature, for the support of their own absurd and oppressive
  • monopolies. Like the laws of Draco, these laws may be said to be all
  • written in blood.
  • By the 8th of Elizabeth, chap. 3, the exporter of sheep, lambs, or rams,
  • was for the first offence, to forfeit all his goods for ever, to suffer a
  • year’s imprisonment, and then to have his left hand cut off in a market
  • town, upon a market day, to be there nailed up; and for the second
  • offence, to be adjudged a felon, and to suffer death accordingly. To
  • prevent the breed of our sheep from being propagated in foreign countries,
  • seems to have been the object of this law. By the 13th and 14th of Charles
  • II. chap. 18, the exportation of wool was made felony, and the exporter
  • subjected to the same penalties and forfeitures as a felon.
  • For the honour of the national humanity, it is to be hoped that neither of
  • these statutes was ever executed. The first of them, however, so far as I
  • know, has never been directly repealed, and serjeant Hawkins seems to
  • consider it as still in force. It may, however, perhaps be considered as
  • virtually repealed by the 12th of Charles II. chap. 32, sect. 3, which,
  • without expressly taking away the penalties imposed by former statutes,
  • imposes a new penalty, viz. that of 20s. for every sheep exported, or
  • attempted to be exported, together with the forfeiture of the sheep, and
  • of the owner’s share of the sheep. The second of them was expressly
  • repealed by the 7th and 8th of William III. chap. 28, sect. 4, by which it
  • is declared that “Whereas the statute of the 13th and 14th of king Charles
  • II. made against the exportation of wool, among other things in the said
  • act mentioned, doth enact the same to be deemed felony, by the severity of
  • which penalty the prosecution of offenders hath not been so effectually
  • put in execution; be it therefore enacted, by the authority aforesaid,
  • that so much of the said act, which relates to the making the said offence
  • felony, be repealed and made void.”
  • The penalties, however, which are either imposed by this milder statute,
  • or which, though imposed by former statutes, are not repealed by this one,
  • are still sufficiently severe. Besides the forfeiture of the goods, the
  • exporter incurs the penalty of 3s. for every pound weight of wool, either
  • exported or attempted to be exported, that is, about four or five times
  • the value. Any merchant, or other person convicted of this offence, is
  • disabled from requiring any debt or account belonging to him from any
  • factor or other person. Let his fortune be what it will, whether he is or
  • is not able to pay those heavy penalties, the law means to ruin him
  • completely. But, as the morals of the great body of the people are not yet
  • so corrupt as those of the contrivers of this statute, I have not heard
  • that any advantage has ever been taken of this clause. If the person
  • convicted of this offence is not able to pay the penalties within three
  • months after judgment, he is to be transported for seven years; and if he
  • returns before the expiration of that term, he is liable to the pains of
  • felony, without benefit of clergy. The owner of the ship, knowing this
  • offence, forfeits all his interest in the ship and furniture. The master
  • and mariners, knowing this offence, forfeit all their goods and chattels,
  • and suffer three months imprisonment. By a subsequent statute, the master
  • suffers six months imprisonment.
  • In order to prevent exportation, the whole inland commerce of wool is laid
  • under very burdensome and oppressive restrictions. It cannot be packed in
  • any box, barrel, cask, case, chest, or any other package, but only in
  • packs of leather or pack-cloth, on which must be marked on the outside the
  • words WOOL or YARN, in large letters, not less than three inches long, on
  • pain of forfeiting the same and the package, and 8s. for every pound
  • weight, to be paid by the owner or packer. It cannot be loaden on any
  • horse or cart, or carried by land within five miles of the coast, but
  • between sun-rising, and sun-setting, on pain of forfeiting the same, the
  • horses and carriages. The hundred next adjoining to the sea coast, out of,
  • or through which the wool is carried or exported, forfeits £20, if the
  • wool is under the value of £10; and if of greater value, then treble that
  • value, together with treble costs, to be sued for within the year. The
  • execution to be against any two of the inhabitants, whom the sessions must
  • reimburse, by an assessment on the other inhabitants, as in the cases of
  • robbery. And if any person compounds with the hundred for less than this
  • penalty, he is to be imprisoned for five years; and any other person may
  • prosecute. These regulations take place through the whole kingdom.
  • But in the particular counties of Kent and Sussex, the restrictions are
  • still more troublesome. Every owner of wool within ten miles of the sea
  • coast must give an account in writing, three days after shearing, to the
  • next officer of the customs, of the number of his fleeces, and of the
  • places where they are lodged. And before he removes any part of them, he
  • must give the like notice of the number and weight of the fleeces, and of
  • the name and abode of the person to whom they are sold, and of the place
  • to which it is intended they should be carried. No person within fifteen
  • miles of the sea, in the said counties, can buy any wool, before he enters
  • into bond to the king, that no part of the wool which he shall so buy
  • shall be sold by him to any other person within fifteen miles of the sea.
  • If any wool is found carrying towards the sea side in the said counties,
  • unless it has been entered and security given as aforesaid, it is
  • forfeited, and the offender also forfeits 3s. for every pound weight, if
  • any person lay any wool, not entered as aforesaid, within fifteen miles of
  • the sea, it must be seized and forfeited; and if, after such seizure, any
  • person shall claim the same, he must give security to the exchequer, that
  • if he is cast upon trial he shall pay treble costs, besides all other
  • penalties.
  • When such restrictions are imposed upon the inland trade, the coasting
  • trade, we may believe, cannot be left very free. Every owner of wool, who
  • carrieth, or causeth to be carried, any wool to any port or place on the
  • sea coast, in order to be from thence transported by sea to any other
  • place or port on the coast, must first cause an entry thereof to be made
  • at the port from whence it is intended to be conveyed, containing the
  • weight, marks, and number, of the packages, before he brings the same
  • within five miles of that port, on pain of forfeiting the same, and also
  • the horses, carts, and other carriages; and also of suffering and
  • forfeiting, as by the other laws in force against the exportation of wool.
  • This law, however (1st of William III. chap. 32), is so very indulgent as
  • to declare, that this shall not hinder any person from carrying his wool
  • home from the place of shearing, though it be within five miles of the
  • sea, provided that in ten days after shearing, and before he remove the
  • wool, he do under his hand certify to the next officer of the customs the
  • true number of fleeces, and where it is housed; and do not remove the
  • same, without certifying to such officer, under his hand, his intention so
  • to do, three days before. Bond must be given that the wool to be carried
  • coast-ways is to be landed at the particular port for which it is entered
  • outwards; and if my part of it is landed without the presence of an
  • officer, not only the forfeiture of the wool is incurred, as in other
  • goods, but the usual additional penalty of 3s. for every pound weight is
  • likewise incurred.
  • Our woollen manufacturers, in order to justify their demand of such
  • extraordinary restrictions and regulations, confidently asserted, that
  • English wool was of a peculiar quality, superior to that of any other
  • country; that the wool of other countries could not, without some mixture
  • of it, be wrought up into any tolerable manufacture; that fine cloth could
  • not be made without it; that England, therefore, if the exportation of it
  • could be totally prevented, could monopolize to herself almost the whole
  • woollen trade of the world; and thus, having no rivals, could sell at what
  • price she pleased, and in a short time acquire the most incredible degree
  • of wealth by the most advantageous balance of trade. This doctrine, like
  • most other doctrines which are confidently asserted by any considerable
  • number of people, was, and still continues to be, most implicitly believed
  • by a much greater number: by almost all those who are either unacquainted
  • with the woollen trade, or who have not made particular inquiries. It is,
  • however, so perfectly false, that English wool is in any respect necessary
  • for the making of fine cloth, that it is altogether unfit for it. Fine
  • cloth is made altogether of Spanish wool. English wool, cannot be even so
  • mixed with Spanish wool, as to enter into the composition without spoiling
  • and degrading, in some degree, the fabric of the cloth.
  • It has been shown in the foregoing part of this work, that the effect of
  • these regulations has been to depress the price of English wool, not only
  • below what it naturally would be in the present times, but very much below
  • what it actually was in the time of Edward III. The price of Scotch wool,
  • when, in consequence of the Union, it became subject to the same
  • regulations, is said to have fallen about one half. It is observed by the
  • very accurate and intelligent author of the Memoirs of Wool, the Reverend
  • Mr. John Smith, that the price of the best English wool in England, is
  • generally below what wool of a very inferior quality commonly sells for in
  • the market of Amsterdam. To depress the price of this commodity below what
  • may be called its natural and proper price, was the avowed purpose of
  • those regulations; and there seems to be no doubt of their having produced
  • the effect that was expected from them.
  • This reduction of price, it may perhaps be thought, by discouraging the
  • growing of wool, must have reduced very much the annual produce of that
  • commodity, though not below what it formerly was, yet below what, in the
  • present state of things, it would probably have been, had it, in
  • consequence of an open and free market, been allowed to rise to the
  • natural and proper price. I am, however, disposed to believe, that the
  • quantity of the annual produce cannot have been much, though it may,
  • perhaps, have been a little affected by these regulations. The growing of
  • wool is not the chief purpose for which the sheep farmer employs his
  • industry and stock. He expects his profit, not so much from the price of
  • the fleece, as from that of the carcase; and the average or ordinary price
  • of the latter must even, in many cases, make up to him whatever deficiency
  • there may be in the average or ordinary price of the former. It has been
  • observed, in the foregoing part of this work, that ‘whatever regulations
  • tend to sink the price, either of wool or of raw hides, below what it
  • naturally would be, must, in an improved and cultivated country, have some
  • tendency to raise the price of butcher’s meat. The price, both of the
  • great and small cattle which are fed on improved and cultivated land, must
  • be sufficient to pay the rent which the landlord, and the profit which the
  • farmer, has reason to expect from improved and cultivated land. If it is
  • not, they will soon cease to feed them. Whatever part of this price,
  • therefore, is not paid by the wool and the hide, must be paid by the
  • carcase. The less there is paid for the one, the more must be paid for the
  • other. In what manner this price is to be divided upon the different parts
  • of the beast, is indifferent to the landlords and farmers, provided it is
  • all paid to them. In an improved and cultivated country, therefore, their
  • interest as landlords and farmers cannot be much affected by such
  • regulations, though their interest as consumers may, by the rise in the
  • price of provisions.’ According to this reasoning, therefore, this
  • degradation in the price of wool is not likely, in an improved and
  • cultivated country, to occasion any diminution in the annual produce of
  • that commodity; except so far as, by raising the price of mutton, it may
  • somewhat diminish the demand for, and consequently the production of, that
  • particular species of butcher’s meat, Its effect, however, even in this
  • way, it is probable, is not very considerable.
  • But though its effect upon the quantity of the annual produce may not have
  • been very considerable, its effect upon the quality, it may perhaps be
  • thought, must necessarily have been very great. The degradation in the
  • quality of English wool, if not below what it was in former times, yet
  • below what it naturally would have been in the present state of
  • improvement and cultivation, must have been, it may perhaps be supposed,
  • very nearly in proportion to the degradation of price. As the quality
  • depends upon the breed, upon the pasture, and upon the management and
  • cleanliness of the sheep, during the whole progress of the growth of the
  • fleece, the attention to these circumstances, it may naturally enough be
  • imagined, can never be greater than in proportion to the recompence which
  • the price of the fleece is likely to make for the labour and expense which
  • that attention requires. It happens, however, that the goodness of the
  • fleece depends, in a great measure, upon the health, growth, and bulk of
  • the animal: the same attention which is necessary for the improvement of
  • the carcase is, in some respect, sufficient for that of the fleece.
  • Notwithstanding the degradation of price, English wool is said to have
  • been improved considerably during the course even of the present century.
  • The improvement, might, perhaps, have been greater if the price had been
  • better; but the lowness of price, though it may have obstructed, yet
  • certainly it has not altogether prevented that improvement.
  • The violence of these regulations, therefore, seems to have affected
  • neither the quantity nor the quality of the annual produce of wool, so
  • much as it might have been expected to do (though I think it probable that
  • it may have affected the latter a good deal more than the former); and the
  • interest of the growers of wool, though it must have been hurt in some
  • degree, seems upon the whole, to have been much less hurt than could well
  • have been imagined.
  • These considerations, however, will not justify the absolute prohibition
  • of the exportation of wool; but they will fully justify the imposition of
  • a considerable tax upon that exportation.
  • To hurt, in any degree, the interest of any one order of citizens, for no
  • other purpose but to promote that of some other, is evidently contrary to
  • that justice and equality of treatment which the sovereign owes to all the
  • different orders of his subjects. But the prohibition certainly hurts, in
  • some degree, the interest of the growers of wool, for no other purpose but
  • to promote that of the manufacturers.
  • Every different order of citizens is bound to contribute to the support of
  • the sovereign or commonwealth. A tax of five, or even of ten shillings,
  • upon the exportation of every tod of wool, would produce a very
  • considerable revenue to the sovereign. It would hurt the interest of the
  • growers somewhat less than the prohibition, because it would not probably
  • lower the price of wool quite so much. It would afford a sufficient
  • advantage to the manufacturer, because, though he might not buy his wool
  • altogether so cheap as under the prohibition, he would still buy it at
  • least five or ten shillings cheaper than any foreign manufacturer could
  • buy it, besides saving the freight and insurance which the other would be
  • obliged to pay. It is scarce possible to devise a tax which could produce
  • any considerable revenue to the sovereign, and at the same time occasion
  • so little inconveniency to anybody.
  • The prohibition, notwithstanding all the penalties which guard it, does
  • not prevent the exportation of wool. It is exported, it is well known, in
  • great quantities. The great difference between the price in the home and
  • that in the foreign market, presents such a temptation to smuggling, that
  • all the rigour of the law cannot prevent it. This illegal exportation is
  • advantageous to nobody but the smuggler. A legal exportation, subject to a
  • tax, by affording a revenue to the sovereign, and thereby saving the
  • imposition of some other, perhaps more burdensome and inconvenient taxes,
  • might prove advantageous to all the different subjects of the state.
  • The exportation of fuller’s earth, or fuller’s clay, supposed to be
  • necessary for preparing and cleansing the woollen manufactures, has been
  • subjected to nearly the same penalties as the exportation of wool. Even
  • tobacco-pipe clay, though acknowledged to be different from fuller’s clay,
  • yet, on account of their resemblance, and because fuller’s clay might
  • sometimes be exported as tobacco-pipe clay, has been laid under the same
  • prohibitions and penalties.
  • By the 13th and 14th of Charles II. chap, 7, the exportation, not only of
  • raw hides, but of tanned leather, except in the shape of boots, shoes, or
  • slippers, was prohibited; and the law gave a monopoly to our boot-makers
  • and shoe-makers, not only against our graziers, but against our tanners.
  • By subsequent statutes, our tanners have got themselves exempted from this
  • monopoly, upon paying a small tax of only one shilling on the hundred
  • weight of tanned leather, weighing one hundred and twelve pounds. They
  • have obtained likewise the drawback of two-thirds of the excise duties
  • imposed upon their commodity, even when exported without further
  • manufacture. All manufactures of leather may be exported duty free; and
  • the exporter is besides entitled to the drawback of the whole duties of
  • excise. Our graziers still continue subject to the old monopoly. Graziers,
  • separated from one another, and dispersed through all the different
  • corners of the country, cannot, without great difficulty, combine together
  • for the purpose either of imposing monopolies upon their fellow-citizens,
  • or of exempting themselves from such as may have been imposed upon them by
  • other people. Manufacturers of all kinds, collected together in numerous
  • bodies in all great cities, easily can. Even the horns of cattle are
  • prohibited to be exported; and the two insignificant trades of the horner
  • and comb-maker enjoy, in this respect, a monopoly against the graziers.
  • Restraints, either by prohibitions, or by taxes, upon the exportation of
  • goods which are partially, but not completely manufactured, are not
  • peculiar to the manufacture of leather. As long as anything remains to be
  • done, in order to fit any commodity for immediate use and consumption, our
  • manufacturers think that they themselves ought to have the doing of it.
  • Woollen yarn and worsted are prohibited to be exported, under the same
  • penalties as wool even white cloths we subject to a duty upon exportation;
  • and our dyers have so far obtained a monopoly against our clothiers. Our
  • clothiers would probably have been able to defend themselves against it;
  • but it happens that the greater part of our principal clothiers are
  • themselves likewise dyers. Watch-cases, clock-cases, and dial-plates for
  • clocks and watches, have been prohibited to be exported. Our clock-makers
  • and watch-makers are, it seems, unwilling that the price of this sort of
  • workmanship should be raised upon them by the competition of foreigners.
  • By some old statutes of Edward III, Henry VIII. and Edward VI. the
  • exportation of all metals was prohibited. Lead and tin were alone
  • excepted, probably on account of the great abundance of those metals; in
  • the exportation of which a considerable part of the trade of the kingdom
  • in those days consisted. For the encouragement of the mining trade, the
  • 5th of William and Mary, chap.17, exempted from this prohibition iron,
  • copper, and mundic metal made from British ore. The exportation of all
  • sorts of copper bars, foreign as well as British, was afterwards permitted
  • by the 9th and 10th of William III. chap 26. The exportation of
  • unmanufactured brass, of what is called gun-metal, bell-metal, and shroff
  • metal, still continues to be prohibited. Brass manufactures of all sorts
  • may be exported duty free.
  • The exportation of the materials of manufacture, where it is not
  • altogether prohibited, is, in many cases, subjected to considerable
  • duties.
  • By the 8th Geo. I. chap.15, the exportation of all goods, the produce of
  • manufacture of Great Britain, upon which any duties had been imposed by
  • former statutes, was rendered duty free. The following goods, however,
  • were excepted: alum, lead, lead-ore, tin, tanned leather, copperas, coals,
  • wool, cards, white woollen cloths, lapis calaminaris, skins of all sorts,
  • glue, coney hair or wool, hares wool, hair of all sorts, horses, and
  • litharge of lead. If you except horses, all these are either materials of
  • manufacture, or incomplete manufactures (which may be considered as
  • materials for still further manufacture), or instruments of trade. This
  • statute leaves them subject to all the old duties which had ever been
  • imposed upon them, the old subsidy, and one per cent. outwards.
  • By the same statute, a great number of foreign drugs for dyers use are
  • exempted from all duties upon importation. Each of them, however, is
  • afterwards subjected to a certain duty, not indeed a very heavy one, upon
  • exportation. Our dyers, it seems, while they thought it for their interest
  • to encourage the importation of those drugs, by an exemption from all
  • duties, thought it likewise for their own interest to throw some small
  • discouragement upon their exportation. The avidity, however, which
  • suggested this notable piece of mercantile ingenuity, most probably
  • disappointed itself of its object. It necessarily taught the importers to
  • be more careful than they might otherwise have been, that their
  • importation should not exceed what was necessary for the supply of the
  • home market. The home market was at all times likely to be more scantily
  • supplied; the commodities were at all times likely to be somewhat dearer
  • there than they would have been, had the exportation been rendered as free
  • as the importation.
  • By the above-mentioned statute, gum senega, or gum arabic, being among the
  • enumerated dyeing drugs, might be imported duty free. They were subjected,
  • indeed, to a small poundage duty, amounting only to threepence in the
  • hundred weight, upon their re-exportation. France enjoyed, at that time,
  • an exclusive trade to the country most productive of those drugs, that
  • which lies in the neighbourhood of the Senegal; and the British market
  • could not be easily supplied by the immediate importation of them from the
  • place of growth. By the 25th Geo. II. therefore, gum senega was allowed to
  • be imported (contrary to the general dispositions of the act of
  • navigation) from any part of Europe. As the law, however, did not mean to
  • encourage this species of trade, so contrary to the general principles of
  • the mercantile policy of England, it imposed a duty of ten shillings the
  • hundred weight upon such importation, and no part of this duty was to be
  • afterwards drawn back upon its exportation. The successful war which began
  • in 1755 gave Great Britain the same exclusive trade to those countries
  • which France had enjoyed before. Our manufactures, as soon as the peace
  • was made, endeavoured to avail themselves of this advantage, and to
  • establish a monopoly in their own favour both against the growers and
  • against the importers of this commodity. By the 5th of Geo. III.
  • therefore, chap. 37, the exportation of gum senega, from his majesty’s
  • dominions in Africa, was confined to Great Britain, and was subjected to
  • all the same restrictions, regulations, forfeitures, and penalties, as
  • that of the enumerated commodities of the British colonies in America and
  • the West Indies. Its importation, indeed, was subjected to a small duty of
  • sixpence the hundred weight; but its re-exportation was subjected to the
  • enormous duty of one pound ten shillings the hundred weight. It was the
  • intention of our manufacturers, that the whole produce of those countries
  • should be imported into Great Britain; and in order that they themselves
  • might be enabled to buy it at their own price, that no part of it should
  • be exported again, but at such an expense as would sufficiently discourage
  • that exportation. Their avidity, however, upon this, as well as upon many
  • other occasions, disappointed itself of its object. This enormous duty
  • presented such a temptation to smuggling, that great quantities of this
  • commodity were clandestinely exported, probably to all the manufacturing
  • countries of Europe, but particularly to Holland, not only from Great
  • Britain, but from Africa. Upon this account, by the 14th Geo. III.
  • chap.10, this duty upon exportation was reduced to five shillings the
  • hundred weight.
  • In the book of rates, according to which the old subsidy was levied,
  • beaver skins were estimated at six shillings and eight pence a piece; and
  • the different subsidies and imposts which, before the year 1722, had been
  • laid upon their importation, amounted to one-fifth part of the rate, or to
  • sixteen pence upon each skin; all of which, except half the old subsidy,
  • amounting only to twopence, was drawn back upon exportation. This duty,
  • upon the importation of so important a material of manufacture, had been
  • thought too high; and, in the year 1722, the rate was reduced to two
  • shillings and sixpence, which reduced the duty upon importation to
  • sixpence, and of this only one-half was to be drawn back upon exportation.
  • The same successful war put the country most productive of beaver under
  • the dominion of Great Britain; and beaver skins being among the enumerated
  • commodities, the exportation from America was consequently confined to the
  • market of Great Britain. Our manufacturers soon bethought themselves of
  • the advantage which they might make of this circumstance; and in the year
  • 1764, the duty upon the importation of beaver skin was reduced to one
  • penny, but the duty upon exportation was raised to sevenpence each skin,
  • without any drawback of the duty upon importation. By the same law, a duty
  • of eighteen pence the pound was imposed upon the exportation of beaver
  • wool or woumbs, without making any alteration in the duty upon the
  • importation of that commodity, which, when imported by British, and in
  • British shipping, amounted at that time to between fourpence and fivepence
  • the piece.
  • Coals may be considered both as a material of manufacture, and as an
  • instrument of trade. Heavy duties, accordingly, have been imposed upon
  • their exportation, amounting at present (1783) to more than five shillings
  • the ton, or more than fifteen shillings the chaldron, Newcastle measure;
  • which is, in most cases, more than the original value of the commodity at
  • the coal-pit, or even at the shipping port for exportation.
  • The exportation, however, of the instruments of trade, properly so called,
  • is commonly restrained, not by high duties, but by absolute prohibitions.
  • Thus, by the 7th and 8th of William III chap.20, sect.8, the exportation
  • of frames or engines for knitting gloves or stockings, is prohibited,
  • under the penalty, not only of the forfeiture of such frames or engines,
  • so exported, or attempted to be exported, but of forty pounds, one half to
  • the king, the other to the person who shall inform or sue for the same. In
  • the same manner, by the 14th Geo. III. chap. 71, the exportation to
  • foreign parts, of any utensils made use of in the cotton, linen, woollen,
  • and silk manufactures, is prohibited under the penalty, not only of the
  • forfeiture of such utensils, but of two hundred pounds, to be paid by the
  • person who shall offend in this manner; and likewise of two hundred
  • pounds, to be paid by the master of the ship, who shall knowingly suffer
  • such utensils to be loaded on board his ship.
  • When such heavy penalties were imposed upon the exportation of the dead
  • instruments of trade, it could not well be expected that the living
  • instrument, the artificer, should be allowed to go free. Accordingly, by
  • the 5th Geo. I. chap. 27, the person who shall be convicted of enticing
  • any artificer, of or in any of the manufactures of Great Britain, to go
  • into any foreign parts, in order to practise or teach his trade, is
  • liable, for the first offence, to be fined in any sum not exceeding one
  • hundred pounds, and to three months imprisonment, and until the fine shall
  • be paid; and for the second offence, to be fined in any sum, at the
  • discretion of the court, and to imprisonment for twelve months, and until
  • the fine shall be paid. By the 23d Geo. II. chap. 13, this penalty is
  • increased, for the first offence, to five hundred pounds for every
  • artificer so enticed, and to twelve months imprisonment, and until the
  • fine shall be paid; and for the second offence, to one thousand pounds,
  • and to two years imprisonment, and until the fine shall be paid.
  • By the former of these two statutes, upon proof that any person has been
  • enticing any artificer, or that any artificer has promised or contracted
  • to go into foreign parts, for the purposes aforesaid, such artificer may
  • be obliged to give security, at the discretion of the court, that he shall
  • not go beyond the seas, and may be committed to prison until he give such
  • security.
  • If any artificer has gone beyond the seas, and is exercising or teaching
  • his trade in any foreign country, upon warning being given to him by any
  • of his majesty’s ministers or consuls abroad, or by one of his majesty’s
  • secretaries of state, for the time being, if he does not, within six
  • months after such warning, return into this realm, and from henceforth
  • abide and inhabit continually within the same, he is from thenceforth
  • declared incapable of taking any legacy devised to him within this
  • kingdom, or of being executor or administrator to any person, or of taking
  • any lands within this kingdom, by descent, devise, or purchase. He
  • likewise forfeits to the king all his lands, goods, and chattels; is
  • declared an alien in every respect; and is put out of the king’s
  • protection.
  • It is unnecessary, I imagine, to observe how contrary such regulations are
  • to the boasted liberty of the subject, of which we affect to be so very
  • jealous; but which, in this case, is so plainly sacrificed to the futile
  • interests of our merchants and manufacturers.
  • The laudable motive of all these regulations, is to extend our own
  • manufactures, not by their own improvement, but by the depression of those
  • of all our neighbours, and by putting an end, as much as possible, to the
  • troublesome competition of such odious and disagreeable rivals. Our master
  • manufacturers think it reasonable that they themselves should have the
  • monopoly of the ingenuity of all their countrymen. Though by restraining,
  • in some trades, the number of apprentices which can be employed at one
  • time, and by imposing the necessity of a long apprenticeship in all
  • trades, they endeavour, all of them, to confine the knowledge of their
  • respective employments to as small a number as possible; they are
  • unwilling, however, that any part of this small number should go abroad to
  • instruct foreigners.
  • Consumption is the sole end and purpose of all production; and the
  • interest of the producer ought to be attended to, only so far as it may be
  • necessary for promoting that of the consumer.
  • The maxim is so perfectly self-evident, that it would be absurd to attempt
  • to prove it. But in the mercantile system, the interest of the consumer is
  • almost constantly sacrificed to that of the producer; and it seems to
  • consider production, and not consumption, as the ultimate end and object
  • of all industry and commerce.
  • In the restraints upon the importation of all foreign commodities which
  • can come into competition with those of our own growth or manufacture, the
  • interest of the home consumer is evidently sacrificed to that of the
  • producer. It is altogether for the benefit of the latter, that the former
  • is obliged to pay that enhancement of price which this monopoly almost
  • always occasions.
  • It is altogether for the benefit of the producer, that bounties are
  • granted upon the exportation of some of his productions. The home consumer
  • is obliged to pay, first the tax which is necessary for paying the bounty;
  • and, secondly, the still greater tax which necessarily arises from the
  • enhancement of the price of the commodity in the home market.
  • By the famous treaty of commerce with Portugal, the consumer is prevented
  • by duties from purchasing of a neighbouring country, a commodity which our
  • own climate does not produce; but is obliged to purchase it of a distant
  • country, though it is acknowledged, that the commodity of the distant
  • country is of a worse quality than that of the near one. The home consumer
  • is obliged to submit to this inconvenience, in order that the producer may
  • import into the distant country some of his productions, upon more
  • advantageous terms than he otherwise would have been allowed to do. The
  • consumer, too, is obliged to pay whatever enhancement in the price of
  • those very productions this forced exportation may occasion in the home
  • market.
  • But in the system of laws which has been established for the management of
  • our American and West Indian colonies, the interest of the home consumer
  • has been sacrificed to that of the producer, with a more extravagant
  • profusion than in all our other commercial regulations. A great empire has
  • been established for the sole purpose of raising up a nation of customers,
  • who should be obliged to buy, from the shops of our different producers,
  • all the goods with which these could supply them. For the sake of that
  • little enhancement of price which this monopoly might afford our
  • producers, the home consumers have been burdened with the whole expense of
  • maintaining and defending that empire. For this purpose, and for this
  • purpose only, in the two last wars, more than two hundred millions have
  • been spent, and a new debt of more than a hundred and seventy millions has
  • been contracted, over and above all that had been expended for the same
  • purpose in former wars. The interest of this debt alone is not only
  • greater than the whole extraordinary profit which, it never could be
  • pretended, was made by the monopoly of the colony trade, but than the
  • whole value of that trade, or than the whole value of the goods which, at
  • an average, have been annually exported to the colonies.
  • It cannot be very difficult to determine who have been the contrivers of
  • this whole mercantile system; not the consumers, we may believe, whose
  • interest has been entirely neglected; but the producers, whose interest
  • has been so carefully attended to; and among this latter class, our
  • merchants and manufacturers have been by far the principal architects. In
  • the mercantile regulations which have been taken notice of in this
  • chapter, the interest of our manufacturers has been most peculiarly
  • attended to; and the interest, not so much of the consumers, as that of
  • some other sets of producers, has been sacrificed to it.
  • CHAPTER IX.
  • OF THE AGRICULTURAL SYSTEMS, OR OF
  • THOSE SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY WHICH REPRESENT THE PRODUCE OF LAND, AS
  • EITHER THE SOLE OR THE PRINCIPAL SOURCE OF THE REVENUE AND WEALTH OF EVERY
  • COUNTRY.
  • The agricultural systems of political economy will not require so long an
  • explanation as that which I have thought it necessary to bestow upon the
  • mercantile or commercial system.
  • That system which represents the produce of land as the sole source of the
  • revenue and wealth of every country, has so far as I know, never been
  • adopted by any nation, and it at present exists only in the speculations
  • of a few men of great learning and ingenuity in France. It would not,
  • surely, be worth while to examine at great length the errors of a system
  • which never has done, and probably never will do, any harm in any part of
  • the world. I shall endeavour to explain, however, as distinctly as I can,
  • the great outlines of this very ingenious system.
  • Mr. Colbert, the famous minister of Lewis XIV. was a man of probity, of
  • great industry, and knowledge of detail; of great experience and acuteness
  • in the examination of public accounts; and of abilities, in short, every
  • way fitted for introducing method and good order into the collection and
  • expenditure of the public revenue. That minister had unfortunately
  • embraced all the prejudices of the mercantile system, in its nature and
  • essence a system of restraint and regulation, and such as could scarce
  • fail to be agreeable to a laborious and plodding man of business, who had
  • been accustomed to regulate the different departments of public offices,
  • and to establish the necessary checks and controls for confining each to
  • its proper sphere. The industry and commerce of a great country, he
  • endeavoured to regulate upon the same model as the departments of a public
  • office; and instead of allowing every man to pursue his own interest his
  • own way, upon the liberal plan of equality, liberty, and justice, he
  • bestowed upon certain branches of industry extraordinary privileges, while
  • he laid others under as extraordinary restraints. He was not only
  • disposed, like other European ministers, to encourage more the industry of
  • the towns than that of the country; but, in order to support the industry
  • of the towns, he was willing even to depress and keep down that of the
  • country. In order to render provisions cheap to the inhabitants of the
  • towns, and thereby to encourage manufactures and foreign commerce, he
  • prohibited altogether the exportation of corn, and thus excluded the
  • inhabitants of the country from every foreign market, for by far the most
  • important part of the produce of their industry. This prohibition, joined
  • to the restraints imposed by the ancient provincial laws of France upon
  • the transportation of corn from one province to another, and to the
  • arbitrary and degrading taxes which are levied upon the cultivators in
  • almost all the provinces, discouraged and kept down the agriculture of
  • that country very much below the state to which it would naturally have
  • risen in so very fertile a soil, and so very happy a climate. This state
  • of discouragement and depression was felt more or less in every different
  • part of the country, and many different inquiries were set on foot
  • concerning the causes of it. One of those causes appeared to be the
  • preference given, by the institutions of Mr. Colbert, to the industry of
  • the towns above that of the country.
  • If the rod be bent too much one way, says the proverb, in order to make it
  • straight, you must bend it as much the other. The French philosophers, who
  • have proposed the system which represents agriculture as the sole source
  • of the revenue and wealth of every country, seem to have adopted this
  • proverbial maxim; and, as in the plan of Mr. Colbert, the industry of the
  • towns was certainly overvalued in comparison with that of the country, so
  • in their system it seems to be as certainly under-valued.
  • The different orders of people, who have ever been supposed to contribute
  • in any respect towards the annual produce of the land and labour of the
  • country, they divide into three classes. The first is the class of the
  • proprietors of land. The second is the class of the cultivators, of
  • farmers and country labourers, whom they honour with the peculiar
  • appellation of the productive class. The third is the class of artificers,
  • manufacturers, and merchants, whom they endeavour to degrade by the
  • humiliating appellation of the barren or unproductive class.
  • The class of proprietors contributes to the annual produce, by the expense
  • which they may occasionally lay out upon the improvement of the land, upon
  • the buildings, drains, inclosures, and other ameliorations, which they may
  • either make or maintain upon it, and by means of which the cultivators are
  • enabled, with the same capital, to raise a greater produce, and
  • consequently to pay a greater rent. This advanced rent may be considered
  • as the interest or profit due to the proprietor, upon the expense or
  • capital which he thus employs in the improvement of his land. Such
  • expenses are in this system called ground expenses (depenses foncieres).
  • The cultivators or farmers contribute to the annual produce, by what are
  • in this system called the original and annual expenses (depenses
  • primitives, et depenses annuelles), which they lay out upon the
  • cultivation of the land. The original expenses consist in the instruments
  • of husbandry, in the stock of cattle, in the seed, and in the maintenance
  • of the farmer’s family, servants, and cattle, during at least a great part
  • of the first year of his occupancy, or till he can receive some return
  • from the land. The annual expenses consist in the seed, in the wear and
  • tear of instruments of husbandry, and in the annual maintenance of the
  • farmer’s servants and cattle, and of his family too, so far as any part of
  • them can be considered as servants employed in cultivation. That part of
  • the produce of the land which remains to him after paying the rent, ought
  • to be sufficient, first, to replace to him, within a reasonable time, at
  • least during the term of his occupancy, the whole of his original
  • expenses, together with the ordinary profits of stock; and, secondly, to
  • replace to him annually the whole of his annual expenses, together
  • likewise with the ordinary profits of stock. Those two sorts of expenses
  • are two capitals which the farmer employs in cultivation; and unless they
  • are regularly restored to him, together with a reasonable profit, he
  • cannot carry on his employment upon a level with other employments; but,
  • from a regard to his own interest, must desert it as soon as possible, and
  • seek some other. That part of the produce of the land which is thus
  • necessary for enabling the farmer to continue his business, ought to be
  • considered as a fund sacred to cultivation, which, if the landlord
  • violates, he necessarily reduces the produce of his own land, and, in a
  • few years, not only disables the farmer from paying this racked rent, but
  • from paying the reasonable rent which he might otherwise have got for his
  • land. The rent which properly belongs to the landlord, is no more than the
  • neat produce which remains after paying, in the completest manner, all the
  • necessary expenses which must be previously laid out, in order to raise
  • the gross or the whole produce. It is because the labour of the
  • cultivators, over and above paying completely all those necessary
  • expenses, affords a neat produce of this kind, that this class of people
  • are in this system peculiarly distinguished by the honourable appellation
  • of the productive class. Their original and annual expenses are for the
  • same reason called, In this system, productive expenses, because, over and
  • above replacing their own value, they occasion the annual reproduction of
  • this neat produce.
  • The ground expenses, as they are called, or what the landlord lays out
  • upon the improvement of his land, are, in this system, too, honoured with
  • the appellation of productive expenses. Till the whole of those expenses,
  • together with the ordinary profits of stock, have been completely repaid
  • to him by the advanced rent which he gets from his land, that advanced
  • rent ought to be regarded as sacred and inviolable, both by the church and
  • by the king; ought to be subject neither to tithe nor to taxation. If it
  • is otherwise, by discouraging the improvement of land, the church
  • discourages the future increase of her own tithes, and the king the future
  • increase of his own taxes. As in a well ordered state of things,
  • therefore, those ground expenses, over and above reproducing in the
  • completest manner their own value, occasion likewise, after a certain
  • time, a reproduction of a neat produce, they are in this system considered
  • as productive expenses.
  • The ground expenses of the landlord, however, together with the original
  • and the annual expenses of the farmer, are the only three sorts of
  • expenses which in this system are considered as productive. All other
  • expenses, and all other orders of people, even those who, in the common
  • apprehensions of men, are regarded as the most productive, are, in this
  • account of things, represented as altogether barren and unproductive.
  • Artificers and manufacturers, in particular, whose industry, in the common
  • apprehensions of men, increases so much the value of the rude produce of
  • land, are in this system represented as a class of people altogether
  • barren and unproductive. Their labour, it is said, replaces only the stock
  • which employs them, together with its ordinary profits. That stock
  • consists in the materials, tools, and wages, advanced to them by their
  • employer; and is the fund destined for their employment and maintenance.
  • Its profits are the fund destined for the maintenance of their employer.
  • Their employer, as he advances to them the stock of materials, tools, and
  • wages, necessary for their employment, so he advances to himself what is
  • necessary for his own maintenance; and this maintenance he generally
  • proportions to the profit which he expects to make by the price of their
  • work. Unless its price repays to him the maintenance which he advances to
  • himself, as well as the materials, tools, and wages, which he advances to
  • his workmen, it evidently does not repay to him the whole expense which he
  • lays out upon it. The profits of manufacturing stock, therefore, are not,
  • like the rent of land, a neat produce which remains after completely
  • repaying the whole expense which must be laid out in order to obtain them.
  • The stock of the farmer yields him a profit, as well as that of the master
  • manufacturer; and it yields a rent likewise to another person, which that
  • of the master manufacturer does not. The expense, therefore, laid out in
  • employing and maintaining artificers and manufacturers, does no more than
  • continue, if one may say so, the existence of its own value, and does not
  • produce any new value. It is, therefore, altogether a barren and
  • unproductive expense. The expense, on the contrary, laid out in employing
  • farmers and country labourers, over and above continuing the existence of
  • its own value, produces a new value the rent of the landlord. It is,
  • therefore, a productive expense.
  • Mercantile stock is equally barren and unproductive with manufacturing
  • stock. It only continues the existence of its own value, without producing
  • any new value. Its profits are only the repayment of the maintenance which
  • its employer advances to himself during the time that he employs it, or
  • till he receives the returns of it. They are only the repayment of a part
  • of the expense which must be laid out in employing it.
  • The labour of artificers and manufacturers never adds any thing to the
  • value of the whole annual amount of the rude produce of the land. It adds,
  • indeed, greatly to the value of some particular parts of it. But the
  • consumption which, in the mean time, it occasions of other parts, is
  • precisely equal to the value which it adds to those parts; so that the
  • value of the whole amount is not, at any one moment of time, in the least
  • augmented by it. The person who works the lace of a pair of fine ruffles
  • for example, will sometimes raise the value of, perhaps, a pennyworth of
  • flax to £30 sterling. But though, at first sight, he appears thereby to
  • multiply the value of a part of the rude produce about seven thousand and
  • two hundred times, he in reality adds nothing to the value of the whole
  • annual amount of the rude produce. The working of that lace costs him,
  • perhaps, two years labour. The £30 which he gets for it when it is
  • finished, is no more than the repayment of the subsistence which he
  • advances to himself during the two years that he is employed about it. The
  • value which, by every day’s, month’s, or year’s labour, he adds to the
  • flax, does no more than replace the value of his own consumption during
  • that day, month, or year. At no moment of time, therefore, does he add any
  • thing to the value of the whole annual amount of the rude produce of the
  • land: the portion of that produce which he is continually consuming, being
  • always equal to the value which he is continually producing. The extreme
  • poverty of the greater part of the persons employed in this expensive,
  • though trifling manufacture, may satisfy us that the price of their work
  • does not, in ordinary cases, exceed the value of their subsistence. It is
  • otherwise with the work of farmers and country labourers. The rent of the
  • landlord is a value which, in ordinary cases, it is continually producing
  • over and above replacing, in the most complete manner, the whole
  • consumption, the whole expense laid out upon the employment and
  • maintenance both of the workmen and of their employer.
  • Artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, can augment the revenue and
  • wealth of their society by parsimony only; or, as it is expressed in this
  • system, by privation, that is, by depriving themselves of a part of the
  • funds destined for their own subsistence. They annually reproduce nothing
  • but those funds. Unless, therefore, they annually save some part of them,
  • unless they annually deprive themselves of the enjoyment of some part of
  • them, the revenue and wealth of their society can never be, in the
  • smallest degree, augmented by means of their industry. Farmers and country
  • labourers, on the contrary, may enjoy completely the whole funds destined
  • for their own subsistence, and yet augment, at the same time, the revenue
  • and wealth of their society. Over and above what is destined for their own
  • subsistence, their industry annually affords a neat produce, of which the
  • augmentation necessarily augments the revenue and wealth of their society.
  • Nations, therefore, which, like France or England, consist in a great
  • measure, of proprietors and cultivators, can be enriched by industry and
  • enjoyment. Nations, on the contrary, which, like Holland and Hamburgh, are
  • composed chiefly of merchants, artificers, and manufacturers, can grow
  • rich only through parsimony and privation. As the interest of nations so
  • differently circumstanced is very different, so is likewise the common
  • character of the people. In those of the former kind, liberality,
  • frankness, and good fellowship, naturally make a part of their common
  • character; in the latter, narrowness, meanness, and a selfish disposition,
  • averse to all social pleasure and enjoyment.
  • The unproductive class, that of merchants, artificers, and manufacturers,
  • is maintained and employed altogether at the expense of the two other
  • classes, of that of proprietors, and of that of cultivators. They furnish
  • it both with the materials of its work, and with the fund of its
  • subsistence, with the corn and cattle which it consumes while it is
  • employed about that work. The proprietors and cultivators finally pay both
  • the wages of all the workmen of the unproductive class, and the profits of
  • all their employers. Those workmen and their employers are properly the
  • servants of the proprietors and cultivators. They are only servants who
  • work without doors, as menial servants work within. Both the one and the
  • other, however, are equally maintained at the expense of the same masters.
  • The labour of both is equally unproductive. It adds nothing to the value
  • of the sum total of the rude produce of the land. Instead of increasing
  • the value of that sum total, it is a charge and expense which must be paid
  • out of it.
  • The unproductive class, however, is not only useful, but greatly useful,
  • to the other two classes. By means of the industry of merchants,
  • artificers, and manufacturers, the proprietors and cultivators can
  • purchase both the foreign goods and the manufactured produce of their own
  • country, which they have occasion for, with the produce of a much smaller
  • quantity of their own labour, than what they would be obliged to employ,
  • if they were to attempt, in an awkward and unskilful manner, either to
  • import the one, or to make the other, for their own use. By means of the
  • unproductive class, the cultivators are delivered from many cares, which
  • would otherwise distract their attention from the cultivation of land. The
  • superiority of produce, which in consequence of this undivided attention,
  • they are enabled to raise, is fully sufficient to pay the whole expense
  • which the maintenance and employment of the unproductive class costs
  • either the proprietors or themselves. The industry of merchants,
  • artificers, and manufacturers, though in its own nature altogether
  • unproductive, yet contributes in this manner indirectly to increase the
  • produce of the land. It increases the productive powers of productive
  • labour, by leaving it at liberty to confine itself to its proper
  • employment, the cultivation of land; and the plough goes frequently the
  • easier and the better, by means of the labour of the man whose business is
  • most remote from the plough.
  • It can never be the interest of the proprietors and cultivators, to
  • restrain or to discourage, in any respect, the industry of merchants,
  • artificers, and manufacturers. The greater the liberty which this
  • unproductive class enjoys, the greater will be the competition in all the
  • different trades which compose it, and the cheaper will the other two
  • classes be supplied, both with foreign goods and with the manufactured
  • produce of their own country.
  • It can never be the interest of the unproductive class to oppress the
  • other two classes. It is the surplus produce of the land, or what remains
  • after deducting the maintenance, first of the cultivators, and afterwards
  • of the proprietors, that maintains and employs the unproductive class. The
  • greater this surplus, the greater must likewise be the maintenance and
  • employment of that class. The establishment of perfect justice, of perfect
  • liberty, and of perfect equality, is the very simple secret which most
  • effectually secures the highest degree of prosperity to all the three
  • classes.
  • The merchants, artificers, and manufacturers of those mercantile states,
  • which, like Holland and Hamburgh, consist chiefly of this unproductive
  • class, are in the same manner maintained and employed altogether at the
  • expense of the proprietors and cultivators of land. The only difference
  • is, that those proprietors and cultivators are, the greater part of them,
  • placed at a most inconvenient distance from the merchants, artificers, and
  • manufacturers, whom they supply with the materials of their work and the
  • fund of their subsistence; are the inhabitants of other countries, and the
  • subjects of other governments.
  • Such mercantile states, however, are not only useful, but greatly useful,
  • to the inhabitants of those other countries. They fill up, in some
  • measure, a very important void; and supply the place of the merchants,
  • artificers, and manufacturers, whom the inhabitants of those countries
  • ought to find at home, but whom, from some defect in their policy, they do
  • not find at home.
  • It can never be the interest of those landed nations, if I may call them
  • so, to discourage or distress the industry of such mercantile states, by
  • imposing high duties upon their trade, or upon the commodities which they
  • furnish. Such duties, by rendering those commodities dearer, could serve
  • only to sink the real value of the surplus produce of their own land, with
  • which, or, what comes to the same thing, with the price of which those
  • commodities are purchased. Such duties could only serve to discourage the
  • increase of that surplus produce, and consequently the improvement and
  • cultivation of their own land. The most effectual expedient, on the
  • contrary, for raising the value of that surplus produce, for encouraging
  • its increase, and consequently the improvement and cultivation of their
  • own land, would be to allow the most perfect freedom to the trade of all
  • such mercantile nations.
  • This perfect freedom of trade would even be the most effectual expedient
  • for supplying them, in due time, with all the artificers, manufacturers,
  • and merchants, whom they wanted at home; and for filling up, in the
  • properest and most advantageous manner, that very important void which
  • they felt there.
  • The continual increase of the surplus produce of their land would, in due
  • time, create a greater capital than what would be employed with the
  • ordinary rate of profit in the improvement and cultivation of land; and
  • the surplus part of it would naturally turn itself to the employment of
  • artificers and manufacturers, at home. But these artificers and
  • manufacturers, finding at home both the materials of their work and the
  • fund of their subsistence, might immediately, even with much less art and
  • skill be able to work as cheap as the little artificers and manufacturers
  • of such mercantile states, who had both to bring from a greater distance.
  • Even though, from want of art and skill, they might not for some time be
  • able to work as cheap, yet, finding a market at home, they might be able
  • to sell their work there as cheap as that of the artificers and
  • manufacturers of such mercantile states, which could not be brought to
  • that market but from so great a distance; and as their art and skill
  • improved, they would soon be able to sell it cheaper. The artificers and
  • manufacturers of such mercantile states, therefore, would immediately be
  • rivalled in the market of those landed nations, and soon after undersold
  • and justled out of it altogether. The cheapness of the manufactures of
  • those landed nations, in consequence of the gradual improvements of art
  • and skill, would, in due time, extend their sale beyond the home market,
  • and carry them to many foreign markets, from which they would, in the same
  • manner, gradually justle out many of the manufacturers of such mercantile
  • nations.
  • This continual increase, both of the rude and manufactured produce of
  • those landed nations, would, in due time, create a greater capital than
  • could, with the ordinary rate of profit, be employed either in agriculture
  • or in manufactures. The surplus of this capital would naturally turn
  • itself to foreign trade and be employed in exporting, to foreign
  • countries, such parts of the rude and manufactured produce of its own
  • country, as exceeded the demand of the home market. In the exportation of
  • the produce of their own country, the merchants of a landed nation would
  • have an advantage of the same kind over those of mercantile nations, which
  • its artificers and manufacturers had over the artificers and manufacturers
  • of such nations; the advantage of finding at home that cargo, and those
  • stores and provisions, which the others were obliged to seek for at a
  • distance. With inferior art and skill in navigation, therefore, they would
  • be able to sell that cargo as cheap in foreign markets as the merchants of
  • such mercantile nations; and with equal art and skill they would be able
  • to sell it cheaper. They would soon, therefore, rival those mercantile
  • nations in this branch of foreign trade, and, in due time, would justle
  • them out of it altogether.
  • According to this liberal and generous system, therefore, the most
  • advantageous method in which a landed nation can raise up artificers,
  • manufacturers, and merchants of its own, is to grant the most perfect
  • freedom of trade to the artificers, manufacturers, and merchants of all
  • other nations. It thereby raises the value of the surplus produce of its
  • own land, of which the continual increase gradually establishes a fund,
  • which, in due time, necessarily raises up all the artificers,
  • manufacturers, and merchants, whom it has occasion for.
  • When a landed nation on the contrary, oppresses, either by high duties or
  • by prohibitions, the trade of foreign nations, it necessarily hurts its
  • own interest in two different ways. First, by raising the price of all
  • foreign goods, and of all sorts of manufactures, it necessarily sinks the
  • real value of the surplus produce of its own land, with which, or, what
  • comes to the same thing, with the price of which, it purchases those
  • foreign goods and manufactures. Secondly, by giving a sort of monopoly of
  • the home market to its own merchants, artificers, and manufacturers, it
  • raises the rate of mercantile and manufacturing profit, in proportion to
  • that of agricultural profit; and, consequently, either draws from
  • agriculture a part of the capital which had before been employed in it, or
  • hinders from going to it a part of what would otherwise have gone to it.
  • This policy, therefore, discourages agriculture in two different ways;
  • first, by sinking the real value of its produce, and thereby lowering the
  • rate of its profits; and, secondly, by raising the rate of profit in all
  • other employments. Agriculture is rendered less advantageous, and trade
  • and manufactures more advantageous, than they otherwise would be; and
  • every man is tempted by his own interest to turn, as much as he can, both
  • his capital and his industry from the former to the latter employments.
  • Though, by this oppressive policy, a landed nation should be able to raise
  • up artificers, manufacturers, and merchants of its own, somewhat sooner
  • than it could do by the freedom of trade; a matter, however, which is not
  • a little doubtful; yet it would raise them up, if one may say so,
  • prematurely, and before it was perfectly ripe for them. By raising up too
  • hastily one species of industry, it would depress another more valuable
  • species of industry. By raising up too hastily a species of industry which
  • duly replaces the stock which employs it, together with the ordinary
  • profit, it would depress a species of industry which, over and above
  • replacing that stock, with its profit, affords likewise a neat produce, a
  • free rent to the landlord. It would depress productive labour, by
  • encouraging too hastily that labour which is altogether barren and
  • unproductive.
  • In what manner, according to this system, the sum total of the annual
  • produce of the land is distributed among the three classes above
  • mentioned, and in what manner the labour of the unproductive class does no
  • more than replace the value of its own consumption, without increasing in
  • any respect the value of that sum total, is represented by Mr Quesnai, the
  • very ingenious and profound author of this system, in some arithmetical
  • formularies. The first of these formularies, which, by way of eminence, he
  • peculiarly distinguishes by the name of the Economical Table, represents
  • the manner in which he supposes this distribution takes place, in a state
  • of the most perfect liberty, and, therefore, of the highest prosperity; in
  • a state where the annual produce is such as to afford the greatest
  • possible neat produce, and where each class enjoys its proper share of the
  • whole annual produce. Some subsequent formularies represent the manner in
  • which he supposes this distribution is made in different states of
  • restraint and regulation; in which, either the class of proprietors, or
  • the barren and unproductive class, is more favoured than the class of
  • cultivators; and in which either the one or the other encroaches, more or
  • less, upon the share which ought properly to belong to this productive
  • class. Every such encroachment, every violation of that natural
  • distribution, which the most perfect liberty would establish, must,
  • according to this system, necessarily degrade, more or less, from one year
  • to another, the value and sum total of the annual produce, and must
  • necessarily occasion a gradual declension in the real wealth and revenue
  • of the society; a declension, of which the progress must be quicker or
  • slower, according to the degree of this encroachment, according as that
  • natural distribution, which the most perfect liberty would establish, is
  • more or less violated. Those subsequent formularies represent the
  • different degrees of declension which, according to this system,
  • correspond to the different degrees in which this natural distribution of
  • things is violated.
  • Some speculative physicians seem to have imagined that the health of the
  • human body could be preserved only by a certain precise regimen of diet
  • and exercise, of which every, the smallest violation, necessarily
  • occasioned some degree of disease or disorder proportionate to the degree
  • of the violation. Experience, however, would seem to shew, that the human
  • body frequently preserves, to all appearance at least, the most perfect
  • state of health under a vast variety of different regimens; even under
  • some which are generally believed to be very far from being perfectly
  • wholesome. But the healthful state of the human body, it would seem,
  • contains in itself some unknown principle of preservation, capable either
  • of preventing or of correcting, in many respects, the bad effects even of
  • a very faulty regimen. Mr Quesnai, who was himself a physician, and a very
  • speculative physician, seems to have entertained a notion of the same kind
  • concerning the political body, and to have imagined that it would thrive
  • and prosper only under a certain precise regimen, the exact regimen of
  • perfect liberty and perfect justice. He seems not to have considered, that
  • in the political body, the natural effort which every man is continually
  • making to better his own condition, is a principle of preservation capable
  • of preventing and correcting, in many respects, the bad effects of a
  • political economy, in some degree both partial and oppressive. Such a
  • political economy, though it no doubt retards more or less, is not always
  • capable of stopping altogether, the natural progress of a nation towards
  • wealth and prosperity, and still less of making it go backwards. If a
  • nation could not prosper without the enjoyment of perfect liberty and
  • perfect justice, there is not in the world a nation which could ever have
  • prospered. In the political body, however, the wisdom of nature has
  • fortunately made ample provision for remedying many of the bad effects of
  • the folly and injustice of man; it the same manner as it has done in the
  • natural body, for remedying those of his sloth and intemperance.
  • The capital error of this system, however, seems to lie in its
  • representing the class of artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, as
  • altogether barren and unproductive. The following observations may serve
  • to shew the impropriety of this representation:—
  • First, this class, it is acknowledged, reproduces annually the value of
  • its own annual consmnption, and continues, at least, the existence of the
  • stock or capital which maintains and employs it. But, upon this account
  • alone, the denomination of barren or unproductive should seem to be very
  • improperly applied to it. We should not call a marriage barren or
  • unproductive, though it produced only a son and a daughter, to replace the
  • father and mother, and though it did not increase the number of the human
  • species, but only continued it as it was before. Farmers and country
  • labourers, indeed, over and above the stock which maintains and employs
  • them, reproduce annually a neat produce, a free rent to the landlord. As a
  • marriage which affords three children is certainly more productive than
  • one which affords only two, so the labour of farmers and country labourers
  • is certainly more productive than that of merchants, artificers, and
  • manufacturers. The superior produce of the one class, however, does not,
  • render the other barren or unproductive.
  • Secondly, it seems, on this account, altogether improper to consider
  • artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, in the same light as menial
  • servants. The labour of menial servants does not continue the existence of
  • the fund which maintains and employs them. Their maintenance and
  • employment is altogether at the expense of their masters, and the work
  • which they perform is not of a nature to repay that expense. That work
  • consists in services which perish generally in the very instant of their
  • performance, and does not fix or realize itself in any vendible commodity,
  • which can replace the value of their wages and maintenance. The labour, on
  • the contrary, of artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, naturally does
  • fix and realize itself in some such vendible commodity. It is upon this
  • account that, in the chapter in which I treat of productive and
  • unproductive labour, I have classed artificers, manufacturers, and
  • merchants among the productive labourers, and menial servants among the
  • barren or unproductive.
  • Thirdly, it seems, upon every supposition, improper to say, that the
  • labour of artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, does not increase the
  • real revenue of the society. Though we should suppose, for example, as it
  • seems to be supposed in this system, that the value of the daily, monthly,
  • and yearly consumption of this class was exactly equal to that of its
  • daily, monthly, and yearly production; yet it would not from thence
  • follow, that its labour added nothing to the real revenue, to the real
  • value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the society. An
  • artificer, for example, who, in the first six months after harvest,
  • executes ten pounds worth of work, though he should, in the same time,
  • consume ten pounds worth of corn and other necessaries, yet really adds
  • the value of ten pounds to the annual produce of the land and labour of
  • the society. While he has been consuming a half-yearly revenue of ten
  • pounds worth of corn and other necessaries, he has produced an equal value
  • of work, capable of purchasing, either to himself, or to some other
  • person, an equal half-yearly revenue. The value, therefore, of what has
  • been consumed and produced during these six months, is equal, not to ten,
  • but to twenty pounds. It is possible, indeed, that no more than ten pounds
  • worth of this value may ever have existed at any one moment of time. But
  • if the ten pounds worth of corn and other necessaries which were consumed
  • by the artificer, had been consumed by a soldier, or by a menial servant,
  • the value of that part of the annual produce which existed at the end of
  • the six months, would have been ten pounds less than it actually is in
  • consequence of the labour of the artificer. Though the value of what the
  • artificer produces, therefore, should not, at any one moment of time, be
  • supposed greater than the value he consumes, yet, at every moment of time,
  • the actually existing value of goods in the market is, in consequence of
  • what he produces, greater than it otherwise would be.
  • When the patrons of this system assert, that the consumption of
  • artificers, manufacturers, and merchants, is equal to the value of what
  • they produce, they probably mean no more than that their revenue, or the
  • fund destined for their consumption, is equal to it. But if they had
  • expressed themselves more accurately, and only asserted, that the revenue
  • of this class was equal to the value of what they produced, it might
  • readily have occurred to the reader, that what would naturally be saved
  • out of this revenue, must necessarily increase more or less the real
  • wealth of the society. In order, therefore, to make out something like an
  • argument, it was necessary that they should express themselves as they
  • have done; and this argument, even supposing things actually were as it
  • seems to presume them to be, turns out to be a very inconclusive one.
  • Fourthly, farmers and country labourers can no more augment, without
  • parsimony, the real revenue, the annual produce of the land and labour of
  • their society, than artificers, manufacturers, and merchants. The annual
  • produce of the land and labour of any society can be augmented only in two
  • ways; either, first, by some improvement in the productive powers of the
  • useful labour actually maintained within it; or, secondly, by some
  • increase in the quantity of that labour.
  • The improvement in the productive powers of useful labour depends, first,
  • upon the improvement in the ability of the workman; and, secondly, upon
  • that of the machinery with which he works. But the labour of artificers
  • and manufacturers, as it is capable of being more subdivided, and the
  • labour of each workman reduced to a greater simplicity of operation, than
  • that of farmers and country labourers; so it is likewise capable of both
  • these sorts of improvement in a much higher degree {See book i chap. 1.}
  • In this respect, therefore, the class of cultivators can have no sort of
  • advantage over that of artificers and manufacturers.
  • The increase in the quantity of useful labour actually employed within any
  • society must depend altogether upon the increase of the capital which
  • employs it; and the increase of that capital, again, must be exactly equal
  • to the amount of the savings from the revenue, either of the particular
  • persons who manage and direct the employment of that capital, or of some
  • other persons, who lend it to them. If merchants, artificers, and
  • manufacturers are, as this system seems to suppose, naturally more
  • inclined to parsimony and saving than proprietors and cultivators, they
  • are, so far, more likely to augment the quantity of useful labour employed
  • within their society, and consequently to increase its real revenue, the
  • annual produce of its land and labour.
  • Fifthly and lastly, though the revenue of the inhabitants of every country
  • was supposed to consist altogether, as this system seems to suppose, in
  • the quantity of subsistence which their industry could procure to them;
  • yet, even upon this supposition, the revenue of a trading and
  • manufacturing country must, other things being equal, always be much
  • greater than that of one without trade or manufactures. By means of trade
  • and manufactures, a greater quantity of subsistence can be annually
  • imported into a particular country, than what its own lands, in the actual
  • state of their cultivation, could afford. The inhabitants of a town,
  • though they frequently possess no lands of their own, yet draw to
  • themselves, by their industry, such a quantity of the rude produce of the
  • lands of other people, as supplies them, not only with the materials of
  • their work, but with the fund of their subsistence. What a town always is
  • with regard to the country in its neighbourhood, one independent state or
  • country may frequently be with regard to other independent states or
  • countries. It is thus that Holland draws a great part of its subsistence
  • from other countries; live cattle from Holstein and Jutland, and corn from
  • almost all the different countries of Europe. A small quantity of
  • manufactured produce, purchases a great quantity of rude produce. A
  • trading and manufacturing country, therefore, naturally purchases, with a
  • small part of its manufactured produce, a great part of the rude produce
  • of other countries; while, on the contrary, a country without trade and
  • manufactures is generally obliged to purchase, at the expense of a great
  • part of its rude produce, a very small part of the manufactured produce of
  • other countries. The one exports what can subsist and accommodate but a
  • very few, and imports the subsistence and accommodation of a great number.
  • The other exports the accommodation and subsistence of a great number, and
  • imports that of a very few only. The inhabitants of the one must always
  • enjoy a much greater quantity of subsistence than what their own lands, in
  • the actual state of their cultivation, could afford. The inhabitants of
  • the other must always enjoy a much smaller quantity.
  • This system, however, with all its imperfections, is perhaps the nearest
  • approximation to the truth that has yet been published upon the subject of
  • political economy; and is upon that account, well worth the consideration
  • of every man who wishes to examine with attention the principles of that
  • very important science. Though in representing the labour which is
  • employed upon land as the only productive labour, the notions which it
  • inculcates are, perhaps, too narrow and confined; yet in representing the
  • wealth of nations as consisting, not in the unconsumable riches of money,
  • but in the consumable goods annually reproduced by the labour of the
  • society, and in representing perfect liberty as the only effectual
  • expedient for rendering this annual reproduction the greatest possible,
  • its doctrine seems to be in every respect as just as it is generous and
  • liberal. Its followers are very numerous; and as men are fond of
  • paradoxes, and of appearing to understand what surpasses the
  • comprehensions of ordinary people, the paradox which it maintains,
  • concerning the unproductive nature of manufacturing labour, has not,
  • perhaps, contributed a little to increase the number of its admirers. They
  • have for some years past made a pretty considerable sect, distinguished in
  • the French republic of letters by the name of the Economists. Their works
  • have certainly been of some service to their country; not only by bringing
  • into general discussion, many subjects which had never been well examined
  • before, but by influencing, in some measure, the public administration in
  • favour of agriculture. It has been in consequence of their
  • representations, accordingly, that the agriculture of France has been
  • delivered from several of the oppressions which it before laboured under.
  • The term, during which such a lease can be granted, as will be valid
  • against every future purchaser or proprietor of the land, has been
  • prolonged from nine to twenty-seven years. The ancient provincial
  • restraints upon the transportation of corn from one province of the
  • kingdom to another, have been entirely taken away; and the liberty of
  • exporting it to all foreign countries, has been established as the common
  • law of the kingdom in all ordinary cases. This sect, in their works, which
  • are very numerous, and which treat not only of what is properly called
  • Political Economy, or of the nature and causes or the wealth of nations,
  • but of every other branch of the system of civil government, all follow
  • implicitly, and without any sensible variation, the doctrine of Mr.
  • Qttesnai. There is, upon this account, little variety in the greater part
  • of their works. The most distinct and best connected account of this
  • doctrine is to be found in a little book written by Mr. Mercier de la
  • Riviere, some time intendant of Martinico, entitled, The natural and
  • essential Order of Political Societies. The admiration of this whole sect
  • for their master, who was himself a man of the greatest modesty and
  • simplicity, is not inferior to that of any of the ancient philosophers for
  • the founders of their respective systems. ‘There have been since the world
  • began,’ says a very diligent and respectable author, the Marquis de
  • Mirabeau, ‘three great inventions which have principally given stability
  • to political societies, independent of many other inventions which have
  • enriched and adorned them. The first is the invention of writing, which
  • alone gives human nature the power of transmitting, without alteration,
  • its laws, its contracts, its annals, and its discoveries. The second is
  • the invention of money, which binds together all the relations between
  • civilized societies. The third is the economical table, the result of the
  • other two, which completes them both by perfecting their object; the great
  • discovery of our age, but of which our posterity will reap the benefit.’
  • As the political economy of the nations of modern Europe has been more
  • favourable to manufactures and foreign trade, the industry of the towns,
  • than to agriculture, the industry of the country; so that of other nations
  • has followed a different plan, and has been more favourable to agriculture
  • than to manufactures and foreign trade.
  • The policy of China favours agriculture more than all other employments.
  • In China, the condition of a labourer is said to be as much superior to
  • that of an artificer, as in most parts of Europe that of an artificer is
  • to that of a labourer. In China, the great ambition of every man is to get
  • possession of a little bit of land, either in property or in lease; and
  • leases are there said to be granted upon very moderate terms, and to be
  • sufficiently secured to the lessees. The Chinese have little respect for
  • foreign trade. Your beggarly commerce! was the language in which the
  • mandarins of Pekin used to talk to Mr. De Lange, the Russian envoy,
  • concerning it {See the Journal of Mr. De Lange, in Bell’s Travels, vol.
  • ii. p. 258, 276, 293.}. Except with Japan, the Chinese carry on,
  • themselves, and in their own bottoms, little or no foreign trade; and it
  • is only into one or two ports of their kingdom that they even admit the
  • ships of foreign nations. Foreign trade, therefore, is, in China, every
  • way confined within a much narrower circle than that to which it would
  • naturally extend itself, if more freedom was allowed to it, either in
  • their own ships, or in those of foreign nations.
  • Manufactures, as in a small bulk they frequently contain a great value,
  • and can upon that account be transported at less expense from one country
  • to another than most parts of rude produce, are, in almost all countries,
  • the principal support of foreign trade. In countries, besides, less
  • extensive, and less favourably circumstanced for inferior commerce than
  • China, they generally require the support of foreign trade. Without an
  • extensive foreign market, they could not well flourish, either in
  • countries so moderately extensive as to afford but a narrow home market,
  • or in countries where the communication between one province and another
  • was so difficult, as to render it impossible for the goods of any
  • particular place to enjoy the whole of that home market which the country
  • could afford. The perfection of manufacturing industry, it must be
  • remembered, depends altogether upon the division of labour; and the degree
  • to which the division of labour can be introduced into any manufacture, is
  • necessarily regulated, it has already been shewn, by the extent of the
  • market. But the great extent of the empire of China, the vast multitude of
  • its inhabitants, the variety of climate, and consequently of productions
  • in its different provinces, and the easy communication by means of
  • water-carriage between the greater part of them, render the home market of
  • that country of so great extent, as to be alone sufficient to support very
  • great manufactures, and to admit of very considerable subdivisions of
  • labour. The home market of China is, perhaps, in extent, not much inferior
  • to the market of all the different countries of Europe put together. A
  • more extensive foreign trade, however, which to this great home market
  • added the foreign market of all the rest of the world, especially if any
  • considerable part of this trade was carried on in Chinese ships, could
  • scarce fail to increase very much the manufactures of China, and to
  • improve very much the productive powers of its manufacturing industry. By
  • a more extensive navigation, the Chinese would naturally learn the art of
  • using and constructing, themselves, all the different machines made use of
  • in other countries, as well as the other improvements of art and industry
  • which are practised in all the different parts of the world. Upon their
  • present plan, they have little opportunity of improving themselves by the
  • example of any other nation, except that of the Japanese.
  • The policy of ancient Egypt, too, and that of the Gentoo government of
  • Indostan, seem to have favoured agriculture more than all other
  • employments.
  • Both in ancient Egypt and Indostan, the whole body of the people was
  • divided into different casts or tribes each of which was confined, from
  • father to son, to a particular employment, or class of employments. The
  • son of a priest was necessarily a priest; the son of a soldier, a soldier;
  • the son of a labourer, a labourer; the son of a weaver, a weaver; the son
  • of a tailor, a tailor, etc. In both countries, the cast of the priests
  • holds the highest rank, and that of the soldiers the next; and in both
  • countries the cast of the farmers and labourers was superior to the casts
  • of merchants and manufacturers.
  • The government of both countries was particularly attentive to the
  • interest of agriculture. The works constructed by the ancient sovereigns
  • of Egypt, for the proper distribution of the waters of the Nile, were
  • famous in antiquity, and the ruined remains of some of them are still the
  • admiration of travellers. Those of the same kind which were constructed by
  • the ancient sovereigns of Indostan, for the proper distribution of the
  • waters of the Ganges, as well as of many other rivers, though they have
  • been less celebrated, seem to have been equally great. Both countries,
  • accordingly, though subject occasionally to dearths, have been famous for
  • their great fertility. Though both were extremely populous, yet, in years
  • of moderate plenty, they were both able to export great quantities of
  • grain to their neighbours.
  • The ancient Egyptians had a superstitious aversion to the sea; and as the
  • Gentoo religion does not permit its followers to light a fire, nor
  • consequently to dress any victuals, upon the water, it, in effect,
  • prohibits them from all distant sea voyages. Both the Egyptians and
  • Indians must have depended almost altogether upon the navigation of other
  • nations for the exportation of their surplus produce; and this dependency,
  • as it must have confined the market, so it must have discouraged the
  • increase of this surplus produce. It must have discouraged, too, the
  • increase of the manufactured produce, more than that of the rude produce.
  • Manufactures require a much more extensive market than the most important
  • parts of the rude produce of the land. A single shoemaker will make more
  • than 300 pairs of shoes in the year; and his own family will not, perhaps,
  • wear out six pairs. Unless, therefore, he has the custom of, at least, 50
  • such families as his own, he cannot dispose of the whole product of his
  • own labour. The most numerous class of artificers will seldom, in a large
  • country, make more than one in 50, or one in a 100, of the whole number of
  • families contained in it. But in such large countries, as France and
  • England, the number of people employed in agriculture has, by some authors
  • been computed at a half, by others at a third and by no author that I know
  • of, at less that a fifth of the whole inhabitants of the country. But as
  • the produce of the agriculture of both France and England is, the far
  • greater part of it, consumed at home, each person employed in it must,
  • according to these computations, require little more than the custom of
  • one, two, or, at most, of four such families as his own, in order to
  • dispose of the whole produce of his own labour. Agriculture, therefore,
  • can support itself under the discouragement of a confined market much
  • better than manufactures. In both ancient Egypt and Indostan, indeed, the
  • confinement of the foreign market was in some measure compensated by the
  • conveniency of many inland navigations, which opened, in the most
  • advantageous manner, the whole extent of the home market to every part of
  • the produce of every different district of those countries. The great
  • extent of Indostan, too, rendered the home market of that country very
  • great, and sufficient to support a great variety of manufactures. But the
  • small extent of ancient Egypt, which was never equal to England, must at
  • all times, have rendered the home market of that country too narrow for
  • supporting any great variety of manufactures. Bengal accordingly, the
  • province of Indostan which commonly exports the greatest quantity of rice,
  • has always been more remarkable for the exportation of a great variety of
  • manufactures, than for that of its grain. Ancient Egypt, on the contrary,
  • though it exported some manufactures, fine linen in particular, as well as
  • some other goods, was always most distinguished for its great exportation
  • of grain. It was long the granary of the Roman empire.
  • The sovereigns of China, of ancient Egypt, and of the different kingdoms
  • into which Indostan has, at different times, been divided, have always
  • derived the whole, or by far the most considerable part, of their revenue,
  • from some sort of land tax or land rent. This land tax, or land rent, like
  • the tithe in Europe, consisted in a certain proportion, a fifth, it is
  • said, of the produce of the land, which was either delivered in kind, or
  • paid in money, according to a certain valuation, and which, therefore,
  • varied from year to year, according to all the variations of the produce.
  • It was natural, therefore, that the sovereigns of those countries should
  • be particularly attentive to the interests of agriculture, upon the
  • prosperity or declension of which immediately depended the yearly increase
  • or diminution of their own revenue.
  • The policy of the ancient republics of Greece, and that of Rome, though it
  • honoured agriculture more than manufactures or foreign trade, yet seems
  • rather to have discouraged the latter employments, than to have given any
  • direct or intentional encouragement to the former. In several of the
  • ancient states of Greece, foreign trade was prohibited altogether; and in
  • several others, the employments of artificers and manufacturers were
  • considered as hurtful to the strength and agility of the human body, as
  • rendering it incapable of those habits which their military and gymnastic
  • exercises endeavoured to form in it, and as thereby disqualifying it, more
  • or less, for undergoing the fatigues and encountering the dangers of war.
  • Such occupations were considered as fit only for slaves, and the free
  • citizens of the states were prohibited from exercising them. Even in those
  • states where no such prohibition took place, as in Rome and Athens, the
  • great body of the people were in effect excluded from all the trades which
  • are now commonly exercised by the lower sort of the inhabitants of towns.
  • Such trades were, at Athens and Rome, all occupied by the slaves of the
  • rich, who exercised them for the benefit of their masters, whose wealth,
  • power, and protection, made it almost impossible for a poor freeman to
  • find a market for his work, when it came into competition with that of the
  • slaves of the rich. Slaves, however, are very seldom inventive; and all
  • the most important improvements, either in machinery, or in the
  • arrangement and distribution of work, which facilitate and abridge labour
  • have been the discoveries of freemen. Should a slave propose any
  • improvement of this kind, his master would be very apt to consider the
  • proposal as the suggestion of laziness, and of a desire to save his own
  • labour at the master’s expense. The poor slave, instead of reward would
  • probably meet with much abuse, perhaps with some punishment. In the
  • manufactures carried on by slaves, therefore, more labour must generally
  • have been employed to execute the same quantity of work, than in those
  • carried on by freemen. The work of the farmer must, upon that account,
  • generally have been dearer than that of the latter. The Hungarian mines,
  • it is remarked by Mr. Montesquieu, though not richer, have always been
  • wrought with less expense, and therefore with more profit, than the
  • Turkish mines in their neighbourhood. The Turkish mines are wrought by
  • slaves; and the arms of those slaves are the only machines which the Turks
  • have ever thought of employing. The Hungarian mines are wrought by
  • freemen, who employ a great deal of machinery, by which they facilitate
  • and abridge their own labour. From the very little that is known about the
  • price of manufactures in the times of the Greeks and Romans, it would
  • appear that those of the finer sort were excessively dear. Silk sold for
  • its weight in gold. It was not, indeed, in those times an European
  • manufacture; and as it was all brought from the East Indies, the distance
  • of the carriage may in some measure account for the greatness of the
  • price. The price, however, which a lady, it is said, would sometimes pay
  • for a piece of very fine linen, seems to have been equally extravagant;
  • and as linen was always either an European, or at farthest, an Egyptian
  • manufacture, this high price can be accounted for only by the great
  • expense of the labour which must have been employed about It, and the
  • expense of this labour again could arise from nothing but the awkwardness
  • of the machinery which is made use of. The price of fine woollens, too,
  • though not quite so extravagant, seems, however, to have been much above
  • that of the present times. Some cloths, we are told by Pliny {Plin. 1.
  • ix.c.39.}, dyed in a particular manner, cost a hundred denarii, or
  • £3:6s:8d. the pound weight. Others, dyed in another manner, cost a
  • thousand denarii the pound weight, or £33:6s:8d. The Roman pound, it must
  • be remembered, contained only twelve of our avoirdupois ounces. This high
  • price, indeed, seems to have been principally owing to the dye. But had
  • not the cloths themselves been much dearer than any which are made in the
  • present times, so very expensive a dye would not probably have been
  • bestowed upon them. The disproportion would have been too great between
  • the value of the accessory and that of the principal. The price mentioned
  • by the same author {Plin. 1. viii.c.48.}, of some triclinaria, a sort of
  • woollen pillows or cushions made use of to lean upon as they reclined upon
  • their couches at table, passes all credibility; some of them being said to
  • have cost more than £30,000, others more than £300,000. This high price,
  • too, is not said to have arisen from the dye. In the dress of the people
  • of fashion of both sexes, there seems to have been much less variety, it
  • is observed by Dr. Arbuthnot, in ancient than in modern times; and the
  • very little variety which we find in that of the ancient statues, confirms
  • his observation. He infers from this, that their dress must, upon the
  • whole, have been cheaper than ours; but the conclusion does not seem to
  • follow. When the expense of fashionable dress is very great, the variety
  • must be very small. But when, by the improvements in the productive powers
  • of manufacturing art and industry, the expense of any one dress comes to
  • be very moderate, the variety will naturally be very great. The rich, not
  • being able to distinguish themselves by the expense of any one dress, will
  • naturally endeavour to do so by the multitude and variety of their
  • dresses.
  • The greatest and most important branch of the commerce of every nation, it
  • has already been observed, is that which is carried on between the
  • inhabitants of the town and those of the country. The inhabitants of the
  • town draw from the country the rude produce, which constitutes both the
  • materials of their work and the fund of their subsistence; and they pay
  • for this rude produce, by sending back to the country a certain portion of
  • it manufactured and prepared for immediate use. The trade which is carried
  • on between these two different sets of people, consists ultimately in a
  • certain quantity of rude produce exchanged for a certain quantity of
  • manufactured produce. The dearer the latter, therefore, the cheaper the
  • former; and whatever tends in any country to raise the price of
  • manufactured produce, tends to lower that of the rude produce of the land,
  • and thereby to discourage agriculture. The smaller the quantity of
  • manufactured produce, which any given quantity of rude produce, or, what
  • comes to the same thing, which the price of any given quantity of rude
  • produce, is capable of purchasing, the smaller the exchangeable value of
  • that given quantity of rude produce; the smaller the encouragement which
  • either the landlord has to increase its quantity by improving, or the
  • farmer by cultivating the land. Whatever, besides, tends to diminish in
  • any country the number of artificers and manufacturers, tends to diminish
  • the home market, the most important of all markets, for the rude produce
  • of the land, and thereby still further to discourage agriculture.
  • Those systems, therefore, which preferring agriculture to all other
  • employments, in order to promote it, impose restraints upon manufactures
  • and foreign trade, act contrary to the very end which they propose, and
  • indirectly discourage that very species of industry which they mean to
  • promote. They are so far, perhaps, more inconsistent than even the
  • mercantile system. That system, by encouraging manufactures and foreign
  • trade more than agriculture, turns a certain portion of the capital of the
  • society, from supporting a more advantageous, to support a less
  • advantageous species of industry. But still it really, and in the end,
  • encourages that species of industry which it means to promote. Those
  • agricultural systems, on the contrary, really, and in the end, discourage
  • their own favourite species of industry.
  • It is thus that every system which endeavours, either, by extraordinary
  • encouragements to draw towards a particular species of industry a greater
  • share of the capital of the society than what would naturally go to it,
  • or, by extraordinary restraints, to force from a particular species of
  • industry some share of the capital which would otherwise be employed in
  • it, is, in reality, subversive of the great purpose which it means to
  • promote. It retards, instead of accelerating the progress of the society
  • towards real wealth and greatness; and diminishes, instead of increasing,
  • the real value of the annual produce of its land and labour.
  • All systems, either of preference or of restraint, therefore, being thus
  • completely taken away, the obvious and simple system of natural liberty
  • establishes itself of its own accord. Every man, as long as he does not
  • violate the laws of justice, is left perfectly free to pursue his own
  • interest his own way, and to bring both his industry and capital into
  • competition with those of any other man, or order of men. The sovereign is
  • completely discharged from a duty, in the attempting to perform which he
  • must always be exposed to innumerable delusions, and for the proper
  • performance of which, no human wisdom or knowledge could ever be
  • sufficient; the duty of superintending the industry of private people, and
  • of directing it towards the employments most suitable to the interests of
  • the society. According to the system of natural liberty, the sovereign has
  • only three duties to attend to; three duties of great importance, indeed,
  • but plain and intelligible to common understandings: first, the duty of
  • protecting the society from the violence and invasion of other independent
  • societies; secondly, the duty of protecting, as far as possible, every
  • member of the society from the injustice or oppression of every other
  • member of it, or the duty of establishing an exact administration of
  • justice; and, thirdly, the duty of erecting and maintaining certain public
  • works, and certain public institutions, which it can never be for the
  • interest of any individual, or small number of individuals to erect and
  • maintain; because the profit could never repay the expense to any
  • individual, or small number of individuals, though it may frequently do
  • much more than repay it to a great society.
  • The proper performance of those several duties of the sovereign
  • necessarily supposes a certain expense; and this expense again necessarily
  • requires a certain revenue to support it. In the following book,
  • therefore, I shall endeavour to explain, first, what are the necessary
  • expenses of the sovereign or commonwealth; and which of those expenses
  • ought to be defrayed by the general contribution of the whole society; and
  • which of them, by that of some particular part only, or of some particular
  • members of the society: secondly, what are the different methods in which
  • the whole society may be made to contribute towards defraying the expenses
  • incumbent on the whole society; and what are the principal advantages and
  • inconveniencies of each of those methods: and thirdly, what are the
  • reasons and causes which have induced almost all modern governments to
  • mortgage some part of this revenue, or to contract debts; and what have
  • been the effects of those debts upon the real wealth, the annual produce
  • of the land and labour of the society. The following book, therefore, will
  • naturally be divided into three chapters.
  • APPENDIX TO BOOK IV
  • The two following accounts are subjoined, in order to illustrate and
  • confirm what is said in the fifth chapter of the fourth book, concerning
  • the Tonnage Bounty to the Whit-herring Fishery. The reader, I believe, may
  • depend upon the accuracy of both accounts.
  • An account of Busses fitted out in Scotland for eleven Years, with the
  • Number of empty Barrels carried out, and the Number of Barrels of Herrings
  • caught; also the Bounty, at a Medium, on each Barrel of Sea-sricks, and on
  • each Barrel when fully packed.
  • Years Number of Empty Barrels Barrels of Her- Bounty paid on
  • Busses carried out rings caught the Busses
  • £. s. d.
  • 1771 29 5,948 2,832 2,885 0 0
  • 1772 168 41,316 22,237 11,055 7 6
  • 1773 190 42,333 42,055 12,510 8 6
  • 1774 240 59,303 56,365 26,932 2 6
  • 1775 275 69,144 52,879 19,315 15 0
  • 1776 294 76,329 51,863 21,290 7 6
  • 1777 240 62,679 43,313 17,592 2 6
  • 1778 220 56,390 40,958 16,316 2 6
  • 1779 206 55,194 29,367 15,287 0 0
  • 1780 181 48,315 19,885 13,445 12 6
  • 1781 135 33,992 16,593 9,613 15 6
  • Totals 2,186 550,943 378,347 £165,463 14 0
  • Sea-sticks 378,347 Bounty, at a medium, for each
  • barrel of sea-sticks, £ 0 8 2¼
  • But a barrel of sea-sticks
  • being only reckoned two thirds
  • of a barrel fully packed, one
  • third to be deducted, which
  • ¹/³deducted 126,115 brings the bounty to £ 0 12 3¾
  • Barrels fully
  • packed 252,231
  • And if the herrings are exported, there is besides a
  • premium of £ 0 2 8
  • So the bounty paid by government in money for each
  • barrel is £ 0 14 11¾
  • But if to this, the duty of the salt usually taken
  • credit for as expended in curing each barrel, which
  • at a medium, is, of foreign, one bushel and one-
  • fourth of a bushel, at 10s. a-bushel, be added, viz 0 12 6
  • the bounty on each barrel would amount to £ 1 7 5¾
  • If the herrings are cured with British salt, it will
  • stand thus, viz.
  • Bounty as before £ 0 14 11¾
  • But if to this bounty, the duty on two bushels of
  • Scotch salt, at 1s.6d. per bushel, supposed to be
  • the quantity, at a medium, used in curing each
  • barrel is added, viz. 0 3 0
  • The bounty on each barrel will amount to £ 0 17 11¾
  • And when buss herrings are entered for home
  • consumption in Scotland, and pay the shilling a
  • barrel of duty, the bounty stands thus, to wit,
  • as before £ 0 12 3¾
  • From which the shilling a barrel is to be deducted 0 1 0
  • £ 0 11 3¾
  • But to that there is to be added again, the duty of
  • the foreign salt used curing a barrel of herring viz 0 12 6
  • So that the premium allowed for each barrel of her-
  • rings entered for home consumption is £ 1 3 9¾
  • If the herrings are cured in British salt, it will
  • stand as follows viz.
  • Bounty on each barrel brought in by the busses, as
  • above £ 0 12 3¾
  • From which deduct 1s. a-barrel, paid at the time
  • they are entered for home consumption 0 1 0
  • £ 0 11 3¾
  • But if to the bounty, the the duty on two bushel
  • of Scotch salt, at 1s.6d. per bushel supposed to
  • be the quantity, at a medium, used in curing each
  • barrel, is added, viz 0 3 0
  • the premium for each barrel entered for home
  • consumption will be £ 1 14 3¾
  • Though the loss of duties upon herrings exported cannot, perhaps, properly
  • be considered as bounty, that upon herrings entered for home consumption
  • certainly may.
  • An account of the Quantity of Foreign Salt imported into Scotland, and of
  • Scotch Salt delivered Duty-free from the Works there, for the Fishery,
  • from the 5th. of April 1771 to the 5th. of April 1782 with the Medium of
  • both for one Year.
  • Foreign Salt Scotch Salt delivered
  • PERIOD imported from the Works
  • Bushels Bushels
  • From 5th. April 1771 to
  • 5th. April 1782 936,974 168,226
  • Medium for one year 85,159½ 15,293¼
  • It is to be observed, that the bushel of foreign salt weighs 48lbs., that
  • of British weighs 56lbs. only.
  • BOOK V.
  • OF THE REVENUE OF THE SOVEREIGN OR COMMONWEALTH
  • CHAPTER I.
  • OF THE EXPENSES OF THE SOVEREIGN OR COMMONWEALTH.
  • PART I. Of the Expense of Defence.
  • The first duty of the sovereign, that of protecting the society from the
  • violence and invasion of other independent societies, can be performed
  • only by means of a military force. But the expense both of preparing this
  • military force in time of peace, and of employing it in time of war, is
  • very different in the different states of society, in the different
  • periods of improvement.
  • Among nations of hunters, the lowest and rudest state of society, such as
  • we find it among the native tribes of North America, every man is a
  • warrior, as well as a hunter. When he goes to war, either to defend his
  • society, or to revenge the injuries which have been done to it by other
  • societies, he maintains himself by his own labour, in the same manner as
  • when he lives at home. His society (for in this state of things there is
  • properly neither sovereign nor commonwealth) is at no sort of expense,
  • either to prepare him for the field, or to maintain him while he is in it.
  • Among nations of shepherds, a more advanced state of society, such as we
  • find it among the Tartars and Arabs, every man is, in the same manner, a
  • warrior. Such nations have commonly no fixed habitation, but live either
  • in tents, or in a sort of covered waggons, which are easily transported
  • from place to place. The whole tribe, or nation, changes its situation
  • according to the different seasons of the year, as well as according to
  • other accidents. When its herds and flocks have consumed the forage of one
  • part of the country, it removes to another, and from that to a third. In
  • the dry season, it comes down to the banks of the rivers; in the wet
  • season, it retires to the upper country. When such a nation goes to war,
  • the warriors will not trust their herds and flocks to the feeble defence
  • of their old men, their women and children; and their old men, their women
  • and children, will not be left behind without defence, and without
  • subsistence. The whole nation, besides, being accustomed to a wandering
  • life, even in time of peace, easily takes the field in time of war.
  • Whether it marches as an army, or moves about as a company of herdsmen,
  • the way of life is nearly the same, though the object proposed by it be
  • very different. They all go to war together, therefore, and everyone does
  • as well as he can. Among the Tartars, even the women have been frequently
  • known to engage in battle. If they conquer, whatever belongs to the
  • hostile tribe is the recompence of the victory; but if they are
  • vanquished, all is lost; and not only their herds and flocks, but their
  • women and children become the booty of the conqueror. Even the greater
  • part of those who survive the action are obliged to submit to him for the
  • sake of immediate subsistence. The rest are commonly dissipated and
  • dispersed in the desert.
  • The ordinary life, the ordinary exercise of a Tartar or Arab, prepares him
  • sufficiently for war. Running, wrestling, cudgel-playing, throwing the
  • javelin, drawing the bow, etc. are the common pastimes of those who live
  • in the open air, and are all of them the images of war. When a Tartar or
  • Arab actually goes to war, he is maintained by his own herds and flocks,
  • which he carries with him, in the same manner as in peace. His chief or
  • sovereign (for those nations have all chiefs or sovereigns) is at no sort
  • of expense in preparing him for the field; and when he is in it, the
  • chance of plunder is the only pay which he either expects or requires.
  • An army of hunters can seldom exceed two or three hundred men. The
  • precarious subsistence which the chace affords, could seldom allow a
  • greater number to keep together for any considerable time. An army of
  • shepherds, on the contrary, may sometimes amount to two or three hundred
  • thousand. As long as nothing stops their progress, as long as they can go
  • on from one district, of which they have consumed the forage, to another,
  • which is yet entire; there seems to be scarce any limit to the number who
  • can march on together. A nation of hunters can never be formidable to the
  • civilized nations in their neighbourhood; a nation of shepherds may.
  • Nothing can be more contemptible than an Indian war in North America;
  • nothing, on the contrary, can be more dreadful than a Tartar invasion has
  • frequently been in Asia. The judgment of Thucydides, that both Europe and
  • Asia could not resist the Scythians united, has been verified by the
  • experience of all ages. The inhabitants of the extensive, but defenceless
  • plains of Scythia or Tartary, have been frequently united under the
  • dominion of the chief of some conquering horde or clan; and the havock and
  • devastation of Asia have always signalized their union. The inhabitants of
  • the inhospitable deserts of Arabia, the other great nation of shepherds,
  • have never been united but once, under Mahomet and his immediate
  • successors. Their union, which was more the effect of religious enthusiasm
  • than of conquest, was signalized in the same manner. If the hunting
  • nations of America should ever become shepherds, their neighbourhood would
  • be much more dangerous to the European colonies than it is at present.
  • In a yet more advanced state of society, among those nations of husbandmen
  • who have little foreign commerce, and no other manufactures but those
  • coarse and household ones, which almost every private family prepares for
  • its own use, every man, in the same manner, either is a warrior, or easily
  • becomes such. Those who live by agriculture generally pass the whole day
  • in the open air, exposed to all the inclemencies of the seasons. The
  • hardiness of their ordinary life prepares them for the fatigues of war, to
  • some of which their necessary occupations bear a great analogy. The
  • necessary occupation of a ditcher prepares him to work in the trenches,
  • and to fortify a camp, as well as to inclose a field. The ordinary
  • pastimes of such husbandmen are the same as those of shepherds, and are in
  • the same manner the images of war. But as husbandmen have less leisure
  • than shepherds, they are not so frequently employed in those pastimes.
  • They are soldiers but soldiers not quite so much masters of their
  • exercise. Such as they are, however, it seldom costs the sovereign or
  • commonwealth any expense to prepare them for the field.
  • Agriculture, even in its rudest and lowest state, supposes a settlement,
  • some sort of fixed habitation, which cannot be abandoned without great
  • loss. When a nation of mere husbandmen, therefore, goes to war, the whole
  • people cannot take the field together. The old men, the women and
  • children, at least, must remain at home, to take care of the habitation.
  • All the men of the military age, however, may take the field, and in small
  • nations of this kind, have frequently done so. In every nation, the men of
  • the military age are supposed to amount to about a fourth or a fifth part
  • of the whole body of the people. If the campaign, too, should begin after
  • seedtime, and end before harvest, both the husbandman and his principal
  • labourers can be spared from the farm without much loss. He trusts that
  • the work which must be done in the mean time, can be well enough executed
  • by the old men, the women, and the children. He is not unwilling,
  • therefore, to serve without pay during a short campaign; and it frequently
  • costs the sovereign or commonwealth as little to maintain him in the field
  • as to prepare him for it. The citizens of all the different states of
  • ancient Greece seem to have served in this manner till after the second
  • Persian war; and the people of Peloponnesus till after the Peloponnesian
  • war. The Peloponnesians, Thucydides observes, generally left the field in
  • the summer, and returned home to reap the harvest. The Roman people, under
  • their kings, and during the first ages of the republic, served in the same
  • manner. It was not till the seige of Veii, that they who staid at home
  • began to contribute something towards maintaining those who went to war.
  • In the European monarchies, which were founded upon the ruins of the Roman
  • empire, both before, and for some time after, the establishment of what is
  • properly called the feudal law, the great lords, with all their immediate
  • dependents, used to serve the crown at their own expense. In the field, in
  • the same manner as at home, they maintained themselves by their own
  • revenue, and not by any stipend or pay which they received from the king
  • upon that particular occasion.
  • In a more advanced state of society, two different causes contribute to
  • render it altogether impossible that they who take the field should
  • maintain themselves at their own expense. Those two causes are, the
  • progress of manufactures, and the improvement in the art of war.
  • Though a husbandman should be employed in an expedition, provided it
  • begins after seedtime, and ends before harvest, the interruption of his
  • business will not always occasion any considerable diminution of his
  • revenue. Without the intervention of his labour, Nature does herself the
  • greater part of the work which remains to be done. But the moment that an
  • artificer, a smith, a carpenter, or a weaver, for example, quits his
  • workhouse, the sole source of his revenue is completely dried up. Nature
  • does nothing for him; he does all for himself. When he takes the field,
  • therefore, in defence of the public, as he has no revenue to maintain
  • himself, he must necessarily be maintained by the public. But in a
  • country, of which a great part of the inhabitants are artificers and
  • manufacturers, a great part of the people who go to war must be drawn from
  • those classes, and must, therefore, be maintained by the public as long as
  • they are employed in its service.
  • When the art of war, too, has gradually grown up to be a very intricate
  • and complicated science; when the event of war ceases to be determined, as
  • in the first ages of society, by a single irregular skirmish or battle;
  • but when the contest is generally spun out through several different
  • campaigns, each of which lasts during the greater part of the year; it
  • becomes universally necessary that the public should maintain those who
  • serve the public in war, at least while they are employed in that service.
  • Whatever, in time of peace, might be the ordinary occupation of those who
  • go to war, so very tedious and expensive a service would otherwise be by
  • far too heavy a burden upon them. After the second Persian war,
  • accordingly, the armies of Athens seem to have been generally composed of
  • mercenary troops, consisting, indeed, partly of citizens, but partly, too,
  • of foreigners; and all of them equally hired and paid at the expense of
  • the state. From the time of the siege of Veii, the armies of Rome received
  • pay for their service during the time which they remained in the field.
  • Under the feudal governments, the military service, both of the great
  • lords, and of their immediate dependents, was, after a certain period,
  • universally exchanged for a payment in money, which was employed to
  • maintain those who served in their stead.
  • The number of those who can go to war, in proportion to the whole number
  • of the people, is necessarily much smaller in a civilized than in a rude
  • state of society. In a civilized society, as the soldiers are maintained
  • altogether by the labour of those who are not soldiers, the number of the
  • former can never exceed what the latter can maintain, over and above
  • maintaining, in a manner suitable to their respective stations, both
  • themselves and the other officers of government and law, whom they are
  • obliged to maintain. In the little agrarian states of ancient Greece, a
  • fourth or a fifth part of the whole body of the people considered the
  • themselves as soldiers, and would sometimes, it is said, take the field.
  • Among the civilized nations of modern Europe, it is commonly computed,
  • that not more than the one hundredth part of the inhabitants of any
  • country can be employed as soldiers, without ruin to the country which
  • pays the expense of their service.
  • The expense of preparing the army for the field seems not to have become
  • considerable in any nation, till long after that of maintaining it in the
  • field had devolved entirely upon the sovereign or commonwealth. In all the
  • different republics of ancient Greece, to learn his military exercises,
  • was a necessary part of education imposed by the state upon every free
  • citizen. In every city there seems to have been a public field, in which,
  • under the protection of the public magistrate, the young people were
  • taught their different exercises by different masters. In this very simple
  • institution consisted the whole expense which any Grecian state seems ever
  • to have been at, in preparing its citizens for war. In ancient Rome, the
  • exercises of the Campus Martius answered the same purpose with those of
  • the Gymnasium in ancient Greece. Under the feudal governments, the many
  • public ordinances, that the citizens of every district should practise
  • archery, as well as several other military exercises, were intended for
  • promoting the same purpose, but do not seem to have promoted it so well.
  • Either from want of interest in the officers entrusted with the execution
  • of those ordinances, or from some other cause, they appear to have been
  • universally neglected; and in the progress of all those governments,
  • military exercises seem to have gone gradually into disuse among the great
  • body of the people.
  • In the republics of ancient Greece and Rome, during the whole period of
  • their existence, and under the feudal governments, for a considerable time
  • after their first establishment, the trade of a soldier was not a
  • separate, distinct trade, which constituted the sole or principal
  • occupation of a particular class of citizens; every subject of the state,
  • whatever might be the ordinary trade or occupation by which he gained his
  • livelihood, considered himself, upon all ordinary occasions, as fit
  • likewise to exercise the trade of a soldier, and, upon many extraordinary
  • occasions, as bound to exercise it.
  • The art of war, however, as it is certainly the noblest of all arts, so,
  • in the progress of improvement, it necessarily becomes one of the most
  • complicated among them. The state of the mechanical, as well as some other
  • arts, with which it is necessarily connected, determines the degree of
  • perfection to which it is capable of being carried at any particular time.
  • But in order to carry it to this degree of perfection, it is necessary
  • that it should become the sole or principal occupation of a particular
  • class of citizens; and the division of labour is as necessary for the
  • improvement of this, as of every other art. Into other arts, the division
  • of labour is naturally introduced by the prudence of individuals, who find
  • that they promote their private interest better by confining themselves to
  • a particular trade, than by exercising a great number. But it is the
  • wisdom of the state only, which can render the trade of a soldier a
  • particular trade, separate and distinct from all others. A private
  • citizen, who, in time of profound peace, and without any particular
  • encouragement from the public, should spend the greater part of his time
  • in military exercises, might, no doubt, both improve himself very much in
  • them, and amuse himself very well; but he certainly would not promote his
  • own interest. It is the wisdom of the state only, which can render it for
  • his interest to give up the greater part of his time to this peculiar
  • occupation; and states have not always had this wisdom, even when their
  • circumstances had become such, that the preservation of their existence
  • required that they should have it.
  • A shepherd has a great deal of leisure; a husbandman, in the rude state of
  • husbandry, has some; an artificer or manufacturer has none at all. The
  • first may, without any loss, employ a great deal of his time in martial
  • exercises; the second may employ some part of it; but the last cannot
  • employ a single hour in them without some loss, and his attention to his
  • own interest naturally leads him to neglect them altogether. Those
  • improvements in husbandry, too, which the progress of arts and
  • manufactures necessarily introduces, leave the husbandman as little
  • leisure as the artificer. Military exercises come to be as much neglected
  • by the inhabitants of the country as by those of the town, and the great
  • body of the people becomes altogether unwarlike. That wealth, at the same
  • time, which always follows the improvements of agriculture and
  • manufactures, and which, in reality, is no more than the accumulated
  • produce of those improvements, provokes the invasion of all their
  • neighbours. An industrious, and, upon that account, a wealthy nation, is
  • of all nations the most likely to be attacked; and unless the state takes
  • some new measure for the public defence, the natural habits of the people
  • render them altogether incapable of defending themselves.
  • In these circumstances, there seem to be but two methods by which the
  • state can make any tolerable provision for the public defence.
  • It may either, first, by means of a very rigorous police, and in spite of
  • the whole bent of the interest, genius, and inclinations of the people,
  • enforce the practice of military exercises, and oblige either all the
  • citizens of the military age, or a certain number of them, to join in some
  • measure the trade of a soldier to whatever other trade or profession they
  • may happen to carry on.
  • Or, secondly, by maintaining and employing a certain number of citizens in
  • the constant practice of military exercises, it may render the trade of a
  • soldier a particular trade, separate and distinct from all others.
  • If the state has recourse to the first of those two expedients, its
  • military force is said to consist in a militia; if to the second, it is
  • said to consist in a standing army. The practice of military exercises is
  • the sole or principal occupation of the soldiers of a standing army, and
  • the maintenance or pay which the state affords them is the principal and
  • ordinary fund of their subsistence. The practice of military exercises is
  • only the occasional occupation of the soldiers of a militia, and they
  • derive the principal and ordinary fund of their subsistence from some
  • other occupation. In a militia, the character of the labourer, artificer,
  • or tradesman, predominates over that of the soldier; in a standing army,
  • that of the soldier predominates over every other character; and in this
  • distinction seems to consist the essential difference between those two
  • different species of military force.
  • Militias have been of several different kinds. In some countries, the
  • citizens destined for defending the state seem to have been exercised
  • only, without being, if I may say so, regimented; that is, without being
  • divided into separate and distinct bodies of troops, each of which
  • performed its exercises under its own proper and permanent officers. In
  • the republics of ancient Greece and Rome, each citizen, as long as he
  • remained at home, seems to have practised his exercises, either separately
  • and independently, or with such of his equals as he liked best; and not to
  • have been attached to any particular body of troops, till he was actually
  • called upon to take the field. In other countries, the militia has not
  • only been exercised, but regimented. In England, in Switzerland, and, I
  • believe, in every other country of modern Europe, where any imperfect
  • military force of this kind has been established, every militiaman is,
  • even in time of peace, attached to a particular body of troops, which
  • performs its exercises under its own proper and permanent officers.
  • Before the invention of fire-arms, that army was superior in which the
  • soldiers had, each individually, the greatest skill and dexterity in the
  • use of their arms. Strength and agility of body were of the highest
  • consequence, and commonly determined the fate of battles. But this skill
  • and dexterity in the use of their arms could be acquired only, in the same
  • manner as fencing is at present, by practising, not in great bodies, but
  • each man separately, in a particular school, under a particular master, or
  • with his own particular equals and companions. Since the invention of
  • fire-arms, strength and agility of body, or even extraordinary dexterity
  • and skill in the use of arms, though they are far from being of no
  • consequence, are, however, of less consequence. The nature of the weapon,
  • though it by no means puts the awkward upon a level with the skilful, puts
  • him more nearly so than he ever was before. All the dexterity and skill,
  • it is supposed, which are necessary for using it, can be well enough
  • acquired by practising in great bodies.
  • Regularity, order, and prompt obedience to command, are qualities which,
  • in modern armies, are of more importance towards determining the fate of
  • battles, than the dexterity and skill of the soldiers in the use of their
  • arms. But the noise of fire-arms, the smoke, and the invisible death to
  • which every man feels himself every moment exposed, as soon as he comes
  • within cannon-shot, and frequently a long time before the battle can be
  • well said to be engaged, must render it very difficult to maintain any
  • considerable degree of this regularity, order, and prompt obedience, even
  • in the beginning of a modern battle. In an ancient battle, there was no
  • noise but what arose from the human voice; there was no smoke, there was
  • no invisible cause of wounds or death. Every man, till some mortal weapon
  • actually did approach him, saw clearly that no such weapon was near him.
  • In these circumstances, and among troops who had some confidence in their
  • own skill and dexterity in the use of their arms, it must have been a good
  • deal less difficult to preserve some degree of regularity and order, not
  • only in the beginning, but through the whole progress of an ancient
  • battle, and till one of the two armies was fairly defeated. But the habits
  • of regularity, order, and prompt obedience to command, can be acquired
  • only by troops which are exercised in great bodies.
  • A militia, however, in whatever manner it may be either disciplined or
  • exercised, must always be much inferior to a well disciplined and well
  • exercised standing army.
  • The soldiers who are exercised only once a week, or once a-month, can
  • never be so expert in the use of their arms, as those who are exercised
  • every day, or every other day; and though this circumstance may not be of
  • so much consequence in modern, as it was in ancient times, yet the
  • acknowledged superiority of the Prussian troops, owing, it is said, very
  • much to their superior expertness in their exercise, may satisfy us that
  • it is, even at this day, of very considerable consequence.
  • The soldiers, who are bound to obey their officer only once a-week, or
  • once a-month, and who are at all other times at liberty to manage their
  • own affairs their own way, without being, in any respect, accountable to
  • him, can never be under the same awe in his presence, can never have the
  • same disposition to ready obedience, with those whose whole life and
  • conduct are every day directed by him, and who every day even rise and go
  • to bed, or at least retire to their quarters, according to his orders. In
  • what is called discipline, or in the habit of ready obedience, a militia
  • must always be still more inferior to a standing army, than it may
  • sometimes be in what is called the manual exercise, or in the management
  • and use of its arms. But, in modern war, the habit of ready and instant
  • obedience is of much greater consequence than a considerable superiority
  • in the management of arms.
  • Those militias which, like the Tartar or Arab militia, go to war under the
  • same chieftains whom they are accustomed to obey in peace, are by far the
  • best. In respect for their officers, in the habit of ready obedience, they
  • approach nearest to standing armies. The Highland militia, when it served
  • under its own chieftains, had some advantage of the same kind. As the
  • Highlanders, however, were not wandering, but stationary shepherds, as
  • they had all a fixed habitation, and were not, in peaceable times,
  • accustomed to follow their chieftain from place to place; so, in time of
  • war, they were less willing to follow him to any considerable distance, or
  • to continue for any long time in the field. When they had acquired any
  • booty, they were eager to return home, and his authority was seldom
  • sufficient to detain them. In point of obedience, they were always much
  • inferior to what is reported of the Tartars and Arabs. As the Highlanders,
  • too, from their stationary life, spend less of their time in the open air,
  • they were always less accustomed to military exercises, and were less
  • expert in the use of their arms than the Tartars and Arabs are said to be.
  • A militia of any kind, it must be observed, however, which has served for
  • several successive campaigns in the field, becomes in every respect a
  • standing army. The soldiers are every day exercised in the use of their
  • arms, and, being constantly under the command of their officers, are
  • habituated to the same prompt obedience which takes place in standing
  • armies. What they were before they took the field, is of little
  • importance. They necessarily become in every respect a standing army,
  • after they have passed a few campaigns in it. Should the war in America
  • drag out through another campaign, the American militia may become, in
  • every respect, a match for that standing army, of which the valour
  • appeared, in the last war at least, not inferior to that of the hardiest
  • veterans of France and Spain.
  • This distinction being well understood, the history of all ages, it will
  • be found, hears testimony to the irresistible superiority which a well
  • regulated standing army has over a militia.
  • One of the first standing armies, of which we have any distinct account in
  • any well authenticated history, is that of Philip of Macedon. His frequent
  • wars with the Thracians, Illyrians, Thessalians, and some of the Greek
  • cities in the neighbourhood of Macedon, gradually formed his troops, which
  • in the beginning were probably militia, to the exact discipline of a
  • standing army. When he was at peace, which he was very seldom, and never
  • for any long time together, he was careful not to disband that army. It
  • vanquished and subdued, after a long and violent struggle, indeed, the
  • gallant and well exercised militias of the principal republics of ancient
  • Greece; and afterwards, with very little struggle, the effeminate and ill
  • exercised militia of the great Persian empire. The fall of the Greek
  • republics, and of the Persian empire was the effect of the irresistible
  • superiority which a standing arm has over every other sort of militia. It
  • is the first great revolution in the affairs of mankind of which history
  • has preserved any distinct and circumstantial account.
  • The fall of Carthage, and the consequent elevation of Rome, is the second.
  • All the varieties in the fortune of those two famous republics may very
  • well be accounted for from the same cause.
  • From the end of the first to the beginning of the second Carthaginian war,
  • the armies of Carthage were continually in the field, and employed under
  • three great generals, who succeeded one another in the command; Amilcar,
  • his son-in-law Asdrubal, and his son Annibal: first in chastising their
  • own rebellious slaves, afterwards in subduing the revolted nations of
  • Africa; and lastly, in conquering the great kingdom of Spain. The army
  • which Annibal led from Spain into Italy must necessarily, in those
  • different wars, have been gradually formed to the exact discipline of a
  • standing army. The Romans, in the meantime, though they had not been
  • altogether at peace, yet they had not, during this period, been engaged in
  • any war of very great consequence; and their military discipline, it is
  • generally said, was a good deal relaxed. The Roman armies which Annibal
  • encountered at Trebi, Thrasymenus, and Cannae, were militia opposed to a
  • standing army. This circumstance, it is probable, contributed more than
  • any other to determine the fate of those battles.
  • The standing army which Annibal left behind him in Spain had the like
  • superiority over the militia which the Romans sent to oppose it; and, in a
  • few years, under the command of his brother, the younger Asdrubal,
  • expelled them almost entirely from that country.
  • Annibal was ill supplied from home. The Roman militia, being continually
  • in the field, became, in the progress of the war, a well disciplined and
  • well exercised standing army; and the superiority of Annibal grew every
  • day less and less. Asdrubal judged it necessary to lead the whole, or
  • almost the whole, of the standing army which he commanded in Spain, to the
  • assistance of his brother in Italy. In this march, he is said to have been
  • misled by his guides; and in a country which he did not know, was
  • surprised and attacked, by another standing army, in every respect equal
  • or superior to his own, and was entirely defeated.
  • When Asdrubal had left Spain, the great Scipio found nothing to oppose him
  • but a militia inferior to his own. He conquered and subdued that militia,
  • and, in the course of the war, his own militia necessarily became a well
  • disciplined and well exercised standing army. That standing army was
  • afterwards carried to Africa, where it found nothing but a militia to
  • oppose it. In order to defend Carthage, it became necessary to recal the
  • standing army of Annibal. The disheartened and frequently defeated African
  • militia joined it, and, at the battle of Zama, composed the greater part
  • of the troops of Annibal. The event of that day determined the fate of the
  • two rival republics.
  • From the end of the second Carthaginian war till the fall of the Roman
  • republic, the armies of Rome were in every respect standing armies. The
  • standing army of Macedon made some resistance to their arms. In the height
  • of their grandeur, it cost them two great wars, and three great battles,
  • to subdue that little kingdom, of which the conquest would probably have
  • been still more difficult, had it not been for the cowardice of its last
  • king. The militias of all the civilized nations of the ancient world, of
  • Greece, of Syria, and of Egypt, made but a feeble resistance to the
  • standing armies of Rome. The militias of some barbarous nations defended
  • themselves much better. The Scythian or Tartar militia, which Mithridates
  • drew from the countries north of the Euxine and Caspian seas, were the
  • most formidable enemies whom the Romans had to encounter after the second
  • Carthaginian war. The Parthian and German militias, too, were always
  • respectable, and upon several occasions, gained very considerable
  • advantages over the Roman armies. In general, however, and when the Roman
  • armies were well commanded, they appear to have been very much superior;
  • and if the Romans did not pursue the final conquest either of Parthia or
  • Germany, it was probably because they judged that it was not worth while
  • to add those two barbarous countries to an empire which was already too
  • large. The ancient Parthians appear to have been a nation of Scythian or
  • Tartar extraction, and to have always retained a good deal of the manners
  • of their ancestors. The ancient Germans were, like the Scythians or
  • Tartars, a nation of wandering shepherds, who went to war under the same
  • chiefs whom they were accustomed to follow in peace. ‘Their militia was
  • exactly of the same kind with that of the Scythians or Tartars, from whom,
  • too, they were probably descended.
  • Many different causes contributed to relax the discipline of the Roman
  • armies. Its extreme severity was, perhaps, one of those causes. In the
  • days of their grandeur, when no enemy appeared capable of opposing them,
  • their heavy armour was laid aside as unnecessarily burdensome, their
  • laborious exercises were neglected, as unnecessarily toilsome. Under the
  • Roman emperors, besides, the standing armies of Rome, those particularly
  • which guarded the German and Pannonian frontiers, became dangerous to
  • their masters, against whom they used frequently to set up their own
  • generals. In order to render them less formidable, according to some
  • authors, Dioclesian, according to others, Constantine, first withdrew them
  • from the frontier, where they had always before been encamped in great
  • bodies, generally of two or three legions each, and dispersed them in
  • small bodies through the different provincial towns, from whence they were
  • scarce ever removed, but when it became necessary to repel an invasion.
  • Small bodies of soldiers, quartered in trading and manufacturing towns,
  • and seldom removed from those quarters, became themselves trades men,
  • artificers, and manufacturers. The civil came to predominate over the
  • military character; and the standing armies of Rome gradually degenerated
  • into a corrupt, neglected, and undisciplined militia, incapable of
  • resisting the attack of the German and Scythian militias, which soon
  • afterwards invaded the western empire. It was only by hiring the militia
  • of some of those nations to oppose to that of others, that the emperors
  • were for some time able to defend themselves. The fall of the western
  • empire is the third great revolution in the affairs of mankind, of which
  • ancient history has preserved any distinct or circumstantial account. It
  • was brought about by the irresistible superiority which the militia of a
  • barbarous has over that of a civilized nation; which the militia of a
  • nation of shepherds has over that of a nation of husbandmen, artificers,
  • and manufacturers. The victories which have been gained by militias have
  • generally been, not over standing armies, but over other militias, in
  • exercise and discipline inferior to themselves. Such were the victories
  • which the Greek militia gained over that of the Persian empire; and such,
  • too, were those which, in later times, the Swiss militia gained over that
  • of the Austrians and Burgundians.
  • The military force of the German and Scythian nations, who established
  • themselves upon ruins of the western empire, continued for some time to be
  • of the same kind in their new settlements, as it had been in their
  • original country. It was a militia of shepherds and husbandmen, which, in
  • time of war, took the field under the command of the same chieftains whom
  • it was accustomed to obey in peace. It was, therefore, tolerably well
  • exercised, and tolerably well disciplined. As arts and industry advanced,
  • however, the authority of the chieftains gradually decayed, and the great
  • body of the people had less time to spare for military exercises. Both the
  • discipline and the exercise of the feudal militia, therefore, went
  • gradually to ruin, and standing armies were gradually introduced to supply
  • the place of it. When the expedient of a standing army, besides, had once
  • been adopted by one civilized nation, it became necessary that all its
  • neighbours should follow the example. They soon found that their safety
  • depended upon their doing so, and that their own militia was altogether
  • incapable of resisting the attack of such an army.
  • The soldiers of a standing army, though they may never have seen an enemy,
  • yet have frequently appeared to possess all the courage of veteran troops,
  • and, the very moment that they took the field, to have been fit to face
  • the hardiest and most experienced veterans. In 1756, when the Russian army
  • marched into Poland, the valour of the Russian soldiers did not appear
  • inferior to that of the Prussians, at that time supposed to be the
  • hardiest and most experienced veterans in Europe. The Russian empire,
  • however, had enjoyed a profound peace for near twenty years before, and
  • could at that time have very few soldiers who had ever seen an enemy. When
  • the Spanish war broke out in 1739, England had enjoyed a profound peace
  • for about eight-and-twenty years. The valour of her soldiers, however, far
  • from being corrupted by that long peace, was never more distinguished than
  • in the attempt upon Carthagena, the first unfortunate exploit of that
  • unfortunate war. In a long peace, the generals, perhaps, may sometimes
  • forget their skill; but where a well regulated standing army has been kept
  • up, the soldiers seem never to forget their valour.
  • When a civilized nation depends for its defence upon a militia, it is at
  • all times exposed to be conquered by any barbarous nation which happens to
  • be in its neighbourhood. The frequent conquests of all the civilized
  • countries in Asia by the Tartars, sufficiently demonstrates the natural
  • superiority which the militia of a barbarous has over that of a civilized
  • nation. A well regulated standing army is superior to every militia. Such
  • an army, as it can best be maintained by an opulent and civilized nation,
  • so it can alone defend such a nation against the invasion of a poor and
  • barbarous neighbour. It is only by means of a standing army, therefore,
  • that the civilization of any country can be perpetuated, or even
  • preserved, for any considerable time.
  • As it is only by means of a well regulated standing army, that a civilized
  • country can be defended, so it is only by means of it that a barbarous
  • country can be suddenly and tolerably civilized. A standing army
  • establishes, with an irresistible force, the law of the sovereign through
  • the remotest provinces of the empire, and maintains some degree of regular
  • government in countries which could not otherwise admit of any. Whoever
  • examines with attention, the improvements which Peter the Great introduced
  • into the Russian empire, will find that they almost all resolve themselves
  • into the establishment of a well regulated standing army. It is the
  • instrument which executes and maintains all his other regulations. That
  • degree of order and internal peace, which that empire has ever since
  • enjoyed, is altogether owing to the influence of that army.
  • Men of republican principles have been jealous of a standing army, as
  • dangerous to liberty. It certainly is so, wherever the interest of the
  • general, and that of the principal officers, are not necessarily connected
  • with the support of the constitution of the state. The standing army of
  • Caesar destroyed the Roman republic. The standing army of Cromwell turned
  • the long parliament out of doors. But where the sovereign is himself the
  • general, and the principal nobility and gentry of the country the chief
  • officers of the army; where the military force is placed under the command
  • of those who have the greatest interest in the support of the civil
  • authority, because they have themselves the greatest share of that
  • authority, a standing army can never be dangerous to liberty. On the
  • contrary, it may, in some cases, be favourable to liberty. The security
  • which it gives to the sovereign renders unnecessary that troublesome
  • jealousy, which, in some modern republics, seems to watch over the
  • minutest actions, and to be at all times ready to disturb the peace of
  • every citizen. Where the security of the magistrate, though supported by
  • the principal people of the country, is endangered by every popular
  • discontent; where a small tumult is capable of bringing about in a few
  • hours a great revolution, the whole authority of government must be
  • employed to suppress and punish every murmur and complaint against it. To
  • a sovereign, on the contrary, who feels himself supported, not only by the
  • natural aristocracy of the country, but by a well regulated standing army,
  • the rudest, the most groundless, and the most licentious remonstrances,
  • can give little disturbance. He can safely pardon or neglect them, and his
  • consciousness of his own superiority naturally disposes him to do so. That
  • degree of liberty which approaches to licentiousness, can be tolerated
  • only in countries where the sovereign is secured by a well regulated
  • standing army. It is in such countries only, that the public safety does
  • not require that the sovereign should be trusted with any discretionary
  • power, for suppressing even the impertinent wantonness of this licentious
  • liberty.
  • The first duty of the sovereign, therefore, that of defending the society
  • from the violence and injustice of other independent societies, grows
  • gradually more and more expensive, as the society advances in
  • civilization. The military force of the society, which originally cost the
  • sovereign no expense, either in time of peace, or in time of war, must, in
  • the progress of improvement, first be maintained by him in time of war,
  • and afterwards even in time of peace.
  • The great change introduced into the art of war by the invention of
  • fire-arms, has enhanced still further both the expense of exercising and
  • disciplining any particular number of soldiers in time of peace, and that
  • of employing them in time of war. Both their arms and their ammunition are
  • become more expensive. A musket is a more expensive machine than a javelin
  • or a bow and arrows; a cannon or a mortar, than a balista or a catapulta.
  • The powder which is spent in a modern review is lost irrecoverably, and
  • occasions a very considerable expense. The javelins and arrows which were
  • thrown or shot in an ancient one, could easily be picked up again, and
  • were, besides, of very little value. The cannon and the mortar are not
  • only much dearer, but much heavier machines than the balista or catapulta;
  • and require a greater expense, not only to prepare them for the field, but
  • to carry them to it. As the superiority of the modern artillery, too, over
  • that of the ancients, is very great; it has become much more difficult,
  • and consequently much more expensive, to fortify a town, so as to resist,
  • even for a few weeks, the attack of that superior artillery. In modern
  • times, many different causes contribute to render the defence of the
  • society more expensive. The unavoidable effects of the natural progress of
  • improvement have, in this respect, been a good deal enhanced by a great
  • revolution in the art of war, to which a mere accident, the invention of
  • gunpowder, seems to have given occasion.
  • In modern war, the great expense of firearms gives an evident advantage to
  • the nation which can best afford that expense; and, consequently, to an
  • opulent and civilized, over a poor and barbarous nation. In ancient times,
  • the opulent and civilized found it difficult to defend themselves against
  • the poor and barbarous nations. In modern times, the poor and barbarous
  • find it difficult to defend themselves against the opulent and civilized.
  • The invention of fire-arms, an invention which at first sight appears to
  • be so pernicious, is certainly favourable, both to the permanency and to
  • the extension of civilization.
  • PART II. Of the Expense of Justice
  • The second duty of the sovereign, that of protecting, as far as possible,
  • every member of the society from the injustice or oppression of every
  • other member of it, or the duty of establishing an exact administration of
  • justice, requires two very different degrees of expense in the different
  • periods of society.
  • Among nations of hunters, as there is scarce any property, or at least
  • none that exceeds the value of two or three days labour; so there is
  • seldom any established magistrate, or any regular administration of
  • justice. Men who have no property, can injure one another only in their
  • persons or reputations. But when one man kills, wounds, beats, or defames
  • another, though he to whom the injury is done suffers, he who does it
  • receives no benefit. It is otherwise with the injuries to property. The
  • benefit of the person who does the injury is often equal to the loss of
  • him who suffers it. Envy, malice, or resentment, are the only passions
  • which can prompt one man to injure another in his person or reputation.
  • But the greater part of men are not very frequently under the influence of
  • those passions; and the very worst men are so only occasionally. As their
  • gratification, too, how agreeable soever it may be to certain characters,
  • is not attended with any real or permanent advantage, it is, in the
  • greater part of men, commonly restrained by prudential considerations. Men
  • may live together in society with some tolerable degree of security,
  • though there is no civil magistrate to protect them from the injustice of
  • those passions. But avarice and ambition in the rich, in the poor the
  • hatred of labour and the love of present ease and enjoyment, are the
  • passions which prompt to invade property; passions much more steady in
  • their operation, and much more universal in their influence. Wherever
  • there is a great property, there is great inequality. For one very rich
  • man, there must be at least five hundred poor, and the affluence of the
  • few supposes the indigence of the many. The affluence of the rich excites
  • the indignation of the poor, who are often both driven by want, and
  • prompted by envy to invade his possessions. It is only under the shelter
  • of the civil magistrate, that the owner of that valuable property, which
  • is acquired by the labour of many years, or perhaps of many successive
  • generations, can sleep a single night in security. He is at all times
  • surrounded by unknown enemies, whom, though he never provoked, he can
  • never appease, and from whose injustice he can be protected only by the
  • powerful arm of the civil magistrate, continually held up to chastise it.
  • The acquisition of valuable and extensive property, therefore, necessarily
  • requires the establishment of civil government. Where there is no
  • property, or at least none that exceeds the value of two or three days
  • labour, civil government is not so necessary.
  • Civil government supposes a certain subordination. But as the necessity of
  • civil government gradually grows up with the acquisition of valuable
  • property; so the principal causes, which naturally introduce
  • subordination, gradually grow up with the growth of that valuable
  • property.
  • The causes or circumstances which naturally introduce subordination, or
  • which naturally and antecedent to any civil institution, give some men
  • some superiority over the greater part of their brethren, seem to be four
  • in number.
  • The first of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority of personal
  • qualifications, of strength, beauty, and agility of body; of wisdom and
  • virtue; of prudence, justice, fortitude, and moderation of mind. The
  • qualifications of the body, unless supported by those of the mind, can
  • give little authority in any period of society. He is a very strong man,
  • who, by mere strength of body, can force two weak ones to obey him. The
  • qualifications of the mind can alone give very great authority. They are
  • however, invisible qualities; always disputable, and generally disputed.
  • No society, whether barbarous or civilized, has ever found it convenient
  • to settle the rules of precedency of rank and subordination, according to
  • those invisible qualities; but according to something that is more plain
  • and palpable.
  • The second of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority of age. An
  • old man, provided his age is not so far advanced as to give suspicion of
  • dotage, is everywhere more respected than a young man of equal rank,
  • fortune, and abilities. Among nations of hunters, such as the native
  • tribes of North America, age is the sole foundation of rank and
  • precedency. Among them, father is the appellation of a superior; brother,
  • of an equal; and son, of an inferior. In the most opulent and civilized
  • nations, age regulates rank among those who are in every other respect
  • equal; and among whom, therefore, there is nothing else to regulate it.
  • Among brothers and among sisters, the eldest always takes place; and in
  • the succession of the paternal estate, every thing which cannot be
  • divided, but must go entire to one person, such as a title of honour, is
  • in most cases given to the eldest. Age is a plain and palpable quality,
  • which admits of no dispute.
  • The third of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority of fortune.
  • The authority of riches, however, though great in every age of society,
  • is, perhaps, greatest in the rudest ages of society, which admits of any
  • considerable inequality of fortune. A Tartar chief, the increase of whose
  • flocks and herds is sufficient to maintain a thousand men, cannot well
  • employ that increase in any other way than in maintaining a thousand men.
  • The rude state of his society does not afford him any manufactured produce
  • any trinkets or baubles of any kind, for which he can exchange that part
  • of his rude produce which is over and above his own consumption. The
  • thousand men whom he thus maintains, depending entirely upon him for their
  • subsistence, must both obey his orders in war, and submit to his
  • jurisdiction in peace. He is necessarily both their general and their
  • judge, and his chieftainship is the necessary effect of the superiority of
  • his fortune. In an opulent and civilized society, a man may possess a much
  • greater fortune, and yet not be able to command a dozen of people. Though
  • the produce of his estate may be sufficient to maintain, and may, perhaps,
  • actually maintain, more than a thousand people, yet, as those people pay
  • for every thing which they get from him, as he gives scarce any thing to
  • any body but in exchange for an equivalent, there is scarce anybody who
  • considers himself as entirely dependent upon him, and his authority
  • extends only over a few menial servants. The authority of fortune,
  • however, is very great, even in an opulent and civilized society. That it
  • is much greater than that either of age or of personal qualities, has been
  • the constant complaint of every period of society which admitted of any
  • considerable inequality of fortune. The first period of society, that of
  • hunters, admits of no such inequality. Universal poverty establishes their
  • universal equality; and the superiority, either of age or of personal
  • qualities, are the feeble, but the sole foundations of authority and
  • subordination. There is, therefore, little or no authority or
  • subordination in this period of society. The second period of society,
  • that of shepherds, admits of very great inequalities of fortune, and there
  • is no period in which the superiority of fortune gives so great authority
  • to those who possess it. There is no period, accordingly, in which
  • authority and subordination are more perfectly established. The authority
  • of an Arabian scherif is very great; that of a Tartar khan altogether
  • despotical.
  • The fourth of those causes or circumstances, is the superiority of birth.
  • Superiority of birth supposes an ancient superiority of fortune in the
  • family of the person who claims it. All families are equally ancient; and
  • the ancestors of the prince, though they may be better known, cannot well
  • be more numerous than those of the beggar. Antiquity of family means
  • everywhere the antiquity either of wealth, or of that greatness which is
  • commonly either founded upon wealth, or accompanied with it. Upstart
  • greatness is everywhere less respected than ancient greatness. The hatred
  • of usurpers, the love of the family of an ancient monarch, are in a great
  • measure founded upon the contempt which men naturally have for the former,
  • and upon their veneration for the latter. As a military officer submits,
  • without reluctance, to the authority of a superior by whom he has always
  • been commanded, but cannot bear that his inferior should be set over his
  • head; so men easily submit to a family to whom they and their ancestors
  • have always submitted; but are fired with indignation when another family,
  • in whom they had never acknowledged any such superiority, assumes a
  • dominion over them.
  • The distinction of birth, being subsequent to the inequality of fortune,
  • can have no place in nations of hunters, among whom all men, being equal
  • in fortune, must likewise be very nearly equal in birth. The son of a wise
  • and brave man may, indeed, even among them, be somewhat more respected
  • than a man of equal merit, who has the misfortune to be the son of a fool
  • or a coward. The difference, however will not be very great; and there
  • never was, I believe, a great family in the world, whose illustration was
  • entirely derived from the inheritance of wisdom and virtue.
  • The distinction of birth not only may, but always does, take place among
  • nations of shepherds. Such nations are always strangers to every sort of
  • luxury, and great wealth can scarce ever be dissipated among them by
  • improvident profusion. There are no nations, accordingly, who abound more
  • in families revered and honoured on account of their descent from a long
  • race of great and illustrious ancestors; because there are no nations
  • among whom wealth is likely to continue longer in the same families.
  • Birth and fortune are evidently the two circumstances which principally
  • set one man above another. They are the two great sources of personal
  • distinction, and are, therefore, the principal causes which naturally
  • establish authority and subordination among men. Among nations of
  • shepherds, both those causes operate with their full force. The great
  • shepherd or herdsman, respected on account of his great wealth, and of the
  • great number of those who depend upon him for subsistence, and revered on
  • account of the nobleness of his birth, and of the immemorial antiquity or
  • his illustrious family, has a natural authority over all the inferior
  • shepherds or herdsmen of his horde or clan. He can command the united
  • force of a greater number of people than any of them. His military power
  • is greater than that of any of them. In time of war, they are all of them
  • naturally disposed to muster themselves under his banner, rather than
  • under that of any other person; and his birth and fortune thus naturally
  • procure to him some sort of executive power. By commanding, too, the
  • united force of a greater number of people than any of them, he is best
  • able to compel any one of them, who may have injured another, to
  • compensate the wrong. He is the person, therefore, to whom all those who
  • are too weak to defend themselves naturally look up for protection. It is
  • to him that they naturally complain of the injuries which they imagine
  • have been done to them; and his interposition, in such cases, is more
  • easily submitted to, even by the person complained of, than that of any
  • other person would be. His birth and fortune thus naturally procure him
  • some sort of judicial authority.
  • It is in the age of shepherds, in the second period of society, that the
  • inequality of fortune first begins to take place, and introduces among men
  • a degree of authority and subordination, which could not possibly exist
  • before. It thereby introduces some degree of that civil government which
  • is indispensably necessary for its own preservation; and it seems to do
  • this naturally, and even independent of the consideration of that
  • necessity. The consideration of that necessity comes, no doubt,
  • afterwards, to contribute very much to maintain and secure that authority
  • and subordination. The rich, in particular, are necessarily interested to
  • support that order of things, which can alone secure them in the
  • possession of their own advantages. Men of inferior wealth combine to
  • defend those of superior wealth in the possession of their property, in
  • order that men of superior wealth may combine to defend them in the
  • possession of theirs. All the inferior shepherds and herdsmen feel, that
  • the security of their own herds and flocks depends upon the security of
  • those of the great shepherd or herdsman; that the maintenance of their
  • lesser authority depends upon that of his greater authority; and that upon
  • their subordination to him depends his power of keeping their inferiors in
  • subordination to them. They constitute a sort of little nobility, who feel
  • themselves interested to defend the property, and to support the
  • authority, of their own little sovereign, in order that he may be able to
  • defend their property, and to support their authority. Civil government,
  • so far as it is instituted for the security of property, is, in reality,
  • instituted for the defence of the rich against the poor, or of those who
  • have some property against those who have none at all.
  • The judicial authority of such a sovereign, however, far from being a
  • cause of expense, was, for a long time, a source of revenue to him. The
  • persons who applied to him for justice were always willing to pay for it,
  • and a present never failed to accompany a petition. After the authority of
  • the sovereign, too, was thoroughly established, the person found guilty,
  • over and above the satisfaction which he was obliged to make to the party,
  • was like-wise forced to pay an amercement to the sovereign. He had given
  • trouble, he had disturbed, he had broke the peace of his lord the king,
  • and for those offences an amercement was thought due. In the Tartar
  • governments of Asia, in the governments of Europe which were founded by
  • the German and Scythian nations who overturned the Roman empire, the
  • administration of justice was a considerable source of revenue, both to
  • the sovereign, and to all the lesser chiefs or lords who exercised under
  • him any particular jurisdiction, either over some particular tribe or
  • clan, or over some particular territory or district. Originally, both the
  • sovereign and the inferior chiefs used to exercise this jurisdiction in
  • their own persons. Afterwards, they universally found it convenient to
  • delegate it to some substitute, bailiff, or judge. This substitute,
  • however, was still obliged to account to his principal or constituent for
  • the profits of the jurisdiction. Whoever reads the instructions (They are
  • to be found in Tyrol’s History of England) which were given to the judges
  • of the circuit in the time of Henry II will see clearly that those judges
  • were a sort of itinerant factors, sent round the country for the purpose
  • of levying certain branches of the king’s revenue. In those days, the
  • administration of justice not only afforded a certain revenue to the
  • sovereign, but, to procure this revenue, seems to have been one of the
  • principal advantages which he proposed to obtain by the administration of
  • justice.
  • This scheme of making the administration of justice subservient to the
  • purposes of revenue, could scarce fail to be productive of several very
  • gross abuses. The person who applied for justice with a large present in
  • his hand, was likely to get something more than justice; while he who
  • applied for it with a small one was likely to get something less. Justice,
  • too, might frequently be delayed, in order that this present might be
  • repeated. The amercement, besides, of the person complained of, might
  • frequently suggest a very strong reason for finding him in the wrong, even
  • when he had not really been so. That such abuses were far from being
  • uncommon, the ancient history of every country in Europe bears witness.
  • When the sovereign or chief exercises his judicial authority in his own
  • person, how much soever he might abuse it, it must have been scarce
  • possible to get any redress; because there could seldom be any body
  • powerful enough to call him to account. When he exercised it by a bailiff,
  • indeed, redress might sometimes be had. If it was for his own benefit
  • only, that the bailiff had been guilty of an act of injustice, the
  • sovereign himself might not always be unwilling to punish him, or to
  • oblige him to repair the wrong. But if it was for the benefit of his
  • sovereign; if it was in order to make court to the person who appointed
  • him, and who might prefer him, that he had committed any act of
  • oppression; redress would, upon most occasions, be as impossible as if the
  • sovereign had committed it himself. In all barbarous governments,
  • accordingly, in all those ancient governments of Europe in particular,
  • which were founded upon the ruins of the Roman empire, the administration
  • of justice appears for a long time to have been extremely corrupt; far
  • from being quite equal and impartial, even under the best monarchs, and
  • altogether profligate under the worst.
  • Among nations of shepherds, where the sovereign or chief is only the
  • greatest shepherd or herdsman of the horde or clan, he is maintained in
  • the same manner as any of his vassals or subjects, by the increase of his
  • own herds or flocks. Among those nations of husbandmen, who are but just
  • come out of the shepherd state, and who are not much advanced beyond that
  • state, such as the Greek tribes appear to have been about the time of the
  • Trojan war, and our German and Scythian ancestors, when they first settled
  • upon the ruins of the western empire; the sovereign or chief is, in the
  • same manner, only the greatest landlord of the country, and is maintained
  • in the same manner as any other landlord, by a revenue derived from his
  • own private estate, or from what, in modern Europe, was called the demesne
  • of the crown. His subjects, upon ordinary occasions, contribute nothing to
  • his support, except when, in order to protect them from the oppression of
  • some of their fellow-subjects, they stand in need of his authority. The
  • presents which they make him upon such occasions constitute the whole
  • ordinary revenue, the whole of the emoluments which, except, perhaps, upon
  • some very extraordinary emergencies, he derives from his dominion over
  • them. When Agamemnon, in Homer, offers to Achilles, for his friendship,
  • the sovereignty of seven Greek cities, the sole advantage which he
  • mentions as likely to be derived from it was, that the people would honour
  • him with presents. As long as such presents, as long as the emoluments of
  • justice, or what may be called the fees of court, constituted, in this
  • manner, the whole ordinary revenue which the sovereign derived from his
  • sovereignty, it could not well be expected, it could not even decently be
  • proposed, that he should give them up altogether. It might, and it
  • frequently was proposed, that he should regulate and ascertain them. But
  • after they had been so regulated and ascertained, how to hinder a person
  • who was all-powerful from extending them beyond those regulations, was
  • still very difficult, not to say impossible. During the continuance of
  • this state of things, therefore, the corruption of justice, naturally
  • resulting from the arbitrary and uncertain nature of those presents,
  • scarce admitted of any effectual remedy.
  • But when, from different causes, chiefly from the continually increasing
  • expense of defending the nation against the invasion of other nations, the
  • private estate of the sovereign had become altogether insufficient for
  • defraying the expense of the sovereignty; and when it had become necessary
  • that the people should, for their own security, contribute towards this
  • expense by taxes of different kinds; it seems to have been very commonly
  • stipulated, that no present for the administration of justice should,
  • under any pretence, be accepted either by the sovereign, or by his
  • bailiffs and substitutes, the judges. Those presents, it seems to have
  • been supposed, could more easily be abolished altogether, than effectually
  • regulated and ascertained. Fixed salaries were appointed to the judges,
  • which were supposed to compensate to them the loss of whatever might have
  • been their share of the ancient emoluments of justice; as the taxes more
  • than compensated to the sovereign the loss of his. Justice was then said
  • to be administered gratis.
  • Justice, however, never was in reality administered gratis in any country.
  • Lawyers and attorneys, at least, must always be paid by the parties; and
  • if they were not, they would perform their duty still worse than they
  • actually perform it. The fees annually paid to lawyers and attorneys,
  • amount, in every court, to a much greater sum than the salaries of the
  • judges. The circumstance of those salaries being paid by the crown, can
  • nowhere much diminish the necessary expense of a law-suit. But it was not
  • so much to diminish the expense, as to prevent the corruption of justice,
  • that the judges were prohibited from receiving my present or fee from the
  • parties.
  • The office of judge is in itself so very honourable, that men are willing
  • to accept of it, though accompanied with very small emoluments. The
  • inferior office of justice of peace, though attended with a good deal of
  • trouble, and in most cases with no emoluments at all, is an object of
  • ambition to the greater part of our country gentlemen. The salaries of all
  • the different judges, high and low, together with the whole expense of the
  • administration and execution of justice, even where it is not managed with
  • very good economy, makes, in any civilized country, but a very
  • inconsiderable part of the whole expense of government.
  • The whole expense of justice, too, might easily be defrayed by the fees of
  • court; and, without exposing the administration of justice to any real
  • hazard of corruption, the public revenue might thus be entirely discharged
  • from a certain, though perhaps but a small incumbrance. It is difficult to
  • regulate the fees of court effectually, where a person so powerful as the
  • sovereign is to share in them and to derive any considerable part of his
  • revenue from them. It is very easy, where the judge is the principal
  • person who can reap any benefit from them. The law can very easily oblige
  • the judge to respect the regulation though it might not always be able to
  • make the sovereign respect it. Where the fees of court are precisely
  • regulated and ascertained where they are paid all at once, at a certain
  • period of every process, into the hands of a cashier or receiver, to be by
  • him distributed in certain known proportions among the different judges
  • after the process is decided and not till it is decided; there seems to be
  • no more danger of corruption than when such fees are prohibited
  • altogether. Those fees, without occasioning any considerable increase in
  • the expense of a law-suit, might be rendered fully sufficient for
  • defraying the whole expense of justice. But not being paid to the judges
  • till the process was determined, they might be some incitement to the
  • diligence of the court in examining and deciding it. In courts which
  • consisted of a considerable number of judges, by proportioning the share
  • of each judge to the number of hours and days which he had employed in
  • examining the process, either in the court, or in a committee, by order of
  • the court, those fees might give some encouragement to the diligence of
  • each particular judge. Public services are never better performed, than
  • when their reward comes only in consequence of their being performed, and
  • is proportioned to the diligence employed in performing them. In the
  • different parliaments of France, the fees of court (called epices and
  • vacations) constitute the far greater part of the emoluments of the
  • judges. After all deductions are made, the neat salary paid by the crown
  • to a counsellor or judge in the parliament of Thoulouse, in rank and
  • dignity the second parliament of the kingdom, amounts only to 150 livres,
  • about £6:11s. sterling a-year. About seven years ago, that sum was in the
  • same place the ordinary yearly wages of a common footman. The distribution
  • of these epices, too, is according to the diligence of the judges. A
  • diligent judge gains a comfortable, though moderate revenue, by his
  • office; an idle one gets little more than his salary. Those parliaments
  • are, perhaps, in many respects, not very convenient courts of justice; but
  • they have never been accused; they seem never even to have been suspected
  • of corruption.
  • The fees of court seem originally to have been the principal support of
  • the different courts of justice in England. Each court endeavoured to draw
  • to itself as much business as it could, and was, upon that account,
  • willing to take cognizance of many suits which were not originally
  • intended to fall under its jurisdiction. The court of king’s bench,
  • instituted for the trial of criminal causes only, took cognizance of civil
  • suits; the plaintiff pretending that the defendant, in not doing him
  • justice, had been guilty of some trespass or misdemeanour. The court of
  • exchequer, instituted for the levying of the king’s revenue, and for
  • enforcing the payment of such debts only as were due to the king, took
  • cognizance of all other contract debts; the planitiff alleging that he
  • could not pay the king, because the defendant would not pay him. In
  • consequence of such fictions, it came, in many cases, to depend altogether
  • upon the parties, before what court they would choose to have their cause
  • tried, and each court endeavoured, by superior dispatch and impartiality,
  • to draw to itself as many causes as it could. The present admirable
  • constitution of the courts of justice in England was, perhaps, originally,
  • in a great measure, formed by this emulation, which anciently took place
  • between their respective judges: each judge endeavouring to give, in his
  • own court, the speediest and most effectual remedy which the law would
  • admit, for every sort of injustice. Originally, the courts of law gave
  • damages only for breach of contract. The court of chancery, as a court of
  • conscience, first took upon it to enforce the specific performance of
  • agreements. When the breach of contract consisted in the non-payment of
  • money, the damage sustained could be compensated in no other way than by
  • ordering payment, which was equivalent to a specific performance of the
  • agreement. In such cases, therefore, the remedy of the courts of law was
  • sufficient. It was not so in others. When the tenant sued his lord for
  • having unjustly outed him of his lease, the damages which he recovered
  • were by no means equivalent to the possession of the land. Such causes,
  • therefore, for some time, went all to the court of chancery, to the no
  • small loss of the courts of law. It was to draw back such causes to
  • themselves, that the courts of law are said to have invented the
  • artificial and fictitious writ of ejectment, the most effectual remedy for
  • an unjust outer or dispossession of land.
  • A stamp-duty upon the law proceedings of each particular court, to be
  • levied by that court, and applied towards the maintenance of the judges,
  • and other officers belonging to it, might in the same manner, afford a
  • revenue sufficient for defraying the expense of the administration of
  • justice, without bringing any burden upon the general revenue of the
  • society. The judges, indeed, might in this case, be under the temptation
  • of multiplying unnecessarily the proceedings upon every cause, in order to
  • increase, as much as possible, the produce of such a stamp-duty. It has
  • been the custom in modern Europe to regulate, upon most occasions, the
  • payment of the attorneys and clerks of court according to the number of
  • pages which they had occasion to write; the court, however, requiring that
  • each page should contain so many lines, and each line so many words. In
  • order to increase their payment, the attorneys and clerks have contrived
  • to multiply words beyond all necessity, to the corruption of the law
  • language of, I believe, every court of justice in Europe. A like
  • temptation might, perhaps, occasion a like corruption in the form of law
  • proceedings.
  • But whether the administration of justice be so contrived as to defray its
  • own expense, or whether the judges be maintained by fixed salaries paid to
  • them from some other fund, it does not seen necessary that the person or
  • persons entrusted with the executive power should be charged with the
  • management of that fund, or with the payment of those salaries. That fund
  • might arise from the rent of landed estates, the management of each estate
  • being entrusted to the particular court which was to be maintained by it.
  • That fund might arise even from the interest of a sum of money, the
  • lending out of which might, in the same manner, be entrusted to the court
  • which was to be maintained by it. A part, though indeed but a small part
  • of the salary of the judges of the court of session in Scotland, arises
  • from the interest of a sum of money. The necessary instability of such a
  • fund seems, however, to render it an improper one for the maintenance of
  • an institution which ought to last for ever.
  • The separation of the judicial from the executive power, seems originally
  • to have arisen from the increasing business of the society, in consequence
  • of its increasing improvement. The administration of justice became so
  • laborious and so complicated a duty, as to require the undivided attention
  • of the person to whom it was entrusted. The person entrusted with the
  • executive power, not having leisure to attend to the decision of private
  • causes himself, a deputy was appointed to decide them in his stead. In the
  • progress of the Roman greatness, the consul was too much occupied with the
  • political affairs of the state, to attend to the administration of
  • justice. A praetor, therefore, was appointed to administer it in his
  • stead. In the progress of the European monarchies, which were founded upon
  • the ruins of the Roman empire, the sovereigns and the great lords came
  • universally to consider the administration of justice as an office both
  • too laborious and too ignoble for them to execute in their own persons.
  • They universally, therefore, discharged themselves of it, by appointing a
  • deputy, bailiff or judge.
  • When the judicial is united to the executive power, it is scarce possible
  • that justice should not frequently be sacrificed to what is vulgarly
  • called politics. The persons entrusted with the great interests of the
  • state may even without any corrupt views, sometimes imagine it necessary
  • to sacrifice to those interests the rights of a private man. But upon the
  • impartial administration of justice depends the liberty of every
  • individual, the sense which he has of his own security. In order to make
  • every individual feel himself perfectly secure in the possession of every
  • right which belongs to him, it is not only necessary that the judicial
  • should be separated from the executive power, but that it should be
  • rendered as much as possible independent of that power. The judge should
  • not be liable to be removed from his office according to the caprice of
  • that power. The regular payment of his salary should not depend upon the
  • good will, or even upon the good economy of that power.
  • PART III. Of the Expense of public Works and public Institutions.
  • The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth, is that of
  • erecting and maintaining those public institutions and those public works,
  • which though they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great
  • society, are, however, of such a nature, that the profit could never repay
  • the expense to any individual, or small number of individuals; and which
  • it, therefore, cannot be expected that any individual, or small number of
  • individuals, should erect or maintain. The performance of this duty
  • requires, too, very different degrees of expense in the different periods
  • of society.
  • After the public institutions and public works necessary for the defence
  • of the society, and for the administration of justice, both of which have
  • already been mentioned, the other works and institutions of this kind are
  • chiefly for facilitating the commerce of the society, and those for
  • promoting the instruction of the people. The institutions for instruction
  • are of two kinds: those for the education of the youth, and those for the
  • instruction of people of all ages. The consideration of the manner in
  • which the expense of those different sorts of public works and
  • institutions may be most properly defrayed will divide this third part of
  • the present chapter into three different articles.
  • ARTICLE I.—Of the public Works and Institutions for facilitating the
  • Commerce of the Society.
  • And, first, of those which are necessary for facilitating Commerce in
  • general.
  • That the erection and maintenance of the public works which facilitate the
  • commerce of any country, such as good roads, bridges, navigable canals,
  • harbours, etc. must require very different degrees of expense in the
  • different periods of society, is evident without any proof. The expense of
  • making and maintaining the public roads of any country must evidently
  • increase with the annual produce of the land and labour of that country,
  • or with the quantity and weight of the goods which it becomes necessary to
  • fetch and carry upon those roads. The strength of a bridge must be suited
  • to the number and weight of the carriages which are likely to pass over
  • it. The depth and the supply of water for a navigable canal must be
  • proportioned to the number and tonnage of the lighters which are likely to
  • carry goods upon it; the extent of a harbour, to the number of the
  • shipping which are likely to take shelter in it.
  • It does not seem necessary that the expense of those public works should
  • be defrayed from that public revenue, as it is commonly called, of which
  • the collection and application are in most countries, assigned to the
  • executive power. The greater part of such public works may easily be so
  • managed, as to afford a particular revenue, sufficient for defraying their
  • own expense without bringing any burden upon the general revenue of the
  • society.
  • A highway, a bridge, a navigable canal, for example, may, in most cases,
  • be both made add maintained by a small toll upon the carriages which make
  • use of them; a harbour, by a moderate port-duty upon the tonnage of the
  • shipping which load or unload in it. The coinage, another institution for
  • facilitating commerce, in many countries, not only defrays its own
  • expense, but affords a small revenue or a seignorage to the sovereign. The
  • post-office, another institution for the same purpose, over and above
  • defraying its own expense, affords, in almost all countries, a very
  • considerable revenue to the sovereign.
  • When the carriages which pass over a highway or a bridge, and the lighters
  • which sail upon a navigable canal, pay toll in proportion to their weight
  • or their tonnage, they pay for the maintenance of those public works
  • exactly in proportion to the wear and tear which they occasion of them. It
  • seems scarce possible to invent a more equitable way of maintaining such
  • works. This tax or toll, too, though it is advanced by the carrier, is
  • finally paid by the consumer, to whom it must always be charged in the
  • price of the goods. As the expense of carriage, however, is very much
  • reduced by means of such public works, the goods, notwithstanding the
  • toll, come cheaper to the consumer than they could otherwise have done,
  • their price not being so much raised by the toll, as it is lowered by the
  • cheapness of the carriage. The person who finally pays this tax,
  • therefore, gains by the application more than he loses by the payment of
  • it. His payment is exactly in proportion to his gain. It is, in reality,
  • no more than a part of that gain which he is obliged to give up, in order
  • to get the rest. It seems impossible to imagine a more equitable method of
  • raising a tax. When the toll upon carriages of luxury, upon coaches,
  • post-chaises, etc. is made somewhat higher in proportion to their weight,
  • than upon carriages of necessary use, such as carts, waggons, etc. the
  • indolence and vanity of the rich is made to contribute, in a very easy
  • manner, to the relief of the poor, by rendering cheaper the transportation
  • of heavy goods to all the different parts of the country.
  • When high-roads, bridges, canals, etc. are in this manner made and
  • supported by the commerce which is carried on by means of them, they can
  • be made only where that commerce requires them, and, consequently, where
  • it is proper to make them. Their expense, too, their grandeur and
  • magnificence, must be suited to what that commerce can afford to pay. They
  • must be made, consequently, as it is proper to make them. A magnificent
  • high-road cannot be made through a desert country, where there is little
  • or no commerce, or merely because it happens to lead to the country villa
  • of the intendant of the province, or to that of some great lord, to whom
  • the intendant finds it convenient to make his court. A great bridge cannot
  • be thrown over a river at a place where nobody passes, or merely to
  • embellish the view from the windows of a neighbouring palace; things which
  • sometimes happen in countries, where works of this kind are carried on by
  • any other revenue than that which they themselves are capable of
  • affording.
  • In several different parts of Europe, the toll or lock-duty upon a canal
  • is the property of private persons, whose private interest obliges them to
  • keep up the canal. If it is not kept in tolerable order, the navigation
  • necessarily ceases altogether, and, along with it, the whole profit which
  • they can make by the tolls. If those tolls were put under the management
  • of commissioners, who had themselves no interest in them, they might be
  • less attentive to the maintenance of the works which produced them. The
  • canal of Languedoc cost the king of France and the province upwards of
  • thirteen millions of livres, which (at twenty-eight livres the mark of
  • silver, the value of French money in the end of the last century) amounted
  • to upwards of nine hundred thousand pounds sterling. When that great work
  • was finished, the most likely method, it was found, of keeping it in
  • constant repair, was to make a present of the tolls to Riquet, the
  • engineer who planned and conducted the work. Those tolls constitute, at
  • present, a very large estate to the different branches of the family of
  • that gentleman, who have, therefore, a great interest to keep the work in
  • constant repair. But had those tolls been put under the management of
  • commissioners, who had no such interest, they might perhaps, have been
  • dissipated in ornamental and unnecessary expenses, while the most
  • essential parts of the works were allowed to go to ruin.
  • The tolls for the maintenance of a highroad cannot, with any safety, be
  • made the property of private persons. A high-road, though entirely
  • neglected, does not become altogether impassable, though a canal does. The
  • proprietors of the tolls upon a high-road, therefore, might neglect
  • altogether the repair of the road, and yet continue to levy very nearly
  • the same tolls. It is proper, therefore, that the tolls for the
  • maintenance of such a work should be put under the management of
  • commissioners or trustees.
  • In Great Britain, the abuses which the trustees have committed in the
  • management of those tolls, have, in many cases, been very justly
  • complained of. At many turnpikes, it has been said, the money levied is
  • more than double of what is necessary for executing, in the completest
  • manner, the work, which is often executed in a very slovenly manner, and
  • sometimes not executed at all. The system of repairing the high-roads by
  • tolls of this kind, it must be observed, is not of very long standing. We
  • should not wonder, therefore, if it has not yet been brought to that
  • degree of perfection of which it seems capable. If mean and improper
  • persons are frequently appointed trustees; and if proper courts of
  • inspection and account have not yet been established for controlling their
  • conduct, and for reducing the tolls to what is barely sufficient for
  • executing the work to be done by them; the recency of the institution both
  • accounts and apologizes for those defects, of which, by the wisdom of
  • parliament, the greater part may, in due time, be gradually remedied.
  • The money levied at the different turnpikes in Great Britain, is supposed
  • to exceed so much what is necessary for repairing the roads, that the
  • savings which, with proper economy, might be made from it, have been
  • considered, even by some ministers, as a very great resource, which might,
  • at some time or another, be applied to the exigencies of the state.
  • Government, it has been said, by taking the management of the turnpikes
  • into its own hands, and by employing the soldiers, who would work for a
  • very small addition to their pay, could keep the roads in good order, at a
  • much less expense than it can be done by trustees, who have no other
  • workmen to employ, but such as derive their whole subsistence from their
  • wages. A great revenue, half a million, perhaps {Since publishing the two
  • first editions of this book, I have got good reasons to believe that all
  • the turnpike tolls levied in Great Britain do not produce a neat revenue
  • that amounts to half a million; a sum which, under the management of
  • government, would not be sufficient to keep, in repair five of the
  • principal roads in the kingdom}, it has been pretended, might in this
  • manner be gained, without laying any new burden upon the people; and the
  • turnpike roads might be made to contribute to the general expense of the
  • state, in the same manner as the post-office does at present.
  • That a considerable revenue might be gained in this manner, I have no
  • doubt, though probably not near so much as the projectors of this plan
  • have supposed. The plan itself, however, seems liable to several very
  • important objections.
  • First, If the tolls which are levied at the turnpikes should ever be
  • considered as one of the resources for supplying the exigencies of the
  • state, they would certainly be augmented as those exigencies were supposed
  • to require. According to the policy of Great Britain, therefore, they
  • would probably he augmented very fast. The facility with which a great
  • revenue could be drawn from them, would probably encourage administration
  • to recur very frequently te this resource. Though it may, perhaps, be more
  • than doubtful whether half a million could by any economy be saved out of
  • the present tolls, it can scarcely be doubted, but that a million might be
  • saved out of them, if they were doubled; and perhaps two millions, if they
  • were tripled {I have now good reason to believe that all these conjectural
  • sums are by much too large.}. This great revenue, too, might be levied
  • without the appointment of a single new officer to collect and receive it.
  • But the turnpike tolls, being continually augmented in this manner,
  • instead of facilitating the inland commerce of the country, as at present,
  • would soon become a very great incumbrance upon it. The expense of
  • transporting all heavy goods from one part of the country to another,
  • would soon be so much increased, the market for all such goods,
  • consequently, would soon be so much narrowed, that their production would
  • be in a great measure discouraged, and the most important branches of the
  • domestic industry of the country annihilated altogether.
  • Secondly, A tax upon carriages, in proportion to their weight, though a
  • very equal tax when applied to the sole purpose of repairing the roads, is
  • a very unequal one when applied to any other purpose, or to supply the
  • common exigencies of the state. When it is applied to the sole purpose
  • above mentioned, each carriage is supposed to pay exactly for the wear and
  • tear which that carriage occasions of the roads. But when it is applied to
  • any other purpose, each carriage is supposed to pay for more than that
  • wear and tear, and contributes to the supply of some other exigency of the
  • state. But as the turnpike toll raises the price of goods in proportion to
  • their weight and not to their value, it is chiefly paid by the consumers
  • of coarse and bulky, not by those of precious and light commodities.
  • Whatever exigency of the state, therefore, this tax might be intended to
  • supply, that exigency would be chiefly supplied at the expense of the
  • poor, not of the rich; at the expense of those who are least able to
  • supply it, not of those who are most able.
  • Thirdly, If government should at any time neglect the reparation of the
  • high-roads, it would be still more difficult, than it is at present, to
  • compel the proper application of any part of the turnpike tolls. A large
  • revenue might thus be levied upon the people, without any part of it being
  • applied to the only purpose to which a revenue levied in this manner ought
  • ever to be applied. If the meanness and poverty of the trustees of
  • turnpike roads render it sometimes difficult, at present, to oblige them
  • to repair their wrong; their wealth and greatness would render it ten
  • times more so in the case which is here supposed.
  • In France, the funds destined for the reparation of the high-roads are
  • under the immediate direction of the executive power. Those funds consist,
  • partly in a certain number of days labour, which the country people are in
  • most parts of Europe obliged to give to the reparation of the highways;
  • and partly in such a portion of the general revenue of the state as the
  • king chooses to spare from his other expenses.
  • By the ancient law of France, as well as by that of most other parts of
  • Europe, the labour of the country people was under the direction of a
  • local or provincial magistracy, which had no immediate dependency upon the
  • king’s council. But, by the present practice, both the labour of the
  • country people, and whatever other fund the king may choose to assign for
  • the reparation of the high-roads in any particular province or generality,
  • are entirely under the management of the intendant; an officer who is
  • appointed and removed by the king’s council who receives his orders from
  • it, and is in constant correspondence with it. In the progress of
  • despotism, the authority of the executive power gradually absorbs that of
  • every other power in the state, and assumes to itself the management of
  • every branch of revenue which is destined for any public purpose. In
  • France, however, the great post-roads, the roads which make the
  • communication between the principal towns of the kingdom, are in general
  • kept in good order; and, in some provinces, are even a good deal superior
  • to the greater part of the turnpike roads of England. But what we call the
  • cross roads, that is, the far greater part of the roads in the country,
  • are entirely neglected, and are in many places absolutely impassable for
  • any heavy carriage. In some places it is even dangerous to travel on
  • horseback, and mules are the only conveyance which can safely be trusted.
  • The proud minister of an ostentatious court, may frequently take pleasure
  • in executing a work of splendour and magnificence, such as a great
  • highway, which is frequently seen by the principal nobility, whose
  • applauses not only flatter his vanity, but even contribute to support his
  • interest at court. But to execute a great number of little works, in which
  • nothing that can be done can make any great appearance, or excite the
  • smallest degree of admiration in any traveller, and which, in short, have
  • nothing to recommend them but their extreme utility, is a business which
  • appears, in every respect, too mean and paltry to merit the attention of
  • so great a magistrate. Under such an administration therefore, such works
  • are almost always entirely neglected.
  • In China, and in several other governments of Asia, the executive power
  • charges itself both with the reparation of the high-roads, and with the
  • maintenance of the navigable canals. In the instructions which are given
  • to the governor of each province, those objects, it is said, are
  • constantly recommended to him, and the judgment which the court forms of
  • his conduct is very much regulated by the attention which he appears to
  • have paid to this part of his instructions. This branch of public police,
  • accordingly, is said to be very much attended to in all those countries,
  • but particularly in China, where the high-roads, and still more the
  • navigable canals, it is pretended, exceed very much every thing of the
  • same kind which is known in Europe. The accounts of those works, however,
  • which have been transmitted to Europe, have generally been drawn up by
  • weak and wondering travellers; frequently by stupid and lying
  • missionaries. If they had been examined by more intelligent eyes, and if
  • the accounts of them had been reported by more faithful witnesses, they
  • would not, perhaps, appear to be so wonderful. The account which Bernier
  • gives of some works of this kind in Indostan, falls very short of what had
  • been reported of them by other travellers, more disposed to the marvellous
  • than he was. It may too, perhaps, be in those countries, as it is in
  • France, where the great roads, the great communications, which are likely
  • to be the subjects of conversation at the court and in the capital, are
  • attended to, and all the rest neglected. In China, besides, in Indostan,
  • and in several other governments of Asia, the revenue of the sovereign
  • arises almost altogether from a land tax or land rent, which rises or
  • falls with the rise and fall of the annual produce of the land. The great
  • interest of the sovereign, therefore, his revenue, is in such countries
  • necessarily and immediately connected with the cultivation of the land,
  • with the greatness of its produce, and with the value of its produce. But
  • in order to render that produce both as great and as valuable as possible,
  • it is necessary to procure to it as extensive a market as possible, and
  • consequently to establish the freest, the easiest, and the least expensive
  • communication between all the different parts of the country; which can be
  • done only by means of the best roads and the best navigable canals. But
  • the revenue of the sovereign does not, in any part of Europe, arise
  • chiefly from a land tax or land rent. In all the great kingdoms of Europe,
  • perhaps, the greater part of it may ultimately depend upon the produce of
  • the land: but that dependency is neither so immediate nor so evident. In
  • Europe, therefore, the sovereign does not feel himself so directly called
  • upon to promote the increase, both in quantity and value of the produce of
  • the land, or, by maintaining good roads and canals, to provide the most
  • extensive market for that produce. Though it should be true, therefore,
  • what I apprehend is not a little doubtful, that in some parts of Asia this
  • department of the public police is very properly managed by the executive
  • power, there is not the least probability that, during the present state
  • of things, it could be tolerably managed by that power in any part of
  • Europe.
  • Even those public works, which are of such a nature that they cannot
  • afford any revenue for maintaining themselves, but of which the
  • conveniency is nearly confined to some particular place or district, are
  • always better maintained by a local or provincial revenue, under the
  • management of a local and provincial administration, than by the general
  • revenue of the state, of which the executive power must always have the
  • management. Were the streets of London to be lighted and paved at the
  • expense of the treasury, is there any probability that they would be so
  • well lighted and paved as they are at present, or even at so small an
  • expense? The expense, besides, instead of being raised by a local tax upon
  • the inhabitants of each particular street, parish, or district in London,
  • would, in this case, be defrayed out of the general revenue of the state,
  • and would consequently be raised by a tax upon all the inhabitants of the
  • kingdom, of whom the greater part derive no sort of benefit from the
  • lighting and paving of the streets of London.
  • The abuses which sometimes creep into the local and provincial
  • administration of a local and provincial revenue, how enormous soever they
  • may appear, are in reality, however, almost always very trifling in
  • comparison of those which commonly take place in the administration and
  • expenditure of the revenue of a great empire. They are, besides, much more
  • easily corrected. Under the local or provincial administration of the
  • justices of the peace in Great Britain, the six days labour which the
  • country people are obliged to give to the reparation of the highways, is
  • not always, perhaps, very judiciously applied, but it is scarce ever
  • exacted with any circumstance of cruelty or oppression. In France, under
  • the administration of the intendants, the application is not always more
  • judicious, and the exaction is frequently the most cruel and oppressive.
  • Such corvees, as they are called, make one of the principal instruments of
  • tyranny by which those officers chastise any parish or communeaute, which
  • has had the misfortune to fall under their displeasure.
  • Of the public Works and Institution which are necessary for facilitating
  • particular Branches of Commerce.
  • The object of the public works and institutions above mentioned, is to
  • facilitate commerce in general. But in order to facilitate some particular
  • branches of it, particular institutions are necessary, which again require
  • a particular and extraordinary expense.
  • Some particular branches of commerce which are carried on with barbarous
  • and uncivilized nations, require extraordinary protection. An ordinary
  • store or counting-house could give little security to the goods of the
  • merchants who trade to the western coast of Africa. To defend them from
  • the barbarous natives, it is necessary that the place where they are
  • deposited should be in some measure fortified. The disorders in the
  • government of Indostan have been supposed to render a like precaution
  • necessary, even among that mild and gentle people; and it was under
  • pretence of securing their persons and property from violence, that both
  • the English and French East India companies were allowed to erect the
  • first forts which they possessed in that country. Among other nations,
  • whose vigorous government will suffer no strangers to possess any
  • fortified place within their territory, it may be necessary to maintain
  • some ambassador, minister, or consul, who may both decide, according to
  • their own customs, the differences arising among his own countrymen, and,
  • in their disputes with the natives, may by means of his public character,
  • interfere with more authority and afford them a more powerful protection
  • than they could expect from any private man. The interests of commerce
  • have frequently made it necessary to maintain ministers in foreign
  • countries, where the purposes either of war or alliance would not have
  • required any. The commerce of the Turkey company first occasioned the
  • establishment of an ordinary ambassador at Constantinople. The first
  • English embassies to Russia arose altogether from commercial interests.
  • The constant interference with those interests, necessarily occasioned
  • between the subjects of the different states of Europe, has probably
  • introduced the custom of keeping, in all neighbouring countries,
  • ambassadors or ministers constantly resident, even in the time of peace.
  • This custom, unknown to ancient times, seems not to be older than the end
  • of the fifteenth, or beginning of the sixteenth century; that is, than the
  • time when commerce first began to extend itself to the greater part of the
  • nations of Europe, and when they first began to attend to its interests.
  • It seems not unreasonable, that the extraordinary expense which the
  • protection of any particular branch of commerce may occasion, should be
  • defrayed by a moderate tax upon that particular branch; by a moderate
  • fine, for example, to be paid by the traders when they first enter into
  • it; or, what is more equal, by a particular duty of so much per cent. upon
  • the goods which they either import into, or export out of, the particular
  • countries with which it is carried on. The protection of trade, in
  • general, from pirates and freebooters, is said to have given occasion to
  • the first institution of the duties of customs. But, if it was thought
  • reasonable to lay a general tax upon trade, in order to defray the expense
  • of protecting trade in general, it should seem equally reasonable to lay a
  • particular tax upon a particular branch of trade, in order to defray the
  • extraordinary expense of protecting that branch.
  • The protection of trade, in general, has always been considered as
  • essential to the defence of the commonwealth, and, upon that account, a
  • necessary part of the duty of the executive power. The collection and
  • application of the general duties of customs, therefore, have always been
  • left to that power. But the protection of any particular branch of trade
  • is a part of the general protection of trade; a part, therefore, of the
  • duty of that power; and if nations always acted consistently, the
  • particular duties levied for the purposes of such particular protection,
  • should always have been left equally to its disposal. But in this respect,
  • as well as in many others, nations have not always acted consistently; and
  • in the greater part of the commercial states of Europe, particular
  • companies of merchants have had the address to persuade the legislature to
  • entrust to them the performance of this part of the duty of the sovereign,
  • together with all the powers which are necessarily connected with it.
  • These companies, though they may, perhaps, have been useful for the first
  • introduction of some branches of commerce, by making, at their own
  • expense, an experiment which the state might not think it prudent to make,
  • have in the long-run proved, universally, either burdensome or useless,
  • and have either mismanaged or confined the trade.
  • When those companies do not trade upon a joint stock, but are obliged to
  • admit any person, properly qualified, upon paying a certain fine, and
  • agreeing to submit to the regulations of the company, each member trading
  • upon his own stock, and at his own risk, they are called regulated
  • companies. When they trade upon a joint stock, each member sharing in the
  • common profit or loss, in proportion to his share in this stock, they are
  • called joint-stock companies. Such companies, whether regulated or
  • joint-stock, sometimes have, and sometimes have not, exclusive privileges.
  • Regulated companies resemble, in every respect, the corporation of trades,
  • so common in the cities and towns of all the different countries of
  • Europe; and are a sort of enlarged monopolies of the same kind. As no
  • inhabitant of a town can exercise an incorporated trade, without first
  • obtaining his freedom in the incorporation, so, in most cases, no subject
  • of the state can lawfully carry on any branch of foreign trade, for which
  • a regulated company is established, without first becoming a member of
  • that company. The monopoly is more or less strict, according as the terms
  • of admission are more or less difficult, and according as the directors of
  • the company have more or less authority, or have it more or less in their
  • power to manage in such a manner as to confine the greater part of the
  • trade to themselves and their particular friends. In the most ancient
  • regulated companies, the privileges of apprenticeship were the same as in
  • other corporations, and entitled the person who had served his time to a
  • member of the company, to become himself a member, either without paying
  • any fine, or upon paying a much smaller one than what was exacted of other
  • people. The usual corporation spirit, wherever the law does not restrain
  • it, prevails in all regulated companies. When they have been allowed to
  • act according to their natural genius, they have always, in order to
  • confine the competition to as small a number of persons as possible,
  • endeavoured to subject the trade to many burdensome regulations. When the
  • law has restrained them from doing this, they have become altogether
  • useless and insignificant.
  • The regulated companies for foreign commerce which at present subsist in
  • Great Britain, are the ancient merchant-adventurers company, now commonly
  • called the Hamburgh company, the Russia company, the Eastland company, the
  • Turkey company, and the African company.
  • The terms of admission into the Hamburgh company are now said to be quite
  • easy; and the directors either have it not in their power to subject the
  • trade to any troublesome restraint or regulations, or, at least, have not
  • of late exercised that power. It has not always been so. About the middle
  • of the last century, the fine for admission was fifty, and at one time one
  • hundred pounds, and the conduct of the company was said to be extremely
  • oppressive. In 1643, in 1645, and in 1661, the clothiers and free traders
  • of the west of England complained of them to parliament, as of
  • monopolists, who confined the trade, and oppressed the manufactures of the
  • country. Though those complaints produced no act of parliament, they had
  • probably intimidated the company so far, as to oblige them to reform their
  • conduct. Since that time, at least, there have been no complaints against
  • them. By the 10th and 11th of William III. c.6, the fine for admission
  • into the Russia company was reduced to five pounds; and by the 25th of
  • Charles II. c.7, that for admission into the Eastland company to forty
  • shillings; while, at the same time, Sweden, Denmark, and Norway, all the
  • countries on the north side of the Baltic, were exempted from their
  • exclusive charter. The conduct of those companies had probably given
  • occasion to those two acts of parliament. Before that time, Sir Josiah
  • Child had represented both these and the Hamburgh company as extremely
  • oppressive, and imputed to their bad management the low state of the
  • trade, which we at that time carried on to the countries comprehended
  • within their respective charters. But though such companies may not, in
  • the present times, be very oppressive, they are certainly altogether
  • useless. To be merely useless, indeed, is perhaps, the highest eulogy
  • which can ever justly be bestowed upon a regulated company; and all the
  • three companies above mentioned seem, in their present state, to deserve
  • this eulogy.
  • The fine for admission into the Turkey company was formerly twenty-five
  • pounds for all persons under twenty-six years of age, and fifty pounds for
  • all persons above that age. Nobody but mere merchants could be admitted; a
  • restriction which excluded all shop-keepers and retailers. By a bye-law,
  • no British manufactures could be exported to Turkey but in the general
  • ships of the company; and as those ships sailed always from the port of
  • London, this restriction confined the trade to that expensive port, and
  • the traders to those who lived in London and in its neighbourhood. By
  • another bye-law, no person living within twenty miles of London, and not
  • free of the city, could be admitted a member; another restriction which,
  • joined to the foregoing, necessarily excluded all but the freemen of
  • London. As the time for the loading and sailing of those general ships
  • depended altogether upon the directors, they could easily fill them with
  • their own goods, and those of their particular friends, to the exclusion
  • of others, who, they might pretend, had made their proposals too late. In
  • this state of things, therefore, this company was, in every respect, a
  • strict and oppressive monopoly. Those abuses gave occasion to the act of
  • the 26th of George II. c. 18, reducing the fine for admission to twenty
  • pounds for all persons, without any distinction of ages, or any
  • restriction, either to mere merchants, or to the freemen of London; and
  • granting to all such persons the liberty of exporting, from all the ports
  • of Great Britain, to any port in Turkey, all British goods, of which the
  • exportation was not prohibited, upon paying both the general duties of
  • customs, and the particular duties assessed for defraying the necessary
  • expenses of the company; and submitting, at the same time, to the lawful
  • authority of the British ambassador and consuls resident in Turkey, and to
  • the bye-laws of the company duly enacted. To prevent any oppression by
  • those bye-laws, it was by the same act ordained, that if any seven members
  • of the company conceived themselves aggrieved by any bye-law which should
  • be enacted after the passing of this act, they might appeal to the board
  • of trade and plantations (to the authority of which a committee of the
  • privy council has now succeeded), provided such appeal was brought within
  • twelve months after the bye-law was enacted; and that, if any seven
  • members conceived themselves aggrieved by any bye-law which had been
  • enacted before the passing of this act, they might bring a like appeal,
  • provided it was within twelve months after the day on which this act was
  • to take place. The experience of one year, however, may not always be
  • sufficient to discover to all the members of a great company the
  • pernicious tendency of a particular bye-law; and if several of them should
  • afterwards discover it, neither the board of trade, nor the committee of
  • council, can afford them any redress. The object, besides, of the greater
  • part of the bye-laws of all regulated companies, as well as of all other
  • corporations, is not so much to oppress those who are already members, as
  • to discourage others from becoming so; which may be done, not only by a
  • high fine, but by many other contrivances. The constant view of such
  • companies is always to raise the rate of their own profit as high as they
  • can; to keep the market, both for the goods which they export, and for
  • those which they import, as much understocked as they can; which can be
  • done only by restraining the competition, or by discouraging new
  • adventurers from entering into the trade. A fine, even of twenty pounds,
  • besides, though it may not, perhaps, be sufficient to discourage any man
  • from entering into the Turkey trade, with an intention to continue in it,
  • may be enough to discourage a speculative merchant from hazarding a single
  • adventure in it. In all trades, the regular established traders, even
  • though not incorporated, naturally combine to raise profits, which are
  • noway so likely to be kept, at all times, down to their proper level, as
  • by the occasional competition of speculative adventurers. The Turkey
  • trade, though in some measure laid open by this act of parliament, is
  • still considered by many people as very far from being altogether free.
  • The Turkey company contribute to maintain an ambassador and two or three
  • consuls, who, like other public ministers, ought to be maintained
  • altogether by the state, and the trade laid open to all his majesty’s
  • subjects. The different taxes levied by the company, for this and other
  • corporation purposes, might afford a revenue much more than sufficient to
  • enable a state to maintain such ministers.
  • Regulated companies, it was observed by Sir Josiah Child, though they had
  • frequently supported public ministers, had never maintained any forts or
  • garrisons in the countries to which they traded; whereas joint-stock
  • companies frequently had. And, in reality, the former seem to be much more
  • unfit for this sort of service than the latter. First, the directors of a
  • regulated company have no particular interest in the prosperity of the
  • general trade of the company, for the sake of which such forts and
  • garrisons are maintained. The decay of that general trade may even
  • frequently contribute to the advantage of their own private trade; as, by
  • diminishing the number of their competitors, it may enable them both to
  • buy cheaper, and to sell dearer. The directors of a joint-stock company,
  • on the contrary, having only their share in the profits which are made
  • upon the common stock committed to their management, have no private trade
  • of their own, of which the interest can be separated from that of the
  • general trade of the company. Their private interest is connected with the
  • prosperity of the general trade of the company, and with the maintenance
  • of the forts and garrisons which are necessary for its defence. They are
  • more likely, therefore, to have that continual and careful attention which
  • that maintenance necessarily requires. Secondly, The directors of a
  • joint-stock company have always the management of a large capital, the
  • joint stock of the company, a part of which they may frequently employ,
  • with propriety, in building, repairing, and maintaining such necessary
  • forts and garrisons. But the directors of a regulated company, having the
  • management of no common capital, have no other fund to employ in this way,
  • but the casual revenue arising from the admission fines, and from the
  • corporation duties imposed upon the trade of the company. Though they had
  • the same interest, therefore, to attend to the maintenance of such forts
  • and garrisons, they can seldom have the same ability to render that
  • attention effectual. The maintenance of a public minister, requiring
  • scarce any attention, and but a moderate and limited expense, is a
  • business much more suitable both to the temper and abilities of a
  • regulated company.
  • Long after the time of Sir Josiah Child, however, in 1750, a regulated
  • company was established, the present company of merchants trading to
  • Africa; which was expressly charged at first with the maintenance of all
  • the British forts and garrisons that lie between Cape Blanc and the Cape
  • of Good Hope, and afterwards with that of those only which lie between
  • Cape Rouge and the Cape of Good Hope. The act which establishes this
  • company (the 23rd of George II. c.51 ), seems to have had two distinct
  • objects in view; first, to restrain effectually the oppressive and
  • monopolizing spirit which is natural to the directors of a regulated
  • company; and, secondly, to force them, as much as possible, to give an
  • attention, which is not natural to them, towards the maintenance of forts
  • and garrisons.
  • For the first of these purposes, the fine for admission is limited to
  • forty shillings. The company is prohibited from trading in their corporate
  • capacity, or upon a joint stock; from borrowing money upon common seal, or
  • from laying any restraints upon the trade, which may be carried on freely
  • from all places, and by all persons being British subjects, and paying the
  • fine. The government is in a committee of nine persons, who meet at
  • London, but who are chosen annually by the freemen of the company at
  • London, Bristol, and Liverpool; three from each place. No committeeman can
  • be continued in office for more than three years together. Any
  • committee-man might be removed by the board of trade and plantations, now
  • by a committee of council, after being heard in his own defence. The
  • committee are forbid to export negroes from Africa, or to import any
  • African goods into Great Britain. But as they are charged with the
  • maintenance of forts and garrisons, they may, for that purpose export from
  • Great Britain to Africa goods and stores of different kinds. Out of the
  • moneys which they shall receive from the company, they are allowed a sum,
  • not exceeding eight hundred pounds, for the salaries of their clerks and
  • agents at London, Bristol, and Liverpool, the house-rent of their offices
  • at London, and all other expenses of management, commission, and agency,
  • in England. What remains of this sum, after defraying these different
  • expenses, they may divide among themselves, as compensation for their
  • trouble, in what manner they think proper. By this constitution, it might
  • have been expected, that the spirit of monopoly would have been
  • effectually restrained, and the first of these purposes sufficiently
  • answered. It would seem, however, that it had not. Though by the 4th of
  • George III. c.20, the fort of Senegal, with all its dependencies, had been
  • invested in the company of merchants trading to Africa, yet, in the year
  • following (by the 5th of George III. c.44), not only Senegal and its
  • dependencies, but the whole coast, from the port of Sallee, in South
  • Barbary, to Cape Rouge, was exempted from the jurisdiction of that
  • company, was vested in the crown, and the trade to it declared free to all
  • his majesty’s subjects. The company had been suspected of restraining the
  • trade and of establishing some sort of improper monopoly. It is not,
  • however, very easy to conceive how, under the regulations of the 23d
  • George II. they could do so. In the printed debates of the house of
  • commons, not always the most authentic records of truth, I observe,
  • however, that they have been accused of this. The members of the committee
  • of nine being all merchants, and the governors and factors in their
  • different forts and settlements being all dependent upon them, it is not
  • unlikely that the latter might have given peculiar attention to the
  • consignments and commissions of the former, which would establish a real
  • monopoly.
  • For the second of these purposes, the maintenance of the forts and
  • garrisons, an annual sum has been allotted to them by parliament,
  • generally about £13,000. For the proper application of this sum, the
  • committee is obliged to account annually to the cursitor baron of
  • exchequer; which account is afterwards to be laid before parliament. But
  • parliament, which gives so little attention to the application of
  • millions, is not likely to give much to that of £13,000 a-year; and the
  • cursitor baron of exchequer, from his profession and education, is not
  • likely to be profoundly skilled in the proper expense of forts and
  • garrisons. The captains of his majesty’s navy, indeed, or any other
  • commissioned officers, appointed by the board of admiralty, may inquire
  • into the condition of the forts and garrisons, and report their
  • observations to that board. But that board seems to have no direct
  • jurisdiction over the committee, nor any authority to correct those whose
  • conduct it may thus inquire into; and the captains of his majesty’s navy,
  • besides, are not supposed to be always deeply learned in the science of
  • fortification. Removal from an office, which can be enjoyed only for the
  • term of three years, and of which the lawful emoluments, even during that
  • term, are so very small, seems to be the utmost punishment to which any
  • committee-man is liable, for any fault, except direct malversation, or
  • embezzlement, either of the public money, or of that of the company; and
  • the fear of the punishment can never be a motive of sufficient weight to
  • force a continual and careful attention to a business to which he has no
  • other interest to attend. The committee are accused of having sent out
  • bricks and stones from England for the reparation of Cape Coast Castle, on
  • the coast of Guinea; a business for which parliament had several times
  • granted an extraordinary sum of money. These bricks and stones, too, which
  • had thus been sent upon so long a voyage, were said to have been of so bad
  • a quality, that it was necessary to rebuild, from the foundation, the
  • walls which had been repaired with them. The forts and garrisons which lie
  • north of Cape Rouge, are not only maintained at the expense of the state,
  • but are under the immediate government of the executive power; and why
  • those which lie south of that cape, and which, too, are, in part at least,
  • maintained at the expense of the state, should be under a different
  • government, it seems not very easy even to imagine a good reason. The
  • protection of the Mediterranean trade was the original purpose or pretence
  • of the garrisons of Gibraltar and Minorca; and the maintenance and
  • government of those garrisons have always been, very properly, committed,
  • not to the Turkey company, but to the executive power. In the extent of
  • its dominion consists, in a great measure, the pride and dignity of that
  • power; and it is not very likely to fail in attention to what is necessary
  • for the defence of that dominion. The garrisons at Gibraltar and Minorca,
  • accordingly, have never been neglected. Though Minorca has been twice
  • taken, and is now probably lost for ever, that disaster has never been
  • imputed to any neglect in the executive power. I would not, however, be
  • understood to insinuate, that either of those expensive garrisons was
  • ever, even in the smallest degree, necessary for the purpose for which
  • they were originally dismembered from the Spanish monarchy. That
  • dismemberment, perhaps, never served any other real purpose than to
  • alienate from England her natural ally the king of Spain, and to unite the
  • two principal branches of the house of Bourbon in a much stricter and more
  • permanent alliance than the ties of blood could ever have united them.
  • Joint-stock companies, established either by royal charter, or by act of
  • parliament, are different in several respects, not only from regulated
  • companies, but from private copartneries.
  • First, In a private copartnery, no partner without the consent of the
  • company, can transfer his share to another person, or introduce a new
  • member into the company. Each member, however, may, upon proper warning,
  • withdraw from the copartnery, and demand payment from them of his share of
  • the common stock. In a joint-stock company, on the contrary, no member can
  • demand payment of his share from the company; but each member can, without
  • their consent, transfer his share to another person, and thereby introduce
  • a new member. The value of a share in a joint stock is always the price
  • which it will bring in the market; and this may be either greater or less
  • in any proportion, than the sum which its owner stands credited for in the
  • stock of the company.
  • Secondly, In a private copartnery, each partner is bound for the debts
  • contracted by the company, to the whole extent of his fortune. In a
  • joint-stock company, on the contrary, each partner is bound only to the
  • extent of his share.
  • The trade of a joint-stock company is always managed by a court of
  • directors. This court, indeed, is frequently subject, in many respects, to
  • the control of a general court of proprietors. But the greater part of
  • these proprietors seldom pretend to understand any thing of the business
  • of the company; and when the spirit of faction happens not to prevail
  • among them, give themselves no trouble about it, but receive contentedly
  • such halfyearly or yearly dividend as the directors think proper to make
  • to them. This total exemption front trouble and front risk, beyond a
  • limited sum, encourages many people to become adventurers in joint-stock
  • companies, who would, upon no account, hazard their fortunes in any
  • private copartnery. Such companies, therefore, commonly draw to themselves
  • much greater stocks, than any private copartnery can boast of. The trading
  • stock of the South Sea company at one time amounted to upwards of
  • thirty-three millions eight hundred thousand pounds. The divided capital
  • of the Bank of England amounts, at present, to ten millions seven hundred
  • and eighty thousand pounds. The directors of such companies, however,
  • being the managers rather of other people’s money than of their own, it
  • cannot well be expected that they should watch over it with the same
  • anxious vigilance with which the partners in a private copartnery
  • frequently watch over their own. Like the stewards of a rich man, they are
  • apt to consider attention to small matters as not for their master’s
  • honour, and very easily give themselves a dispensation from having it.
  • Negligence and profusion, therefore, must always prevail, more or less, in
  • the management of the affairs of such a company. It is upon this account,
  • that joint-stock companies for foreign trade have seldom been able to
  • maintain the competition against private adventurers. They have,
  • accordingly, very seldom succeeded without an exclusive privilege; and
  • frequently have not succeeded with one. Without an exclusive privilege,
  • they have commonly mismanaged the trade. With an exclusive privilege, they
  • have both mismanaged and confined it.
  • The Royal African company, the predecessors of the present African
  • company, had an exclusive privilege by charter; but as that charter had
  • not been confirmed by act of parliament, the trade, in consequence of the
  • declaration of rights, was, soon after the Revolution, laid open to all
  • his majesty’s subjects. The Hudson’s Bay company are, as to their legal
  • rights, in the same situation as the Royal African company. Their
  • exclusive charter has not been confirmed by act of parliament. The South
  • Sea company, as long as they continued to be a trading company, had an
  • exclusive privilege confirmed by act of parliament; as have likewise the
  • present united company of merchants trading to the East Indies.
  • The Royal African company soon found that they could not maintain the
  • competition against private adventurers, whom, notwithstanding the
  • declaration of rights, they continued for some time to call interlopers,
  • and to persecute as such. In 1698, however, the private adventurers were
  • subjected to a duty of ten per cent. upon almost all the different
  • branches of their trade, to be employed by the company in the maintenance
  • of their forts and garrisons. But, notwithstanding this heavy tax, the
  • company were still unable to maintain the competition. Their stock and
  • credit gradually declined. In 1712, their debts had become so great, that
  • a particular act of parliament was thought necessary, both for their
  • security and for that of their creditors. It was enacted, that the
  • resolution of two-thirds of these creditors in number and value should
  • bind the rust, both with regard to the time which should be allowed to the
  • company for the payment of their debts, and with regard to any other
  • agreement which it might be thought proper to make with them concerning
  • those debts. In 1730, their affairs were in so great disorder, that they
  • were altogether incapable of maintaining their forts and garrisons, the
  • sole purpose and pretext of their institution. From that year till their
  • final dissolution, the parliament judged it necessary to allow the annual
  • sum of £10,000 for that purpose. In 1732, after having been for many years
  • losers by the trade of carrying negroes to the West Indies, they at last
  • resolved to give it up altogether; to sell to the private traders to
  • America the negroes which they purchased upon the coast; awl to employ
  • their servants in a trade to the inland parts of Africa for gold dust,
  • elephants teeth, dyeing drugs, etc. But their success in this more
  • confined trade was not greater than in their former extensive one. Their
  • affairs continued to go gradually to decline, till at last, being in every
  • respect a bankrupt company, they were dissolved by act of parliament, and
  • their forts and garrisons vested in the present regulated company of
  • merchants trading to Africa. Before the erection of the Royal African
  • company, there had been three other joint-stock companies successively
  • established, one after another, for the African trade. They were all
  • equally unsuccessful. They all, however, had exclusive charters, which,
  • though not confirmed by act of parliament, were in those days supposed to
  • convey a real exclusive privilege.
  • The Hudson’s Bay company, before their misfortunes in the late war, had
  • been much more fortunate than the Royal African company. Their necessary
  • expense is much smaller. The whole number of people whom they maintain in
  • their different settlements and habitations, which they have honoured with
  • the name of forts, is said not to exceed a hundred and twenty persons.
  • This number, however, is sufficient to prepare beforehand the cargo of
  • furs and other goods necessary for loading their ships, which, on account
  • of the ice, can seldom remain above six or eight weeks in those seas. This
  • advantage of having a cargo ready prepared, could not, for several years,
  • be acquired by private adventurers; and without it there seems to be no
  • possibility of trading to Hudson’s Bay. The moderate capital of the
  • company, which, it is said, does not exceed one hundred and ten thousand
  • pounds, may, besides, be sufficient to enable them to engross the whole,
  • or almost the whole trade and surplus produce, of the miserable though
  • extensive country comprehended within their charter. No private
  • adventurers, accordingly, have ever attempted to trade to that country in
  • competition with them. This company, therefore, have always enjoyed an
  • exclusive trade, in fact, though they may have no right to it in law. Over
  • and above all this, the moderate capital of this company is said to be
  • divided among a very small number of proprietors. But a joint-stock
  • company, consisting of a small number of proprietors, with a moderate
  • capital, approaches very nearly to the nature of a private copartnery, and
  • may be capable of nearly the same degree of vigilance and attention. It is
  • not to be wondered at, therefore, if, in consequence of these different
  • advantages, the Hudson’s Bay company had, before the late war, been able
  • to carry on their trade with a considerable degree of success. It does not
  • seem probable, however, that their profits ever approached to what the
  • late Mr Dobbs imagined them. A much more sober and judicious writer, Mr
  • Anderson, author of the Historical and Chronological Deduction of
  • Commerce, very justly observes, that upon examining the accounts which Mr
  • Dobbs himself has given for several years together, of their exports and
  • imports, and upon making proper allowances for their extraordinary risk
  • and expense, it does not appear that their profits deserve to be envied,
  • or that they can much, if at all, exceed the ordinary profits of trade.
  • The South Sea company never had any forts or garrisons to maintain, and
  • therefore were entirely exempted from one great expense, to which other
  • joint-stock companies for foreign trade are subject; but they had an
  • immense capital divided among an immense number of proprietors. It was
  • naturally to be expected, therefore, that folly, negligence, and
  • profusion, should prevail in the whole management of their affairs. The
  • knavery and extravagance of their stock-jobbing projects are sufficiently
  • known, and the explication of them would be foreign to the present
  • subject. Their mercantile projects were not much better conducted. The
  • first trade which they engaged in, was that of supplying the Spanish West
  • Indies with negroes, of which (in consequence of what was called the
  • Assiento Contract granted them by the treaty of Utrecht) they had the
  • exclusive privilege. But as it was not expected that much profit could be
  • made by this trade, both the Portuguese and French companies, who had
  • enjoyed it upon the same terms before them, having been ruined by it, they
  • were allowed, as compensation, to send annually a ship of a certain
  • burden, to trade directly to the Spanish West Indies. Of the ten voyages
  • which this annual ship was allowed to make, they are said to have gained
  • considerably by one, that of the Royal Caroline, in 1731; and to have been
  • losers, more or less, by almost all the rest. Their ill success was
  • imputed, by their factors and agents, to the extortion and oppression of
  • the Spanish government; but was, perhaps, principally owing to the
  • profusion and depredations of those very factors and agents; some of whom
  • are said to have acquired great fortunes, even in one year. In 1734, the
  • company petitioned the king, that they might be allowed to dispose of the
  • trade and tonnage of their annual ship, on account of the little profit
  • which they made by it, and to accept of such equivalent as they could
  • obtain from the king of Spain.
  • In 1724, this company had undertaken the whale fishery. Of this, indeed,
  • they had no monopoly; but as long as they carried it on, no other British
  • subjects appear to have engaged in it. Of the eight voyages which their
  • ships made to Greenland, they were gainers by one, and losers by all the
  • rest. After their eighth and last voyage, when they had sold their ships,
  • stores, and utensils, they found that their whole loss upon this branch,
  • capital and interest included, amounted to upwards of £237,000.
  • In 1722, this company petitioned the parliament to be allowed to divide
  • their immense capital of more than thirty-three millions eight hundred
  • thousand pounds, the whole of which had been lent to government, into two
  • equal parts; the one half, or upwards of £16,900,000, to be put upon the
  • same footing with other government annuities, and not to be subject to the
  • debts contracted, or losses incurred, by the directors of the company, in
  • the prosecution of their mercantile projects; the other half to remain as
  • before, a trading stock, and to be subject to those debts and losses. The
  • petition was too reasonable not to be granted. In 1733, they again
  • petitioned the parliament, that three-fourths of their trading stock might
  • be turned into annuity stock, and only one-fourth remain as trading stock,
  • or exposed to the hazards arising from the bad management of their
  • directors. Both their annuity and trading stocks had, by this time, been
  • reduced more than two millions each, by several different payments from
  • government; so that this fourth amounted only to £3,662,784:8:6. In 1748,
  • all the demands of the company upon the king of Spain, in consequence of
  • the assiento contract, were, by the treaty of Aix-la-Chapelle, given up
  • for what was supposed an equivalent. An end was put to their trade with
  • the Spanish West Indies; the remainder of their trading stock was turned
  • into an annuity stock; and the company ceased, in every respect, to be a
  • trading company.
  • It ought to be observed, that in the trade which the South Sea company
  • carried on by means of their annual ship, the only trade by which it ever
  • was expected that they could make any considerable profit, they were not
  • without competitors, either in the foreign or in the home market. At
  • Carthagena, Porto Bello, and La Vera Cruz, they had to encounter the
  • competition of the Spanish merchants, who brought from Cadiz to those
  • markets European goods, of the same kind with the outward cargo of their
  • ship; and in England they had to encounter that of the English merchants,
  • who imported from Cadiz goods of the Spanish West Indies, of the same kind
  • with the inward cargo. The goods, both of the Spanish and English
  • merchants, indeed, were, perhaps, subject to higher duties. But the loss
  • occasioned by the negligence, profusion, and malversation of the servants
  • of the company, had probably been a tax much heavier than all those
  • duties. That a joint-stock company should be able to carry on successfully
  • any branch of foreign trade, when private adventurers can come into any
  • sort of open and fair competition with them, seems contrary to all
  • experience.
  • The old English East India company was established in 1600, by a charter
  • from Queen Elizabeth. In the first twelve voyages which they fitted out
  • for India, they appear to have traded as a regulated company, with
  • separate stocks, though only in the general ships of the company. In 1612,
  • they united into a joint stock. Their charter was exclusive, and, though
  • not confirmed by act of parliament, was in those days supposed to convey a
  • real exclusive privilege. For many years, therefore, they were not much
  • disturbed by interlopers. Their capital, which never exceeded £744,000,
  • and of which £50 was a share, was not so exorbitant, nor their dealings so
  • extensive, as to afford either a pretext for gross negligence and
  • profusion, or a cover to gross malversation. Notwithstanding some
  • extraordinary losses, occasioned partly by the malice of the Dutch East
  • India company, and partly by other accidents, they carried on for many
  • years a successful trade. But in process of time, when the principles of
  • liberty were better understood, it became every day more and more
  • doubtful, how far a royal charter, not confirmed by act of parliament,
  • could convey an exclusive privilege. Upon this question the decisions of
  • the courts of justice were not uniform, but varied with the authority of
  • government, and the humours of the times. Interlopers multiplied upon
  • them; and towards the end of the reign of Charles II., through the whole
  • of that of James II., and during a part of that of William III., reduced
  • them to great distress. In 1698, a proposal was made to parliament, of
  • advancing two millions to government, at eight per cent. provided the
  • subscribers were erected into a new East India company, with exclusive
  • privileges. The old East India company offered seven hundred thousand
  • pounds, nearly the amount of their capital, at four per cent. upon the
  • same conditions. But such was at that time the state of public credit,
  • that it was more convenient for government to borrow two millions at eight
  • per cent. than seven hundred thousand pounds at four. The proposal of the
  • new subscribers was accepted, and a new East India company established in
  • consequence. The old East India company, however, had a right to continue
  • their trade till 1701. They had, at the same time, in the name of their
  • treasurer, subscribed very artfully three hundred and fifteen thousand
  • pounds into the stock of the new. By a negligence in the expression of the
  • act of parliament, which vested the East India trade in the subscribers to
  • this loan of two millions, it did not appear evident that they were all
  • obliged to unite into a joint stock. A few private traders, whose
  • subscriptions amounted only to seven thousand two hundred pounds, insisted
  • upon the privilege of trading separately upon their own stocks, and at
  • their own risks. The old East India company had a right to a separate
  • trade upon their own stock till 1701; and they had likewise, both before
  • and after that period, a right, like that or other private traders, to a
  • separate trade upon the £315,000, which they had subscribed into the stock
  • of the new company. The competition of the two companies with the private
  • traders, and with one another, is said to have well nigh ruined both. Upon
  • a subsequent occasion, in 1750, when a proposal was made to parliament for
  • putting the trade under the management of a regulated company, and thereby
  • laying it in some measure open, the East India company, in opposition to
  • this proposal, represented, in very strong terms, what had been, at this
  • time, the miserable effects, as they thought them, of this competition. In
  • India, they said, it raised the price of goods so high, that they were not
  • worth the buying; and in England, by overstocking the market, it sunk
  • their price so low, that no profit could be made by them. That by a more
  • plentiful supply, to the great advantage and conveniency of the public, it
  • must have reduced very much the price of India goods in the English
  • market, cannot well be doubted; but that it should have raised very much
  • their price in the Indian market, seems not very probable, as all the
  • extraordinary demand which that competition could occasion must have been
  • but as a drop of water in the immense ocean of Indian commerce. The
  • increase of demand, besides, though in the beginning it may sometimes
  • raise the price of goods, never fails to lower it in the long-run. It
  • encourages production, and thereby increases the competition of the
  • producers, who, in order to undersell one another, have recourse to new
  • divisions or labour and new improvements of art, which might never
  • otherwise have been thought of. The miserable effects of which the company
  • complained, were the cheapness of consumption, and the encouragement given
  • to production; precisely the two effects which it is the great business of
  • political economy to promote. The competition, however, of which they gave
  • this doleful account, had not been allowed to be of long continuance. In
  • 1702, the two companies were, in some measure, united by an indenture
  • tripartite, to which the queen was the third party; and in 1708, they were
  • by act of parliament, perfectly consolidated into one company, by their
  • present name of the United Company of Merchants trading to the East
  • Indies. Into this act it was thought worth while to insert a clause,
  • allowing the separate traders to continue their trade till Michaelmas
  • 1711; but at the same time empowering the directors, upon three years
  • notice, to redeem their little capital of seven thousand two hundred
  • pounds, and thereby to convert the whole stock of the company into a joint
  • stock. By the same act, the capital of the company, in consequence of a
  • new loan to government, was augmented from two millions to three millions
  • two hundred thousand pounds. In 1743, the company advanced another million
  • to government. But this million being raised, not by a call upon the
  • proprietors, but by selling annuities and contracting bond-debts, it did
  • not augment the stock upon which the proprietors could claim a dividend.
  • It augmented, however, their trading stock, it being equally liable with
  • the other three millions two hundred thousand pounds, to the losses
  • sustained, and debts contracted by the company in prosecution of their
  • mercantile projects. From 1708, or at least from 1711, this company, being
  • delivered from all competitors, and fully established in the monopoly of
  • the English commerce to the East Indies, carried on a successful trade,
  • and from their profits, made annually a moderate dividend to their
  • proprietors. During the French war, which began in 1741, the ambition of
  • Mr. Dupleix, the French governor of Pondicherry, involved them in the wars
  • of the Carnatic, and in the politics of the Indian princes. After many
  • signal successes, and equally signal losses, they at last lost Madras, at
  • that time their principal settlement in India. It was restored to them by
  • the treaty of Aix-la-Chapelle; and, about this time the spirit of war and
  • conquest seems to have taken possession of their servants in India, and
  • never since to have left them. During the French war, which began in 1755,
  • their arms partook of the general good fortune of those of Great Britain.
  • They defended Madras, took Pondicherry, recovered Calcutta, and acquired
  • the revenues of a rich and extensive territory, amounting, it was then
  • said, to upwards of three millions a-year. They remained for several years
  • in quiet possession of this revenue; but in 1767, administration laid
  • claim to their territorial acquisitions, and the revenue arising from
  • them, as of right belonging to the crown; and the company, in compensation
  • for this claim, agreed to pay to government £400,000 a-year. They had,
  • before this, gradually augmented their dividend from about six to ten per
  • cent.; that is, upon their capital of three millions two hundred thousand
  • pounds, they had increased it by £128,000, or had raised it from one
  • hundred and ninety-two thousand to three hundred and twenty thousand
  • pounds a-year. They were attempting about this time to raise it still
  • further, to twelve and a-half per cent., which would have made their
  • annual payments to their proprietors equal to what they had agreed to pay
  • annually to government, or to £400,000 a-year. But during the two years in
  • which their agreement with government was to take place, they were
  • restrained from any further increase of dividend by two successive acts of
  • parliament, of which the object was to enable them to make a speedier
  • progress in the payment of their debts, which were at this time estimated
  • at upwards of six or seven millions sterling. In 1769, they renewed their
  • agreement with government for five years more, and stipulated, that during
  • the course of that period, they should be allowed gradually to increase
  • their dividend to twelve and a-half per cent; never increasing it,
  • however, more than one per cent. in one year. This increase of dividend,
  • therefore, when it had risen to its utmost height, could augment their
  • annual payments, to their proprietors and government together, but by
  • £680,000, beyond what they had been before their late territorial
  • acquisitions. What the gross revenue of those territorial acquisitions was
  • supposed to amount to, has already been mentioned; and by an account
  • brought by the Cruttenden East Indiaman in 1769, the neat revenue, clear
  • of all deductions and military charges, was stated at two millions
  • forty-eight thousand seven hundred and forty-seven pounds. They were said,
  • at the same time, to possess another revenue, arising partly from lands,
  • but chiefly from the customs established at their different settlements,
  • amounting to £439,000. The profits of their trade, too, according to the
  • evidence of their chairman before the house of commons, amounted, at this
  • time, to at least £400,000 a-year; according to that of their accountant,
  • to at least £500,000; according to the lowest account, at least equal to
  • the highest dividend that was to be paid to their proprietors. So great a
  • revenue might certainly have afforded an augmentation of £680,000 in their
  • annual payments; and, at the same time, have left a large sinking fund,
  • sufficient for the speedy reduction of their debt. In 1773, however, their
  • debts, instead of being reduced, were augmented by an arrear to the
  • treasury in the payment of the four hundred thousand pounds; by another to
  • the custom-house for duties unpaid; by a large debt to the bank, for money
  • borrowed; and by a fourth, for bills drawn upon them from India, and
  • wantonly accepted, to the amount of upwards of twelve hundred thousand
  • pounds. The distress which these accumulated claims brought upon them,
  • obliged them not only to reduce all at once their dividend to six per
  • cent. but to throw themselves upon the mercy of govermnent, and to
  • supplicate, first, a release from the further payment of the stipulated
  • £400,000 a-year; and, secondly, a loan of fourteen hundred thousand, to
  • save them from immediate bankruptcy. The great increase of their fortune
  • had, it seems, only served to furnish their servants with a pretext for
  • greater profusion, and a cover for greater malversation, than in
  • proportion even to that increase of fortune. The conduct of their servants
  • in India, and the general state of their affairs both in India and in
  • Europe, became the subject of a parliamentary inquiry: in consequence of
  • which, several very important alterations were made in the constitution of
  • their government, both at home and abroad. In India, their principal
  • settlements or Madras, Bombay, and Calcutta, which had before been
  • altogether independent of one another, were subjected to a
  • governor-general, assisted by a council of four assessors, parliament
  • assuming to itself the first nomination of this governor and council, who
  • were to reside at Calcutta; that city having now become, what Madras was
  • before, the most important of the English settlements in India. The court
  • of the Mayor of Calcutta, originally instituted for the trial of
  • mercantile causes, which arose in the city and neighbourhood, had
  • gradually extended its jurisdiction with the extension of the empire. It
  • was now reduced and confined to the original purpose of its institution.
  • Instead of it, a new supreme court of judicature was established,
  • consisting of a chief justice and three judges, to be appointed by the
  • crown. In Europe, the qualification necessary to entitle a proprietor to
  • vote at their general courts was raised, from five hundred pounds, the
  • original price of a share in the stock of the company, to a thousand
  • pounds. In order to vote upon this qualification, too, it was declared
  • necessary, that he should have possessed it, if acquired by his own
  • purchase, and not by inheritance, for at least one year, instead of six
  • months, the term requisite before. The court of twenty-four directors had
  • before been chosen annually; but it was now enacted, that each director
  • should, for the future, be chosen for four years; six of them, however, to
  • go out of office by rotation every year, and not be capable of being
  • re-chosen at the election of the six new directors for the ensuing year.
  • In consequence of these alterations, the courts, both of the proprietors
  • and directors, it was expected, would be likely to act with more dignity
  • and steadiness than they had usually done before. But it seems impossible,
  • by any alterations, to render those courts, in any respect, fit to govern,
  • or even to share in the government of a great empire; because the greater
  • part of their members must always have too little interest in the
  • prosperity of that empire, to give any serious attention to what may
  • promote it. Frequently a man of great, sometimes even a man of small
  • fortune, is willing to purchase a thousand pounds share in India stock,
  • merely for the influence which he expects to aquire by a vote in the court
  • of proprietors. It gives him a share, though not in the plunder, yet in
  • the appointment of the plunderers of India; the court of directors, though
  • they make that appointment, being necessarily more or less under the
  • influence of the proprietors, who not only elect those directors, but
  • sometimes over-rule the appointments of their servants in India. Provided
  • he can enjoy this influence for a few years, and thereby provide for a
  • certain number of his friends, he frequently cares little about the
  • dividend, or even about the value of the stock upon which his vote is
  • founded. About the prosperity of the great empire, in the government of
  • which that vote gives him a share, he seldom cares at all. No other
  • sovereigns ever were, or, from the nature of things, ever could be, so
  • perfectly indifferent about the happiness or misery of their subjects, the
  • improvement or waste of their dominions, the glory or disgrace of their
  • administration, as, from irresistible moral causes, the greater part of
  • the proprietors of such a mercantile company are, and necessarily must be.
  • This indifference, too, was more likely to be increased than diminished by
  • some of the new regulations which were made in consequence of the
  • parliamentary inquiry. By a resolution of the house of commons, for
  • example, it was declared, that when the £1,400,000 lent to the company by
  • government, should be paid, and their bond-debts be reduced to £1,500,000,
  • they might then, and not till then, divide eight per cent. upon their
  • capital; and that whatever remained of their revenues and neat profits at
  • home should be divided into four parts; three of them to be paid into the
  • exchequer for the use of the public, and the fourth to be reserved as a
  • fund, either for the further reduction of their bond-debts, or for the
  • discharge of other contingent exigencies which the company might labour
  • under. But if the company were bad stewards and bad sovereigns, when the
  • whole of their neat revenue and profits belonged to themselves, and were
  • at their own disposal, they were surely not likely to be better when
  • three-fourths of them were to belong to other people, and the other
  • fourth, though to be laid out for the benefit of the company, yet to be so
  • under the inspection and with the approbation of other people.
  • It might be more agreeable to the company, that their own servants and
  • dependants should have either the pleasure of wasting, or the profit of
  • embezzling, whatever surplus might remain, after paying the proposed
  • dividend of eight per cent. than that it should come into the hands of a
  • set of people with whom those resolutions could scarce fail to set them in
  • some measure at variance. The interest of those servants and dependants
  • might so far predominate in the court of proprietors, as sometimes to
  • dispose it to support the authors of depredations which had been committed
  • in direct violation of its own authority. With the majority of
  • proprietors, the support even of the authority of their own court might
  • sometimes be a matter of less consequence than the support of those who
  • had set that authority at defiance.
  • The regulations of 1773, accordingly, did not put an end to the disorder
  • of the company’s government in India. Notwithstanding that, during a
  • momentary fit of good conduct, they had at one time collected into the
  • treasury of Calcutta more than £3,000,000 sterling; notwithstanding that
  • they had afterwards extended either their dominion or their depredations
  • over a vast accession of some of the richest and most fertile countries in
  • India, all was wasted and destroyed. They found themselves altogether
  • unprepared to stop or resist the incursion of Hyder Ali; and in
  • consequence of those disorders, the company is now (1784) in greater
  • distress than ever; and, in order to prevent immediate bankruptcy, is once
  • more reduced to supplicate the assistance of government. Different plans
  • have been proposed by the different parties in parliament for the better
  • management of its affairs; and all those plans seem to agree in supposing,
  • what was indeed always abundantly evident, that it is altogether unfit to
  • govern its territorial possessions. Even the company itself seems to be
  • convinced of its own incapacity so far, and seems, upon that account
  • willing to give them up to government.
  • With the right of possessing forts and garrisons in distant and barbarous
  • countries is necessarily connected the right of making peace and war in
  • those countries. The joint-stock companies, which have had the one right,
  • have constantly exercised the other, and have frequently had it expressly
  • conferred upon them. How unjustly, how capriciously, how cruelly, they
  • have commonly exercised it, is too well known from recent experience.
  • When a company of merchants undertake, at their own risk and expense, to
  • establish a new trade with some remote and barbarous nation, it may not be
  • unreasonable to incorporate them into a joint-stock company, and to grant
  • them, in case of their success, a monopoly of the trade for a certain
  • number of years. It is the easiest and most natural way in which the state
  • can recompense them for hazarding a dangerous and expensive experiment, of
  • which the public is afterwards to reap the benefit. A temporary monopoly
  • of this kind may be vindicated, upon the same principles upon which a like
  • monopoly of a new machine is granted to its inventor, and that of a new
  • book to its author. But upon the expiration of the term, the monopoly
  • ought certainly to determine; the forts and garrisons, if it was found
  • necessary to establish any, to be taken into the hands of government,
  • their value to be paid to the company, and the trade to be laid open to
  • all the subjects of the state. By a perpetual monopoly, all the other
  • subjects of the state are taxed very absurdly in two different ways:
  • first, by the high price of goods, which, in the case of a free trade,
  • they could buy much cheaper; and, secondly, by their total exclusion from
  • a branch of business which it might be both convenient and profitable for
  • many of them to carry on. It is for the most worthless of all purposes,
  • too, that they are taxed in this manner. It is merely to enable the
  • company to support the negligence, profusion, and malversation of their
  • own servants, whose disorderly conduct seldom allows the dividend of the
  • company to exceed the ordinary rate of profit in trades which are
  • altogether free, and very frequently makes a fall even a good deal short
  • of that rate. Without a monopoly, however, a joint-stock company, it would
  • appear from experience, cannot long carry on any branch of foreign trade.
  • To buy in one market, in order to sell with profit in another, when there
  • are many competitors in both; to watch over, not only the occasional
  • variations in the demand, but the much greater and more frequent
  • variations in the competition, or in the supply which that demand is
  • likely to get from other people; and to suit with dexterity and judgment
  • both the quantity and quality of each assortment of goods to all these
  • circumstances, is a species of warfare, of which the operations are
  • continually changing, and which can scarce ever be conducted successfully,
  • without such an unremitting exertion of vigilance and attention as cannot
  • long be expected from the directors of a joint-stock company. The East
  • India company, upon the redemption of their funds, and the expiration of
  • their exclusive privilege, have a right, by act of parliament, to continue
  • a corporation with a joint stock, and to trade in their corporate capacity
  • to the East Indies, in common with the rest of their fellow subjects. But
  • in this situation, the superior vigilance and attention of a private
  • adventurer would, in all probability, soon make them weary of the trade.
  • An eminent French author, of great knowledge in matters of political
  • economy, the Abbe Morellet, gives a list of fifty-five joint-stock
  • companies for foreign trade, which have been established in different
  • parts of Europe since the year 1600, and which, according to him, have all
  • failed from mismanagement, notwithstanding they had exclusive privileges.
  • He has been misinformed with regard to the history of two or three of
  • them, which were not joint-stock companies and have not failed. But, in
  • compensation, there have been several joint-stock companies which have
  • failed, and which he has omitted.
  • The only trades which it seems possible for a joint-stock company to carry
  • on successfully, without an exclusive privilege, are those, of which all
  • the operations are capable of being reduced to what is called a routine,
  • or to such a uniformity of method as admits of little or no variation. Of
  • this kind is, first, the banking trade; secondly, the trade of insurance
  • from fire and from sea risk, and capture in time of war; thirdly, the
  • trade of making and maintaining a navigable cut or canal; and, fourthly,
  • the similar trade of bringing water for the supply of a great city.
  • Though the principles of the banking trade may appear somewhat abstruse,
  • the practice is capable of being reduced to strict rules. To depart upon
  • any occasion from those rules, in consequence of some flattering
  • speculation of extraordinary gain, is almost always extremely dangerous
  • and frequently fatal to the banking company which attempts it. But the
  • constitution of joint-stock companies renders them in general, more
  • tenacious of established rules than any private copartnery. Such
  • companies, therefore, seem extremely well fitted for this trade. The
  • principal banking companies in Europe, accordingly, are joint-stock
  • companies, many of which manage their trade very successfully without any
  • exclusive privilege. The bank of England has no other exclusive privilege,
  • except that no other banking company in England shall consist of more than
  • six persons. The two banks of Edinburgh are joint-stock companies, without
  • any exclusive privilege.
  • The value of the risk, either from fire, or from loss by sea, or by
  • capture, though it cannot, perhaps, be calculated very exactly, admits,
  • however, of such a gross estimation, as renders it, in some degree,
  • reducible to strict rule and method. The trade of insurance, therefore,
  • may be carried on successfully by a joint-stock company, without any
  • exclusive privilege. Neither the London Assurance, nor the Royal Exchange
  • Assurance companies have any such privilege.
  • When a navigable cut or canal has been once made, the management of it
  • becomes quite simple and easy, and it is reducible to strict rule and
  • method. Even the making of it is so, as it may be contracted for with
  • undertakers, at so much a mile, and so much a lock. The same thing may be
  • said of a canal, an aqueduct, or a great pipe for bringing water to supply
  • a great city. Such under-takings, therefore, may be, and accordingly
  • frequently are, very successfully managed by joint-stock companies,
  • without any exclusive privilege.
  • To establish a joint-stock company, however, for any undertaking, merely
  • because such a company might be capable of managing it successfully; or,
  • to exempt a particular set of dealers from some of the general laws which
  • take place with regard to all their neighbours, merely because they might
  • be capable of thriving, if they had such an exemption, would certainly not
  • be reasonable. To render such an establishment perfectly reasonable, with
  • the circumstance of being reducible to strict rule and method, two other
  • circumstances ought to concur. First, it ought to appear with the clearest
  • evidence, that the undertaking is of greater and more general utility than
  • the greater part of common trades; and, secondly, that it requires a
  • greater capital than can easily be collected into a private copartnery. If
  • a moderate capital were sufficient, the great utility of the undertaking
  • would not be a sufficient reason for establishing a joint-stock company;
  • because, in this case, the demand for what it was to produce, would
  • readily and easily be supplied by private adventurers. In the four trades
  • above mentioned, both those circumstances concur.
  • The great and general utility of the banking trade, when prudently
  • managed, has been fully explained in the second book of this Inquiry. But
  • a public bank, which is to support public credit, and, upon particular
  • emergencies, to advance to government the whole produce of a tax, to the
  • amount, perhaps, of several millions, a year or two before it comes in,
  • requires a greater capital than can easily be collected into any private
  • copartnery.
  • The trade of insurance gives great security to the fortunes of private
  • people, and, by dividing among a great many that loss which would ruin an
  • individual, makes it fall light and easy upon the whole society. In order
  • to give this security, however, it is necessary that the insurers should
  • have a very large capital. Before the establishment of the two joint-stock
  • companies for insurance in London, a list, it is said, was laid before the
  • attorney-general, of one hundred and fifty private usurers, who had failed
  • in the course of a few years.
  • That navigable cuts and canals, and the works which are sometimes
  • necessary for supplying a great city with water, are of great and general
  • utility, while, at the same time, they frequently require a greater
  • expense than suits the fortunes of private people, is sufficiently
  • obvious.
  • Except the four trades above mentioned, I have not been able to recollect
  • any other, in which all the three circumstances requisite for rendering
  • reasonable the establishment of a joint-stock company concur. The English
  • copper company of London, the lead-smelting company, the glass-grinding
  • company, have not even the pretext of any great or singular utility in the
  • object which they pursue; nor does the pursuit of that object seem to
  • require any expense unsuitable to the fortunes of many private men.
  • Whether the trade which those companies carry on, is reducible to such
  • strict rule and method as to render it fit for the management of a
  • joint-stock company, or whether they have any reason to boast of their
  • extraordinary profits, I do not pretend to know. The mine-adventurers
  • company has been long ago bankrupt. A share in the stock of the British
  • Linen company of Edinburgh sells, at present, very much below par, though
  • less so than it did some years ago. The joint-stock companies, which are
  • established for the public-spirited purpose of promoting some particular
  • manufacture, over and above managing their own affairs ill, to the
  • diminution of the general stock of the society, can, in other respects,
  • scarce ever fail to do more harm than good. Notwithstanding the most
  • upright intentions, the unavoidable partiality of their directors to
  • particular branches of the manufacture, of which the undertakers mislead
  • and impose upon them, is a real discouragement to the rest, and
  • necessarily breaks, more or less, that natural proportion which would
  • otherwise establish itself between judicious industry and profit, and
  • which, to the general industry of the country, is of all encouragements
  • the greatest and the most effectual.
  • ART. II.—Of the Expense of the Institution for the Education of
  • Youth.
  • The institutions for the education of the youth may, in the same manner,
  • furnish a revenue sufficient for defraying their own expense. The fee or
  • honorary, which the scholar pays to the master, naturally constitutes a
  • revenue of this kind.
  • Even where the reward of the master does not arise altogether from this
  • natural revenue, it still is not necessary that it should be derived from
  • that general revenue of the society, of which the collection and
  • application are, in most countries, assigned to the executive power.
  • Through the greater part of Europe, accordingly, the endowment of schools
  • and colleges makes either no charge upon that general revenue, or but a
  • very small one. It everywhere arises chiefly from some local or provincial
  • revenue, from the rent of some landed estate, or from the interest of some
  • sum of money, allotted and put under the management of trustees for this
  • particular purpose, sometimes by the sovereign himself, and sometimes by
  • some private donor.
  • Have those public endowments contributed in general, to promote the end of
  • their institution? Have they contributed to encourage the diligence, and
  • to improve the abilities, of the teachers? Have they directed the course
  • of education towards objects more useful, both to the individual and to
  • the public, than those to which it would naturally have gone of its own
  • accord? It should not seem very difficult to give at least a probable
  • answer to each of those questions.
  • In every profession, the exertion of the greater part of those who
  • exercise it, is always in proportion to the necessity they are under of
  • making that exertion. This necessity is greatest with those to whom the
  • emoluments of their profession are the only source from which they expect
  • their fortune, or even their ordinary revenue and subsistence. In order to
  • acquire this fortune, or even to get this subsistence, they must, in the
  • course of a year, execute a certain quantity of work of a known value;
  • and, where the competition is free, the rivalship of competitors, who are
  • all endeavouring to justle one another out of employment, obliges every
  • man to endeavour to execute his work with a certain degree of exactness.
  • The greatness of the objects which are to be acquired by success in some
  • particular professions may, no doubt, sometimes animate the exertions of a
  • few men of extraordinary spirit and ambition. Great objects, however, are
  • evidently not necessary, in order to occasion the greatest exertions.
  • Rivalship and emulation render excellency, even in mean professions, an
  • object of ambition, and frequently occasion the very greatest exertions.
  • Great objects, on the contrary, alone and unsupported by the necessity of
  • application, have seldom been sufficient to occasion any considerable
  • exertion. In England, success in the profession of the law leads to some
  • very great objects of ambition; and yet how few men, born to easy
  • fortunes, have ever in this country been eminent in that profession?
  • The endowments of schools and colleges have necessarily diminished, more
  • or less, the necessity of application in the teachers. Their subsistence,
  • so far as it arises from their salaries, is evidently derived from a fund,
  • altogether independent of their success and reputation in their particular
  • professions.
  • In some universities, the salary makes but a part, and frequently but a
  • small part, of the emoluments of the teacher, of which the greater part
  • arises from the honoraries or fees of his pupils. The necessity of
  • application, though always more or less diminished, is not, in this case,
  • entirely taken away. Reputation in his profession is still of some
  • importance to him, and he still has some dependency upon the affection,
  • gratitude, and favourable report of those who have attended upon his
  • instructions; and these favourable sentiments he is likely to gain in no
  • way so well as by deserving them, that is, by the abilities and diligence
  • with which he discharges every part of his duty.
  • In other universities, the teacher is prohibited from receiving any
  • honorary or fee from his pupils, and his salary constitutes the whole of
  • the revenue which he derives from his office. His interest is, in this
  • case, set as directly in opposition to his duty as it is possible to set
  • it. It is the interest of every man to live as much at his ease as he can;
  • and if his emoluments are to be precisely the same, whether he does or
  • does not perform some very laborious duty, it is certainly his interest,
  • at least as interest is vulgarly understood, either to neglect it
  • altogether, or, if he is subject to some authority which will not suffer
  • him to do this, to perform it in as careless and slovenly a manner as that
  • authority will permit. If he is naturally active and a lover of labour, it
  • is his interest to employ that activity in any way from which he can
  • derive some advantage, rather than in the performance of his duty, from
  • which he can derive none.
  • If the authority to which he is subject resides in the body corporate, the
  • college, or university, of which he himself is a member, and in which the
  • greater part of the other members are, like himself, persons who either
  • are, or ought to be teachers, they are likely to make a common cause, to
  • be all very indulgent to one another, and every man to consent that his
  • neighbour may neglect his duty, provided he himself is allowed to neglect
  • his own. In the university of Oxford, the greater part of the public
  • professors have, for these many years, given up altogether even the
  • pretence of teaching.
  • If the authority to which he is subject resides, not so much in the body
  • corporate, of which he is a member, as in some other extraneous persons,
  • in the bishop of the diocese, for example, in the governor of the
  • province, or, perhaps, in some minister of state, it is not, indeed, in
  • this case, very likely that he will be suffered to neglect his duty
  • altogether. All that such superiors, however, can force him to do, is to
  • attend upon his pupils a certain number of hours, that is, to give a
  • certain number of lectures in the week, or in the year. What those
  • lectures shall be, must still depend upon the diligence of the teacher;
  • and that diligence is likely to be proportioned to the motives which he
  • has for exerting it. An extraneous jurisdiction of this kind, besides, is
  • liable to be exercised both ignorantly and capriciously. In its nature, it
  • is arbitrary and discretionary; and the persons who exercise it, neither
  • attending upon the lectures of the teacher themselves, nor perhaps
  • understanding the sciences which it is his business to teach, are seldom
  • capable of exercising it with judgment. From the insolence of office, too,
  • they are frequently indifferent how they exercise it, and are very apt to
  • censure or deprive him of his office wantonly and without any just cause.
  • The person subject to such jurisdiction is necessarily degraded by it,
  • and, instead of being one of the most respectable, is rendered one of the
  • meanest and most contemptible persons in the society. It is by powerful
  • protection only, that he can effectually guard himself against the bad
  • usage to which he is at all times exposed; and this protection he is most
  • likely to gain, not by ability or diligence in his profession, but by
  • obsequiousness to the will of his superiors, and by being ready, at all
  • times, to sacrifice to that will the rights, the interest, and the honour
  • of the body corporate, of which he is a member. Whoever has attended for
  • any considerable time to the administration of a French university, must
  • have had occasion to remark the effects which naturally result from an
  • arbitrary and extraneous jurisdiction of this kind.
  • Whatever forces a certain number of students to any college or university,
  • independent of the merit or reputation of the teachers, tends more or less
  • to diminish the necessity of that merit or reputation.
  • The privileges of graduates in arts, in law, physic, and divinity, when
  • they can be obtained only by residing a certain number of years in certain
  • universities, necessarily force a certain number of students to such
  • universities, independent of the merit or reputation of the teachers. The
  • privileges of graduates are a sort of statutes of apprenticeship, which
  • have contributed to the improvement of education just as the other
  • statutes of apprenticeship have to that of arts and manufactures.
  • The charitable foundations of scholarships, exhibitions, bursaries, etc.
  • necessarily attach a certain number of students to certain colleges,
  • independent altogether of the merit of those particular colleges. Were the
  • students upon such charitable foundations left free to choose what college
  • they liked best, such liberty might perhaps contribute to excite some
  • emulation among different colleges. A regulation, on the contrary, which
  • prohibited even the independent members of every particular college from
  • leaving it, and going to any other, without leave first asked and obtained
  • of that which they meant to abandon, would tend very much to extinguish
  • that emulation.
  • If in each college, the tutor or teacher, who was to instruct each student
  • in all arts and sciences, should not be voluntarily chosen by the student,
  • but appointed by the head of the college; and if, in case of neglect,
  • inability, or bad usage, the student should not be allowed to change him
  • for another, without leave first asked and obtained; such a regulation
  • would not only tend very much to extinguish all emulation among the
  • different tutors of the same college, but to diminish very much, in all of
  • them, the necessity of diligence and of attention to their respective
  • pupils. Such teachers, though very well paid by their students, might be
  • as much disposed to neglect them, as those who are not paid by them at all
  • or who have no other recompense but their salary.
  • If the teacher happens to be a man of sense, it must be an unpleasant
  • thing to him to be conscious, while he is lecturing to his students, that
  • he is either speaking or reading nonsense, or what is very little better
  • than nonsense. It must, too, be unpleasant to him to observe, that the
  • greater part of his students desert his lectures; or perhaps, attend upon
  • them with plain enough marks of neglect, contempt, and derision. If he is
  • obliged, therefore, to give a certain number of lectures, these motives
  • alone, without any other interest, might dispose him to take some pains to
  • give tolerably good ones. Several different expedients, however, may be
  • fallen upon, which will effectually blunt the edge of all those
  • incitements to diligence. The teacher, instead of explaining to his pupils
  • himself the science in which he proposes to instruct them, may read some
  • book upon it; and if this book is written in a foreign and dead language,
  • by interpreting it to them into their own, or, what would give him still
  • less trouble, by making them interpret it to him, and by now and then
  • making an occasional remark upon it, he may flatter himself that he is
  • giving a lecture. The slightest degree of knowledge and application will
  • enable him to do this, without exposing himself to contempt or derision,
  • by saying any thing that is really foolish, absurd, or ridiculous. The
  • discipline of the college, at the same time, may enable him to force all
  • his pupils to the most regular attendance upon his sham lecture, and to
  • maintain the most decent and respectful behaviour during the whole time of
  • the performance.
  • The discipline of colleges and universities is in general contrived, not
  • for the benefit of the students, but for the interest, or, more properly
  • speaking, for the ease of the masters. Its object is, in all cases, to
  • maintain the authority of the master, and, whether he neglects or performs
  • his duty, to oblige the students in all cases to behave to him as if he
  • performed it with the greatest diligence and ability. It seems to presume
  • perfect wisdom and virtue in the one order, and the greatest weakness and
  • folly in the other. Where the masters, however, really perform their duty,
  • there are no examples, I believe, that the greater part of the students
  • ever neglect theirs. No discipline is ever requisite to force attendance
  • upon lectures which are really worth the attending, as is well known
  • wherever any such lectures are given. Force and restraint may, no doubt,
  • be in some degree requisite, in order to oblige children, or very young
  • boys, to attend to those parts of education, which it is thought necessary
  • for them to acquire during that early period of life; but after twelve or
  • thirteen years of age, provided the master does his duty, force or
  • restraint can scarce ever be necessary to carry on any part of education.
  • Such is the generosity of the greater part of young men, that so far from
  • being disposed to neglect or despise the instructions of their master,
  • provided he shews some serious intention of being of use to them, they are
  • generally inclined to pardon a great deal of incorrectness in the
  • performance of his duty, and sometimes even to conceal from the public a
  • good deal of gross negligence.
  • Those parts of education, it is to be observed, for the teaching of which
  • there are no public institutions, are generally the best taught. When a
  • young man goes to a fencing or a dancing school, he does not, indeed,
  • always learn to fence or to dance very well; but he seldom fails of
  • learning to fence or to dance. The good effects of the riding school are
  • not commonly so evident. The expense of a riding school is so great, that
  • in most places it is a public institution. The three most essential parts
  • of literary education, to read, write, and account, it still continues to
  • be more common to acquire in private than in public schools; and it very
  • seldom happens, that anybody fails of acquiring them to the degree in
  • which it is necessary to acquire them.
  • In England, the public schools are much less corrupted than the
  • universities. In the schools, the youth are taught, or at least may be
  • taught, Greek and Latin; that is, everything which the masters pretend to
  • teach, or which it is expected they should teach. In the universities, the
  • youth neither are taught, nor always can find any proper means of being
  • taught the sciences, which it is the business of those incorporated bodies
  • to teach. The reward of the schoolmaster, in most cases, depends
  • principally, in some cases almost entirely, upon the fees or honoraries of
  • his scholars. Schools have no exclusive privileges. In order to obtain the
  • honours of graduation, it is not necessary that a person should bring a
  • certificate of his having studied a certain number of years at a public
  • school. If, upon examination, he appears to understand what is taught
  • there, no questions are asked about the place where he learnt it.
  • The parts of education which are commonly taught in universities, it may
  • perhaps be said, are not very well taught. But had it not been for those
  • institutions, they would not have been commonly taught at all; and both
  • the individual and the public would have suffered a good deal from the
  • want of those important parts of education.
  • The present universities of Europe were originally, the greater part of
  • them, ecclesiastical corporations, instituted for the education of
  • churchmen. They were founded by the authority of the pope; and were so
  • entirely under his immediate protection, that their members, whether
  • masters or students, had all of them what was then called the benefit of
  • clergy, that is, were exempted from the civil jurisdiction of the
  • countries in which their respective universities were situated, and were
  • amenable only to the ecclesiastical tribunals. What was taught in the
  • greater part of those universities was suitable to the end of their
  • institution, either theology, or something that was merely preparatory to
  • theology.
  • When Christianity was first established by law, a corrupted Latin had
  • become the common language of all the western parts of Europe. The service
  • of the church, accordingly, and the translation of the Bible which were
  • read in churches, were both in that corrupted Latin; that is, in the
  • common language of the country, After the irruption of the barbarous
  • nations who overturned the Roman empire, Latin gradually ceased to be the
  • language of any part of Europe. But the reverence of the people naturally
  • preserves the established forms and ceremonies of religion long after the
  • circumstances which first introduced and rendered them reasonable, are no
  • more. Though Latin, therefore, was no longer understood anywhere by the
  • great body of the people, the whole service of the church still continued
  • to be performed in that language. Two different languages were thus
  • established in Europe, in the same manner as in ancient Egypt: a language
  • of the priests, and a language of the people; a sacred and a profane, a
  • learned and an unlearned language. But it was necessary that the priests
  • should understand something of that sacred and learned language in which
  • they were to officiate; and the study of the Latin language therefore
  • made, from the beginning, an essential part of university education.
  • It was not so with that either of the Greek or of the Hebrew language. The
  • infallible decrees of the church had pronounced the Latin translation of
  • the Bible, commonly called the Latin Vulgate, to have been equally
  • dictated by divine inspiration, and therefore of equal authority with the
  • Greek and Hebrew originals. The knowledge of those two languages,
  • therefore, not being indispensably requisite to a churchman, the study of
  • them did not for along time make a necessary part of the common course of
  • university education. There are some Spanish universities, I am assured,
  • in which the study of the Greek language has never yet made any part of
  • that course. The first reformers found the Greek text of the New
  • Testament, and even the Hebrew text of the Old, more favourable to their
  • opinions than the vulgate translation, which, as might naturally be
  • supposed, had been gradually accommodated to support the doctrines of the
  • Catholic Church. They set themselves, therefore, to expose the many errors
  • of that translation, which the Roman catholic clergy were thus put under
  • the necessity of defending or explaining. But this could not well be done
  • without some knowledge of the original languages, of which the study was
  • therefore gradually introduced into the greater part of universities; both
  • of those which embraced, and of those which rejected, the doctrines of the
  • reformation. The Greek language was connected with every part of that
  • classical learning, which, though at first principally cultivated by
  • catholics and Italians, happened to come into fashion much about the same
  • time that the doctrines of the reformation were set on foot. In the
  • greater part of universities, therefore, that language was taught previous
  • to the study of philosophy, and as soon as the student had made some
  • progress in the Latin. The Hebrew language having no connection with
  • classical learning, and, except the Holy Scriptures, being the language of
  • not a single book in any esteem the study of it did not commonly commence
  • till after that of philosophy, and when the student had entered upon the
  • study of theology.
  • Originally, the first rudiments, both of the Greek and Latin languages,
  • were taught in universities; and in some universities they still continue
  • to be so. In others, it is expected that the student should have
  • previously acquired, at least, the rudiments of one or both of those
  • languages, of which the study continues to make everywhere a very
  • considerable part of university education.
  • The ancient Greek philosophy was divided into three great branches;
  • physics, or natural philosophy; ethics, or moral philosophy; and logic.
  • This general division seems perfectly agreeable to the nature of things.
  • The great phenomena of nature, the revolutions of the heavenly bodies,
  • eclipses, comets; thunder and lightning, and other extraordinary meteors;
  • the generation, the life, growth, and dissolution of plants and animals;
  • are objects which, as they necessarily excite the wonder, so they
  • naturally call forth the curiosity of mankind to inquire into their
  • causes. Superstition first attempted to satisfy this curiosity, by
  • referring all those wonderful appearances to the immediate agency of the
  • gods. Philosophy afterwards endeavoured to account for them from more
  • familiar causes, or from such as mankind were better acquainted with, than
  • the agency of the gods. As those great phenomena are the first objects of
  • human curiosity, so the science which pretends to explain them must
  • naturally have been the first branch of philosophy that was cultivated.
  • The first philosophers, accordingly, of whom history has preserved any
  • account, appear to have been natural philosophers.
  • In every age and country of the world, men must have attended to the
  • characters, designs, and actions of one another; and many reputable rules
  • and maxims for the conduct of human life must have been laid down and
  • approved of by common consent. As soon as writing came into fashion, wise
  • men, or those who fancied themselves such, would naturally endeavour to
  • increase the number of those established and respected maxims, and to
  • express their own sense of what was either proper or improper conduct,
  • sometimes in the more artificial form of apologues, like what are called
  • the fables of Aesop; and sometimes in the more simple one of apophthegms
  • or wise sayings, like the proverbs of Solomon, the verses of Theognis and
  • Phocyllides, and some part of the works of Hesiod. They might continue in
  • this manner, for a long time, merely to multiply the number of those
  • maxims of prudence and morality, without even attempting to arrange them
  • in any very distinct or methodical order, much less to connect them
  • together by one or more general principles, from which they were all
  • deducible, like effects from their natural causes. The beauty of a
  • systematical arrangement of different observations, connected by a few
  • common principles, was first seen in the rude essays of those ancient
  • times towards a system of natural philosophy. Something of the same kind
  • was afterwards attempted in morals. The maxims of common life were
  • arranged in some methodical order, and connected together by a few common
  • principles, in the same manner as they had attempted to arrange and
  • connect the phenomena of nature. The science which pretends to investigate
  • and explain those connecting principles, is what is properly called Moral
  • Philosophy.
  • Different authors gave different systems, both of natural and moral
  • philosophy. But the arguments by which they supported those different
  • systems, far from being always demonstrations, were frequently at best but
  • very slender probabilities, and sometimes mere sophisms, which had no
  • other foundation but the inaccuracy and ambiguity of common language.
  • Speculative systems, have, in all ages of the world, been adopted for
  • reasons too frivolous to have determined the judgment of any man of common
  • sense, in a matter of the smallest pecuniary interest. Gross sophistry has
  • scarce ever had any influence upon the opinions of mankind, except in
  • matters of philosophy and speculation; and in these it has frequently had
  • the greatest. The patrons of each system of natural and moral philosophy,
  • naturally endeavoured to expose the weakness of the arguments adduced to
  • support the systems which were opposite to their own. In examining those
  • arguments, they were necessarily led to consider the difference between a
  • probable and a demonstrative argument, between a fallacious and a
  • conclusive one; and logic, or the science of the general principles of
  • good and bad reasoning, necessarily arose out of the observations which a
  • scrutiny of this kind gave occasion to; though, in its origin, posterior
  • both to physics and to ethics, it was commonly taught, not indeed in all,
  • but in the greater part of the ancient schools of philosophy, previously
  • to either of those sciences. The student, it seems to have been thought,
  • ought to understand well the difference between good and bad reasoning,
  • before he was led to reason upon subjects of so great importance.
  • This ancient division of philosophy into three parts was, in the greater
  • part of the universities of Europe, changed for another into five.
  • In the ancient philosophy, whatever was taught concerning the nature
  • either of the human mind or of the Deity, made a part of the system of
  • physics. Those beings, in whatever their essence might be supposed to
  • consist, were parts of the great system of the universe, and parts, too,
  • productive of the most important effects. Whatever human reason could
  • either conclude or conjecture concerning them, made, as it were, two
  • chapters, though no doubt two very important ones, of the science which
  • pretended to give an account of the origin and revolutions of the great
  • system of the universe. But in the universities of Europe, where
  • philosophy was taught only as subservient to theology, it was natural to
  • dwell longer upon these two chapters than upon any other of the science.
  • They were gradually more and more extended, and were divided into many
  • inferior chapters; till at last the doctrine of spirits, of which so
  • little can be known, came to take up as much room in the system of
  • philosophy as the doctrine of bodies, of which so much can be known. The
  • doctrines concerning those two subjects were considered as making two
  • distinct sciences. What are called metaphysics, or pneumatics, were set in
  • opposition to physics, and were cultivated not only as the more sublime,
  • but, for the purposes of a particular profession, as the more useful
  • science of the two. The proper subject of experiment and observation, a
  • subject in which a careful attention is capable of making so many useful
  • discoveries, was almost entirely neglected. The subject in which, after a
  • very few simple and almost obvious truths, the most careful attention can
  • discover nothing but obscurity and uncertainty, and can consequently
  • produce nothing but subtleties and sophisms, was greatly cultivated.
  • When those two sciences had thus been set in opposition to one another,
  • the comparison between them naturally gave birth to a third, to what was
  • called ontology, or the science which treated of the qualities and
  • attributes which were common to both the subjects of the other two
  • sciences. But if subtleties and sophisms composed the greater part of the
  • metaphysics or pneumatics of the schools, they composed the whole of this
  • cobweb science of ontology, which was likewise sometimes called
  • metaphysics.
  • Wherein consisted the happiness and perfection of a man, considered not
  • only as an individual, but as the member of a family, of a state, and of
  • the great society of mankind, was the object which the ancient moral
  • philosophy proposed to investigate. In that philosophy, the duties of
  • human life were treated of as subservient to the happiness and perfection
  • of human life, But when moral, as well as natural philosophy, came to be
  • taught only as subservient to theology, the duties of human life were
  • treated of as chiefly subservient to the happiness of a life to come. In
  • the ancient philosophy, the perfection of virtue was represented as
  • necessarily productive, to the person who possessed it, of the most
  • perfect happiness in this life. In the modern philosophy, it was
  • frequently represented as generally, or rather as almost always,
  • inconsistent with any degree of happiness in this life; and heaven was to
  • be earned only by penance and mortification, by the austerities and
  • abasement of a monk, not by the liberal, generous, and spirited conduct of
  • a man. Casuistry, and an ascetic morality, made up, in most cases, the
  • greater part of the moral philosophy of the schools. By far the most
  • important of all the different branches of philosophy became in this
  • manner by far the most corrupted.
  • Such, therefore, was the common course of philosophical education in the
  • greater part of the universities in Europe. Logic was taught first;
  • ontology came in the second place; pneumatology, comprehending the
  • doctrine concerning the nature of the human soul and of the Deity, in the
  • third; in the fourth followed a debased system of moral philosophy, which
  • was considered as immediately connected with the doctrines of
  • pneumatology, with the immortality of the human soul, and with the rewards
  • and punishments which, from the justice of the Deity, were to be expected
  • in a life to come: a short and superficial system of physics usually
  • concluded the course.
  • The alterations which the universities of Europe thus introduced into the
  • ancient course of philosophy were all meant for the education of
  • ecclesiastics, and to render it a more proper introduction to the study of
  • theology. But the additional quantity of subtlety and sophistry, the
  • casuistry and ascetic morality which those alterations introduced into it,
  • certainly did not render it more for the education of gentlemen or men of
  • the world, or more likely either to improve the understanding or to mend
  • the heart.
  • This course of philosophy is what still continues to be taught in the
  • greater part of the universities of Europe, with more or less diligence,
  • according as the constitution of each particular university happens to
  • render diligence more or less necessary to the teachers. In some of the
  • richest and best endowed universities, the tutors content themselves with
  • teaching a few unconnected shreds and parcels of this corrupted course;
  • and even these they commonly teach very negligently and superficially.
  • The improvements which, in modern times have been made in several
  • different branches of philosophy, have not, the greater part of them, been
  • made in universities, though some, no doubt, have. The greater part of
  • universities have not even been very forward to adopt those improvements
  • after they were made; and several of those learned societies have chosen
  • to remain, for a long time, the sanctuaries in which exploded systems and
  • obsolete prejudices found shelter and protection, after they had been
  • hunted out of every other corner of the world. In general, the richest and
  • best endowed universities have been slowest in adopting those
  • improvements, and the most averse to permit any considerable change in the
  • established plan of education. Those improvements were more easily
  • introduced into some of the poorer universities, in which the teachers,
  • depending upon their reputation for the greater part of their subsistence,
  • were obliged to pay more attention to the current opinions of the world.
  • But though the public schools and universities of Europe were originally
  • intended only for the education of a particular profession, that of
  • churchmen; and though they were not always very diligent in instructing
  • their pupils, even in the sciences which were supposed necessary for that
  • profession; yet they gradually drew to themselves the education of almost
  • all other people, particularly of almost all gentlemen and men of fortune.
  • No better method, it seems, could be fallen upon, of spending, with any
  • advantage, the long interval between infancy and that period of life at
  • which men begin to apply in good earnest to the real business of the
  • world, the business which is to employ them during the remainder of their
  • days. The greater part of what is taught in schools and universities,
  • however, does not seem to be the most proper preparation for that
  • business.
  • In England, it becomes every day more and more the custom to send young
  • people to travel in foreign countries immediately upon their leaving
  • school, and without sending them to any university. Our young people, it
  • is said, generally return home much improved by their travels. A young
  • man, who goes abroad at seventeen or eighteen, and returns home at
  • one-and-twenty, returns three or four years older than he was when he went
  • abroad; and at that age it is very difficult not to improve a good deal in
  • three or four years. In the course of his travels, he generally acquires
  • some knowledge of one or two foreign languages; a knowledge, however,
  • which is seldom sufficient to enable him either to speak or write them
  • with propriety. In other respects, he commonly returns home more
  • conceited, more unprincipled, more dissipated, and more incapable of my
  • serious application, either to study or to business, than he could well
  • have become in so short a time had he lived at home. By travelling so very
  • young, by spending in the most frivolous dissipation the most previous
  • years of his life, at a distance from the inspection and control of his
  • parents and relations, every useful habit, which the earlier parts of his
  • education might have had some tendency to form in him, instead of being
  • riveted and confirmed, is almost necessarily either weakened or effaced.
  • Nothing but the discredit into which the universities are allowing
  • themselves to fall, could ever have brought into repute so very absurd a
  • practice as that of travelling at this early period of life. By sending
  • his son abroad, a father delivers himself, at least for some time, from so
  • disagreeable an object as that of a son unemployed, neglected, and going
  • to ruin before his eyes.
  • Such have been the effects of some of the modern institutions for
  • education.
  • Different plans and different institutions for education seem to have
  • taken place in other ages and nations.
  • In the republics of ancient Greece, every free citizen was instructed,
  • under the direction of the public magistrate, in gymnastic exercises and
  • in music. By gymnastic exercises, it was intended to harden his body, to
  • sharpen his courage, and to prepare him for the fatigues and dangers of
  • war; and as the Greek militia was, by all accounts, one of the best that
  • ever was in the world, this part of their public education must have
  • answered completely the purpose for which it was intended. By the other
  • part, music, it was proposed, at least by the philosophers and historians,
  • who have given us an account of those institutions, to humanize the mind,
  • to soften the temper, and to dispose it for performing all the social and
  • moral duties of public and private life.
  • In ancient Rome, the exercises of the Campus Martius answered the same
  • purpose as those of the Gymnasium in ancient Greece, and they seem to have
  • answered it equally well. But among the Romans there was nothing which
  • corresponded to the musical education of the Greeks. The morals of the
  • Romans, however, both in private and public life, seem to have been, not
  • only equal, but, upon the whole, a good deal superior to those of the
  • Greeks. That they were superior in private life, we have the express
  • testimony of Polybius, and of Dionysius of Halicarnassus, two authors well
  • acquainted with both nations; and the whole tenor of the Greek and Roman
  • history bears witness to the superiority of the public morals of the
  • Romans. The good temper and moderation of contending factions seem to be
  • the most essential circumstances in the public morals of a free people.
  • But the factions of the Greeks were almost always violent and sanguinary;
  • whereas, till the time of the Gracchi, no blood had ever been shed in any
  • Roman faction; and from the time of the Gracchi, the Roman republic may be
  • considered as in reality dissolved. Notwithstanding, therefore, the very
  • respectable authority of Plato, Aristotle, and Polybius, and
  • notwithstanding the very ingenious reasons by which Mr. Montesquieu
  • endeavours to support that authority, it seems probable that the musical
  • education of the Greeks had no great effect in mending their morals,
  • since, without any such education, those of the Romans were, upon the
  • whole, superior. The respect of those ancient sages for the institutions
  • of their ancestors had probably disposed them to find much political
  • wisdom in what was, perhaps, merely an ancient custom, continued, without
  • interruption, from the earliest period of those societies, to the times in
  • which they had arrived at a considerable degree of refinement. Music and
  • dancing are the great amusements of almost all barbarous nations, and the
  • great accomplishments which are supposed to fit any man for entertaining
  • his society. It is so at this day among the negroes on the coast of
  • Africa. It was so among the ancient Celtes, among the ancient
  • Scandinavians, and, as we may learn from Homer, among the ancient Greeks,
  • in the times preceding the Trojan war. When the Greek tribes had formed
  • themselves into little republics, it was natural that the study of those
  • accomplishments should for a long time make a part of the public and
  • common education of the people.
  • The masters who instructed the young people, either in music or in
  • military exercises, do not seem to have been paid, or even appointed by
  • the state, either in Rome or even at Athens, the Greek republic of whose
  • laws and customs we are the best informed. The state required that every
  • free citizen should fit himself for defending it in war, and should upon
  • that account, learn his military exercises. But it left him to learn them
  • of such masters as he could find; and it seems to have advanced nothing
  • for this purpose, but a public field or place of exercise, in which he
  • should practise and perform them.
  • In the early ages, both of the Greek and Roman republics, the other parts
  • of education seem to have consisted in learning to read, write, and
  • account, according to the arithmetic of the times. These accomplishments
  • the richer citizens seem frequently to have acquired at home, by the
  • assistance of some domestic pedagogue, who was, generally, either a slave
  • or a freedman; and the poorer citizens in the schools of such masters as
  • made a trade of teaching for hire. Such parts of education, however, were
  • abandoned altogether to the care of the parents or guardians of each
  • individual. It does not appear that the state ever assumed any inspection
  • or direction of them. By a law of Solon, indeed, the children were
  • acquitted from maintaining those parents who had neglected to instruct
  • them in some profitable trade or business.
  • In the progress of refinement, when philosophy and rhetoric came into
  • fashion, the better sort of people used to send their children to the
  • schools of philosophers and rhetoricians, in order to be instructed in
  • these fashionable sciences. But those schools were not supported by the
  • public. They were, for a long time, barely tolerated by it. The demand for
  • philosophy and rhetoric was, for a long time, so small, that the first
  • professed teachers of either could not find constant employment in any one
  • city, but were obliged to travel about from place to place. In this manner
  • lived Zeno of Elea, Protagoras, Gorgias, Hippias, and many others. As the
  • demand increased, the school, both of philosophy and rhetoric, became
  • stationary, first in Athens, and afterwards in several other cities. The
  • state, however, seems never to have encouraged them further, than by
  • assigning to some of them a particular place to teach in, which was
  • sometimes done, too, by private donors. The state seems to have assigned
  • the Academy to Plato, the Lyceum to Aristotle, and the Portico to Zeno of
  • Citta, the founder of the Stoics. But Epicurus bequeathed his gardens to
  • his own school. Till about the time of Marcus Antoninus, however, no
  • teacher appears to have had any salary from the public, or to have had any
  • other emoluments, but what arose from the honorarius or fees of his
  • scholars. The bounty which that philosophical emperor, as we learn from
  • Lucian, bestowed upon one of the teachers of philosophy, probably lasted
  • no longer than his own life. There was nothing equivalent to the
  • privileges of graduation; and to have attended any of those schools was
  • not necessary, in order to be permitted to practise any particular trade
  • or profession. If the opinion of their own utility could not draw scholars
  • to them, the law neither forced anybody to go to them, nor rewarded
  • anybody for having gone to them. The teachers had no jurisdiction over
  • their pupils, nor any other authority besides that natural authority which
  • superior virtue and abilities never fail to procure from young people
  • towards those who are entrusted with any part of their education.
  • At Rome, the study of the civil law made a part of the education, not of
  • the greater part of the citizens, but of some particular families. The
  • young people, however, who wished to acquire knowledge in the law, had no
  • public school to go to, and had no other method of studying it, than by
  • frequenting the company of such of their relations and friends as were
  • supposed to understand it. It is, perhaps, worth while to remark, that
  • though the laws of the twelve tables were many of them copied from those
  • of some ancient Greek republics, yet law never seems to have grown up to
  • be a science in any republic of ancient Greece. In Rome it became a
  • science very early, and gave a considerable degree of illustration to
  • those citizens who had the reputation of understanding it. In the
  • republics of ancient Greece, particularly in Athens, the ordinary courts
  • of justice consisted of numerous, and therefore disorderly, bodies of
  • people, who frequently decided almost at random, or as clamour, faction,
  • and party-spirit, happened to determine. The ignominy of an unjust
  • decision, when it was to be divided among five hundred, a thousand, or
  • fifteen hundred people (for some of their courts were so very numerous),
  • could not fall very heavy upon any individual. At Rome, on the contrary,
  • the principal courts of justice consisted either of a single judge, or of
  • a small number of judges, whose characters, especially as they deliberated
  • always in public, could not fail to be very much affected by any rash or
  • unjust decision. In doubtful cases such courts, from their anxiety to
  • avoid blame, would naturally endeavour to shelter themselves under the
  • example or precedent of the judges who had sat before them, either in the
  • same or in some other court. This attention to practice and precedent,
  • necessarily formed the Roman law into that regular and orderly system in
  • which it has been delivered down to us; and the like attention has had the
  • like effects upon the laws of every other country where such attention has
  • taken place. The superiority of character in the Romans over that of the
  • Greeks, so much remarked by Polybius and Dionysius of Halicarnassus, was
  • probably more owing to the better constitution of their courts of justice,
  • than to any of the circumstances to which those authors ascribe it. The
  • Romans are said to have been particularly distinguished for their superior
  • respect to an oath. But the people who were accustomed to make oath only
  • before some diligent and well informed court of justice, would naturally
  • be much more attentive to what they swore, than they who were accustomed
  • to do the same thing before mobbish and disorderly assemblies.
  • The abilities, both civil and military, of the Greeks and Romans, will
  • readily be allowed to have been at least equal to those of any modern
  • nation. Our prejudice is perhaps rather to overrate them. But except in
  • what related to military exercises, the state seems to have been at no
  • pains to form those great abilities; for I cannot be induced to believe
  • that the musical education of the Greeks could be of much consequence in
  • forming them. Masters, however, had been found, it seems, for instructing
  • the better sort of people among those nations, in every art and science in
  • which the circumstances of their society rendered it necessary or
  • convenient for them to be instructed. The demand for such instruction
  • produced, what it always produces, the talent for giving it; and the
  • emulation which an unrestrained competition never fails to excite, appears
  • to have brought that talent to a very high degree of perfection. In the
  • attention which the ancient philosophers excited, in the empire which they
  • acquired over the opinions and principles of their auditors, in the
  • faculty which they possessed of giving a certain tone and character to the
  • conduct and conversation of those auditors, they appear to have been much
  • superior to any modern teachers. In modern times, the diligence of public
  • teachers is more or less corrupted by the circumstances which render them
  • more or less independent of their success and reputation in their
  • particular professions. Their salaries, too, put the private teacher, who
  • would pretend to come into competition with them, in the same state with a
  • merchant who attempts to trade without a bounty, in competition with those
  • who trade with a considerable one. If he sells his goods at nearly the
  • same price, he cannot have the same profit; and poverty and beggary at
  • least, if not bankruptcy and ruin, will infallibly be his lot. If he
  • attempts to sell them much dearer, he is likely to have so few customers,
  • that his circumstances will not be much mended. The privileges of
  • graduation, besides, are in many countries necessary, or at least
  • extremely convenient, to most men of learned professions, that is, to the
  • far greater part of those who have occasion for a learned education. But
  • those privileges can be obtained only by attending the lectures of the
  • public teachers. The most careful attendance upon the ablest instructions
  • of any private teacher cannot always give any title to demand them. It is
  • from these different causes that the private teacher of any of the
  • sciences, which are commonly taught in universities, is, in modern times,
  • generally considered as in the very lowest order of men of letters. A man
  • of real abilities can scarce find out a more humiliating or a more
  • unprofitable employment to turn them to. The endowments of schools and
  • colleges have in this manner not only corrupted the diligence of public
  • teachers, but have rendered it almost impossible to have any good private
  • ones.
  • Were there no public institutions for education, no system, no science,
  • would be taught, for which there was not some demand, or which the
  • circumstances of the times did not render it either necessary or
  • convenient, or at least fashionable to learn. A private teacher could
  • never find his account in teaching either an exploded and antiquated
  • system of a science acknowledged to be useful, or a science universally
  • believed to be a mere useless and pedantic heap of sophistry and nonsense.
  • Such systems, such sciences, can subsist nowhere but in those incorporated
  • societies for education, whose prosperity and revenue are in a great
  • measure independent of their industry. Were there no public institutions
  • for education, a gentleman, after going through, with application and
  • abilities, the most complete course of education which the circumstances
  • of the times were supposed to afford, could not come into the world
  • completely ignorant of everything which is the common subject of
  • conversation among gentlemen and men of the world.
  • There are no public institutions for the education of women, and there is
  • accordingly nothing useless, absurd, or fantastical, in the common course
  • of their education. They are taught what their parents or guardians judge
  • it necessary or useful for them to learn, and they are taught nothing
  • else. Every part of their education tends evidently to some useful
  • purpose; either to improve the natural attractions of their person, or to
  • form their mind to reserve, to modesty, to chastity, and to economy; to
  • render them both likely to became the mistresses of a family, and to
  • behave properly when they have become such. In every part of her life, a
  • woman feels some conveniency or advantage from every part of her
  • education. It seldom happens that a man, in any part of his life, derives
  • any conveniency or advantage from some of the most laborious and
  • troublesome parts of his education.
  • Ought the public, therefore, to give no attention, it may be asked, to the
  • education of the people? Or, if it ought to give any, what are the
  • different parts of education which it ought to attend to in the different
  • orders of the people? and in what manner ought it to attend to them?
  • In some cases, the state of society necessarily places the greater part of
  • individuals in such situations as naturally form in them, without any
  • attention of government, almost all the abilities and virtues which that
  • state requires, or perhaps can admit of. In other cases, the state of the
  • society does not place the greater part of individuals in such situations;
  • and some attention of government is necessary, in order to prevent the
  • almost entire corruption and degeneracy of the great body of the people.
  • In the progress of the division of labour, the employment of the far
  • greater part of those who live by labour, that is, of the great body of
  • the people, comes to be confined to a few very simple operations;
  • frequently to one or two. But the understandings of the greater part of
  • men are necessarily formed by their ordinary employments. The man whose
  • whole life is spent in performing a few simple operations, of which the
  • effects, too, are perhaps always the same, or very nearly the same, has no
  • occasion to exert his understanding, or to exercise his invention, in
  • finding out expedients for removing difficulties which never occur. He
  • naturally loses, therefore, the habit of such exertion, and generally
  • becomes as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to
  • become. The torpor of his mind renders him not only incapable of relishing
  • or bearing a part in any rational conversation, but of conceiving any
  • generous, noble, or tender sentiment, and consequently of forming any just
  • judgment concerning many even of the ordinary duties of private life. Of
  • the great and extensive interests of his country he is altogether
  • incapable of judging; and unless very particular pains have been taken to
  • render him otherwise, he is equally incapable of defending his country in
  • war. The uniformity of his stationary life naturally corrupts the courage
  • of his mind, and makes him regard, with abhorrence, the irregular,
  • uncertain, and adventurous life of a soldier. It corrupts even the
  • activity of his body, and renders him incapable of exerting his strength
  • with vigour and perseverance in any other employment, than that to which
  • he has been bred. His dexterity at his own particular trade seems, in this
  • manner, to be acquired at the expense of his intellectual, social, and
  • martial virtues. But in every improved and civilized society, this is the
  • state into which the labouring poor, that is, the great body of the
  • people, must necessarily fall, unless government takes some pains to
  • prevent it.
  • It is otherwise in the barbarous societies, as they are commonly called,
  • of hunters, of shepherds, and even of husbandmen in that rude state of
  • husbandry which precedes the improvement of manufactures, and the
  • extension of foreign commerce. In such societies, the varied occupations
  • of every man oblige every man to exert his capacity, and to invent
  • expedients for removing difficulties which are continually occurring.
  • Invention is kept alive, and the mind is not suffered to fall into that
  • drowsy stupidity, which, in a civilized society, seems to benumb the
  • understanding of almost all the inferior ranks of people. In those
  • barbarous societies, as they are called, every man, it has already been
  • observed, is a warrior. Every man, too, is in some measure a statesman,
  • and can form a tolerable judgment concerning the interest of the society,
  • and the conduct of those who govern it. How far their chiefs are good
  • judges in peace, or good leaders in war, is obvious to the observation of
  • almost every single man among them. In such a society, indeed, no man can
  • well acquire that improved and refined understanding which a few men
  • sometimes possess in a more civilized state. Though in a rude society
  • there is a good deal of variety in the occupations of every individual,
  • there is not a great deal in those of the whole society. Every man does,
  • or is capable of doing, almost every thing which any other man does, or is
  • capable of being. Every man has a considerable degree of knowledge,
  • ingenuity, and invention but scarce any man has a great degree. The
  • degree, however, which is commonly possessed, is generally sufficient for
  • conducting the whole simple business of the society. In a civilized state,
  • on the contrary, though there is little variety in the occupations of the
  • greater part of individuals, there is an almost infinite variety in those
  • of the whole society. These varied occupations present an almost infinite
  • variety of objects to the contemplation of those few, who, being attached
  • to no particular occupation themselves, have leisure and inclination to
  • examine the occupations of other people. The contemplation of so great a
  • variety of objects necessarily exercises their minds in endless
  • comparisons and combinations, and renders their understandings, in an
  • extraordinary degree, both acute anti comprehensive. Unless those few,
  • however, happen to be placed in some very particular situations, their
  • great abilities, though honourable to themselves, may contribute very
  • little to the good government or happiness of their society.
  • Notwithstanding the great abilities of those few, all the nobler parts of
  • the human character may be, in a great measure, obliterated and
  • extinguished in the great body of the people.
  • The education of the common people requires, perhaps, in a civilized and
  • commercial society, the attention of the public, more than that of people
  • of some rank and fortune. People of some rank and fortune are generally
  • eighteen or nineteen years of age before they enter upon that particular
  • business, profession, or trade, by which they propose to distinguish
  • themselves in the world. They have, before that, full time to acquire, or
  • at least to fit themselves for afterwards acquiring, every accomplishment
  • which can recommend them to the public esteem, or render them worthy of
  • it. Their parents or guardians are generally sufficiently anxious that
  • they should be so accomplished, and are in most cases, willing enough to
  • lay out the expense which is necessary for that purpose. If they are not
  • always properly educated, it is seldom from the want of expense laid out
  • upon their education, but from the improper application of that expense.
  • It is seldom from the want of masters, but from the negligence and
  • incapacity of the masters who are to be had, and from the difficulty, or
  • rather from the impossibility, which there is, in the present state of
  • things, of finding any better. The employments, too, in which people of
  • some rank or fortune spend the greater part of their lives, are not, like
  • those of the common people, simple and uniform. They are almost all of
  • them extremely complicated, and such as exercise the head more than the
  • hands. The understandings of those who are engaged in such employments,
  • can seldom grow torpid for want of exercise. The employments of people of
  • some rank and fortune, besides, are seldom such as harass them from
  • morning to night. They generally have a good deal of leisure, during which
  • they may perfect themselves in every branch, either of useful or
  • ornamental knowledge, of which they may have laid the foundation, or for
  • which they may have acquired some taste in the earlier part of life.
  • It is otherwise with the common people. They have little time to spare for
  • education. Their parents can scarce afford to maintain them, even in
  • infancy. As soon as they are able to work, they must apply to some trade,
  • by which they can earn their subsistence. That trade, too, is generally so
  • simple and uniform, as to give little exercise to the understanding;
  • while, at the same time, their labour is both so constant and so severe,
  • that it leaves them little leisure and less inclination to apply to, or
  • even to think of any thing else.
  • But though the common people cannot, in any civilized society, be so well
  • instructed as people of some rank and fortune; the most essential parts of
  • education, however, to read, write, and account, can be acquired at so
  • early a period of life, that the greater part, even of those who are to be
  • bred to the lowest occupations, have time to acquire them before they can
  • be employed in those occupations. For a very small expense, the public can
  • facilitate, can encourage and can even impose upon almost the whole body
  • of the people, the necessity of acquiring those most essential parts of
  • education.
  • The public can facilitate this acquisition, by establishing in every
  • parish or district a little school, where children maybe taught for a
  • reward so moderate, that even a common labourer may afford it; the master
  • being partly, but not wholly, paid by the public; because, if he was
  • wholly, or even principally, paid by it, he would soon learn to neglect
  • his business. In Scotland, the establishment of such parish schools has
  • taught almost the whole common people to read, and a very great proportion
  • of them to write and account. In England, the establishment of charity
  • schools has had an effect of the same kind, though not so universally,
  • because the establishment is not so universal. If, in those little
  • schools, the books by which the children are taught to read, were a little
  • more instructive than they commonly are; and if, instead of a little
  • smattering in Latin, which the children of the common people are sometimes
  • taught there, and which can scarce ever be of any use to them, they were
  • instructed in the elementary parts of geometry and mechanics; the literary
  • education of this rank of people would, perhaps, be as complete as can be.
  • There is scarce a common trade, which does not afford some opportunities
  • of applying to it the principles of geometry and mechanics, and which
  • would not, therefore, gradually exercise and improve the common people in
  • those principles, the necessary introduction to the most sublime, as well
  • as to the most useful sciences.
  • The public can encourage the acquisition of those most essential parts of
  • education, by giving small premiums, and little badges of distinction, to
  • the children of the common people who excel in them.
  • The public can impose upon almost the whole body of the people the
  • necessity of acquiring the most essential parts of education, by obliging
  • every man to undergo an examination or probation in them, before he can
  • obtain the freedom in any corporation, or be allowed to set up any trade,
  • either in a village or town corporate.
  • It was in this manner, by facilitating the acquisition of their military
  • and gymnastic exercises, by encouraging it, and even by imposing upon the
  • whole body of the people the necessity of learning those exercises, that
  • the Greek and Roman republics maintained the martial spirit of their
  • respective citizens. They facilitated the acquisition of those exercises,
  • by appointing a certain place for learning and practising them, and by
  • granting to certain masters the privilege of teaching in that place. Those
  • masters do not appear to have had either salaries or exclusive privileges
  • of any kind. Their reward consisted altogether in what they got from their
  • scholars; and a citizen, who had learnt his exercises in the public
  • gymnasia, had no sort of legal advantage over one who had learnt them
  • privately, provided the latter had learned them equally well. Those
  • republics encouraged the acquisition of those exercises, by bestowing
  • little premiums and badges of distinction upon those who excelled in them.
  • To have gained a prize in the Olympic, Isthmian, or Nemaean games, gave
  • illustration, not only to the person who gained it, but to his whole
  • family and kindred. The obligation which every citizen was under, to serve
  • a certain number of years, if called upon, in the armies of the republic,
  • sufficiently imposed the necessity of learning those exercises, without
  • which he could not be fit for that service.
  • That in the progress of improvement, the practice of military exercises,
  • unless government takes proper pains to support it, goes gradually to
  • decay, and, together with it, the martial spirit of the great body of the
  • people, the example of modern Europe sufficiently demonstrates. But the
  • security of every society must always depend, more or less, upon the
  • martial spirit of the great body of the people. In the present times,
  • indeed, that martial spirit alone, and unsupported by a well-disciplined
  • standing army, would not, perhaps, be sufficient for the defence and
  • security of any society. But where every citizen had the spirit of a
  • soldier, a smaller standing army would surely be requisite. That spirit,
  • besides, would necessarily diminish very much the dangers to liberty,
  • whether real or imaginary, which are commonly apprehended from a standing
  • army. As it would very much facilitate the operations of that army against
  • a foreign invader; so it would obstruct them as much, if unfortunately
  • they should ever be directed against the constitution of the state.
  • The ancient institutions of Greece and Rome seem to have been much more
  • effectual for maintaining the martial spirit of the great body of the
  • people, than the establishment of what are called the militias of modern
  • times. They were much more simple. When they were once established, they
  • executed themselves, and it required little or no attention from
  • government to maintain them in the most perfect vigour. Whereas to
  • maintain, even in tolerable execution, the complex regulations of any
  • modern militia, requires the continual and painful attention of
  • government, without which they are constantly falling into total neglect
  • and disuse. The influence, besides, of the ancient institutions, was much
  • more universal. By means of them, the whole body of the people was
  • completely instructed in the use of arms; whereas it is but a very small
  • part of them who can ever be so instructed by the regulations of any
  • modern militia, except, perhaps, that of Switzerland. But a coward, a man
  • incapable either of defending or of revenging himself, evidently wants one
  • of the most essential parts of the character of a man. He is as much
  • mutilated and deformed in his mind as another is in his body, who is
  • either deprived of some of its most essential members, or has lost the use
  • of them. He is evidently the more wretched and miserable of the two;
  • because happiness and misery, which reside altogether in the mind, must
  • necessarily depend more upon the healthful or unhealthful, the mutilated
  • or entire state of the mind, than upon that of the body. Even though the
  • martial spirit of the people were of no use towards the defence of the
  • society, yet, to prevent that sort of mental mutilation, deformity, and
  • wretchedness, which cowardice necessarily involves in it, from spreading
  • themselves through the great body of the people, would still deserve the
  • most serious attention of government; in the same manner as it would
  • deserve its most serious attention to prevent a leprosy, or any other
  • loathsome and offensive disease, though neither mortal nor dangerous, from
  • spreading itself among them; though, perhaps, no other public good might
  • result from such attention, besides the prevention of so great a public
  • evil.
  • The same thing may be said of the gross ignorance and stupidity which, in
  • a civilized society, seem so frequently to benumb the understandings of
  • all the inferior ranks of people. A man without the proper use of the
  • intellectual faculties of a man, is, if possible, more contemptible than
  • even a coward, and seems to be mutilated and deformed in a still more
  • essential part of the character of human nature. Though the state was to
  • derive no advantage from the instruction of the inferior ranks of people,
  • it would still deserve its attention that they should not be altogether
  • uninstructed. The state, however, derives no inconsiderable advantage from
  • their instruction. The more they are instructed, the less liable they are
  • to the delusions of enthusiasm and superstition, which, among ignorant
  • nations frequently occasion the most dreadful disorders. An instructed and
  • intelligent people, besides, are always more decent and orderly than an
  • ignorant and stupid one. They feel themselves, each individually, more
  • respectable, and more likely to obtain the respect of their lawful
  • superiors, and they are, therefore, more disposed to respect those
  • superiors. They are more disposed to examine, and more capable of seeing
  • through, the interested complaints of faction and sedition; and they are,
  • upon that account, less apt to be misled into any wanton or unnecessary
  • opposition to the measures of government. In free countries, where the
  • safety of government depends very much upon the favourable judgment which
  • the people may form of its conduct, it must surely be of the highest
  • importance, that they should not be disposed to judge rashly or
  • capriciously concerning it.
  • Art. III.—Of the Expense of the Institutions for the Instruction of
  • People of all Ages.
  • The institutions for the instruction of people of all ages, are chiefly
  • those for religious instruction. This is a species of instruction, of
  • which the object is not so much to render the people good citizens in this
  • world, as to prepare them for another and a better world in the life to
  • come. The teachers of the doctrine which contains this instruction, in the
  • same manner as other teachers, may either depend altogether for their
  • subsistence upon the voluntary contributions of their hearers; or they may
  • derive it from some other fund, to which the law of their country may
  • entitle them; such as a landed estate, a tythe or land tax, an established
  • salary or stipend. Their exertion, their zeal and industry, are likely to
  • be much greater in the former situation than in the latter. In this
  • respect, the teachers of a new religion have always had a considerable
  • advantage in attacking those ancient and established systems, of which the
  • clergy, reposing themselves upon their benefices, had neglected to keep up
  • the fervour of faith and devotion in the great body of the people; and
  • having given themselves up to indolence, were become altogether incapable
  • of making any vigorous exertion in defence even of their own
  • establishment. The clergy of an established and well endowed religion
  • frequently become men of learning and elegance, who possess all the
  • virtues of gentlemen, or which can recommend them to the esteem of
  • gentlemen; but they are apt gradually to lose the qualities, both good and
  • bad, which gave them authority and influence with the inferior ranks of
  • people, and which had perhaps been the original causes of the success and
  • establishment of their religion. Such a clergy, when attacked by a set of
  • popular and bold, though perhaps stupid and ignorant enthusiasts, feel
  • themselves as perfectly defenceless as the indolent, effeminate, and full
  • fed nations of the southern parts of Asia, when they were invaded by the
  • active, hardy, and hungry Tartars of the north. Such a clergy, upon such
  • an emergency, have commonly no other resource than to call upon the civil
  • magistrate to persecute, destroy, or drive out their adversaries, as
  • disturbers of the public peace. It was thus that the Roman catholic clergy
  • called upon the civil magistrate to persecute the protestants, and the
  • church of England to persecute the dissenters; and that in general every
  • religious sect, when it has once enjoyed, for a century or two, the
  • security of a legal establishment, has found itself incapable of making
  • any vigorous defence against any new sect which chose to attack its
  • doctrine or discipline. Upon such occasions, the advantage, in point of
  • learning and good writing, may sometimes be on the side of the established
  • church. But the arts of popularity, all the arts of gaining proselytes,
  • are constantly on the side of its adversaries. In England, those arts have
  • been long neglected by the well endowed clergy of the established church,
  • and are at present chiefly cultivated by the dissenters and by the
  • methodists. The independent provisions, however, which in many places have
  • been made for dissenting teachers, by means of voluntary subscriptions, of
  • trust rights, and other evasions of the law, seem very much to have abated
  • the zeal and activity of those teachers. They have many of them become
  • very learned, ingenious, and respectable men; but they have in general
  • ceased to be very popular preachers. The methodists, without half the
  • learning of the dissenters, are much more in vogue.
  • In the church of Rome the industry and zeal of the inferior clergy are
  • kept more alive by the powerful motive of self-interest, than perhaps in
  • any established protestant church. The parochial clergy derive many of
  • them, a very considerable part of their subsistence from the voluntary
  • oblations of the people; a source of revenue, which confession gives them
  • many opportunities of improving. The mendicant orders derive their whole
  • subsistence from such oblations. It is with them as with the hussars and
  • light infantry of some armies; no plunder, no pay. The parochial clergy
  • are like those teachers whose reward depends partly upon their salary, and
  • partly upon the fees or honoraries which they get from their pupils; and
  • these must always depend, more or less, upon their industry and
  • reputation. The mendicant orders are like those teachers whose subsistence
  • depends altogether upon their industry. They are obliged, therefore, to
  • use every art which can animate the devotion of the common people. The
  • establishment of the two great mendicant orders of St Dominic and St.
  • Francis, it is observed by Machiavel, revived, in the thirteenth and
  • fourteenth centuries, the languishing faith and devotion of the catholic
  • church. In Roman catholic countries, the spirit of devotion is supported
  • altogether by the monks, and by the poorer parochial clergy. The great
  • dignitaries of the church, with all the accomplishments of gentlemen and
  • men of the world, and sometimes with those of men of learning, are careful
  • to maintain the necessary discipline over their inferiors, but seldom give
  • themselves any trouble about the instruction of the people.
  • “Most of the arts and professions in a state,” says by far the most
  • illustrious philosopher and historian of the present age, “are of such a
  • nature, that, while they promote the interests of the society, they are
  • also useful or agreeable to some individuals; and, in that case, the
  • constant rule of the magistrate, except, perhaps, on the first
  • introduction of any art, is, to leave the profession to itself, and trust
  • its encouragement to the individuals who reap the benefit of it. The
  • artizans, finding their profits to rise by the favour of their customers,
  • increase, as much as possible, their skill and industry; and as matters
  • are not disturbed by any injudicious tampering, the commodity is always
  • sure to be at all times nearly proportioned to the demand.
  • “But there are also some callings which, though useful and even necessary
  • in a state, bring no advantage or pleasure to any individual; and the
  • supreme power is obliged to alter its conduct with regard to the retainers
  • of those professions. It must give them public encouragement in order to
  • their subsistence; and it must provide against that negligence to which
  • they will naturally be subject, either by annexing particular honours to
  • profession, by establishing a long subordination of ranks, and a strict
  • dependence, or by some other expedient. The persons employed in the
  • finances, fleets, and magistracy, are instances of this order of men.
  • “It may naturally be thought, at first sight, that the ecclesiastics
  • belong to the first class, and that their encouragement, as well as that
  • of lawyers and physicians, may safely be entrusted to the liberality of
  • individuals, who are attached to their doctrines, and who find benefit or
  • consolation from their spiritual ministry and assistance. Their industry
  • and vigilance will, no doubt, be whetted by such an additional motive; and
  • their skill in the profession, as well as their address in governing the
  • minds of the people, must receive daily increase, from their increasing
  • practice, study, and attention.
  • “But if we consider the matter more closely, we shall find that this
  • interested diligence of the clergy is what every wise legislator will
  • study to prevent; because, in every religion except the true, it is highly
  • pernicious, and it has even a natural tendency to pervert the truth, by
  • infusing into it a strong mixture of superstition, folly, and delusion.
  • Each ghostly practitioner, in order to render himself more precious and
  • sacred in the eyes of his retainers, will inspire them with the most
  • violent abhorrence of all other sects, and continually endeavour, by some
  • novelty, to excite the languid devotion of his audience. No regard will be
  • paid to truth, morals, or decency, in the doctrines inculcated. Every
  • tenet will be adopted that best suits the disorderly affections of the
  • human frame. Customers will be drawn to each conventicle by new industry
  • and address, in practising on the passions and credulity of the populace.
  • And, in the end, the civil magistrate will find that he has dearly paid
  • for his intended frugality, in saving a fixed establishment for the
  • priests; and that, in reality, the most decent and advantageous
  • composition, which he can make with the spiritual guides, is to bribe
  • their indolence, by assigning stated salaries to their profession, and
  • rendering it superfluous for them to be farther active, than merely to
  • prevent their flock from straying in quest of new pastors. And in this
  • manner ecclesiastical establishments, though commonly they arose at first
  • from religious views, prove in the end advantageous to the political
  • interests of society.”
  • But whatever may have been the good or bad effects of the independent
  • provision of the clergy, it has, perhaps, been very seldom bestowed upon
  • them from any view to those effects. Times of violent religious
  • controversy have generally been times of equally violent political
  • faction. Upon such occasions, each political party has either found it, or
  • imagined it, for his interest, to league itself with some one or other of
  • the contending religious sects. But this could be done only by adopting,
  • or, at least, by favouring the tenets of that particular sect. The sect
  • which had the good fortune to be leagued with the conquering party
  • necessarily shared in the victory of its ally, by whose favour and
  • protection it was soon enabled, in some degree, to silence and subdue all
  • its adversaries. Those adversaries had generally leagued themselves with
  • the enemies of the conquering party, and were, therefore the enemies of
  • that party. The clergy of this particular sect having thus become complete
  • masters of the field, and their influence and authority with the great
  • body of the people being in its highest vigour, they were powerful enough
  • to overawe the chiefs and leaders of their own party, and to oblige the
  • civil magistrate to respect their opinions and inclinations. Their first
  • demand was generally that he should silence and subdue all their
  • adversaries; and their second, that he should bestow an independent
  • provision on themselves. As they had generally contributed a good deal to
  • the victory, it seemed not unreasonable that they should have some share
  • in the spoil. They were weary, besides, of humouring the people, and of
  • depending upon their caprice for a subsistence. In making this demand,
  • therefore, they consulted their own ease and comfort, without troubling
  • themselves about the effect which it might have, in future times, upon the
  • influence and authority of their order. The civil magistrate, who could
  • comply with their demand only by giving them something which he would have
  • chosen much rather to take, or to keep to himself, was seldom very forward
  • to grant it. Necessity, however, always forced him to submit at last,
  • though frequently not till after many delays, evasions, and affected
  • excuses.
  • But if politics had never called in the aid of religion, had the
  • conquering party never adopted the tenets of one sect more than those of
  • another, when it had gained the victory, it would probably have dealt
  • equally and impartially with all the different sects, and have allowed
  • every man to choose his own priest, and his own religion, as he thought
  • proper. There would, and, in this case, no doubt, have been, a great
  • multitude of religious sects. Almost every different congregation might
  • probably have had a little sect by itself, or have entertained some
  • peculiar tenets of its own. Each teacher, would, no doubt, have felt
  • himself under the necessity of making the utmost exertion, and of using
  • every art, both to preserve and to increase the number of his disciples.
  • But as every other teacher would have felt himself under the same
  • necessity, the success of no one teacher, or sect of teachers, could have
  • been very great. The interested and active zeal of religious teachers can
  • be dangerous and troublesome only where there is either but one sect
  • tolerated in the society, or where the whole of a large society is divided
  • into two or three great sects; the teachers of each acting by concert, and
  • under a regular discipline and subordination. But that zeal must be
  • altogether innocent, where the society is divided into two or three
  • hundred, or, perhaps, into as many thousand small sects, of which no one
  • could be considerable enough to disturb the public tranquillity. The
  • teachers of each sect, seeing themselves surrounded on all sides with more
  • adversaries than friends, would be obliged to learn that candour and
  • moderation which are so seldom to be found among the teachers of those
  • great sects, whose tenets, being supported by the civil magistrate, are
  • held in veneration by almost all the inhabitants of extensive kingdoms and
  • empires, and who, therefore, see nothing round them but followers,
  • disciples, and humble admirers. The teachers of each little sect, finding
  • themselves almost alone, would be obliged to respect those of almost every
  • other sect; and the concessions which they would mutually find in both
  • convenient and agreeable to make one to another, might in time, probably
  • reduce the doctrine of the greater part of them to that pure and rational
  • religion, free from every mixture of absurdity, imposture, or fanaticism,
  • such as wise men have, in all ages of the world, wished to see
  • established; but such as positive law has, perhaps, never yet established,
  • and probably never will establish in any country; because, with regard to
  • religion, positive law always has been, and probably always will be, more
  • or less influenced by popular superstition and enthusiasm. This plan of
  • ecclesiastical government, or, more properly, of no ecclesiastical
  • government, was what the sect called Independents (a sect, no doubt, of
  • very wild enthusiasts), proposed to establish in England towards the end
  • of the civil war. If it had been established, though of a very
  • unphilosophical origin, it would probably, by this time, have been
  • productive of the most philosophical good temper and moderation with
  • regard to every sort of religious principle. It has been established in
  • Pennsylvania, where, though the quakers happen to be the most numerous,
  • the law, in reality, favours no one sect more than another; and it is
  • there said to have been productive of this philosophical good temper and
  • moderation.
  • But though this equality of treatment should not be productive of this
  • good temper and moderation in all, or even in the greater part of the
  • religious sects of a particular country; yet, provided those sects were
  • sufficiently numerous, and each of them consequently too small to disturb
  • the public tranquillity, the excessive zeal of each for its particular
  • tenets could not well be productive of any very hurtful effects, but, on
  • the contrary, of several good ones; and if the government was perfectly
  • decided, both to let them all alone, and to oblige them all to let alone
  • one another, there is little danger that they would not of their own
  • accord, subdivide themselves fast enough, so as soon to become
  • sufficiently numerous.
  • In every civilized society, in every society where the distinction of
  • ranks has once been completely established, there have been always two
  • different schemes or systems of morality current at the same time; of
  • which the one may be called the strict or austere; the other the liberal,
  • or, if you will, the loose system. The former is generally admired and
  • revered by the common people; the latter is commonly more esteemed and
  • adopted by what are called the people of fashion. The degree of
  • disapprobation with which we ought to mark the vices of levity, the vices
  • which are apt to arise from great prosperity, and from the excess of
  • gaiety and good humour, seems to constitute the principal distinction
  • between those two opposite schemes or systems. In the liberal or loose
  • system, luxury, wanton, and even disorderly mirth, the pursuit of pleasure
  • to some degree of intemperance, the breach of chastity, at least in one of
  • the two sexes, etc. provided they are not accompanied with gross
  • indecency, and do not lead to falsehood and injustice, are generally
  • treated with a good deal of indulgence, and are easily either excused or
  • pardoned altogether. In the austere system, on the contrary, those
  • excesses are regarded with the utmost abhorrence and detestation. The
  • vices of levity are always ruinous to the common people, and a single
  • week’s thoughtlessness and dissipation is often sufficient to undo a poor
  • workman for ever, and to drive him, through despair, upon committing the
  • most enormous crimes. The wiser and better sort of the common people,
  • therefore, have always the utmost abhorrence and detestation of such
  • excesses, which their experience tells them are so immediately fatal to
  • people of their condition. The disorder and extravagance of several years,
  • on the contrary, will not always ruin a man of fashion; and people of that
  • rank are very apt to consider the power of indulging in some degree of
  • excess, as one of the advantages of their fortune; and the liberty of
  • doing so without censure or reproach, as one of the privileges which
  • belong to their station. In people of their own station, therefore, they
  • regard such excesses with but a small degree of disapprobation, and
  • censure them either very slightly or not at all.
  • Almost all religious sects have begun among the common people, from whom
  • they have generally drawn their earliest, as well as their most numerous
  • proselytes. The austere system of morality has, accordingly, been adopted
  • by those sects almost constantly, or with very few exceptions; for there
  • have been some. It was the system by which they could best recommend
  • themselves to that order of people, to whom they first proposed their plan
  • of reformation upon what had been before established. Many of them,
  • perhaps the greater part of them, have even endeavoured to gain credit by
  • refining upon this austere system, and by carrying it to some degree of
  • folly and extravagance; and this excessive rigour has frequently
  • recommended them, more than any thing else, to the respect and veneration
  • of the common people.
  • A man of rank and fortune is, by his station, the distinguished member of
  • a great society, who attend to every part of his conduct, and who thereby
  • oblige him to attend to every part of it himself. His authority and
  • consideration depend very much upon the respect which this society bears
  • to him. He dares not do anything which would disgrace or discredit him in
  • it; and he is obliged to a very strict observation of that species of
  • morals, whether liberal or austere, which the general consent of this
  • society prescribes to persons of his rank and fortune. A man of low
  • condition, on the contrary, is far from being a distinguished member of
  • any great society. While he remains in a country village, his conduct may
  • be attended to, and he may be obliged to attend to it himself. In this
  • situation, and in this situation only, he may have what is called a
  • character to lose. But as soon as he comes into a great city, he is sunk
  • in obscurity and darkness. His conduct is observed and attended to by
  • nobody; and he is, therefore, very likely to neglect it himself, and to
  • abandon himself to every sort of low profligacy and vice. He never emerges
  • so effectually from this obscurity, his conduct never excites so much the
  • attention of any respectable society, as by his becoming the member of a
  • small religious sect. He from that moment acquires a degree of
  • consideration which he never had before. All his brother sectaries are,
  • for the credit of the sect, interested to observe his conduct; and, if he
  • gives occasion to any scandal, if he deviates very much from those austere
  • morals which they almost always require of one another, to punish him by
  • what is always a very severe punishment, even where no evil effects attend
  • it, expulsion or excommunication from the sect. In little religious sects,
  • accordingly, the morals of the common people have been almost always
  • remarkably regular and orderly; generally much more so than in the
  • established church. The morals of those little sects, indeed, have
  • frequently been rather disagreeably rigorous and unsocial.
  • There are two very easy and effectual remedies, however, by whose joint
  • operation the state might, without violence, correct whatever was unsocial
  • or disagreeably rigorous in the morals of all the little sects into which
  • the country was divided.
  • The first of those remedies is the study of science and philosophy, which
  • the state might render almost universal among all people of middling or
  • more than middling rank and fortune; not by giving salaries to teachers in
  • order to make them negligent and idle, but by instituting some sort of
  • probation, even in the higher and more difficult sciences, to be undergone
  • by every person before he was permitted to exercise any liberal
  • profession, or before he could be received as a candidate for any
  • honourable office, of trust or profit. If the state imposed upon this
  • order of men the necessity of learning, it would have no occasion to give
  • itself any trouble about providing them with proper teachers. They would
  • soon find better teachers for themselves, than any whom the state could
  • provide for them. Science is the great antidote to the poison of
  • enthusiasm and superstition; and where all the superior ranks of people
  • were secured from it, the inferior ranks could not be much exposed to it.
  • The second of those remedies is the frequency and gaiety of public
  • diversions. The state, by encouraging, that is, by giving entire liberty
  • to all those who, from their own interest, would attempt, without scandal
  • or indecency, to amuse and divert the people by painting, poetry, music,
  • dancing; by all sorts of dramatic representations and exhibitions; would
  • easily dissipate, in the greater part of them, that melancholy and gloomy
  • humour which is almost always the nurse of popular superstition and
  • enthusiasm. Public diversions have always been the objects of dread and
  • hatred to all the fanatical promoters of those popular frenzies. The
  • gaiety and good humour which those diversions inspire, were altogether
  • inconsistent with that temper of mind which was fittest for their purpose,
  • or which they could best work upon. Dramatic representations, besides,
  • frequently exposing their artifices to public ridicule, and sometimes even
  • to public execration, were, upon that account, more than all other
  • diversions, the objects of their peculiar abhorrence.
  • In a country where the law favoured the teachers of no one religion more
  • than those of another, it would not be necessary that any of them should
  • have any particular or immediate dependency upon the sovereign or
  • executive power; or that he should have anything to do either in
  • appointing or in dismissing them from their offices. In such a situation,
  • he would have no occasion to give himself any concern about them, further
  • than to keep the peace among them, in the same manner as among the rest of
  • his subjects, that is, to hinder them from persecuting, abusing, or
  • oppressing one another. But it is quite otherwise in countries where there
  • is an established or governing religion. The sovereign can in this case
  • never be secure, unless he has the means of influencing in a considerable
  • degree the greater part of the teachers of that religion.
  • The clergy of every established church constitute a great incorporation.
  • They can act in concert, and pursue their interest upon one plan, and with
  • one spirit as much as if they were under the direction of one man; and
  • they are frequently, too, under such direction. Their interest as an
  • incorporated body is never the same with that of the sovereign, and is
  • sometimes directly opposite to it. Their great interest is to maintain
  • their authority with the people, and this authority depends upon the
  • supposed certainty and importance of the whole doctrine which they
  • inculcate, and upon the supposed necessity of adopting every part of it
  • with the most implicit faith, in order to avoid eternal misery. Should the
  • sovereign have the imprudence to appear either to deride, or doubt himself
  • of the most trifling part of their doctrine, or from humanity, attempt to
  • protect those who did either the one or the other, the punctilious honour
  • of a clergy, who have no sort of dependency upon him, is immediately
  • provoked to proscribe him as a profane person, and to employ all the
  • terrors of religion, in order to oblige the people to transfer their
  • allegiance to some more orthodox and obedient prince. Should he oppose any
  • of their pretensions or usurpations, the danger is equally great. The
  • princes who have dared in this manner to rebel against the church, over
  • and above this crime of rebellion, have generally been charged, too, with
  • the additional crime of heresy, notwithstanding their solemn protestations
  • of their faith, and humble submission to every tenet which she thought
  • proper to prescribe to them. But the authority of religion is superior to
  • every other authority. The fears which it suggests conquer all other
  • fears. When the authorized teachers of religion propagate through the
  • great body of the people, doctrines subversive of the authority of the
  • sovereign, it is by violence only, or by the force of a standing army,
  • that he can maintain his authority. Even a standing army cannot in this
  • case give him any lasting security; because if the soldiers are not
  • foreigners, which can seldom be the case, but drawn from the great body of
  • the people, which must almost always be the case, they are likely to be
  • soon corrupted by those very doctrines. The revolutions which the
  • turbulence of the Greek clergy was continually occasioning at
  • Constantinople, as long as the eastern empire subsisted; the convulsions
  • which, during the course of several centuries, the turbulence of the Roman
  • clergy was continually occasioning in every part of Europe, sufficiently
  • demonstrate how precarious and insecure must always be the situation of
  • the sovereign, who has no proper means of influencing the clergy of the
  • established and governing religion of his country.
  • Articles of faith, as well as all other spiritual matters, it is evident
  • enough, are not within the proper department of a temporal sovereign, who,
  • though he may be very well qualified for protecting, is seldom supposed to
  • be so for instructing the people. With regard to such matters, therefore,
  • his authority can seldom be sufficient to counterbalance the united
  • authority of the clergy of the established church. The public
  • tranquillity, however, and his own security, may frequently depend upon
  • the doctrines which they may think proper to propagate concerning such
  • matters. As he can seldom directly oppose their decision, therefore, with
  • proper weight and authority, it is necessary that he should be able to
  • influence it; and he can influence it only by the fears and expectations
  • which he may excite in the greater part of the individuals of the order.
  • Those fears and expectations may consist in the fear of deprivation or
  • other punishment, and in the expectation of further preferment.
  • In all Christian churches, the benefices of the clergy are a sort of
  • freeholds, which they enjoy, not during pleasure, but during life or good
  • behaviour. If they held them by a more precarious tenure, and were liable
  • to be turned out upon every slight disobligation either of the sovereign
  • or of his ministers, it would perhaps be impossible for them to maintain
  • their authority with the people, who would then consider them as mercenary
  • dependents upon the court, in the sincerity of whose instructions they
  • could no longer have any confidence. But should the sovereign attempt
  • irregularly, and by violence, to deprive any number of clergymen of their
  • freeholds, on account, perhaps, of their having propagated, with more than
  • ordinary zeal, some factious or seditious doctrine, he would only render,
  • by such persecution, both them and their doctrine ten times more popular,
  • and therefore ten times more troublesome and dangerous, than they had been
  • before. Fear is in almost all cases a wretched instrument of govermnent,
  • and ought in particular never to be employed against any order of men who
  • have the smallest pretensions to independency. To attempt to terrify them,
  • serves only to irritate their bad humour, and to confirm them in an
  • opposition, which more gentle usage, perhaps, might easily induce them
  • either to soften, or to lay aside altogether. The violence which the
  • French government usually employed in order to oblige all their
  • parliaments, or sovereign courts of justice, to enregister any unpopular
  • edict, very seldom succeeded. The means commonly employed, however, the
  • imprisonment of all the refractory members, one would think, were forcible
  • enough. The princes of the house of Stuart sometimes employed the like
  • means in order to influence some of the members of the parliament of
  • England, and they generally found them equally intractable. The parliament
  • of England is now managed in another manner; and a very small experiment,
  • which the duke of Choiseul made, about twelve years ago, upon the
  • parliament of Paris, demonstrated sufficiently that all the parliaments of
  • France might have been managed still more easily in the same manner. That
  • experiment was not pursued. For though management and persuasion are
  • always the easiest and safest instruments of government as force and
  • violence are the worst and the most dangerous; yet such, it seems, is the
  • natural insolence of man, that he almost always disdains to use the good
  • instrument, except when he cannot or dare not use the bad one. The French
  • government could and durst use force, and therefore disdained to use
  • management and persuasion. But there is no order of men, it appears I
  • believe, from the experience of all ages, upon whom it is so dangerous or
  • rather so perfectly ruinous, to employ force and violence, as upon the
  • respected clergy of an established church. The rights, the privileges, the
  • personal liberty of every individual ecclesiastic, who is upon good terms
  • with his own order, are, even in the most despotic governments, more
  • respected than those of any other person of nearly equal rank and fortune.
  • It is so in every gradation of despotism, from that of the gentle and mild
  • government of Paris, to that of the violent and furious government of
  • Constantinople. But though this order of men can scarce ever be forced,
  • they may be managed as easily as any other; and the security of the
  • sovereign, as well as the public tranquillity, seems to depend very much
  • upon the means which he has of managing them; and those means seem to
  • consist altogether in the preferment which he has to bestow upon them.
  • In the ancient constitution of the Christian church, the bishop of each
  • diocese was elected by the joint votes of the clergy and of the people of
  • the episcopal city. The people did not long retain their right of
  • election; and while they did retain it, they almost always acted under the
  • influence of the clergy, who, in such spiritual matters, appeared to be
  • their natural guides. The clergy, however, soon grew weary of the trouble
  • of managing them, and found it easier to elect their own bishops
  • themselves. The abbot, in the same manner, was elected by the monks of the
  • monastery, at least in the greater part of abbacies. All the inferior
  • ecclesiastical benefices comprehended within the diocese were collated by
  • the bishop, who bestowed them upon such ecclesiastics as he thought
  • proper. All church preferments were in this manner in the disposal of the
  • church. The sovereign, though he might have some indirect influence in
  • those elections, and though it was sometimes usual to ask both his consent
  • to elect, and his approbation of the election, yet had no direct or
  • sufficient means of managing the clergy. The ambition of every clergyman
  • naturally led him to pay court, not so much to his sovereign as to his own
  • order, from which only he could expect preferment.
  • Through the greater part of Europe, the pope gradually drew to himself,
  • first the collation of almost all bishoprics and abbacies, or of what were
  • called consistorial benefices, and afterwards, by various machinations and
  • pretences, of the greater part of inferior benefices comprehended within
  • each diocese, little more being left to the bishop than what was barely
  • necessary to give him a decent authority with his own clergy. By this
  • arrangement the condition of the sovereign was still worse than it had
  • been before. The clergy of all the different countries of Europe were thus
  • formed into a sort of spiritual army, dispersed in different quarters
  • indeed, but of which all the movements and operations could now be
  • directed by one head, and conducted upon one uniform plan. The clergy of
  • each particular country might be considered as a particular detachment of
  • that army, of which the operations could easily be supported and seconded
  • by all the other detachments quartered in the different countries round
  • about. Each detachment was not only independent of the sovereign of the
  • country in which it was quartered, and by which it was maintained, but
  • dependent upon a foreign sovereign, who could at any time turn its arms
  • against the sovereign of that particular country, and support them by the
  • arms of all the other detachments.
  • Those arms were the most formidable that can well be imagined. In the
  • ancient state of Europe, before the establishment of arts and
  • manufactures, the wealth of the clergy gave them the same sort of
  • influence over the common people which that of the great barons gave them
  • over their respective vassals, tenants, and retainers. In the great landed
  • estates, which the mistaken piety both of princes and private persons had
  • bestowed upon the church, jurisdictions were established, of the same kind
  • with those of the great barons, and for the same reason. In those great
  • landed estates, the clergy, or their bailiffs, could easily keep the
  • peace, without the support or assistance either of the king or of any
  • other person; and neither the king nor any other person could keep the
  • peace there without the support and assistance of the clergy. The
  • jurisdictions of the clergy, therefore, in their particular baronies or
  • manors, were equally independent, and equally exclusive of the authority
  • of the king’s courts, as those of the great temporal lords. The tenants of
  • the clergy were, like those of the great barons, almost all tenants at
  • will, entirely dependent upon their immediate lords, and, therefore,
  • liable to be called out at pleasure, in order to fight in any quarrel in
  • which the clergy might think proper to engage them. Over and above the
  • rents of those estates, the clergy possessed in the tithes a very large
  • portion of the rents of all the other estates in every kingdom of Europe.
  • The revenues arising from both those species of rents were, the greater
  • part of them, paid in kind, in corn, wine, cattle, poultry, etc. The
  • quantity exceeded greatly what the clergy could themselves consume; and
  • there were neither arts nor manufactures, for the produce of which they
  • could exchange the surplus. The clergy could derive advantage from this
  • immense surplus in no other way than by employing it, as the great barons
  • employed the like surplus of their revenues, in the most profuse
  • hospitality, and in the most extensive charity. Both the hospitality and
  • the charity of the ancient clergy, accordingly, are said to have been very
  • great. They not only maintained almost the whole poor of every kingdom,
  • but many knights and gentlemen had frequently no other means of
  • subsistence than by travelling about from monastery to monastery, under
  • pretence of devotion, but in reality to enjoy the hospitality of the
  • clergy. The retainers of some particular prelates were often as numerous
  • as those of the greatest lay-lords; and the retainers of all the clergy
  • taken together were, perhaps, more numerous than those of all the
  • lay-lords. There was always much more union among the clergy than among
  • the lay-lords. The former were under a regular discipline and
  • subordination to the papal authority. The latter were under no regular
  • discipline or subordination, but almost always equally jealous of one
  • another, and of the king. Though the tenants and retainers of the clergy,
  • therefore, had both together been less numerous than those of the great
  • lay-lords, and their tenants were probably much less numerous, yet their
  • union would have rendered them more formidable. The hospitality and
  • charity of the clergy, too, not only gave them the command of a great
  • temporal force, but increased very much the weight of their spiritual
  • weapons. Those virtues procured them the highest respect and veneration
  • among all the inferior ranks of people, of whom many were constantly, and
  • almost all occasionally, fed by them. Everything belonging or related to
  • so popular an order, its possessions, its privileges, its doctrines,
  • necessarily appeared sacred in the eyes of the common people; and every
  • violation of them, whether real or pretended, the highest act of
  • sacrilegious wickedness and profaneness. In this state of things, if the
  • sovereign frequently found it difficult to resist the confederacy of a few
  • of the great nobility, we cannot wonder that he should find it still more
  • so to resist the united force of the clergy of his own dominions,
  • supported by that of the clergy of all the neighbouring dominions. In such
  • circumstances, the wonder is, not that he was sometimes obliged to yield,
  • but that he ever was able to resist.
  • The privileges of the clergy in those ancient times (which to us, who live
  • in the present times, appear the most absurd), their total exemption from
  • the secular jurisdiction, for example, or what in England was called the
  • benefit of clergy, were the natural, or rather the necessary, consequences
  • of this state of things. How dangerous must it have been for the sovereign
  • to attempt to punish a clergyman for any crime whatever, if his order were
  • disposed to protect him, and to represent either the proof as insufficient
  • for convicting so holy a man, or the punishment as too severe to be
  • inflicted upon one whose person had been rendered sacred by religion? The
  • sovereign could, in such circumstances, do no better than leave him to be
  • tried by the ecclesiastical courts, who, for the honour of their own
  • order, were interested to restrain, as much as possible, every member of
  • it from committing enormous crimes, or even from giving occasion to such
  • gross scandal as might disgust the minds of the people.
  • In the state in which things were, through the greater part of Europe,
  • during the tenth, eleventh, twelfth, and thirteenth centuries, and for
  • some time both before and after that period, the constitution of the
  • church of Rome may be considered as the most formidable combination that
  • ever was formed against the authority and security of civil government, as
  • well as against the liberty, reason, and happiness of mankind, which can
  • flourish only where civil government is able to protect them. In that
  • constitution, the grossest delusions of superstition were supported in
  • such a manner by the private interests of so great a number of people, as
  • put them out of all danger from any assault of human reason; because,
  • though human reason might, perhaps, have been able to unveil, even to the
  • eyes of the common people, some of the delusions of superstition, it could
  • never have dissolved the ties of private interest. Had this constitution
  • been attacked by no other enemies but the feeble efforts of human reason,
  • it must have endured for ever. But that immense and well-built fabric,
  • which all the wisdom and virtue of man could never have shaken, much less
  • have overturned, was, by the natural course of things, first weakened, and
  • afterwards in part destroyed; and is now likely, in the course of a few
  • centuries more, perhaps, to crumble into ruins altogether.
  • The gradual improvements of arts, manufactures, and commerce, the same
  • causes which destroyed the power of the great barons, destroyed, in the
  • same manner, through the greater part of Europe, the whole temporal
  • manufactures, and commerce, the clergy, like the great barons, found
  • something for which they could exchange their rude produce, and thereby
  • discovered the means of spending their whole revenues upon their own
  • persons, without giving any considerable share of them to other people.
  • Their charity became gradually less extensive, their hospitality less
  • liberal, or less profuse. Their retainers became consequently less
  • numerous, and, by degrees, dwindled away altogether. The clergy, too, like
  • the great barons, wished to get a better rent from their landed estates,
  • in order to spend it, in the same manner, upon the gratification of their
  • own private vanity and folly. But this increase of rent could be got only
  • by granting leases to their tenants, who thereby became, in a great
  • measure, independent of them. The ties of interest, which bound the
  • inferior ranks of people to the clergy, were in this manner gradually
  • broken and dissolved. They were even broken and dissolved sooner than
  • those which bound the same ranks of people to the great barons; because
  • the benefices of the church being, the greater part of them, much smaller
  • than the estates of the great barons, the possessor of each benefice was
  • much sooner able to spend the whole of its revenue upon his own person.
  • During the greater part of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, the
  • power of the great barons was, through the greater part of Europe, in full
  • vigour. But the temporal power of the clergy, the absolute command which
  • they had once had over the great body of the people was very much decayed.
  • The power of the church was, by that time, very nearly reduced, through
  • the greater part of Europe, to what arose from their spiritual authority;
  • and even that spiritual authority was much weakened, when it ceased to be
  • supported by the charity and hospitality of the clergy. The inferior ranks
  • of people no longer looked upon that order as they had done before; as the
  • comforters of their distress, and the relievers of their indigence. On the
  • contrary, they were provoked and disgusted by the vanity, luxury, and
  • expense of the richer clergy, who appeared to spend upon their own
  • pleasures what had always before been regarded as the patrimony of the
  • poor.
  • In this situation of things, the sovereigns in the different states of
  • Europe endeavoured to recover the influence which they had once had in the
  • disposal of the great benefices of the church; by procuring to the deans
  • and chapters of each diocese the restoration of their ancient right of
  • electing the bishop; and to the monks of each abbacy that of electing the
  • abbot. The re-establishing this ancient order was the object of several
  • statutes enacted in England during the course of the fourteenth century,
  • particularly of what is called the statute of provisors; and of the
  • pragmatic sanction, established in France in the fifteenth century. In
  • order to render the election valid, it was necessary that the sovereign
  • should both consent to it before hand, and afterwards approve of the
  • person elected; and though the election was still supposed to be free, he
  • had, however all the indirect means which his situation necessarily
  • afforded him, of influencing the clergy in his own dominions. Other
  • regulations, of a similar tendency, were established in other parts of
  • Europe. But the power of the pope, in the collation of the great benefices
  • of the church, seems, before the reformation, to have been nowhere so
  • effectually and so universally restrained as in France and England. The
  • concordat afterwards, in the sixteenth century, gave to the kings of
  • France the absolute right of presenting to all the great, or what are
  • called the consistorial, benefices of the Gallican church.
  • Since the establishment of the pragmatic sanction and of the concordat,
  • the clergy of France have in general shewn less respect to the decrees of
  • the papal court, than the clergy of any other catholic country. In all the
  • disputes which their sovereign has had with the pope, they have almost
  • constantly taken part with the former. This independency of the clergy of
  • France upon the court of Rome seems to be principally founded upon the
  • pragmatic sanction and the concordat. In the earlier periods of the
  • monarchy, the clergy of France appear to have been as much devoted to the
  • pope as those of any other country. When Robert, the second prince of the
  • Capetian race, was most unjustly excommunicated by the court of Rome, his
  • own servants, it is said, threw the victuals which came from his table to
  • the dogs, and refused to taste any thing themselves which had been
  • polluted by the contact of a person in his situation. They were taught to
  • do so, it may very safely be presumed, by the clergy of his own dominions.
  • The claim of collating to the great benefices of the church, a claim in
  • defence of which the court of Rome had frequently shaken, and sometimes
  • overturned, the thrones of some of the greatest sovereigns in Christendom,
  • was in this manner either restrained or modified, or given up altogether,
  • in many different parts of Europe, even before the time of the
  • reformation. As the clergy had now less influence over the people, so the
  • state had more influence over the clergy. The clergy, therefore, had both
  • less power, and less inclination, to disturb the state.
  • The authority of the church of Rome was in this state of declension, when
  • the disputes which gave birth to the reformation began in Germany, and
  • soon spread themselves through every part of Europe. The new doctrines
  • were everywhere received with a high degree of popular favour. They were
  • propagated with all that enthusiastic zeal which commonly animates the
  • spirit of party, when it attacks established authority. The teachers of
  • those doctrines, though perhaps, in other respects, not more learned than
  • many of the divines who defended the established church, seem in general
  • to have been better acquainted with ecclesiastical history, and with the
  • origin and progress of that system of opinions upon which the authority of
  • the church was established; and they had thereby the advantage in almost
  • every dispute. The austerity of their manners gave them authority with the
  • common people, who contrasted the strict regularity of their conduct with
  • the disorderly lives of the greater part of their own clergy. They
  • possessed, too, in a much higher degree than their adversaries, all the
  • arts of popularity and of gaining proselytes; arts which the lofty and
  • dignified sons of the church had long neglected, as being to them in a
  • great measure useless. The reason of the new doctrines recommended them to
  • some, their novelty to many; the hatred and contempt of the established
  • clergy to a still greater number: but the zealous, passionate, and
  • fanatical, though frequently coarse and rustic eloquence, with which they
  • were almost everywhere inculcated, recommended them to by far the greatest
  • number.
  • The success of the new doctrines was almost everywhere so great, that the
  • princes, who at that time happened to be on bad terms with the court of
  • Rome, were, by means of them, easily enabled, in their own dominions, to
  • overturn the church, which having lost the respect and veneration of the
  • inferior ranks of people, could make scarce any resistance. The court of
  • Rome had disobliged some of the smaller princes in the northern parts of
  • Germany, whom it had probably considered as too insignificant to be worth
  • the managing. They universally, therefore, established the reformation in
  • their own dominions. The tyranny of Christiern II., and of Troll
  • archbishop of Upsal, enabled Gustavus Vasa to expel them both from Sweden.
  • The pope favoured the tyrant and the archbishop, and Gustavus Vasa found
  • no difficulty in establishing the reformation in Sweden. Christiern II.
  • was afterwards deposed from the throne of Denmark, where his conduct had
  • rendered him as odious as in Sweden. The pope, however, was still disposed
  • to favour him; and Frederic of Holstein, who had mounted the throne in his
  • stead, revenged himself, by following the example of Gustavus Vasa. The
  • magistrates of Berne and Zurich, who had no particular quarrel with the
  • pope, established with great ease the reformation in their respective
  • cantons, where just before some of the clergy had, by an imposture
  • somewhat grosser than ordinary, rendered the whole order both odious and
  • contemptible.
  • In this critical situation of its affairs the papal court was at
  • sufficient pains to cultivate the friendship of the powerful sovereigns of
  • France and Spain, of whom the latter was at that time emperor of Germany.
  • With their assistance, it was enabled, though not without great
  • difficulty, and much bloodshed, either to suppress altogether, or to
  • obstruct very much, the progress of the reformation in their dominions. It
  • was well enough inclined, too, to be complaisant to the king of England.
  • But from the circumstances of the times, it could not be so without giving
  • offence to a still greater sovereign, Charles V., king of Spain and
  • emperor of Germany. Henry VIII., accordingly, though he did not embrace
  • himself the greater part of the doctrines of the reformation, was yet
  • enabled, by their general prevalence, to suppress all the monasteries, and
  • to abolish the authority of the church of Rome in his dominions. That he
  • should go so far, though he went no further, gave some satisfaction to the
  • patrons of the reformation, who, having got possession of the government
  • in the reign of his son and successor completed, without any difficulty,
  • the work which Henry VIII. had begun.
  • In some countries, as in Scotland, where the government was weak,
  • unpopular, and not very firmly established, the reformation was strong
  • enough to overturn, not only the church, but the state likewise, for
  • attempting to support the church.
  • Among the followers of the reformation, dispersed in all the different
  • countries of Europe, there was no general tribunal, which, like that of
  • the court of Rome, or an oecumenical council, could settle all disputes
  • among them, and, with irresistible authority, prescribe to all of them the
  • precise limits of orthodoxy. When the followers of the reformation in one
  • country, therefore, happened to differ from their brethren in another, as
  • they had no common judge to appeal to, the dispute could never be decided;
  • and many such disputes arose among them. Those concerning the government
  • of the church, and the right of conferring ecclesiastical benefices, were
  • perhaps the most interesting to the peace and welfare of civil society.
  • They gave birth, accordingly, to the two principal parties or sects among
  • the followers of the reformation, the Lutheran and Calvinistic sects, the
  • only sects among them, of which the doctrine and discipline have ever yet
  • been established by law in any part of Europe.
  • The followers of Luther, together with what is called the church of
  • England, preserved more or less of the episcopal government, established
  • subordination among the clergy, gave the sovereign the disposal of all the
  • bishoprics, and other consistorial benefices within his dominions, and
  • thereby rendered him the real head of the church; and without depriving
  • the bishop of the right of collating to the smaller benefices within his
  • diocese, they, even to those benefices, not only admitted, but favoured
  • the right of presentation, both in the sovereign and in all other lay
  • patrons. This system of church government was, from the beginning,
  • favourable to peace and good order, and to submission to the civil
  • sovereign. It has never, accordingly, been the occasion of any tumult or
  • civil commotion in any country in which it has once been established. The
  • church of England, in particular, has always valued herself, with great
  • reason, upon the unexceptionable loyalty of her principles. Under such a
  • government, the clergy naturally endeavour to recommend themselves to the
  • sovereign, to the court, and to the nobility and gentry of the country, by
  • whose influence they chiefly expect to obtain preferment. They pay court
  • to those patrons, sometimes, no doubt, by the vilest flattery and
  • assentation; but frequently, too, by cultivating all those arts which best
  • deserve, and which are therefore most likely to gain them, the esteem of
  • people of rank and fortune; by their knowledge in all the different
  • branches of useful and ornamental learning, by the decent liberality of
  • their manners, by the social good humour of their conversation, and by
  • their avowed contempt of those absurd and hypocritical austerities which
  • fanatics inculcate and pretend to practise, in order to draw upon
  • themselves the veneration, and upon the greater part of men of rank and
  • fortune, who avow that they do not practise them, the abhorrence of the
  • common people. Such a clergy, however, while they pay their court in this
  • manner to the higher ranks of life, are very apt to neglect altogether the
  • means of maintaining their influence and authority with the lower. They
  • are listened to, esteemed, and respected by their superiors; but before
  • their inferiors they are frequently incapable of defending, effectually,
  • and to the conviction of such hearers, their own sober and moderate
  • doctrines, against the most ignorant enthusiast who chooses to attack
  • them.
  • The followers of Zuinglius, or more properly those of Calvin, on the
  • contrary, bestowed upon the people of each parish, whenever the church
  • became vacant, the right of electing their own pastor; and established, at
  • the same time, the most perfect equality among the clergy. The former part
  • of this institution, as long as it remained in vigour, seems to have been
  • productive of nothing but disorder and confusion, and to have tended
  • equally to corrupt the morals both of the clergy and of the people. The
  • latter part seems never to have had any effects but what were perfectly
  • agreeable.
  • As long as the people of each parish preserved the right of electing their
  • own pastors, they acted almost always under the influence of the clergy,
  • and generally of the most factious and fanatical of the order. The clergy,
  • in order to preserve their influence in those popular elections, became,
  • or affected to become, many of them, fanatics themselves, encouraged
  • fanaticism among the people, and gave the preference almost always to the
  • most fanatical candidate. So small a matter as the appointment of a parish
  • priest, occasioned almost always a violent contest, not only in one
  • parish, but in all the neighbouring parishes who seldom failed to take
  • part in the quarrel. When the parish happened to be situated in a great
  • city, it divided all the inhabitants into two parties; and when that city
  • happened, either to constitute itself a little republic, or to be the head
  • and capital of a little republic, as in the case with many of the
  • considerable cities in Switzerland and Holland, every paltry dispute of
  • this kind, over and above exasperating the animosity of all their other
  • factions, threatened to leave behind it, both a new schism in the church,
  • and a new faction in the state. In those small republics, therefore, the
  • magistrate very soon found it necessary, for the sake of preserving the
  • public peace, to assume to himself the right of presenting to all vacant
  • benefices. In Scotland, the most extensive country in which this
  • presbyterian form of church government has ever been established, the
  • rights of patronage were in effect abolished by the act which established
  • presbytery in the beginning of the reign of William III. That act, at
  • least, put in the power of certain classes of people in each parish to
  • purchase, for a very small price, the right of electing their own pastor.
  • The constitution which this act established, was allowed to subsist for
  • about two-and-twenty years, but was abolished by the 10th of queen Anne,
  • ch.12, on account of the confusions and disorders which this more popular
  • mode of election had almost everywhere occasioned. In so extensive a
  • country as Scotland, however, a tumult in a remote parish was not so
  • likely to give disturbance to government as in a smaller state. The 10th
  • of queen Anne restored the rights of patronage. But though, in Scotland,
  • the law gives the benefice, without any exception to the person presented
  • by the patron; yet the church requires sometimes (for she has not in this
  • respect been very uniform in her decisions) a certain concurrence of the
  • people, before she will confer upon the presentee what is called the cure
  • of souls, or the ecclesiastical jurisdiction in the parish. She sometimes,
  • at least, from an affected concern for the peace of the parish, delays the
  • settlement till this concurrence can be procured. The private tampering of
  • some of the neighbouring clergy, sometimes to procure, but more frequently
  • to prevent this concurrence, and the popular arts which they cultivate, in
  • order to enable them upon such occasions to tamper more effectually, are
  • perhaps the causes which principally keep up whatever remains of the old
  • fanatical spirit, either in the clergy or in the people of Scotland.
  • The equality which the presbyterian form of church government establishes
  • among the clergy, consists, first, in the equality of authority or
  • ecclesiastical jurisdiction; and, secondly, in the equality of benefice.
  • In all presbyterian churches, the equality of authority is perfect; that
  • of benefice is not so. The difference, however, between one benefice and
  • another, is seldom so considerable, as commonly to tempt the possessor
  • even of the small one to pay court to his patron, by the vile arts of
  • flattery and assentation, in order to get a better. In all the
  • presbyterian churches, where the rights of patronage are thoroughly
  • established, it is by nobler and better arts, that the established clergy
  • in general endeavour to gain the favour of their superiors; by their
  • learning, by the irreproachable regularity of their life, and by the
  • faithful and diligent discharge of their duty. Their patrons even
  • frequently complain of the independency of their spirit, which they are
  • apt to construe into ingratitude for past favours, but which, at worse,
  • perhaps, is seldom anymore than that indifference which naturally arises
  • from the consciousness that no further favours of the kind are ever to be
  • expected. There is scarce, perhaps, to be found anywhere in Europe, a more
  • learned, decent, independent, and respectable set of men, than the greater
  • part of the presbyterian clergy of Holland, Geneva, Switzerland, and
  • Scotland.
  • Where the church benefices are all nearly equal, none of them can be very
  • great; and this mediocrity of benefice, though it may be, no doubt,
  • carried too far, has, however, some very agreeable effects. Nothing but
  • exemplary morals can give dignity to a man of small fortune. The vices of
  • levity and vanity necessarily render him ridiculous, and are, besides,
  • almost as ruinous to him as they are to the common people. In his own
  • conduct, therefore, he is obliged to follow that system of morals which
  • the common people respect the most. He gains their esteem and affection,
  • by that plan of life which his own interest and situation would lead him
  • to follow. The common people look upon him with that kindness with which
  • we naturally regard one who approaches somewhat to our own condition, but
  • who, we think, ought to be in a higher. Their kindness naturally provokes
  • his kindness. He becomes careful to instruct them, and attentive to assist
  • and relieve them. He does not even despise the prejudices of people who
  • are disposed to be so favourable to him, and never treats them with those
  • contemptuous and arrogant airs, which we so often meet with in the proud
  • dignitaries of opulent and well endowed churches. The presbyterian clergy,
  • accordingly, have more influence over the minds of the common people, than
  • perhaps the clergy of any other established church. It is, accordingly, in
  • presbyterian countries only, that we ever find the common people
  • converted, without persecution completely, and almost to a man, to the
  • established church.
  • In countries where church benefices are, the greater part of them, very
  • moderate, a chair in a university is generally a better establishment than
  • a church benefice. The universities have, in this case, the picking and
  • chusing of their members from all the churchmen of the country, who, in
  • every country, constitute by far the most numerous class of men of
  • letters. Where church benefices, on the contrary, are many of them very
  • considerable, the church naturally draws from the universities the greater
  • part of their eminent men of letters; who generally find some patron, who
  • does himself honour by procuring them church preferment. In the former
  • situation, we are likely to find the universities filled with the most
  • eminent men of letters that are to be found in the country. In the latter,
  • we are likely to find few eminent men among them, and those few among the
  • youngest members of the society, who are likely, too, to be drained away
  • from it, before they can have acquired experience and knowledge enough to
  • be of much use to it. It is observed by Mr. de Voltaire, that father
  • Porée, a jesuit of no great eminence in the republic of letters, was the
  • only professor they had ever had in France, whose works were worth the
  • reading. In a country which has produced so many eminent men of letters,
  • it must appear somewhat singular, that scarce one of them should have been
  • a professor in a university. The famous Cassendi was, in the beginning of
  • his life, a professor in the university of Aix. Upon the first dawning of
  • his genius, it was represented to him, that by going into the church he
  • could easily find a much more quiet and comfortable subsistence, as well
  • as a better situation for pursuing his studies; and he immediately
  • followed the advice. The observation of Mr. de Voltaire may be applied, I
  • believe, not only to France, but to all other Roman Catholic countries. We
  • very rarely find in any of them an eminent man of letters, who is a
  • professor in a university, except, perhaps, in the professions of law and
  • physic; professions from which the church is not so likely to draw them.
  • After the church of Rome, that of England is by far the richest and best
  • endowed church in Christendom. In England, accordingly, the church is
  • continually draining the universities of all their best and ablest
  • members; and an old college tutor who is known and distinguished in Europe
  • as an eminent man of letters, is as rarely to be found there as in any
  • Roman catholic country, In Geneva, on the contrary, in the protestant
  • cantons of Switzerland, in the protestant countries of Germany, in
  • Holland, in Scotland, in Sweden, and Denmark, the most eminent men of
  • letters whom those countries have produced, have, not all indeed, but the
  • far greater part of them, been professors in universities. In those
  • countries, the universities are continually draining the church of all its
  • most eminent men of letters.
  • It may, perhaps, be worth while to remark, that, if we except the poets, a
  • few orators, and a few historians, the far greater part of the other
  • eminent men of letters, both of Greece and Rome, appear to have been
  • either public or private teachers; generally either of philosophy or of
  • rhetoric. This remark will be found to hold true, from the days of Lysias
  • and Isocrates, of Plato and Aristotle, down to those of Plutarch and
  • Epictetus, Suetonius, and Quintilian. To impose upon any man the necessity
  • of teaching, year after year, in any particular branch of science seems in
  • reality to be the most effectual method for rendering him completely
  • master of it himself. By being obliged to go every year over the same
  • ground, if he is good for any thing, he necessarily becomes, in a few
  • years, well acquainted with every part of it, and if, upon any particular
  • point, he should form too hasty an opinion one year, when he comes, in the
  • course of his lectures to reconsider the same subject the year thereafter,
  • he is very likely to correct it. As to be a teacher of science is
  • certainly the natural employment of a mere man of letters; so is it
  • likewise, perhaps, the education which is most likely to render him a man
  • of solid learning and knowledge. The mediocrity of church benefices
  • naturally tends to draw the greater part of men of letters in the country
  • where it takes place, to the employment in which they can be the most
  • useful to the public, and at the same time to give them the best
  • education, perhaps, they are capable of receiving. It tends to render
  • their learning both as solid as possible, and as useful as possible.
  • The revenue of every established church, such parts of it excepted as may
  • arise from particular lands or manors, is a branch, it ought to be
  • observed, of the general revenue of the state, which is thus diverted to a
  • purpose very different from the defence of the state. The tithe, for
  • example, is a real land tax, which puts it out of the power of the
  • proprietors of land to contribute so largely towards the defence of the
  • state as they otherwise might be able to do. The rent of land, however,
  • is, according to some, the sole fund; and, according to others, the
  • principal fund, from which, in all great monarchies, the exigencies of the
  • state must be ultimately supplied. The more of this fund that is given to
  • the church, the less, it is evident, can be spared to the state. It may be
  • laid down as a certain maxim, that all other things being supposed equal,
  • the richer the church, the poorer must necessarily be, either the
  • sovereign on the one hand, or the people on the other; and, in all cases,
  • the less able must the state be to defend itself. In several protestant
  • countries, particularly in all the protestant cantons of Switzerland, the
  • revenue which anciently belonged to the Roman catholic church, the tithes
  • and church lands, has been found a fund sufficient, not only to afford
  • competent salaries to the established clergy, but to defray, with little
  • or no addition, all the other expenses of the state. The magistrates of
  • the powerful canton of Berne, in particular, have accumulated, out of the
  • savings from this fund, a very large sum, supposed to amount to several
  • millions; part or which is deposited in a public treasure, and part is
  • placed at interest in what are called the public funds of the different
  • indebted nations of Europe; chiefly in those of France and Great Britain.
  • What may be the amount of the whole expense which the church, either of
  • Berne, or of any other protestant canton, costs the state, I do not
  • pretend to know. By a very exact account it appears, that, in 1755, the
  • whole revenue of the clergy of the church of Scotland, including their
  • glebe or church lands, and the rent of their manses or dwelling-houses,
  • estimated according to a reasonable valuation, amounted only to
  • £68,514:1:5 1/12d. This very moderate revenue affords a decent subsistence
  • to nine hundred and forty-four ministers. The whole expense of the church,
  • including what is occasionally laid out for the building and reparation of
  • churches, and of the manses of ministers, cannot well be supposed to
  • exceed eighty or eighty-five thousand pounds a-year. The most opulent
  • church in Christendom does not maintain better the uniformity of faith,
  • the fervour of devotion, the spirit of order, regularity, and austere
  • morals, in the great body of the people, than this very poorly endowed
  • church of Scotland. All the good effects, both civil and religious, which
  • an established church can be supposed to produce, are produced by it as
  • completely as by any other. The greater part of the protestant churches of
  • Switzerland, which, in general, are not better endowed than the church of
  • Scotland, produce those effects in a still higher degree. In the greater
  • part of the protestant cantons, there is not a single person to be found,
  • who does not profess himself to be of the established church. If he
  • professes himself to be of any other, indeed, the law obliges him to leave
  • the canton. But so severe, or, rather, indeed, so oppressive a law, could
  • never have been executed in such free countries, had not the diligence of
  • the clergy beforehand converted to the established church the whole body
  • of the people, with the exception of, perhaps, a few individuals only. In
  • some parts of Switzerland, accordingly, where, from the accidental union
  • of a protestant and Roman catholic country, the conversion has not been so
  • complete, both religions are not only tolerated, but established by law.
  • The proper performance of every service seems to require, that its pay or
  • recompence should be, as exactly as possible, proportioned to the nature
  • of the service. If any service is very much underpaid, it is very apt to
  • suffer by the meanness and incapacity of the greater part of those who are
  • employed in it. If it is very much overpaid, it is apt to suffer, perhaps
  • still more, by their negligence and idleness. A man of a large revenue,
  • whatever may be his profession, thinks he ought to live like other men of
  • large revenues; and to spend a great part of his time in festivity, in
  • vanity, and in dissipation. But in a clergyman, this train of life not
  • only consumes the time which ought to be employed in the duties of his
  • function, but in the eyes of the common people, destroys almost entirely
  • that sanctity of character, which can alone enable him to perform those
  • duties with proper weight and authority.
  • PART IV. Of the Expense of supporting the Dignity of the Sovereign.
  • Over and above the expenses necessary for enabling the sovereign to
  • perform his several duties, a certain expense is requisite for the support
  • of his dignity. This expense varies, both with the different periods of
  • improvement, and with the different forms of government.
  • In an opulent and improved society, where all the different orders of
  • people are growing every day more expensive in their houses, in their
  • furniture, in their tables, in their dress, and in their equipage; it
  • cannot well be expected that the sovereign should alone hold out against
  • the fashion. He naturally, therefore, or rather necessarily, becomes more
  • expensive in all those different articles too. His dignity even seems to
  • require that he should become so.
  • As, in point of dignity, a monarch is more raised above his subjects than
  • the chief magistrate of any republic is ever supposed to be above his
  • fellow-citizens; so a greater expense is necessary for supporting that
  • higher dignity. We naturally expect more splendour in the court of a king,
  • than in the mansion-house of a doge or burgo-master.
  • CONCLUSION.
  • The expense of defending the society, and that of supporting the dignity
  • of the chief magistrate, are both laid out for the general benefit of the
  • whole society. It is reasonable, therefore, that they should be defrayed
  • by the general contribution of the whole society; all the different
  • members contributing, as nearly as possible, in proportion to their
  • respective abilities.
  • The expense of the administration of justice, too, may no doubt be
  • considered as laid out for the benefit of the whole society. There is no
  • impropriety, therefore, in its being defrayed by the general contribution
  • of the whole society. The persons, however, who give occasion to this
  • expense, are those who, by their injustice in one way or another, make it
  • necessary to seek redress or protection from the courts of justice. The
  • persons, again, most immediately benefited by this expense, are those whom
  • the courts of justice either restore to their rights, or maintain in their
  • rights. The expense of the administration of justice, therefore, may very
  • properly be defrayed by the particular contribution of one or other, or
  • both, of those two different sets of persons, according as different
  • occasions may require, that is, by the fees of court. It cannot be
  • necessary to have recourse to the general contribution of the whole
  • society, except for the conviction of those criminals who have not
  • themselves any estate or fund sufficient for paying those fees.
  • Those local or provincial expenses, of which the benefit is local or
  • provincial (what is laid out, for example, upon the police of a particular
  • town or district), ought to be defrayed by a local or provincial revenue,
  • and ought to be no burden upon the general revenue of the society. It is
  • unjust that the whole society should contribute towards an expense, of
  • which the benefit is confined to a part of the society.
  • The expense of maintaining good roads and communications is, no doubt,
  • beneficial to the whole society, and may, therefore, without any
  • injustice, be defrayed by the general contributions of the whole society.
  • This expense, however, is most immediately and directly beneficial to
  • those who travel or carry goods from one place to another, and to those
  • who consume such goods. The turnpike tolls in England, and the duties
  • called peages in other countries, lay it altogether upon those two
  • different sets of people, and thereby discharge the general revenue of the
  • society from a very considerable burden.
  • The expense of the institutions for education and religious instruction,
  • is likewise, no doubt, beneficial to the whole society, and may,
  • therefore, without injustice, be defrayed by the general contribution of
  • the whole society. This expense, however, might, perhaps, with equal
  • propriety, and even with some advantage, be defrayed altogether by those
  • who receive the immediate benefit of such education and instruction, or by
  • the voluntary contribution of those who think they have occasion for
  • either the one or the other.
  • When the institutions, or public works, which are beneficial to the whole
  • society, either cannot be maintained altogether, or are not maintained
  • altogether, by the contribution of such particular members of the society
  • as are most immediately benefited by them; the deficiency must, in most
  • cases, be made up by the general contribution of the whole society. The
  • general revenue of the society, over and above defraying the expense of
  • defending the society, and of supporting the dignity of the chief
  • magistrate, must make up for the deficiency of many particular branches of
  • revenue. The sources of this general or public revenue, I shall endeavour
  • to explain in the following chapter.
  • CHAPTER II.
  • OF THE SOURCES OF THE GENERAL OR PUBLIC
  • REVENUE OF THE SOCIETY.
  • The revenue which must defray, not only the expense of defending the
  • society and of supporting the dignity of the chief magistrate, but all the
  • other necessary expenses of government, for which the constitution of the
  • state has not provided any particular revenue may be drawn, either, first,
  • from some fund which peculiarly belongs to the sovereign or commonwealth,
  • and which is independent of the revenue of the people; or, secondly, from
  • the revenue of the people.
  • PART I. Of the Funds, or Sources, of Revenue, which may peculiarly belong
  • to the Sovereign or Commonwealth.
  • The funds, or sources, of revenue, which may peculiarly belong to the
  • sovereign or commonwealth, must consist, either in stock, or in land.
  • The sovereign, like, any other owner of stock, may derive a revenue from
  • it, either by employing it himself, or by lending it. His revenue is, in
  • the one case, profit, in the other interest.
  • The revenue of a Tartar or Arabian chief consists in profit. It arises
  • principally from the milk and increase of his own herds and flocks, of
  • which he himself superintends the management, and is the principal
  • shepherd or herdsman of his own horde or tribe. It is, however, in this
  • earliest and rudest state of civil government only, that profit has ever
  • made the principal part of the public revenue of a monarchical state.
  • Small republics have sometimes derived a considerable revenue from the
  • profit of mercantile projects. The republic of Hamburgh is said to do so
  • from the profits of a public wine-cellar and apothecary’s shop. {See
  • Memoires concernant les Droits et Impositions en Europe, tome i. page 73.
  • This work was compiled by the order of the court, for the use of a
  • commission employed for some years past in considering the proper means
  • for reforming the finances of France. The account of the French taxes,
  • which takes up three volumes in quarto, may be regarded as perfectly
  • authentic. That of those of other European nations was compiled from such
  • information as the French ministers at the different courts could procure.
  • It is much shorter, and probably not quite so exact as that of the French
  • taxes.} That state cannot be very great, of which the sovereign has
  • leisure to carry on the trade of a wine-merchant or an apothecary. The
  • profit of a public bank has been a source of revenue to more considerable
  • states. It has been so, not only to Hamburgh, but to Venice and Amsterdam.
  • A revenue of this kind has even by some people been thought not below the
  • attention of so great an empire as that of Great Britain. Reckoning the
  • ordinary dividend of the bank of England at five and a-half per cent., and
  • its capital at ten millions seven hundred and eighty thousand pounds, the
  • neat annual profit, after paying the expense of management, must amount,
  • it is said, to five hundred and ninety-two thousand nine hundred pounds.
  • Government, it is pretended, could borrow this capital at three per cent.
  • interest, and, by taking the management of the bank into its own hands,
  • might make a clear profit of two hundred and sixty-nine thousand five
  • hundred pounds a-year. The orderly, vigilant, and parsimonious
  • administration of such aristocracies as those of Venice and Amsterdam, is
  • extremely proper, it appears from experience, for the management of a
  • mercantile project of this kind. But whether such a government us that of
  • England, which, whatever may be its virtues, has never been famous for
  • good economy; which, in time of peace, has generally conducted itself with
  • the slothful and negligent profusion that is, perhaps, natural to
  • monarchies; and, in time of war, has constantly acted with all the
  • thoughtless extravagance that democracies are apt to fall into, could be
  • safely trusted with the management of such a project, must at least be a
  • good deal more doubtful.
  • The post-office is properly a mercantile project. The government advances
  • the expense of establishing the different offices, and of buying or hiring
  • the necessary horses or carriages, and is repaid, with a large profit, by
  • the duties upon what is carried. It is, perhaps, the only mercantile
  • project which has been successfully managed by, I believe, every sort of
  • government. The capital to be advanced is not very considerable. There is
  • no mystery in the business. The returns are not only certain but
  • immediate.
  • Princes, however, have frequently engaged in many other mercantile
  • projects, and have been willing, like private persons, to mend their
  • fortunes, by becoming adventurers in the common branches of trade. They
  • have scarce ever succeeded. The profusion with which the affairs of
  • princes are always managed, renders it almost impossible that they should.
  • The agents of a prince regard the wealth of their master as inexhaustible;
  • are careless at what price they buy, are careless at what price they sell,
  • are careless at what expense they transport his goods from one place to
  • another. Those agents frequently live with the profusion of princes; and
  • sometimes, too, in spite of that profusion, and by a proper method of
  • making up their accounts, acquire the fortunes of princes. It was thus, as
  • we are told by Machiavel, that the agents of Lorenzo of Medicis, not a
  • prince of mean abilities, carried on his trade. The republic of Florence
  • was several times obliged to pay the debt into which their extravagance
  • had involved him. He found it convenient, accordingly to give up the
  • business of merchant, the business to which his family had originally owed
  • their fortune, and, in the latter part of his life, to employ both what
  • remained of that fortune, and the revenue of the state, of which he had
  • the disposal, in projects and expenses more suitable to his station.
  • No two characters seem more inconsistent than those of trader and
  • sovereign. If the trading spirit of the English East India company renders
  • them very bad sovereigns, the spirit of sovereignty seems to have rendered
  • them equally bad traders. While they were traders only, they managed their
  • trade successfully, and were able to pay from their profits a moderate
  • dividend to the proprietors of their stock. Since they became sovereigns,
  • with a revenue which, it is said, was originally more than three millions
  • sterling, they have been obliged to beg the ordinary assistance of
  • government, in order to avoid immediate bankruptcy. In their former
  • situation, their servants in India considered themselves as the clerks of
  • merchants; in their present situation, those servants consider themselves
  • as the ministers of sovereigns.
  • A state may sometimes derive some part of its public revenue from the
  • interest of money, as well as from the profits of stock. If it has amassed
  • a treasure, it may lend a part of that treasure, either to foreign states,
  • or to its own subjects.
  • The canton of Berne derives a considerable revenue by lending a part of
  • its treasure to foreign states, that is, by placing it in the public funds
  • of the different indebted nations of Europe, chiefly in those of France
  • and England. The security of this revenue must depend, first, upon the
  • security of the funds in which it is placed, or upon the good faith of the
  • government which has the management of them; and, secondly, upon the
  • certainty or probability of the continuance of peace with the debtor
  • nation. In the case of a war, the very first act of hostility on the part
  • of the debtor nation might be the forfeiture of the funds of its credit.
  • This policy of lending money to foreign states is, so far as I know
  • peculiar to the canton of Berne.
  • The city of Hamburgh {See Memoire concernant les Droites et Impositions en
  • Europe tome i p. 73.}has established a sort of public pawn-shop, which
  • lends money to the subjects of the state, upon pledges, at six per cent.
  • interest. This pawn-shop, or lombard, as it is called, affords a revenue,
  • it is pretended, to the state, of a hundred and fifty thousand crowns,
  • which, at four and sixpence the crown, amounts to £33,750 sterling.
  • The government of Pennsylvania, without amassing any treasure, invented a
  • method of lending, not money, indeed, but what is equivalent to money, to
  • its subjects. By advancing to private people, at interest, and upon land
  • security to double the value, paper bills of credit, to be redeemed
  • fifteen years after their date; and, in the mean time, made transferable
  • from hand to hand, like banknotes, and declared by act of assembly to be a
  • legal tender in all payments from one inhabitant of the province to
  • another, it raised a moderate revenue, which went a considerable way
  • towards defraying an annual expense of about £4,500, the whole ordinary
  • expense of that frugal and orderly government. The success of an expedient
  • of this kind must have depended upon three different circumstances: first,
  • upon the demand for some other instrument of commerce, besides gold and
  • silver money, or upon the demand for such a quantity of consumable stock
  • as could not be had without sending abroad the greater part of their gold
  • and silver money, in order to purchase it; secondly, upon the good credit
  • of the government which made use of this expedient; and, thirdly, upon the
  • moderation with which it was used, the whole value of the paper bills of
  • credit never exceeding that of the gold and silver money which would have
  • been necessary for carrying on their circulation, had there been no paper
  • bills of credit. The same expedient was, upon different occasions, adopted
  • by several other American colonies; but, from want of this moderation, it
  • produced, in the greater part of them, much more disorder than
  • conveniency.
  • The unstable and perishable nature of stock and credit, however, renders
  • them unfit to be trusted to as the principal funds of that sure, steady,
  • and permanent revenue, which can alone give security and dignity to
  • government. The government of no great nation, that was advanced beyond
  • the shepherd state, seems ever to have derived the greater part of its
  • public revenue from such sources.
  • Land is a fund of more stable and permanent nature; and the rent of public
  • lands, accordingly, has been the principal source of the public revenue of
  • many a great nation that was much advanced beyond the shepherd state. From
  • the produce or rent of the public lands, the ancient republics of Greece
  • and Italy derived for a long the the greater part of that revenue which
  • defrayed the necessary expenses of the commonwealth. The rent of the crown
  • lands constituted for a long time the greater part of the revenue of the
  • ancient sovereigns of Europe.
  • War, and the preparation for war, are the two circumstances which, in
  • modern times, occasion the greater part of the necessary expense or all
  • great states. But in the ancient republics of Greece and Italy, every
  • citizen was a soldier, and both served, and prepared himself for service,
  • at his own expense. Neither of those two circumstances, therefore, could
  • occasion any very considerable expense to the state. The rent of a very
  • moderate landed estate might be fully sufficient for defraying all the
  • other necessary expenses of government.
  • In the ancient monarchies of Europe, the manners and customs of the time
  • sufficiently prepared the great body of the people for war; and when they
  • took the field, they were, by the condition of their feudal tenures, to be
  • maintained either at their own expense, or at that of their immediate
  • lords, without bringing any new charge upon the sovereign. The other
  • expenses of government were, the greater part of them, very moderate. The
  • administration of justice, it has been shewn, instead of being a cause of
  • expense was a source of revenue. The labour of the country people, for
  • three days before, and for three days after, harvest, was thought a fund
  • sufficient for making and maintaining all the bridges, highways, and other
  • public works, which the commerce of the country was supposed to require.
  • In those days the principal expense of the sovereign seems to have
  • consisted in the maintenance of his own family and household. The officers
  • of his household, accordingly, were then the great officers of state. The
  • lord treasurer received his rents. The lord steward and lord chamberlain
  • looked after the expense of his family. The care of his stables was
  • committed to the lord constable and the lord marshal. His houses were all
  • built in the form of castles, and seem to have been the principal
  • fortresses which he possessed. The keepers of those houses or castles
  • might be considered as a sort of military governors. They seem to have
  • been the only military officers whom it was necessary to maintain in time
  • of peace. In these circumstances, the rent of a great landed estate might,
  • upon ordinary occasions, very well defray all the necessary expenses of
  • government.
  • In the present state of the greater part of the civilized monarchies of
  • Europe, the rent of all the lands in the country, managed as they probably
  • would be, if they all belonged to one proprietor, would scarce, perhaps,
  • amount to the ordinary revenue which they levy upon the people even in
  • peaceable times. The ordinary revenue of Great Britain, for example,
  • including not only what is necessary for defraying the current expense of
  • the year, but for paying the interest of the public debts, and for sinking
  • a part of the capital of those debts, amounts to upwards of ten millions
  • a-year. But the land tax, at four shillings in the pound, falls short of
  • two millions a-year. This land tax, as it is called however, is supposed
  • to be one-fifth, not only of the rent of all the land, but of that of all
  • the houses, and of the interest of all the capital stock of Great Britain,
  • that part of it only excepted which is either lent to the public, or
  • employed as farming stock in the cultivation of land. A very considerable
  • part of the produce of this tax arises from the rent of houses and the
  • interest of capital stock. The land tax of the city of London, for
  • example, at four shillings in the pound, amounts to £123,399: 6: 7; that
  • of the city of Westminster to £63,092: 1: 5; that of the palaces of
  • Whitehall and St. James’s, to £30,754: 6: 3. A certain proportion of the
  • land tax is, in the same manner, assessed upon all the other cities and
  • towns corporate in the kingdom; and arises almost altogether, either from
  • the rent of houses, or from what is supposed to be the interest of trading
  • and capital stock. According to the estimation, therefore, by which Great
  • Britain is rated to the land tax, the whole mass of revenue arising from
  • the rent of all the lands, from that of all the houses, and from the
  • interest of all the capital stock, that part of it only excepted which is
  • either lent to the public, or employed in the cultivation of land, does
  • not exceed ten millions sterling a-year, the ordinary revenue which
  • government levies upon the people, even in peaceable times. The estimation
  • by which Great Britain is rated to the land tax is, no doubt, taking the
  • whole kingdom at an average, very much below the real value; though in
  • several particular counties and districts it is said to be nearly equal to
  • that value. The rent of the lands alone, exclusive of that of houses and
  • of the interest of stock, has by many people been estimated at twenty
  • millions; an estimation made in a great measure at random, and which, I
  • apprehend, is as likely to be above as below the truth. But if the lands
  • of Great Britain, in the present state of their cultivation, do not afford
  • a rent of more than twenty millions a-year, they could not well afford the
  • half, most probably not the fourth part of that rent, if they all belonged
  • to a single proprietor, and were put under the negligent, expensive, and
  • oppressive management of his factors and agents. The crown lands of Great
  • Britain do not at present afford the fourth part of the rent which could
  • probably be drawn from them if they were the property of private persons.
  • If the crown lands were more extensive, it is probable, they would be
  • still worse managed.
  • The revenue which the great body of the people derives from land is, in
  • proportion, not to the rent, but to the produce of the land. The whole
  • annual produce of the land of every country, if we except what is reserved
  • for seed, is either annually consumed by the great body of the people, or
  • exchanged for something else that is consumed by them. Whatever keeps down
  • the produce of the land below what it would otherwise rise to, keeps down
  • the revenue of the great body of the people, still more than it does that
  • of the proprietors of land. The rent of land, that portion of the produce
  • which belongs to the proprietors, is scarce anywhere in Great Britain
  • supposed to be more than a third part of the whole produce. If the land
  • which, in one state of cultivation, affords a revenue of ten millions
  • sterling a-year, would in another afford a rent of twenty millions; the
  • rent being, in both cases, supposed a third part of the produce, the
  • revenue of the proprietors would be less than it otherwise might be, by
  • ten millions a-year only; but the revenue of the great hotly of the people
  • would be less than it otherwise might be, by thirty millions a-year,
  • deducting only what would be necessary for seed. The population of the
  • country would be less by the number of people which thirty millions
  • a-year, deducting always the seed, could maintain, according to the
  • particular mode of living, and expense which might take place in the
  • different ranks of men, among whom the remainder was distributed.
  • Though there is not at present in Europe, any civilized state of any kind
  • which derives the greater part of its public revenue from the rent of
  • lands which are the property of the state; yet, in all the great
  • monarchies of Europe, there are still many large tracts of land which
  • belong to the crown. They are generally forest, and sometimes forests
  • where, after travelling several miles, you will scarce find a single tree;
  • a mere waste and loss of country, in respect both of produce and
  • population. In every great monarchy of Europe, the sale of the crown lands
  • would produce a very large sum of money, which, if applied to the payment
  • of the public debts, would deliver from mortgage a much greater revenue
  • than any which those lands have even afforded to the crown. In countries
  • where lands, improved and cultivated very highly, and yielding, at the
  • time of sale, as great a rent as can easily be got from them, commonly
  • sell at thirty years purchase; the unimproved, uncultivated, and
  • low-rented crown lands, might well be expected to sell at forty, fifty, or
  • sixty years purchase. The crown might immediately enjoy the revenue which
  • this great price would redeem from mortgage. In the course of a few years,
  • it would probably enjoy another revenue. When the crown lands had become
  • private property, they would, in the course of a few years, become well
  • improved and well cultivated. The increase of their produce would increase
  • the population of the country, by augmenting the revenue and consumption
  • of the people. But the revenue which the crown derives from the duties or
  • custom and excise, would necessarily increase with the revenue and
  • consumption of the people.
  • The revenue which, in any civilized monarchy, the crown derives from the
  • crown lands, though it appears to cost nothing to individuals, in reality
  • costs more to the society than perhaps any other equal revenue which the
  • crown enjoys. It would, in all cases, be for the interest of the society,
  • to replace this revenue to the crown by some other equal revenue, and to
  • divide the lands among the people, which could not well be done better,
  • perhaps, than by exposing them to public sale.
  • Lands, for the purposes of pleasure and magnificence, parks, gardens,
  • public walks, etc. possessions which are everywhere considered as causes
  • of expense, not as sources of revenue, seem to be the only lands which, in
  • a great and civilized monarchy, ought to belong to the crown.
  • Public stock and public lands, therefore, the two sources of revenue which
  • may peculiarly belong to the sovereign or commonwealth, being both
  • improper and insufficient funds for defraying the necessary expense of any
  • great and civilized state; it remains that this expense must, the greater
  • part of it, be defrayed by taxes of one kind or another; the people
  • contributing a part of their own private revenue, in order to make up a
  • public revenue to the sovereign or commonwealth.
  • PART II. Of Taxes.
  • The private revenue of individuals, it has been shown in the first book of
  • this Inquiry, arises, ultimately from three different sources; rent,
  • profit, and wages. Every tax must finally be paid from some one or other
  • of those three different sources of revenue, or from all of them
  • indifferently. I shall endeavour to give the best account I can, first, of
  • those taxes which, it is intended should fall upon rent; secondly, of
  • those which, it is intended should fall upon profit; thirdly, of those
  • which, it is intended should fall upon wages; and fourthly, of those
  • which, it is intended should fall indifferently upon all those three
  • different sources of private revenue. The particular consideration of each
  • of these four different sorts of taxes will divide the second part of the
  • present chapter into four articles, three of which will require several
  • other subdivisions. Many of these taxes, it will appear from the following
  • review, are not finally paid from the fund, or source of revenue, upon
  • which it is intended they should fall.
  • Before I enter upon the examination of particular taxes, it is necessary
  • to premise the four following maximis with regard to taxes in general.
  • 1. The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of
  • the government, as nearly as possible, in proportion to their respective
  • abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which they respectively
  • enjoy under the protection of the state. The expense of government to the
  • individuals of a great nation, is like the expense of management to the
  • joint tenants of a great estate, who are all obliged to contribute in
  • proportion to their respective interests in the estate. In the observation
  • or neglect of this maxim, consists what is called the equality or
  • inequality of taxation. Every tax, it must be observed once for all, which
  • falls finally upon one only of the three sorts of revenue above mentioned,
  • is necessarily unequal, in so far as it does not affect the other two. In
  • the following examination of different taxes, I shall seldom take much
  • farther notice of this sort of inequality; but shall, in most cases,
  • confine my observations to that inequality which is occasioned by a
  • particular tax falling unequally upon that particular sort of private
  • revenue which is affected by it.
  • 2. The tax which each individual is bound to pay, ought to be certain and
  • not arbitrary. The time of payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to
  • be paid, ought all to be clear and plain to the contributor, and to every
  • other person. Where it is otherwise, every person subject to the tax is
  • put more or less in the power of the tax-gatherer, who can either
  • aggravate the tax upon any obnoxious contributor, or extort, by the terror
  • of such aggravation, some present or perquisite to himself. The
  • uncertainty of taxation encourages the insolence, and favours the
  • corruption, of an order of men who are naturally unpopular, even where
  • they are neither insolent nor corrupt. The certainty of what each
  • individual ought to pay is, in taxation, a matter of so great importance,
  • that a very considerable degree of inequality, it appears, I believe, from
  • the experience of all nations, is not near so great an evil as a very
  • small degree of uncertainty.
  • 3. Every tax ought to be levied at the time, or in the manner, in which it
  • is most likely to be convenient for the contributor to pay it. A tax upon
  • the rent of land or of houses, payable at the same term at which such
  • rents are usually paid, is levied at the time when it is most likely to be
  • convenient for the contributor to pay; or when he is most likely to have
  • wherewithall to pay. Taxes upon such consumable goods as are articles of
  • luxury, are all finally paid by the consumer, and generally in a manner
  • that is very convenient for him. He pays them by little and little, as he
  • has occasion to buy the goods. As he is at liberty too, either to buy or
  • not to buy, as he pleases, it must be his own fault if he ever suffers any
  • considerable inconveniency from such taxes.
  • 4. Every tax ought to be so contrived, as both to take out and to keep out
  • of the pockets of the people as little as possible, over and above what it
  • brings into the public treasury of the state. A tax may either take out or
  • keep out of the pockets of the people a great deal more than it brings
  • into the public treasury, in the four following ways. First, the levying
  • of it may require a great number of officers, whose salaries may eat up
  • the greater part of the produce of the tax, and whose perquisites may
  • impose another additional tax upon the people. Secondly, it may obstruct
  • the industry of the people, and discourage them from applying to certain
  • branches of business which might give maintenance and employment to great
  • multitudes. While it obliges the people to pay, it may thus diminish, or
  • perhaps destroy, some of the funds which might enable them more easily to
  • do so. Thirdly, by the forfeitures and other penalties which those
  • unfortunate individuals incur, who attempt unsuccessfully to evade the
  • tax, it may frequently ruin them, and thereby put an end to the benefit
  • which the community might have received from the employment of their
  • capitals. An injudicious tax offers a great temptation to smuggling. But
  • the penalties of smuggling must arise in proportion to the temptation. The
  • law, contrary to all the ordinary principles of justice, first creates the
  • temptation, and then punishes those who yield to it; and it commonly
  • enhances the punishment, too, in proportion to the very circumstance which
  • ought certainly to alleviate it, the temptation to commit the crime. {See
  • Sketches of the History of Man page 474, and Seq.} Fourthly, by subjecting
  • the people to the frequent visits and the odious examination of the
  • tax-gatherers, it may expose them to much unnecessary trouble, vexation,
  • and oppression; and though vexation is not, strictly speaking, expense, it
  • is certainly equivalent to the expense at which every man would be willing
  • to redeem himself from it. It is in some one or other of these four
  • different ways, that taxes are frequently so much more burdensome to the
  • people than they are beneficial to the sovereign.
  • The evident justice and utility of the foregoing maxims have recommended
  • them, more or less, to the attention of all nations. All nations have
  • endeavoured, to the best of their judgment, to render their taxes as equal
  • as they could contrive; as certain, as convenient to the contributor, both
  • the time and the mode of payment, and in proportion to the revenue which
  • they brought to the prince, as little burdensome to the people. The
  • following short review of some of the principal taxes which have taken
  • place in different ages and countries, will show, that the endeavours of
  • all nations have not in this respect been equally successful.
  • ARTICLE I.—Taxes upon Rent—Taxes upon the Rent of Land.
  • A tax upon the rent of land may either be imposed according to a certain
  • canon, every district being valued at a curtain rent, which valuation is
  • not afterwards to be altered; or it may be imposed in such a manner, as to
  • vary with every variation in the real rent of the land, and to rise or
  • fall with the improvement or declension of its cultivation.
  • A land tax which, like that of Great Britain, is assessed upon each
  • district according to a certain invariable canon, though it should be
  • equal at the time of its first establishment, necessarily becomes unequal
  • in process of time, according to the unequal degrees of improvement or
  • neglect in the cultivation of the different parts of the country. In
  • England, the valuation, according to which the different counties and
  • parishes were assessed to the land tax by the 4th of William and Mary, was
  • very unequal even at its first establishment. This tax, therefore, so far
  • offends against the first of the four maxims above mentioned. It is
  • perfectly agreeable to the other three. It is perfectly certain. The time
  • of payment for the tax, being the same as that for the rent, is as
  • convenient as it can be to the contributor. Though the landlord is, in all
  • cases, the real contributor, the tax is commonly advanced by the tenant,
  • to whom the landlord is obliged to allow it in the payment of the rent.
  • This tax is levied by a much smaller number of officers than any other
  • which affords nearly the same revenue. As the tax upon each district does
  • not rise with the rise of the rent, the sovereign does not share in the
  • profits of the landlord’s improvements. Those improvements sometimes
  • contribute, indeed, to the discharge of the other landlords of the
  • district. But the aggravation of the tax, which this may sometimes
  • occasion upon a particular estate, is always so very small, that it never
  • can discourage those improvements, nor keep down the produce of the land
  • below what it would otherwise rise to. As it has no tendency to diminish
  • the quantity, it can have none to raise the price of that produce. It does
  • not obstruct the industry of the people; it subjects the landlord to no
  • other inconveniency besides the unavoidable one of paying the tax. The
  • advantage, however, which the land-lord has derived from the invariable
  • constancy of the valuation, by which all the lands of Great Britain are
  • rated to the land-tax, has been principally owing to some circumstances
  • altogether extraneous to the nature of the tax.
  • It has been owing in part, to the great prosperity of almost every part of
  • the country, the rents of almost all the estates of Great Britain having,
  • since the time when this valuation was first established, been continually
  • rising, and scarce any of them having fallen. The landlords, therefore,
  • have almost all gained the difference between the tax which they would
  • have paid, according to the present rent of their estates, and that which
  • they actually pay according to the ancient valuation. Had the state of the
  • country been different, had rents been gradually falling in consequence of
  • the declension of cultivation, the landlords would almost all have lost
  • this difference. In the state of things which has happened to take place
  • since the revolution, the constancy of the valuation has been advantageous
  • to the landlord and hurtful to the sovereign. In a different state of
  • things it might have been advantageous to the sovereign and hurtful to the
  • landlord.
  • As the tax is made payable in money, so the valuation of the land is
  • expressed in money. Since the establishment of this valuation, the value
  • of silver has been pretty uniform, and there has been no alteration in the
  • standard of the coin, either as to weight or fineness. Had silver risen
  • considerably in its value, as it seems to have done in the course of the
  • two centuries which preceded the discovery of the mines of America, the
  • constancy of the valuation might have proved very oppressive to the
  • landlord. Had silver fallen considerably in its value, as it certainly did
  • for about a century at least after the discovery of those mines, the same
  • constancy of valuation would have reduced very much this branch of the
  • revenue of the sovereign. Had any considerable alteration been made in the
  • standard of the money, either by sinking the same quantity of silver to a
  • lower denomination, or by raising it to a higher; had an ounce of silver,
  • for example, instead of being coined into five shillings and two pence,
  • been coined either into pieces which bore so low a denomination as two
  • shillings and seven pence, or into pieces which bore so high a one as ten
  • shillings and four pence, it would, in the one case, have hurt the revenue
  • of the proprietor, in the other that of the sovereign.
  • In circumstances, therefore, somewhat different from those which have
  • actually taken place, this constancy of valuation might have been a very
  • great inconveniency, either to the contributors or to the commonwealth. In
  • the course of ages, such circumstances, however, must at some time or
  • other happen. But though empires, like all the other works of men, have
  • all hitherto proved mortal, yet every empire aims at immortality. Every
  • constitution, therefore, which it is meant should be as permanent as the
  • empire itself, ought to be convenient, not in certain circumstances only,
  • but in all circumstances; or ought to be suited, not to those
  • circumstances which are transitory, occasional, or accidental, but to
  • those which are necessary, and therefore always the same.
  • A tax upon the rent of land, which varies with every variation of the
  • rent, or which rises and falls according to the improvement or neglect of
  • cultivation, is recommended by that sect of men of letters in France, who
  • call themselves the economists, as the most equitable of all taxes. All
  • taxes, they pretend, fall ultimately upon the rent of land, and ought,
  • therefore, to be imposed equally upon the fund which must finally pay
  • them. That all taxes ought to fall as equally as possible upon the fund
  • which must finally pay them, is certainly true. But without entering into
  • the disagreeable discussion of the metaphysical arguments by which they
  • support their very ingenious theory, it will sufficiently appear, from the
  • following review, what are the taxes which fall finally upon the rent of
  • the land, and what are those which fall finally upon some other fund.
  • In the Venetian territory, all the arable lands which are given in lease
  • to farmers are taxed at a tenth of the rent. {Memoires concernant les
  • Droits, p. 240, 241.} The leases are recorded in a public register, which
  • is kept by the officers of revenue in each province or district. When the
  • proprietor cultivates his own lands, they are valued according to an
  • equitable estimation, and he is allowed a deduction of one-fifth of the
  • tax; so that for such land he pays only eight instead of ten per cent. of
  • the supposed rent.
  • A land-tax of this kind is certainly more equal than the land-tax of
  • England. It might not, perhaps, be altogether so certain, and the
  • assessment of the tax might frequently occasion a good deal more trouble
  • to the landlord. It might, too, be a good deal more expensive in the
  • levying.
  • Such a system of administration, however, might, perhaps, be contrived, as
  • would in a great measure both prevent this uncertainty, and moderate this
  • expense.
  • The landlord and tenant, for example, might jointly be obliged to record
  • their lease in a public register. Proper penalties might be enacted
  • against concealing or misrepresenting any of the conditions; and if part
  • of those penalties were to be paid to either of the two parties who
  • informed against and convicted the other of such concealment or
  • misrepresentation, it would effectually deter them from combining together
  • in order to defraud the public revenue. All the conditions of the lease
  • might be sufficiently known from such a record.
  • Some landlords, instead of raising the rent, take a fine for the renewal
  • of the lease. This practice is, in most cases, the expedient of a
  • spendthrift, who, for a sum of ready money sells a future revenue of much
  • greater value. It is, in most cases, therefore, hurtful to the landlord;
  • it is frequently hurtful to the tenant; and it is always hurtful to the
  • community. It frequently takes from the tenant so great a part of his
  • capital, and thereby diminishes so much his ability to cultivate the land,
  • that he finds it more difficult to pay a small rent than it would
  • otherwise have been to pay a great one. Whatever diminishes his ability to
  • cultivate, necessarily keeps down, below what it would otherwise have
  • been, the most important part of the revenue of the community. By
  • rendering the tax upon such fines a good deal heavier than upon the
  • ordinary rent, this hurtful practice might be discouraged, to the no small
  • advantage of all the different parties concerned, of the landlord, of the
  • tenant, of the sovereign, and of the whole community.
  • Some leases prescribe to the tenant a certain mode of cultivation, and a
  • certain succession of crops, during the whole continuance of the lease.
  • This condition, which is generally the effect of the landlord’s conceit of
  • his own superior knowledge (a conceit in most cases very ill-founded),
  • ought always to be considered as an additional rent, as a rent in service,
  • instead of a rent in money. In order to discourage the practice, which is
  • generally a foolish one, this species of rent might be valued rather high,
  • and consequently taxed somewhat higher than common money-rents.
  • Some landlords, instead of a rent in money, require a rent in kind, in
  • corn, cattle, poultry, wine, oil, etc.; others, again, require a rent in
  • service. Such rents are always more hurtful to the tenant than beneficial
  • to the landlord. They either take more, or keep more out of the pocket of
  • the former, than they put into that of the latter. In every country where
  • they take place, the tenants are poor and beggarly, pretty much according
  • to the degree in which they take place. By valuing, in the same manner,
  • such rents rather high, and consequently taxing them somewhat higher than
  • common money-rents, a practice which is hurtful to the whole community,
  • might, perhaps, be sufficiently discouraged.
  • When the landlord chose to occupy himself a part of his own lands, the
  • rent might be valued according to an equitable arbitration of the farmers
  • and landlords in the neighbourhood, and a moderate abatement of the tax
  • might be granted to him, in the same manner as in the Venetian territory,
  • provided the rent of the lands which he occupied did not exceed a certain
  • sum. It is of importance that the landlord should be encouraged to
  • cultivate a part of his own land. His capital is generally greater than
  • that of the tenant, and, with less skill, he can frequently raise a
  • greater produce. The landlord can afford to try experiments, and is
  • generally disposed to do so. His unsuccessful experiments occasion only a
  • moderate loss to himself. His successful ones contribute to the
  • improvement and better cultivation of the whole country. It might be of
  • importance, however, that the abatement of the tax should encourage him to
  • cultivate to a certain extent only. If the landlords should, the greater
  • part of them, be tempted to farm the whole of their own lands, the country
  • (instead of sober and industrious tenants, who are bound by their own
  • interest to cultivate as well as their capital and skill will allow them)
  • would be filled with idle and profligate bailiffs, whose abusive
  • management would soon degrade the cultivation, and reduce the annual
  • produce of the land, to the diminution, not only of the revenue of their
  • masters, but of the most important part of that of the whole society.
  • Such a system of administration might, perhaps, free a tax of this kind
  • from any degree of uncertainty, which could occasion either oppression or
  • inconveniency to the contributor; and might, at the same time, serve to
  • introduce into the common management of land such a plan of policy as
  • might contribute a good deal to the general improvement and good
  • cultivation of the country.
  • The expense of levying a land-tax, which varied with every variation of
  • the rent, would, no doubt, be somewhat greater than that of levying one
  • which was always rated according to a fixed valuation. Some additional
  • expense would necessarily be incurred, both by the different
  • register-offices which it would be proper to establish in the different
  • districts of the country, and by the different valuations which might
  • occasionally be made of the lands which the proprietor chose to occupy
  • himself. The expense of all this, however, might be very moderate, and
  • much below what is incurred in the levying of many other taxes, which
  • afford a very inconsiderable revenue in comparison of what might easily be
  • drawn from a tax of this kind.
  • The discouragement which a variable land-tax of this kind might give to
  • the improvement of land, seems to be the most important objection which
  • can be made to it. The landlord would certainly be less disposed to
  • improve, when the sovereign, who contributed nothing to the expense, was
  • to share in the profit of the improvement. Even this objection might,
  • perhaps, be obviated, by allowing the landlord, before he began his
  • improvement, to ascertain, in conjunction with the officers of revenue,
  • the actual value of his lands, according to the equitable arbitration of a
  • certain number of landlords and farmers in the neighbourhood, equally
  • chosen by both parties: and by rating him, according to this valuation,
  • for such a number of years as might be fully sufficient for his complete
  • indemnification. To draw the attention of the sovereign towards the
  • improvement of the land, from a regard to the increase of his own revenue,
  • is one or the principal advantages proposed by this species of land-tax.
  • The term, therefore, allowed, for the indemnification of the landlord,
  • ought not to be a great deal longer than what was necessary for that
  • purpose, lest the remoteness of the interest should discourage too much
  • this attention. It had better, however, be somewhat too long, than in any
  • respect too short. No incitement to the attention of the sovereign can
  • ever counterbalance the smallest discouragement to that of the landlord.
  • The attention of the sovereign can be, at best, but a very general and
  • vague consideration of what is likely to contribute to the better
  • cultivation of the greater part of his dominions. The attention of the
  • landlord is a particular and minute consideration of what is likely to be
  • the most advantageous application of every inch of ground upon his estate.
  • The principal attention of the sovereign ought to be, to encourage, by
  • every means in his power, the attention both of the landlord and of the
  • farmer, by allowing both to pursue their own interest in their own way,
  • and according to their own judgment; by giving to both the most perfect
  • security that they shall enjoy the full recompence of their own industry;
  • and by procuring to both the most extensive market for every part of their
  • produce, in consequence of establishing the easiest and safest
  • communications, both by land and by water, through every part of his own
  • dominions, as well as the most unbounded freedom of exportation to the
  • dominions of all other princes.
  • If, by such a system of administration, a tax of this kind could be so
  • managed as to give, not only no discouragement, but, on the contrary, some
  • encouragement to the improvement or land, it does not appear likely to
  • occasion any other inconveniency to the landlord, except always the
  • unavoidable one of being obliged to pay the tax. In all the variations of
  • the state of the society, in the improvement and in the declension of
  • agriculture; in all the variations in the value of silver, and in all
  • those in the standard of the coin, a tax of this kind would, of its own
  • accord, and without any attention of government, readily suit itself to
  • the actual situation of things, and would be equally just and equitable in
  • all those different changes. It would, therefore, be much more proper to
  • be established as a perpetual and unalterable regulation, or as what is
  • called a fundamental law of the commonwealth, than any tax which was
  • always to be levied according to a certain valuation.
  • Some states, instead of the simple and obvious expedient of a register of
  • leases, have had recourse to the laborious and expensive one of an actual
  • survey and valuation of all the lands in the country. They have suspected,
  • probably, that the lessor and lessee, in order to defraud the public
  • revenue, might combine to conceal the real terms of the lease.
  • Doomsday-book seems to have been the result of a very accurate survey of
  • this kind.
  • In the ancient dominions of the king of Prussia, the land-tax is assessed
  • according to an actual survey and valuation, which is reviewed and altered
  • from time to time. {Memoires concurent les Droits, etc. tom, i. p. 114,
  • 115, 116, etc.} According to that valuation, the lay proprietors pay from
  • twenty to twenty-five per cent. of their revenue; ecclesiastics from forty
  • to forty-five per cent. The survey and valuation of Silesia was made by
  • order of the present king, it is said, with great accuracy. According to
  • that valuation, the lands belonging to the bishop of Breslaw are taxed at
  • twenty-five per cent. of their rent. The other revenues of the
  • ecclesiastics of both religions at fifty per cent. The commanderies of the
  • Teutonic order, and of that of Malta, at forty per cent. Lands held by a
  • noble tenure, at thirty-eight and one-third per cent. Lands held by a base
  • tenure, at thirty-five and one-third per cent.
  • The survey and valuation of Bohemia is said to have been the work of more
  • than a hundred years. It was not perfected till after the peace of 1748,
  • by the orders of the present empress queen. {Id. tom i. p.85, 84.} The
  • survey of the duchy of Milan, which was begun in the time of Charles VI.,
  • was not perfected till after 1760 It is esteemed one of the most accurate
  • that has ever been made. The survey of Savoy and Piedmont was executed
  • under the orders of the late king of Sardinia. {Id. p. 280, etc.; also p,
  • 287. etc. to 316.}
  • In the dominions of the king of Prussia, the revenue of the church is
  • taxed much higher than that of lay proprietors. The revenue of the church
  • is, the greater part of it, a burden upon the rent of land. It seldom
  • happens that any part of it is applied towards the improvement of land; or
  • is so employed as to contribute, in any respect, towards increasing the
  • revenue of the great body of the people. His Prussian majesty had
  • probably, upon that account, thought it reasonable that it should
  • contribute a good deal more towards relieving the exigencies of the state.
  • In some countries, the lands of the church are exempted from all taxes. In
  • others, they are taxed more lightly than other lands. In the duchy of
  • Milan, the lands which the church possessed before 1575, are rated to the
  • tax at a third only or their value.
  • In Silesia, lands held by a noble tenure are taxed three per cent. higher
  • than those held by a base tenure. The honours and privileges of different
  • kinds annexed to the former, his Prussian majesty had probably imagined,
  • would sufficiently compensate to the proprietor a small aggravation of the
  • tax; while, at the same time, the humiliating inferiority of the latter
  • would be in some measure alleviated, by being taxed somewhat more lightly.
  • In other countries, the system of taxation, instead of alleviating,
  • aggravates this inequality. In the dominions of the king of Sardinia, and
  • in those provinces of France which are subject to what is called the real
  • or predial taille, the tax falls altogether upon the lands held by a base
  • tenure. Those held by a noble one are exempted.
  • A land tax assessed according to a general survey and valuation, how equal
  • soever it may be at first, must, in the course of a very moderate period
  • of time, become unequal. To prevent its becoming so would require the
  • continual and painful attention of government to all the variations in the
  • state and produce of every different farm in the country. The governments
  • of Prussia, of Bohemia, of Sardinia, and of the duchy of Milan, actually
  • exert an attention of this kind; an attention so unsuitable to the nature
  • of government, that it is not likely to be of long continuance, and which,
  • if it is continued, will probably, in the long-run, occasion much more
  • trouble and vexation than it can possibly bring relief to the
  • contributors.
  • In 1666, the generality of Montauban was assessed to the real or predial
  • taille, according, it is said, to a very exact survey and valuation.
  • {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. ii p. 139, etc.} By 1727, this
  • assessment had become altogether unequal. In order to remedy this
  • inconveniency, government has found no better expedient, than to impose
  • upon the whole generality an additional tax of a hundred and twenty
  • thousand livres. This additional tax is rated upon all the different
  • districts subject to the taille according to the old assessment. But it is
  • levied only upon those which, in the actual state of things, are by that
  • assessment under-taxed; and it is applied to the relief of those which, by
  • the same assessment, are over-taxed. Two districts, for example, one of
  • which ought, in the actual state of things, to be taxed at nine hundred,
  • the other at eleven hundred livres, are, by the old assessment, both taxed
  • at a thousand livres. Both these districts are, by the additional tax,
  • rated at eleven hundred livres each. But this additional tax is levied
  • only upon the district under-charged, and it is applied altogether to the
  • relief of that overcharged, which consequently pays only nine hundred
  • livres. The government neither gains nor loses by the additional tax,
  • which is applied altogether to remedy the inequalities arising from the
  • old assessment. The application is pretty much regulated according to the
  • discretion of the intendant of the generality, and must, therefore, be in
  • a great measure arbitrary.
  • Taxes which are proportioned, not in the Rent, but to the Produce of Land.
  • Taxes upon the produce of land are, In reality, taxes upon the rent; and
  • though they may be originally advanced by the farmer, are finally paid by
  • the landlord. When a certain portion of the produce is to be paid away for
  • a tax, the farmer computes as well as he can, what the value of this
  • portion is, one year with another, likely to amount to, and he makes a
  • proportionable abatement in the rent which he agrees to pay to the
  • landlord. There is no farmer who does not compute beforehand what the
  • church tythe, which is a land tax of this kind, is, one year with another,
  • likely to amount to.
  • The tythe, and every other land tax of this kind, under the appearance of
  • perfect equality, are very unequal taxes; a certain portion of the produce
  • being in differrent situations, equivalent to a very different portion of
  • the rent. In some very rich lands, the produce is so great, that the one
  • half of it is fully sufficient to replace to the farmer his capital
  • employed in cultivation, together with the ordinary profits of farming
  • stock in the neighbourhood. The other half, or, what comes to the same
  • thing, the value of the other half, he could afford to pay as rent to the
  • landlord, if there was no tythe. But if a tenth of the produce is taken
  • from him in the way of tythe, he must require an abatement of the fifth
  • part of his rent, otherwise he cannot get back his capital with the
  • ordinary profit. In this case, the rent of the landlord, instead of
  • amounting to a half, or five-tenths of the whole produce, will amount only
  • to four-tenths of it. In poorer lands, on the contrary, the produce is
  • sometimes so small, and the expense of cultivation so great, that it
  • requires four-fifths of the whole produce, to replace to the farmer his
  • capital with the ordinary profit. In this case, though there was no tythe,
  • the rent of the landlord could amount to no more than one-fifth or
  • two-tenths of the whole produce. But if the farmer pays one-tenth of the
  • produce in the way of tythe, he must require an equal abatement of the
  • rent of the landlord, which will thus be reduced to one-tenth only of the
  • whole produce. Upon the rent of rich lands the tythe may sometimes be a
  • tax of no more than one-fifth part, or four shillings in the pound;
  • whereas upon that of poorer lands, it may sometimes be a tax of one half,
  • or of ten shillings in the pound.
  • The tythe, as it is frequently a very unequal tax upon the rent, so it is
  • always a great discouragement, both to the improvements of the landlord,
  • and to the cultivation of the farmer. The one cannot venture to make the
  • most important, which are generally the most expensive improvements; nor
  • the other to raise the most valuable, which are generally, too, the most
  • expensive crops; when the church, which lays out no part of the expense,
  • is to share so very largely in the profit. The cultivation of madder was,
  • for a long time, confined by the tythe to the United Provinces, which,
  • being presbyterian countries, and upon that account exempted from this
  • destructive tax, enjoyed a sort of monopoly of that useful dyeing drug
  • against the rest of Europe. The late attempts to introduce the culture of
  • this plant into England, have been made only in consequence of the
  • statute, which enacted that five shillings an acre should be received in
  • lieu of all manner of tythe upon madder.
  • As through the greater part of Europe, the church, so in many different
  • countries of Asia, the state, is principally supported by a land tax,
  • proportioned not to the rent, but to the produce of the land. In China,
  • the principal revenue of the sovereign consists in a tenth part of the
  • produce of all the lands of the empire. This tenth part, however, is
  • estimated so very moderately, that, in many provinces, it is said not to
  • exceed a thirtieth part of the ordinary produce. The land tax or land rent
  • which used to be paid to the Mahometan government of Bengal, before that
  • country fell into the hands of the English East India company, is said to
  • have amounted to about a fifth part of the produce. The land tax of
  • ancient Egypt is said likewise to have amounted to a fifth part.
  • In Asia, this sort of land tax is said to interest the sovereign in the
  • improvement and cultivation of land. The sovereigns of China, those of
  • Bengal while under the Mahometan govermnent, and those of ancient Egypt,
  • are said, accordingly, to have been extremely attentive to the making and
  • maintaining of good roads and navigable canals, in order to increase, as
  • much as possible, both the quantity and value of every part of the produce
  • of the land, by procuring to every part of it the most extensive market
  • which their own dominions could afford. The tythe of the church is divided
  • into such small portions that no one of its proprietors can have any
  • interest of this kind. The parson of a parish could never find his
  • account, in making a road or canal to a distant part of the country, in
  • order to extend the market for the produce of his own particular parish.
  • Such taxes, when destined for the maintenance of the state, have some
  • advantages, which may serve in some measure to balance their
  • inconveniency. When destined for the maintenance of the church, they are
  • attended with nothing but inconveniency.
  • Taxes upon the produce of land may be levied, either in kind, or,
  • according to a certain valuation in money.
  • The parson of a parish, or a gentleman of small fortune who lives upon his
  • estate, may sometimes, perhaps find some advantage in receiving, the one
  • his tythe, and the other his rent, in kind. The quantity to be collected,
  • and the district within which it is to be collected, are so small, that
  • they both can oversee, with their own eyes, the collection and disposal of
  • every part of what is due to them. A gentleman of great fortune, who lived
  • in the capital, would be in danger of suffering much by the neglect, and
  • more by the fraud, of his factors and agents, if the rents of an estate in
  • a distant province were to be paid to him in this manner. The loss of the
  • sovereign, from the abuse and depredation of his tax-gatherers, would
  • necessarily be much greater. The servants of the most careless private
  • person are, perhaps, more under the eye of their master than those of the
  • most careful prince; and a public revenue, which was paid in kind, would
  • suffer so much from the mismanagement of the collectors, that a very small
  • part of what was levied upon the people would ever arrive at the treasury
  • of the prince. Some part of the public revenue of China, however, is said
  • to be paid in this manner. The mandarins and other tax-gatherers will, no
  • doubt, find their advantage in continuing the practice of a payment, which
  • is so much more liable to abuse than any payment in money.
  • A tax upon the produce of land, which is levied in money, may be levied,
  • either according to a valuation, which varies with all the variations of
  • the market price; or according to a fixed valuation, a bushel of wheat,
  • for example, being always valued at one and the same money price, whatever
  • may be the state of the market. The produce of a tax levied in the former
  • way will vary only according to the variations in the real produce of the
  • land, according to the improvement or neglect of cultivation. The produce
  • of a tax levied in the latter way will vary, not only according to the
  • variations in the produce of the land, but according both to those in the
  • value of the precious metals, and those in the quantity of those metals
  • which is at different times contained in coin of the same denomination.
  • The produce of the former will always bear the same proportion to the
  • value of the real produce of the land. The produce of the latter may, at
  • different times, bear very different proportions to that value.
  • When, instead either of a certain portion of the produce of land, or of
  • the price of a certain portion, a certain sum of money is to be paid in
  • full compensation for all tax or tythe; the tax becomes, in this case,
  • exactly of the same nature with the land tax of England. It neither rises
  • nor falls with the rent of the land. It neither encourages nor discourages
  • improvement. The tythe in the greater part of those parishes which pay
  • what is called a modus, in lieu of all other tythe is a tax of this kind.
  • During the Mahometan government of Bengal, instead of the payment in kind
  • of the fifth part of the produce, a modus, and, it is said, a very
  • moderate one, was established in the greater part of the districts or
  • zemindaries of the country. Some of the servants of the East India
  • company, under pretence of restoring the public revenue to its proper
  • value, have, in some provinces, exchanged this modus for a payment in
  • kind. Under their management, this change is likely both to discourage
  • cultivation, and to give new opportunities for abuse in the collection of
  • the public revenue, which has fallen very much below what it was said to
  • have been when it first fell under the management of the company. The
  • servants of the company may, perhaps, have profited by the change, but at
  • the expense, it is probable, both of their masters and of the country.
  • Taxes upon the Rent of Houses.
  • The rent of a house may be distinguished into two parts, of which the one
  • may very properly be called the building-rent; the other is commonly
  • called the ground-rent.
  • The building-rent is the interest or profit of the capital expended in
  • building the house. In order to put the trade of a builder upon a level
  • with other trades, it is necessary that this rent should be sufficient,
  • first, to pay him the same interest which he would have got for his
  • capital, if he had lent it upon good security; and, secondly, to keep the
  • house in constant repair, or, what comes to the same thing, to replace,
  • within a certain term of years, the capital which had been employed in
  • building it. The building-rent, or the ordinary profit of building, is,
  • therefore, everywhere regulated by the ordinary interest of money. Where
  • the market rate of interest is four per cent. the rent of a house, which,
  • over and above paying the ground-rent, affords six or six and a-half per
  • cent. upon the whole expense of building, may, perhaps, afford a
  • sufficient profit to the builder. Where the market rate of interest is
  • five per cent. it may perhaps require seven or seven and a half per cent.
  • If, in proportion to the interest of money, the trade of the builders
  • affords at any time much greater profit than this, it will soon draw so
  • much capital from other trades as will reduce the profit to its proper
  • level. If it affords at any time much less than this, other trades will
  • soon draw so much capital from it as will again raise that profit.
  • Whatever part of the whole rent of a house is over and above what is
  • sufficient for affording this reasonable profit, naturally goes to the
  • ground-rent; and, where the owner of the ground and the owner of the
  • building are two different persons, is, in most cases, completely paid to
  • the former. This surplus rent is the price which the inhabitant of the
  • house pays for some real or supposed advantage of the situation. In
  • country houses, at a distance from any great town, where there is plenty
  • of ground to chuse upon, the ground-rent is scarce anything, or no more
  • than what the ground which the house stands upon would pay, if employed in
  • agriculture. In country villas, in the neighbourhood of some great town,
  • it is sometimes a good deal higher; and the peculiar conveniency or beauty
  • of situation is there frequently very well paid for. Ground-rents are
  • generally highest in the capital, and in those particular parts of it
  • where there happens to be the greatest demand for houses, whatever be the
  • reason of that demand, whether for trade and business, for pleasure and
  • society, or for mere vanity and fashion.
  • A tax upon house-rent, payable by the tenant, and proportioned to the
  • whole rent of each house, could not, for any considerable time at least,
  • affect the building-rent. If the builder did not get his reasonable
  • profit, he would be obliged to quit the trade; which, by raising the
  • demand for building, would, in a short time, bring back his profit to its
  • proper level with that of other trades. Neither would such a tax fall
  • altogether upon the ground-rent; but it would divide itself in such a
  • manner, as to fall partly upon the inhabitant of the house, and partly
  • upon the owner of the ground.
  • Let us suppose, for example, that a particular person judges that he can
  • afford for house-rent all expense of sixty pounds a-year; and let us
  • suppose, too, that a tax of four shillings in the pound, or of one-fifth,
  • payable by the inhabitant, is laid upon house-rent. A house of sixty
  • pounds rent will, in that case, cost him seventy-two pounds a-year, which
  • is twelve pounds more than he thinks he can afford. He will, therefore,
  • content himself with a worse house, or a house of fifty pounds rent,
  • which, with the additional ten pounds that he must pay for the tax, will
  • make up the sum of sixty pounds a-year, the expense which he judges he can
  • afford, and, in order to pay the tax, he will give up a part of the
  • additional conveniency which he might have had from a house of ten pounds
  • a-year more rent. He will give up, I say, a part of this additional
  • conveniency; for he will seldom be obliged to give up the whole, but will,
  • in consequence of the tax, get a better house for fifty pounds a-year,
  • than he could have got if there had been no tax for as a tax of this kind,
  • by taking away this particular competitor, must diminish the competition
  • for houses of sixty pounds rent, so it must likewise diminish it for those
  • of fifty pounds rent, and in the same manner for those of all other rents,
  • except the lowest rent, for which it would for some time increase the
  • competition. But the rents of every class of houses for which the
  • competition was diminished, would necessarily be more or less reduced. As
  • no part of this reduction, however, could for any considerable time at
  • least, affect the building-rent, the whole of it must, in the long-run,
  • necessarily fall upon the ground-rent. The final payment of this tax,
  • therefore, would fall partly upon the inhabitant of the house, who, in
  • order to pay his share, would be obliged to give up a part of his
  • conveniency; and partly upon the owner of the ground, who, in order to pay
  • his share, would be obliged to give up a part of his revenue. In what
  • proportion this final payment would be divided between them, it is not,
  • perhaps, very easy to ascertain. The division would probably be very
  • different in different circumstances, and a tax of this kind might,
  • according to those different circumstances, affect very unequally, both
  • the inhabitant of the house and the owner of the ground.
  • The inequality with which a tax of this kind might fall upon the owners of
  • different ground-rents, would arise altogether from the accidental
  • inequality of this division. But the inequality with which it might fall
  • upon the inhabitants of different houses, would arise, not only from this,
  • but from another cause. The proportion of the expense of house-rent to the
  • whole expense of living, is different in the different degrees of fortune.
  • It is, perhaps, highest in the highest degree, and it diminishes gradually
  • through the inferior degrees, so as in general to be lowest in the lowest
  • degree. The necessaries of life occasion the great expense of the poor.
  • They find it difficult to get food, and the greater part of their little
  • revenue is spent in getting it. The luxuries and vanities of life occasion
  • the principal expense of the rich; and a magnificent house embellishes and
  • sets off to the best advantage all the other luxuries and vanities which
  • they possess. A tax upon house-rents, therefore, would in general fall
  • heaviest upon the rich; and in this sort of inequality there would not,
  • perhaps, be any thing very unreasonable. It is not very unreasonable that
  • the rich should contribute to the public expense, not only in proportion
  • to their revenue, but something more than in that proportion.
  • The rent of houses, though it in some respects resembles the rent of land,
  • is in one respect essentially different from it. The rent of land is paid
  • for the use of a productive subject. The land which pays it produces it.
  • The rent of houses is paid for the use of an unproductive subject. Neither
  • the house, nor the ground which it stands upon, produce anything. The
  • person who pays the rent, therefore, must draw it from some other source
  • of revenue, distinct from and independent of this subject. A tax upon the
  • rent of houses, so far as it falls upon the inhabitants, must be drawn
  • from the same source as the rent itself, and must be paid from their
  • revenue, whether derived from the wages of labour, the profits of stock,
  • or the rent of land. So far as it falls upon the inhabitants, it is one of
  • those taxes which fall, not upon one only, but indifferently upon all the
  • three different sources of revenue; and is, in every respect, of the same
  • nature as a tax upon any other sort of consumable commodities. In general,
  • there is not perhaps, any one article of expense or consumption by which
  • the liberality or narrowness of a man’s whole expense can be better judged
  • of than by his house-rent. A proportional tax upon this particular article
  • of expense might, perhaps, produce a more considerable revenue than any
  • which has hitherto been drawn from it in any part of Europe. If the tax,
  • indeed, was very high, the greater part of people would endeavour to evade
  • it as much as they could, by contenting themselves with smaller houses,
  • and by turning the greater part of their expense into some other channel.
  • The rent of houses might easily be ascertained with sufficient accuracy,
  • by a policy of the same kind with that which would be necessary for
  • ascertaining the ordinary rent of land. Houses not inhabited ought to pay
  • no tax. A tax upon them would fall altogether upon the proprietor, who
  • would thus be taxed for a subject which afforded him neither conveniency
  • nor revenue. Houses inhabited by the proprietor ought to be rated, not
  • according to the expense which they might have cost in building, but
  • according to the rent which an equitable arbitration might judge them
  • likely to bring if leased to a tenant. If rated according to the expense
  • which they might have cost in building, a tax of three or four shillings
  • in the pound, joined with other taxes, would ruin almost all the rich and
  • great families of this, and, I believe, of every other civilized country.
  • Whoever will examine with attention the different town and country houses
  • of some of the richest and greatest families in this country, will find
  • that, at the rate of only six and a-half, or seven per cent. upon the
  • original expense of building, their house-rent is nearly equal to the
  • whole neat rent of their estates. It is the accumulated expense of several
  • successive generations, laid out upon objects of great beauty and
  • magnificence, indeed, but, in proportion to what they cost, of very small
  • exchangeable value. {Since the first publication of this book, a tax
  • nearly upon the above-mentioned principles has been imposed.}
  • Ground-rents are a still more proper subject of taxation than the rent of
  • houses. A tax upon ground-rents would not raise the rent of houses; it
  • would fall altogether upon the owner of the ground-rent, who acts always
  • as a monopolist, and exacts the greatest rent which can be got for the use
  • of his ground. More or less can be got for it, according as the
  • competitors happen to be richer or poorer, or can afford to gratify their
  • fancy for a particular spot of ground at a greater or smaller expense. In
  • every country, the greatest number of rich competitors is in the capital,
  • and it is there accordingly that the highest ground-rents are always to be
  • found. As the wealth of those competitors would in no respect be increased
  • by a tax upon ground-rents, they would not probably be disposed to pay
  • more for the use of the ground. Whether the tax was to be advanced by the
  • inhabitant or by the owner of the ground, would be of little importance.
  • The more the inhabitant was obliged to pay for the tax, the less he would
  • incline to pay for the ground; so that the final payment of the tax would
  • fall altogether upon the owner of the ground-rent. The ground-rents of
  • uninhabited houses ought to pay no tax. Both ground-rents, and the
  • ordinary rent of land, are a species of revenue which the owner, in many
  • cases, enjoys without any care or attention of his own. Though a part of
  • this revenue should be taken from him in order to defray the expenses of
  • the state, no discouragement will thereby be given to any sort of
  • industry. The annual produce of the land and labour of the society, the
  • real wealth and revenue of the great body of the people, might be the same
  • after such a tax as before. Ground-rents, and the ordinary rent of land,
  • are therefore, perhaps, the species of revenue which can best bear to have
  • a peculiar tax imposed upon them.
  • Ground-rents seem, in this respect, a more proper subject of peculiar
  • taxation, than even the ordinary rent of land. The ordinary rent of land
  • is, in many cases, owing partly, at least, to the attention and good
  • management of the landlord. A very heavy tax might discourage, too much,
  • this attention and good management. Ground-rents, so far as they exceed
  • the ordinary rent of land, are altogether owing to the good government of
  • the sovereign, which, by protecting the industry either of the whole
  • people or of the inhabitants of some particular place, enables them to pay
  • so much more than its real value for the ground which they build their
  • houses upon; or to make to its owner so much more than compensation for
  • the loss which he might sustain by this use of it. Nothing can be more
  • reasonable, than that a fund, which owes its existence to the good
  • government of the state, should be taxed peculiarly, or should contribute
  • something more than the greater part of other funds, towards the support
  • of that government.
  • Though, in many different countries of Europe, taxes have been imposed
  • upon the rent of houses, I do not know of any in which ground-rents have
  • been considered as a separate subject of taxation. The contrivers of taxes
  • have, probably, found some difficulty in ascertaining what part of the
  • rent ought to be considered as ground-rent, and what part ought to be
  • considered as building-rent. It should not, however, seem very difficult
  • to distinguish those two parts of the rent from one another.
  • In Great Britain the rent of houses is supposed to be taxed in the same
  • proportion as the rent of land, by what is called the annual land tax. The
  • valuation, according to which each different parish and district is
  • assessed to this tax, is always the same. It was originally extremely
  • unequal, and it still continues to be so. Through the greater part of the
  • kingdom this tax falls still more lightly upon the rent of houses than
  • upon that of land. In some few districts only, which were originally rated
  • high, and in which the rents of houses have fallen considerably, the land
  • tax of three or four shillings in the pound is said to amount to an equal
  • proportion of the real rent of houses. Untenanted houses, though by law
  • subject to the tax, are, in most districts, exempted from it by the favour
  • of the assessors; and this exemption sometimes occasions some little
  • variation in the rate of particular houses, though that of the district is
  • always the same. Improvements of rent, by new buildings, repairs, etc. go
  • to the discharge of the district, which occasions still further variations
  • in the rate of particular houses.
  • In the province of Holland, {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. p. 223.}
  • every house is taxed at two and a-half per cent. of its value, without any
  • regard, either to the rent which it actually pays, or to the circumstance
  • of its being tenanted or untenanted. There seems to be a hardship in
  • obliging the proprietor to pay a tax for an untenanted house, from which
  • he can derive no revenue, especially so very heavy a tax. In Holland,
  • where the market rate of interest does not exceed three per cent., two and
  • a-half per cent. upon the whole value of the house must, in most cases,
  • amount to more than a third of the building-rent, perhaps of the whole
  • rent. The valuation, indeed, according to which the houses are rated,
  • though very unequal, is said to be always below the real value. When a
  • house is rebuilt, improved, or enlarged, there is a new valuation, and the
  • tax is rated accordingly.
  • The contrivers of the several taxes which in England have, at different
  • times, been imposed upon houses, seem to have imagined that there was some
  • great difficulty in ascertaining, with tolerable exactness, what was the
  • real rent of every house. They have regulated their taxes, therefore,
  • according to some more obvious circumstance, such as they had probably
  • imagined would, in most cases, bear some proportion to the rent.
  • The first tax of this kind was hearth-money; or a tax of two shillings
  • upon every hearth. In order to ascertain how many hearths were in the
  • house, it was necessary that the tax-gatherer should enter every room in
  • it. This odious visit rendered the tax odious. Soon after the Revolution,
  • therefore, it was abolished as a badge of slavery.
  • The next tax of this kind was a tax of two shillings upon every
  • dwelling-house inhabited. A house with ten windows to pay four shillings
  • more. A house with twenty windows and upwards to pay eight shillings. This
  • tax was afterwards so far altered, that houses with twenty windows, and
  • with less than thirty, were ordered to pay ten shillings, and those with
  • thirty windows and upwards to pay twenty shillings. The number of windows
  • can, in most cases, be counted from the outside, and, in all cases,
  • without entering every room in the house. The visit of the tax-gatherer,
  • therefore, was less offensive in this tax than in the hearth-money.
  • This tax was afterwards repealed, and in the room of it was established
  • the window-tax, which has undergone two several alterations and
  • augmentations. The window tax, as it stands at present (January 1775),
  • over and above the duty of three shillings upon every house in England,
  • and of one shilling upon every house in Scotland, lays a duty upon every
  • window, which in England augments gradually from twopence, the lowest rate
  • upon houses with not more than seven windows, to two shillings, the
  • highest rate upon houses with twenty-five windows and upwards.
  • The principal objection to all such taxes is their inequality; an
  • inequality of the worst kind, as they must frequently fall much heavier
  • upon the poor than upon the rich. A house of ten pounds rent in a country
  • town, may sometimes have more windows than a house of five hundred pounds
  • rent in London; and though the inhabitant of the former is likely to be a
  • much poorer man than that of the latter, yet, so far as his contribution
  • is regulated by the window tax, he must contribute more to the support of
  • the state. Such taxes are, therefore, directly contrary to the first of
  • the four maxims above mentioned. They do not seem to offend much against
  • any of the other three.
  • The natural tendency of the window tax, and of all other taxes upon
  • houses, is to lower rents. The more a man pays for the tax, the less, it
  • is evident, he can afford to pay for the rent. Since the imposition of the
  • window tax, however, the rents of houses have, upon the whole, risen more
  • or less, in almost every town and village of Great Britain, with which I
  • am acquainted. Such has been, almost everywhere, the increase of the
  • demand for houses, that it has raised the rents more than the window tax
  • could sink them; one of the many proofs of the great prosperity of the
  • country, and of the increasing revenue of its inhabitants. Had it not been
  • for the tax, rents would probably have risen still higher.
  • ARTICLE II.—Taxes upon Profit, or upon the Revenue arising from
  • Stock.
  • The revenue or profit arising from stock naturally divides itself into two
  • parts; that which pays the interest, and which belongs to the owner of the
  • stock; and that surplus part which is over and above what is necessary for
  • paying the interest.
  • This latter part of profit is evidently a subject not taxable directly. It
  • is the compensation, and, in most cases, it is no more than a very
  • moderate compensation for the risk and trouble of employing the stock. The
  • employer must have this compensation, otherwise he cannot, consistently
  • with his own interest, continue the employment. If he was taxed directly,
  • therefore, in proportion to the whole profit, he would be obliged either
  • to raise the rate of his profit, or to charge the tax upon the interest of
  • money; that is, to pay less interest. If he raised the rate of his profit
  • in proportion to the tax, the whole tax, though it might be advanced by
  • him, would be finally paid by one or other of two different sets of
  • people, according to the different ways in which he might employ the stock
  • of which he had the management. If he employed it as a farming stock, in
  • the cultivation of land, he could raise the rate of his profit only by
  • retaining a greater portion, or, what comes to the same thing, the price
  • of a greater portion, of the produce of the land; and as this could be
  • done only by a reduction of rent, the final payment of the tax would fall
  • upon the landlord. If he employed it as a mercantile or manufacturing
  • stock, he could raise the rate of his profit only by raising the price of
  • his goods; in which case, the final payment of the tax would fall
  • altogether upon the consumers of those goods. If he did not raise the rate
  • of his profit, he would be obliged to charge the whole tax upon that part
  • of it which was allotted for the interest of money. He could afford less
  • interest for whatever stock he borrowed, and the whole weight of the tax
  • would, in this case, fall ultimately upon the interest of money. So far as
  • he could not relieve himself from the tax in the one way, he would be
  • obliged to relieve himself in the other.
  • The interest of money seems, at first sight, a subject equally capable of
  • being taxed directly as the rent of land. Like the rent of land, it is a
  • neat produce, which remains, after completely compensating the whole risk
  • and trouble of employing the stock. As a tax upon the rent of land cannot
  • raise rents, because the neat produce which remains, after replacing the
  • stock of the farmer, together with his reasonable profit, cannot be
  • greater after the tax than before it, so, for the same reason, a tax upon
  • the interest of money could not raise the rate of interest; the quantity
  • of stock or money in the country, like the quantity of land, being
  • supposed to remain the same after the tax as before it. The ordinary rate
  • of profit, it has been shewn, in the first book, is everywhere regulated
  • by the quantity of stock to be employed, in proportion to the quantity of
  • the employment, or of the business which must be done by it. But the
  • quantity of the employment, or of the business to be done by stock, could
  • neither be increased nor diminished by any tax upon the interest of money.
  • If the quantity of the stock to be employed, therefore, was neither
  • increased nor diminished by it, the ordinary rate of profit would
  • necessarily remain the same. But the portion of this profit, necessary for
  • compensating the risk and trouble of the employer, would likewise remain
  • the same; that risk and trouble being in no respect altered. The residue,
  • therefore, that portion which belongs to the owner of the stock, and which
  • pays the interest of money, would necessarily remain the same too. At
  • first sight, therefore, the interest of money seems to be a subject as fit
  • to be taxed directly as the rent of land.
  • There are, however, two different circumstances, which render the interest
  • of money a much less proper subject of direct taxation than the rent of
  • land.
  • First, the quantity and value of the land which any man possesses, can
  • never be a secret, and can always be ascertained with great exactness. But
  • the whole amount of the capital stock which he possesses is almost always
  • a secret, and can scarce ever be ascertained with tolerable exactness. It
  • is liable, besides, to almost continual variations. A year seldom passes
  • away, frequently not a month, sometimes scarce a single day, in which it
  • does not rise or fall more or less. An inquisition into every man’s
  • private circumstances, and an inquisition which, in order to accommodate
  • the tax to them, watched over all the fluctuations of his fortune, would
  • be a source of such continual and endless vexation as no person could
  • support.
  • Secondly, land is a subject which cannot be removed; whereas stock easily
  • may. The proprietor of land is necessarily a citizen of the particular
  • country in which his estate lies. The proprietor of stock is properly a
  • citizen of the world, and is not necessarily attached to any particular
  • country. He would be apt to abandon the country in which he was exposed to
  • a vexatious inquisition, in order to be assessed to a burdensome tax; and
  • would remove his stock to some other country, where he could either carry
  • on his business, or enjoy his fortune more at his ease. By removing his
  • stock, he would put an end to all the industry which it had maintained in
  • the country which he left. Stock cultivates land; stock employs labour. A
  • tax which tended to drive away stock from any particular country, would so
  • far tend to dry up every source of revenue, both to the sovereign and to
  • the society. Not only the profits of stock, but the rent of land, and the
  • wages of labour, would necessarily be more or less diminished by its
  • removal.
  • The nations, accordingly, who have attempted to tax the revenue arising
  • from stock, instead of any severe inquisition of this kind, have been
  • obliged to content themselves with some very loose, and, therefore, more
  • or less arbitrary estimation. The extreme inequality and uncertainty of a
  • tax assessed in this manner, can be compensated only by its extreme
  • moderation; in consequence of which, every man finds himself rated so very
  • much below his real revenue, that he gives himself little disturbance
  • though his neighbour should be rated somewhat lower.
  • By what is called the land tax in England, it was intended that the stock
  • should be taxed in the same proportion as land. When the tax upon land was
  • at four shillings in the pound, or at one-fifth of the supposed rent, it
  • was intended that stock should be taxed at one-fifth of the supposed
  • interest. When the present annual land tax was first imposed, the legal
  • rate of interest was six per cent. Every hundred pounds stock,
  • accordingly, was supposed to be taxed at twenty-four shillings, the fifth
  • part of six pounds. Since the legal rate of interest has been reduced to
  • five per cent. every hundred pounds stock is supposed to be taxed at
  • twenty shillings only. The sum to be raised, by what is called the land
  • tax, was divided between the country and the principal towns. The greater
  • part of it was laid upon the country; and of what was laid upon the towns,
  • the greater part was assessed upon the houses. What remained to be
  • assessed upon the stock or trade of the towns (for the stock upon the land
  • was not meant to be taxed) was very much below the real value of that
  • stock or trade. Whatever inequalities, therefore, there might be in the
  • original assessment, gave little disturbance. Every parish and district
  • still continues to be rated for its land, its houses, and its stock,
  • according to the original assessment; and the almost universal prosperity
  • of the country, which, in most places, has raised very much the value of
  • all these, has rendered those inequalities of still less importance now.
  • The rate, too, upon each district, continuing always the same, the
  • uncertainty of this tax, so far as it might he assessed upon the stock of
  • any individual, has been very much diminished, as well as rendered of much
  • less consequence. If the greater part of the lands of England are not
  • rated to the land tax at half their actual value, the greater part of the
  • stock of England is, perhaps, scarce rated at the fiftieth part of its
  • actual value. In some towns, the whole land tax is assessed upon houses;
  • as in Westminster, where stock and trade are free. It is otherwise in
  • London.
  • In all countries, a severe inquisition into the circumstances of private
  • persons has been carefully avoided.
  • At Hamburg, {Memoires concernant les Droits, tom. i, p.74} every
  • inhabitant is obliged to pay to the state one fourth per cent. of all that
  • he possesses; and as the wealth of the people of Hamburg consists
  • principally in stock, this tax maybe considered as a tax upon stock. Every
  • man assesses himself, and, in the presence of the magistrate, puts
  • annually into the public coffer a certain sum of money, which he declares
  • upon oath, to be one fourth per cent. of all that he possesses, but
  • without declaring what it amounts to, or being liable to any examination
  • upon that subject. This tax is generally supposed to be paid with great
  • fidelity. In a small republic, where the people have entire confidence in
  • their magistrates, are convinced of the necessity of the tax for the
  • support of the state, and believe that it will be faithfully applied to
  • that purpose, such conscientious and voluntary payment may sometimes be
  • expected. It is not peculiar to the people of Hamburg.
  • The canton of Underwald, in Switzerland, is frequently ravaged by storms
  • and inundations, and it is thereby exposed to extraordinary expenses. Upon
  • such occasions the people assemble, and every one is said to declare with
  • the greatest frankness what he is worth, in order to be taxed accordingly.
  • At Zurich, the law orders, that in cases of necessity, every one should be
  • taxed in proportion to his revenue; the amount of which he is obliged to
  • declare upon oath. They have no suspicion, it is said, that any of their
  • fellow citizens will deceive them. At Basil, the principal revenue of the
  • state arises from a small custom upon goods exported. All the citizens
  • make oath, that they will pay every three months all the taxes imposed by
  • law. All merchants, and even all inn-keepers, are trusted with keeping
  • themselves the account of the goods which they sell, either within or
  • without the territory. At the end of every three months, they send this
  • account to the treasurer, with the amount of the tax computed at the
  • bottom of it. It is not suspected that the revenue suffers by this
  • confidence. {Memoires concernant les Droits, tom. i p. 163, 167,171.}
  • To oblige every citizen to declare publicly upon oath, the amount of his
  • fortune, must not, it seems, in those Swiss cantons, be reckoned a
  • hardship. At Hamburg it would be reckoned the greatest. Merchants engaged
  • in the hazardous projects of trade, all tremble at the thoughts of being
  • obliged, at all times, to expose the real state of their circumstances.
  • The ruin of their credit, and the miscarriage of their projects, they
  • foresee, would too often be the consequence. A sober and parsimonious
  • people, who are strangers to all such projects, do not feel that they have
  • occasion for any such concealment.
  • In Holland, soon after the exaltation of the late prince of Orange to the
  • stadtholdership, a tax of two per cent. or the fiftieth penny, as it was
  • called, was imposed upon the whole substance of every citizen. Every
  • citizen assesed himself, and paid his tax, in the same manner as at
  • Hamburg, and it was in general supposed to have been paid with great
  • fidelity. The people had at that time the greatest affection for their new
  • government, which they had just established by a general insurrection. The
  • tax was to be paid but once, in order to relieve the state in a particular
  • exigency. It was, indeed, too heavy to be permanent. In a country where
  • the market rate of interest seldom exceeds three per cent., a tax of two
  • per cent. amounts to thirteen shillings and four pence in the pound, upon
  • the highest neat revenue which is commonly drawn from stock. It is a tax
  • which very few people could pay, without encroaching more or less upon
  • their capitals. In a particular exigency, the people may, from great
  • public zeal, make a great effort, and give up even a part of their
  • capital, in order to relieve the state. But it is impossible that they
  • should continue to do so for any considerable time; and if they did, the
  • tax would soon ruin them so completely, as to render them altogether
  • incapable of supporting the state.
  • The tax upon stock, imposed by the land tax bill in England, though it is
  • proportioned to the capital, is not intended to diminish or, take away any
  • part of that capital. It is meant only to be a tax upon the interest of
  • money, proportioned to that upon the rent of land; so that when the latter
  • is at four shillings in the pound, the former may be at four shillings in
  • the pound too. The tax at Hamburg, and the still more moderate taxes of
  • Underwald and Zurich, are meant, in the same manner, to be taxes, not upon
  • the capital, but upon the interest or neat revenue of stock. That of
  • Holland was meant to be a tax upon the capital.
  • Taxes upon the Profit of particular Employments.
  • In some countries, extraordinary taxes are imposed upon the profits of
  • stock; sometimes when employed in particular branches of trade, and
  • sometimes when employed in agriculture.
  • Of the former kind, are in England, the tax upon hawkers and pedlars, that
  • upon hackney-coaches and chairs, and that which the keepers of ale-houses
  • pay for a licence to retail ale and spiritous liquors. During the late
  • war, another tax of the same kind was proposed upon shops. The war having
  • been undertaken, it was said, in defence of the trade of the country, the
  • merchants, who were to profit by it, ought to contribute towards the
  • support of it.
  • A tax, however, upon the profits of stock employed in any particular
  • branch of trade, can never fall finally upon the dealers (who must in all
  • ordinary cases have their reasonable profit, and, where the competition is
  • free, can seldom have more than that profit), but always upon the
  • consumers, who must be obliged to pay in the price of the goods the tax
  • which the dealer advances; and generally with some overcharge.
  • A tax of this kind, when it is proportioned to the trade of the dealer, is
  • finally paid by the consumer, and occasions no oppression to the dealer.
  • When it is not so proportioned, but is the same upon all dealers, though
  • in this case, too, it is finally paid by the consumer, yet it favours the
  • great, and occasions some oppression to the small dealer. The tax of five
  • shillings a-week upon every hackney coach, and that of ten shillings
  • a-year upon every hackney chair, so far as it is advanced by the different
  • keepers of such coaches and chairs, is exactly enough proportioned to the
  • extent of their respective dealings. It neither favours the great, nor
  • oppresses the smaller dealer. The tax of twenty shillings a-year for a
  • licence to sell ale; of forty shillings for a licence to sell spiritous
  • liquors; and of forty shillings more for a licence to sell wine, being the
  • same upon all retailers, must necessarily give some advantage to the
  • great, and occasion some oppression to the small dealers. The former must
  • find it more easy to get back the tax in the price of their goods than the
  • latter. The moderation of the tax, however, renders this inequality of
  • less importance; and it may to many people appear not improper to give
  • some discouragement to the multiplication of little ale-houses. The tax
  • upon shops, it was intended, should be the same upon all shops. It could
  • not well have been otherwise. It would have been impossible to proportion,
  • with tolerable exactness, the tax upon a shop to the extent of the trade
  • carried on in it, without such an inquisition as would have been
  • altogether insupportable in a free country. If the tax had been
  • considerable, it would have oppressed the small, and forced almost the
  • whole retail trade into the hands of the great dealers. The competition of
  • the former being taken away, the latter would have enjoyed a monopoly of
  • the trade; and, like all other monopolists, would soon have combined to
  • raise their profits much beyond what was necessary for the payment of the
  • tax. The final payment, instead of falling upon the shop-keeper, would
  • have fallen upon the consumer, with a considerable overcharge to the
  • profit of the shop-keeper. For these reasons, the project of a tax upon
  • shops was laid aside, and in the room of it was substituted the subsidy,
  • 1759.
  • What in France is called the personal taille, is perhaps, the most
  • important tax upon the profits of stock employed in agriculture, that is
  • levied in any part of Europe.
  • In the disorderly state of Europe, during the prevalence of the feudal
  • government, the sovereign was obliged to content himself with taxing those
  • who were too weak to refuse to pay taxes. The great lords, though willing
  • to assist him upon particular emergencies, refused to subject themselves
  • to any constant tax, and he was not strong enough to force them. The
  • occupiers of land all over Europe were, the greater part of them,
  • originally bond-men. Through the greater part of Europe, they were
  • gradually emancipated. Some of them acquired the property of landed
  • estates, which they held by some base or ignoble tenure, sometimes under
  • the king, and sometimes under some other great lord, like the ancient
  • copy-holders of England. Others, without acquiring the property, obtained
  • leases for terms of years, of the lands which they occupied under their
  • lord, and thus became less dependent upon him. The great lords seem to
  • have beheld the degree of prosperity and independency, which this inferior
  • order of men had thus come to enjoy, with a malignant and contemptuous
  • indignation, and willingly consented that the sovereign should tax them.
  • In some countries, this tax was confined to the lands which were held in
  • property by an ignoble tenure; and, in this case, the taille was said to
  • be real. The land tax established by the late king of Sardinia, and the
  • taille in the provinces of Languedoc, Provence, Dauphine, and Britanny; in
  • the generality of Montauban, and in the elections of Agen and Condom, as
  • well as in some other districts of France; are taxes upon lands held in
  • property by an ignoble tenure. In other countries, the tax was laid upon
  • the supposed profits of all those who held, in farm or lease, lands
  • belonging to other people, whatever might be the tenure by which the
  • proprietor held them; and in this case, the taille was said to be
  • personal. In the greater part of those provinces of France, which are
  • called the countries of elections, the taille is of this kind. The real
  • taille, as it is imposed only upon a part of the lands of the country, is
  • necessarily an unequal, but it is not always an arbitrary tax, though it
  • is so upon some occasions. The personal taille, as it is intended to be
  • proportioned to the profits of a certain class of people, which can only
  • be guessed at, is necessarily both arbitrary and unequal.
  • In France, the personal taille at present (1775) annually imposed upon the
  • twenty generalities, called the countries of elections, amounts to
  • 40,107,239 livres, 16 sous. {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc tom. ii,
  • p.17.} the proportion in which this sum is assessed upon those different
  • provinces, varies from year to year, according to the reports which are
  • made to the king’s council concerning the goodness or badness of the
  • crops, as well as other circumstances, which may either increase or
  • diminish their respective abilities to pay. Each generality is divided
  • into a certain number of elections; and the proportion in which the sum
  • imposed upon the whole generality is divided among those different
  • elections, varies likewise from year to year, according to the reports
  • made to the council concerning their respective abilities. It seems
  • impossible, that the council, with the best intentions, can ever
  • proportion, with tolerable exactness, either of these two assessments to
  • the real abilities of the province or district upon which they are
  • respectively laid. Ignorance and misinformation must always, more or less,
  • mislead the most upright council. The proportion which each parish ought
  • to support of what is assessed upon the whole election, and that which
  • each individual ought to support of what is assessed upon his particular
  • parish, are both in the same manner varied from year to year, according as
  • circumstances are supposed to require. These circumstances are judged of,
  • in the one case, by the officers of the election, in the other, by those
  • of the parish; and both the one and the other are, more or less, under the
  • direction and influence of the intendant. Not only ignorance and
  • misinformation, but friendship, party animosity, and private resentment,
  • are said frequently to mislead such assessors. No man subject to such a
  • tax, it is evident, can ever be certain, before he is assessed, of what he
  • is to pay. He cannot even be certain after he is assessed. If any person
  • has been taxed who ought to have been exempted, or if any person has been
  • taxed beyond his proportion, though both must pay in the mean time, yet if
  • they complain, and make good their complaints, the whole parish is
  • reimposed next year, in order to reimburse them. If any of the
  • contributors become bankrupt or insolvent, the collector is obliged to
  • advance his tax; and the whole parish is reimposed next year, in order to
  • reimburse the collector. If the collector himself should become bankrupt,
  • the parish which elects him must answer for his conduct to the
  • receiver-general of the election. But, as it might be troublesome for the
  • receiver to prosecute the whole parish, he takes at his choice five or six
  • of the richest contributors, and obliges them to make good what had been
  • lost by the insolvency of the collector. The parish is afterwards
  • reimposed, in order to reimburse those five or six. Such reimpositions are
  • always over and above the taille of the particular year in which they are
  • laid on.
  • When a tax is imposed upon the profits of stock in a particular branch of
  • trade, the traders are all careful to bring no more goods to market than
  • what they can sell at a price sufficient to reimburse them from advancing
  • the tax. Some of them withdraw a part of their stocks from the trade, and
  • the market is more sparingly supplied than before. The price of the goods
  • rises, and the final payment of the tax falls upon the consumer. But when
  • a tax is imposed upon the profits of stock employed in agriculture, it is
  • not the interest of the farmers to withdraw any part of their stock from
  • that employment. Each farmer occupies a certain quantity of land, for
  • which he pays rent. For the proper cultivation of this land, a certain
  • quantity of stock is necessary; and by withdrawing any part of this
  • necessary quantity, the farmer is not likely to be more able to pay either
  • the rent or the tax. In order to pay the tax, it can never be his interest
  • to diminish the quantity of his produce, nor consequently to supply the
  • market more sparingly than before. The tax, therefore, will never enable
  • him to raise the price of his produce, so as to reimburse himself, by
  • throwing the final payment upon the consumer. The farmer, however, must
  • have his reasonable profit as well as every other dealer, otherwise he
  • must give up the trade. After the imposition of a tax of this kind, he can
  • get this reasonable profit only by paying less rent to the landlord. The
  • more he is obliged to pay in the way of tax, the less he can afford to pay
  • in the way of rent. A tax of this kind, imposed during the currency of a
  • lease, may, no doubt, distress or ruin the farmer. Upon the renewal of the
  • lease, it must always fall upon the landlord.
  • In the countries where the personal taille takes place, the farmer is
  • commonly assessed in proportion to the stock which he appears to employ in
  • cultivation. He is, upon this account, frequently afraid to have a good
  • team of horses or oxen, but endeavours to cultivate with the meanest and
  • most wretched instruments of husbandry that he can. Such is his distrust
  • in the justice of his assessors, that he counterfeits poverty, and wishes
  • to appear scarce able to pay anything, for fear of being obliged to pay
  • too much. By this miserable policy, he does not, perhaps, always consult
  • his own interest in the most effectual manner; and he probably loses more
  • by the diminution of his produce, than he saves by that of his tax.
  • Though, in consequence of this wretched cultivation, the market is, no
  • doubt, somewhat worse supplied; yet the small rise of price which this may
  • occasion, as it is not likely even to indemnify the farmer for the
  • diminution of his produce, it is still less likely to enable him to pay
  • more rent to the landlord. The public, the farmer, the landlord, all
  • suffer more or less by this degraded cultivation. That the personal taille
  • tends, in many different ways, to discourage cultivation, and consequently
  • to dry up the principal source of the wealth of every great country, I
  • have already had occasion to observe in the third book of this Inquiry.
  • What are called poll-taxes in the southern provinces of North America, and
  • the West India islands, annual taxes of so much a-head upon every negro,
  • are properly taxes upon the profits of a certain species of stock employed
  • in agriculture. As the planters, are the greater part of them, both
  • farmers and landlords, the final payment of the tax falls upon them in
  • their quality of landlords, without any retribution.
  • Taxes of so much a head upon the bondmen employed in cultivation, seem
  • anciently to have been common all over Europe. There subsists at present a
  • tax of this kind in the empire of Russia. It is probably upon this account
  • that poll-taxes of all kinds have often been represented as badges of
  • slavery. Every tax, however, is, to the person who pays it, a badge, not
  • of slavery, but of liberty. It denotes that he is subject to government,
  • indeed; but that, as he has some property, he cannot himself be the
  • property of a master. A poll tax upon slaves is altogether different from
  • a poll-tax upon freemen. The latter is paid by the persons upon whom it is
  • imposed; the former, by a different set of persons. The latter is either
  • altogether arbitrary, or altogether unequal, and, in most cases, is both
  • the one and the other; the former, though in some respects unequal,
  • different slaves being of different values, is in no respect arbitrary.
  • Every master, who knows the number of his own slaves, knows exactly what
  • he has to pay. Those different taxes, however, being called by the same
  • name, have been considered as of the same nature.
  • The taxes which in Holland are imposed upon men and maid servants, are
  • taxes, not upon stock, but upon expense; and so far resemble the taxes
  • upon consumable commodities. The tax of a guinea a-head for every
  • man-servant, which has lately been imposed in Great Britain, is of the
  • same kind. It falls heaviest upon the middling rank. A man of two hundred
  • a-year may keep a single man-servant. A man of ten thousand a-year will
  • not keep fifty. It does not affect the poor.
  • Taxes upon the profits of stock, in particular employments, can never
  • affect the interest of money. Nobody will lend his money for less interest
  • to those who exercise the taxed, than to those who exercise the untaxed
  • employments. Taxes upon the revenue arising from stock in all employments,
  • where the government attempts to levy them with any degree of exactness,
  • will, in many cases, fall upon the interest of money. The vingtieme, or
  • twentieth penny, in France, is a tax of the same kind with what is called
  • the land tax in England, and is assessed, in the same manner, upon the
  • revenue arising upon land, houses, and stock. So far as it affects stock,
  • it is assessed, though not with great rigour, yet with much more exactness
  • than that part of the land tax in England which is imposed upon the same
  • fund. It, in many cases, falls altogether upon the interest of money.
  • Money is frequently sunk in France, upon what are called contracts for the
  • constitution of a rent; that is, perpetual annuities, redeemable at any
  • time by the debtor, upon payment of the sum originally advanced, but of
  • which this redemption is not exigible by the creditor except in particular
  • cases. The vingtieme seems not to have raised the rate of those annuities,
  • though it is exactly levied upon them all.
  • APPENDIX TO ARTICLES I. AND II.—Taxes upon the Capital Value of
  • Lands, Houses, and Stock.
  • While property remains in the possession of the same person, whatever
  • permanent taxes may have been imposed upon it, they have never been
  • intended to diminish or take away any part of its capital value, but only
  • some part of the revenue arising from it. But when property changes hands,
  • when it is transmitted either from the dead to the living, or from the
  • living to the living, such taxes have frequently been imposed upon it as
  • necessarily take away some part of its capital value.
  • The transference of all sorts of property from the dead to the living, and
  • that of immoveable property of land and houses from the living to the
  • living, are transactions which are in their nature either public and
  • notorious, or such as cannot be long concealed. Such transactions,
  • therefore, may be taxed directly. The transference of stock or moveable
  • property, from the living to the living, by the lending of money, is
  • frequently a secret transaction, and may always be made so. It cannot
  • easily, therefore, be taxed directly. It has been taxed indirectly in two
  • different ways; first, by requiring that the deed, containing the
  • obligation to repay, should be written upon paper or parchment which had
  • paid a certain stamp duty, otherwise not to be valid; secondly, by
  • requiring, under the like penalty of invalidity, that it should be
  • recorded either in a public or secret register, and by imposing certain
  • duties upon such registration. Stamp duties, and duties of registration,
  • have frequently been imposed likewise upon the deeds transferring property
  • of all kinds from the dead to the living, and upon those transferring
  • immoveable property from the living to the living; transactions which
  • might easily have been taxed directly.
  • The vicesima hereditatum, or the twentieth penny of inheritances, imposed
  • by Augustus upon the ancient Romans, was a tax upon the transference of
  • property from the dead to the living. Dion Cassius, { Lib. 55. See also
  • Burman. de Vectigalibus Pop. Rom. cap. xi. and Bouchaud de l’impot du
  • vingtieme sur les successions.} the author who writes concerning it the
  • least indistinctly, says, that it was imposed upon all successions,
  • legacies and donations, in case of death, except upon those to the nearest
  • relations, and to the poor.
  • Of the same kind is the Dutch tax upon successions. {See Memoires
  • concernant les Droits, etc. tom i, p. 225.} Collateral successions are
  • taxed according to the degree of relation, from five to thirty per cent.
  • upon the whole value of the succession. Testamentary donations, or
  • legacies to collaterals, are subject to the like duties. Those from
  • husband to wife, or from wife to husband, to the fiftieth penny. The
  • luctuosa hereditas, the mournful succession of ascendants to descendants,
  • to the twentieth penny only. Direct successions, or those of descendants
  • to ascendants, pay no tax. The death of a father, to such of his children
  • as live in the same house with him, is seldom attended with any increase,
  • and frequently with a considerable diminution of revenue; by the loss of
  • his industry, of his office, or of some life-rent estate, of which he may
  • have been in possession. That tax would be cruel and oppressive, which
  • aggravated their loss, by taking from them any part of his succession. It
  • may, however, sometimes be otherwise with those children, who, in the
  • language of the Roman law, are said to be emancipated; in that of the
  • Scotch law, to be foris-familiated; that is, who have received their
  • portion, have got families of their own, and are supported by funds
  • separate and independent of those of their father. Whatever part of his
  • succession might come to such children, would be a real addition to their
  • fortune, and might, therefore, perhaps, without more inconveniency than
  • what attends all duties of this kind, be liable to some tax. The
  • casualties of the feudal law were taxes upon the transference of land,
  • both from the dead to the living, and from the living to the living. In
  • ancient times, they constituted, in every part of Europe, one of the
  • principal branches of the revenue of the crown.
  • The heir of every immediate vassal of the crown paid a certain duty,
  • generally a year’s rent, upon receiving the investiture of the estate. If
  • the heir was a minor, the whole rents of the estate, during the
  • continuance of the minority, devolved to the superior, without any other
  • charge besides the maintenance of the minor, and the payment of the
  • widow’s dower, when there happened to be a dowager upon the land. When the
  • minor came to de of age, another tax, called relief, was still due to the
  • superior, which generally amounted likewise to a year’s rent. A long
  • minority, which, in the present times, so frequently disburdens a great
  • estate of all its incumbrances, and restores the family to their ancient
  • splendour, could in those times have no such effect. The waste, and not
  • the disincumbrance of the estate, was the common effect of a long
  • minority.
  • By a feudal law, the vassal could not alienate without the consent of his
  • superior, who generally extorted a fine or composition on granting it.
  • This fine, which was at first arbitrary, came, in many countries, to be
  • regulated at a certain portion of the price of the land. In some
  • countries, where the greater part of the other feudal customs have gone
  • into disuse, this tax upon the alienation of land still continues to make
  • a very considerable branch of the revenue of the sovereign. In the canton
  • of Berne it is so high as a sixth part of the price of all noble fiefs,
  • and a tenth part of that of all ignoble ones. {Memoires concernant les
  • Droits, etc, tom.i p.154} In the canton of Lucern, the tax upon the sale
  • of land is not universal, and takes place only in certain districts. But
  • if any person sells his land in order to remove out of the territory, he
  • pays ten per cent. upon the whole price of the sale. {id. p.157.} Taxes of
  • the same kind, upon the sale either of all lands, or of lands held by
  • certain tenures, take place in many other countries, and make a more or
  • less considerable branch of the revenue of the sovereign.
  • Such transactions may be taxed indirectly, by means either of stamp
  • duties, or of duties upon registration; and those duties either may, or
  • may not, be proportioned to the value of the subject which is transferred.
  • In Great Britain, the stamp duties are higher or lower, not so much
  • according to the value of the property transferred (an eighteen-penny or
  • half-crown stamp being sufficient upon a bond for the largest sum of
  • money), as according to the nature of the deed. The highest do not exceed
  • six pounds upon every sheet of paper, or skin of parchment; and these high
  • duties fall chiefly upon grants from the crown, and upon certain law
  • proceedings, without any regard to the value of the subject. There are, in
  • Great Britain, no duties on the registration of deeds or writings, except
  • the fees of the officers who keep the register; and these are seldom more
  • than a reasonable recompence for their labour. The crown derives no
  • revenue from them.
  • In Holland {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. i. p 223, 224, 225.}
  • there are both stamp duties and duties upon registration; which in some
  • cases are, and in some are not, proportioned to the value of the property
  • transferred. All testaments must be written upon stamped paper, of which
  • the price is proportioned to the property disposed of; so that there are
  • stamps which cost from three pence or three stivers a-sheet, to three
  • hundred florins, equal to about twenty-seven pounds ten shillings of our
  • money. If the stamp is of an inferior price to what the testator ought to
  • have made use of, his succession is confiscated. This is over and above
  • all their other taxes on succession. Except bills of exchange, and some
  • other mercantile bills, all other deeds, bonds, and contracts, are subject
  • to a stamp duty. This duty, however, does not rise in proportion to the
  • value of the subject. All sales of land and of houses, and all mortgages
  • upon either, must be registered, and, upon registration, pay a duty to the
  • state of two and a-half per cent. upon the amount of the price or of the
  • mortgage. This duty is extended to the sale of all ships and vessels of
  • more than two tons burden, whether decked or undecked. These, it seems,
  • are considered as a sort of houses upon the water. The sale of moveables,
  • when it is ordered by a court of justice, is subject to the like duty of
  • two and a-half per cent.
  • In France, there are both stamp duties and duties upon registration. The
  • former are considered as a branch of the aids of excise, and, in the
  • provinces where those duties take place, are levied by the excise
  • officers. The latter are considered as a branch of the domain of the crown
  • and are levied by a different set of officers.
  • Those modes of taxation by stamp duties and by duties upon registration,
  • are of very modern invention. In the course of little more than a century,
  • however, stamp duties have, in Europe, become almost universal, and duties
  • upon registration extremely common. There is no art which one government
  • sooner learns of another, than that of draining money from the pockets of
  • the people.
  • Taxes upon the transference of property from the dead to the living, fall
  • finally, as well as immediately, upon the persons to whom the property is
  • transferred. Taxes upon the sale of land fall altogether upon the seller.
  • The seller is almost always under the necessity of selling, and must,
  • therefore, take such a price as he can get. The buyer is scarce ever under
  • the necessity of buying, and will, therefore, only give such a price as he
  • likes. He considers what the land will cost him, in tax and price
  • together. The more he is obliged to pay in the way of tax, the less he
  • will be disposed to give in the way of price. Such taxes, therefore, fall
  • almost always upon a necessitous person, and must, therefore, be
  • frequently very cruel and oppressive. Taxes upon the sale of new-built
  • houses, where the building is sold without the ground, fall generally upon
  • the buyer, because the builder must generally have his profit; otherwise
  • he must give up the trade. If he advances the tax, therefore, the buyer
  • must generally repay it to him. Taxes upon the sale of old houses, for the
  • same reason as those upon the sale of land, fall generally upon the
  • seller; whom, in most cases, either conveniency or necessity obliges to
  • sell. The number of new-built houses that are annually brought to market,
  • is more or less regulated by the demand. Unless the demand is such as to
  • afford the builder his profit, after paying all expenses, he will build no
  • more houses. The number of old houses which happen at any time to come to
  • market, is regulated by accidents, of which the greater part have no
  • relation to the demand. Two or three great bankruptcies in a mercantile
  • town, will bring many houses to sale, which must be sold for what can be
  • got for them. Taxes upon the sale of ground-rents fall altogether upon the
  • seller, for the same reason as those upon the sale of lands. Stamp duties,
  • and duties upon the registration of bonds and contracts for borrowed
  • money, fall altogether upon the borrower, and, in fact, are always paid by
  • him. Duties of the same kind upon law proceedings fall upon the suitors.
  • They reduce to both the capital value of the subject in dispute. The more
  • it costs to acquire any property, the less must be the neat value of it
  • when acquired.
  • All taxes upon the transference of property of every kind, so far as they
  • diminish the capital value of that property, tend to diminish the funds
  • destined for the maintenance of productive labour. They are all more or
  • less unthrifty taxes that increase the revenue of the sovereign, which
  • seldom maintains any but unproductive labourers, at the expense of the
  • capital of the people, which maintains none but productive.
  • Such taxes, even when they are proportioned to the value of the property
  • transferred, are still unequal; the frequency of transference not being
  • always equal in property of equal value. When they are not proportioned to
  • this value, which is the case with the greater part of the stamp duties
  • and duties of registration, they are still more so. They are in no respect
  • arbitrary, but are, or may be, in all cases, perfectly clear and certain.
  • Though they sometimes fall upon the person who is not very able to pay,
  • the time of payment is, in most cases, sufficiently convenient for him.
  • When the payment becomes due, he must, in most cases, have the more to
  • pay. They are levied at very little expense, and in general subject the
  • contributors to no other inconveniency, besides always the unavoidable one
  • of paying the tax. In France, the stamp duties are not much complained of.
  • Those of registration, which they call the Controle, are. They give
  • occasion, it is pretended, to much extortion in the officers of the
  • farmers-general who collect the tax, which is in a great measure arbitrary
  • and uncertain. In the greater part of the libels which have been written
  • against the present system of finances in France, the abuses of the
  • controle make a principal article. Uncertainty, however, does not seem to
  • be necessarily inherent in the nature of such taxes. If the popular
  • complaints are well founded, the abuse must arise, not so much from the
  • nature of the tax as from the want of precision and distinctness in the
  • words of the edicts or laws which impose it.
  • The registration of mortgages, and in general of all rights upon
  • immoveable property, as it gives great security both to creditors and
  • purchasers, is extremely advantageous to the public. That of the greater
  • part of deeds of other kinds, is frequently inconvenient and even
  • dangerous to individuals, without any advantage to the public. All
  • registers which, it is acknowledged, ought to be kept secret, ought
  • certainly never to exist. The credit of individuals ought certainly never
  • to depend upon so very slender a security, as the probity and religion of
  • the inferior officers of revenue. But where the fees of registration have
  • been made a source of revenue to the sovereign, register-offices have
  • commonly been multiplied without end, both for the deeds which ought to be
  • registered, and for those which ought not. In France there are several
  • different sorts of secret registers. This abuse, though not perhaps a
  • necessary, it must be acknowledged, is a very natural effect of such
  • taxes.
  • Such stamp duties as those in England upon cards and dice, upon newspapers
  • and periodical pamphlets, etc. are properly taxes upon consumption; the
  • final payment falls upon the persons who use or consume such commodities.
  • Such stamp duties as those upon licences to retail ale, wine, and
  • spiritous liquors, though intended, perhaps, to fall upon the profits of
  • the retailers, are likewise finally paid by the consumers of those
  • liquors. Such taxes, though called by the same name, and levied by the
  • same officers, and in the same manner with the stamp duties above
  • mentioned upon the transference of property, are, however, of a quite
  • different nature, and fall upon quite different funds.
  • ARTICLE III.—Taxes upon the Wages of Labour.
  • The wages of the inferior classes of work men, I have endeavoured to show
  • in the first book are everywhere necessarily regulated by two different
  • circumstances; the demand for labour, and the ordinary or average price of
  • provisions. The demand for labour, according as it happens to be either
  • increasing stationary or declining; or to require an increasing,
  • stationary, or declining population, regulates the subsistence of the
  • labourer, and determines in what degree it shall be either liberal,
  • moderate, or scanty. The ordinary average price of provisions determines
  • the quantity of money which must be paid to the workman, in order to
  • enable him, one year with another, to purchase this liberal, moderate, or
  • scanty subsistence. While the demand for the labour and the price of
  • provisions, therefore, remain the same, a direct tax upon the wages of
  • labour can have no other effect, than to raise them somewhat higher than
  • the tax. Let us suppose, for example, that, in a particular place, the
  • demand for labour and the price of provisions were such as to render ten
  • shillings a-week the ordinary wages of labour; and that a tax of
  • one-fifth, or four shillings in the pound, was imposed upon wages. If the
  • demand for labour and the price of provisions remained the same, it would
  • still be necessary that the labourer should, in that place, earn such a
  • subsistence as could be bought only for ten shillings a-week; so that,
  • after paying the tax, he should have ten shillings a-week free wages. But,
  • in order to leave him such free wages, after paying such a tax, the price
  • of labour must, in that place, soon rise, not to twelve shillings a week
  • only, but to twelve and sixpence; that is, in order to enable him to pay a
  • tax of one-fifth, his wages must necessarily soon rise, not one-fifth part
  • only, but one-fourth. Whatever was the proportion of the tax, the wages of
  • labour must, in all cases rise, not only in that proportion, but in a
  • higher proportion. If the tax for example, was one-tenth, the wages of
  • labour must necessarily soon rise, not one-tenth part only, but
  • one-eighth.
  • A direct tax upon the wages of labour, therefore, though the labourer
  • might, perhaps, pay it out of his hand, could not properly be said to be
  • even advanced by him; at least if the demand for labour and the average
  • price of provisions remained the same after the tax as before it. In all
  • such cases, not only the tax, but something more than the tax, would in
  • reality be advanced by the person who immediately employed him. The final
  • payment would, in different cases, fall upon different persons. The rise
  • which such a tax might occasion in the wages of manufacturing labour would
  • be advanced by the master manufacturer, who would both be entitled and
  • obliged to charge it, with a profit, upon the price of his goods. The
  • final payment of this rise of wages, therefore, together with the
  • additional profit of the master manufacturer would fall upon the consumer.
  • The rise which such a tax might occasion in the wages of country labour
  • would be advanced by the farmer, who, in order to maintain the same number
  • of labourers as before, would be obliged to employ a greater capital. In
  • order to get back this greater capital, together with the ordinary profits
  • of stock, it would be necessary that he should retain a larger portion,
  • or, what comes to the same thing, the price of a larger portion, of the
  • produce of the land, and, consequently, that he should pay less rent to
  • the landlord. The final payment of this rise of wages, therefore, would,
  • in this case, fall upon the landlord, together with the additional profit
  • of the farmer who had advanced it. In all cases, a direct tax upon the
  • wages of labour must, in the long-run, occasion both a greater reduction
  • in the rent of land, and a greater rise in the price of manufactured goods
  • than would have followed from the proper assessment of a sum equal to the
  • produce of the tax, partly upon the rent of land, and partly upon
  • consumable commodities.
  • If direct taxes upon the wages of labour have not always occasioned a
  • proportionable rise in those wages, it is because they have generally
  • occasioned a considerable fall in the demand of labour. The declension of
  • industry, the decrease of employment for the poor, the diminution of the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of the country, have generally been
  • the effects of such taxes. In consequence of them, however, the price of
  • labour must always be higher than it otherwise would have been in the
  • actual state of the demand; and this enhancement of price, together with
  • the profit of those who advance it, must always be finally paid by the
  • landlords and consumers.
  • A tax upon the wages of country labour does not raise the price of the
  • rude produce of land in proportion to the tax; for the same reason that a
  • tax upon the farmer’s profit does not raise that price in that proportion.
  • Absurd and destructive as such taxes are, however, they take place in many
  • countries. In France, that part of the taille which is charged upon the
  • industry of workmen and day-labourers in country villages, is properly a
  • tax of this kind. Their wages are computed according to the common rate of
  • the district in which they reside; and, that they may be as little liable
  • as possible to any overcharge, their yearly gains are estimated at no more
  • than two hundred working days in the year. {Memoires concernant les
  • Droits, etc. tom. ii. p. 108.} The tax of each individual is varied from
  • year to year, according to different circumstances, of which the collector
  • or the commissary, whom intendant appoints to assist him, are the judges.
  • In Bohemia, in consequence of the alteration in the system of finances
  • which was begun in 1748, a very heavy tax is imposed upon the industry of
  • artificers. They are divided into four classes. The highest class pay a
  • hundred florins a year, which, at two-and-twenty pence half penny
  • a-florin, amounts to £9:7:6. The second class are taxed at seventy; the
  • third at fifty; and the fourth, comprehending artificers in villages, and
  • the lowest class of those in towns, at twenty-five florins. {Memoires
  • concemant les Droits, etc. tom. iii. p. 87.}
  • The recompence of ingenious artists, and of men of liberal professions, I
  • have endeavoured to show in the first book, necessarily keeps a certain
  • proportion to the emoluments of inferior trades. A tax upon this
  • recompence, therefore, could have no other effect than to raise it
  • somewhat higher than in proportion to the tax. If it did not rise in this
  • manner, the ingenious arts and the liberal professions, being; no longer
  • upon a level with other trades, would be so much deserted, that they would
  • soon return to that level.
  • The emoluments of offices are not, like those of trades and professions,
  • regulated by the free competition of the market, and do not, therefore,
  • always bear a just proportion to what the nature of the employment
  • requires. They are, perhaps, in most countries, higher than it requires;
  • the persons who have the administration of government being generally
  • disposed to regard both themselves and their immediate dependents, rather
  • more than enough. The emoluments of offices, therefore, can, in most
  • cases, very well bear to be taxed. The persons, besides, who enjoy public
  • offices, especially the more lucrative, are, in all countries, the objects
  • of general envy; and a tax upon their emoluments, even though it should be
  • somewhat higher than upon any other sort of revenue, is always a very
  • popular tax. In England, for example, when, by the land-tax, every other
  • sort of revenue was supposed to be assessed at four shillings in the
  • pound, it was very popular to lay a real tax of five shillings and
  • sixpence in the pound upon the salaries of offices which exceeded a
  • hundred pounds a-year; the pensions of the younger branches of the royal
  • family, the pay of the officers of the army and navy, and a few others
  • less obnoxious to envy, excepted. There are in England no other direct
  • taxes upon the wages of labour.
  • ARTICLE IV.—Taxes which it is intended should fall indifferently
  • upon every different Species of Revenue.
  • The taxes which it is intended should fall indifferently upon every
  • different species of revenue, are capitation taxes, and taxes upon
  • consumable commodities. Those must be paid indifferently, from whatever
  • revenue the contributors may possess; from the rent of their land, from
  • the profits of their stock, or from the wages of their labour.
  • Capitation Taxes.
  • Capitation taxes, if it is attempted to proportion them to the fortune or
  • revenue of each contributor, become altogether arbitrary. The state of a
  • man’s fortune varies from day to day; and, without an inquisition, more
  • intolerable than any tax, and renewed at least once every year, can only
  • be guessed at. His assessment, therefore, must, in most cases, depend upon
  • the good or bad humour of his assessors, and must, therefore, be
  • altogether arbitrary and uncertain.
  • Capitation taxes, if they are proportioned, not to the supposed fortune,
  • but to the rank of each contributor, become altogether unequal; the
  • degrees of fortune being frequently unequal in the same degree of rank.
  • Such taxes, therefore, if it is attempted to render them equal, become
  • altogether arbitrary and uncertain; and if it is attempted to render them
  • certain and not arbitrary, become altogether unequal. Let the tax be light
  • or heavy, uncertainty is always a great grievance. In a light tax, a
  • considerable degree of inequality may be supported; in a heavy one, it is
  • altogether intolerable.
  • In the different poll-taxes which took place in England during the reign
  • of William III. the contributors were, the greater part of them, assessed
  • according to the degree of their rank; as dukes, marquises, earls,
  • viscounts, barons, esquires, gentlemen, the eldest and youngest sons of
  • peers, etc. All shop-keepers and tradesmen worth more than three hundred
  • pounds, that is, the better sort of them, were subject to the same
  • assessment, how great soever might be the difference in their fortunes.
  • Their rank was more considered than their fortune. Several of those who,
  • in the first poll-tax, were rated according to their supposed fortune were
  • afterwards rated according to their rank. Serjeants, attorneys, and
  • proctors at law, who, in the first poll-tax, were assessed at three
  • shillings in the pound of their supposed income, were afterwards assessed
  • as gentlemen. In the assessment of a tax which was not very heavy, a
  • considerable degree of inequality had been found less insupportable than
  • any degree of uncertainty.
  • In the capitation which has been levied in France, without-any
  • interruption, since the beginning of the present century, the highest
  • orders of people are rated according to their rank, by an invariable
  • tariff; the lower orders of people, according to what is supposed to be
  • their fortune, by an assessment which varies from year to year. The
  • officers of the king’s court, the judges, and other officers in the
  • superior courts of justice, the officers of the troops, etc are assessed
  • in the first manner. The inferior ranks of people in the provinces are
  • assessed in the second. In France, the great easily submit to a
  • considerable degree of inequality in a tax which, so far as it affects
  • them, is not a very heavy one; but could not brook the arbitrary
  • assessment of an intendant.
  • The inferior ranks of people must, in that country, suffer patiently the
  • usage which their superiors think proper to give them.
  • In England, the different poll-taxes never produced the sum which had been
  • expected from them, or which it was supposed they might have produced, had
  • they been exactly levied. In France, the capitation always produces the
  • sum expected from it. The mild government of England, when it assessed the
  • different ranks of people to the poll-tax, contented itself with what that
  • assessment happened to produce, and required no compensation for the loss
  • which the state might sustain, either by those who could not pay, or by
  • those who would not pay (for there were many such), and who, by the
  • indulgent execution of the law, were not forced to pay. The more severe
  • government of France assesses upon each generality a certain sum, which
  • the intendant must find as he can. If any province complains of being
  • assessed too high, it may, in the assessment of next year, obtain an
  • abatement proportioned to the overcharge of the year before; but it must
  • pay in the mean time. The intendant, in order to be sure of finding the
  • sum assessed upon his generality, was empowered to assess it in a larger
  • sum, that the failure or inability of some of the contributors might be
  • compensated by the overcharge of the rest; and till 1765, the fixation of
  • this surplus assessment was left altogether to his discretion. In that
  • year, indeed, the council assumed this power to itself. In the capitation
  • of the provinces, it is observed by the perfectly well informed author of
  • the Memoirs upon the Impositions in France, the proportion which falls
  • upon the nobility, and upon those whose privileges exempt them from the
  • taille, is the least considerable. The largest falls upon those subject to
  • the taille, who are assessed to the capitation at so much a-pound of what
  • they pay to that other tax. Capitation taxes, so far as they are levied
  • upon the lower ranks of people, are direct taxes upon the wages of labour,
  • and are attended with all the inconveniencies of such taxes.
  • Capitation taxes are levied at little expense; and, where they are
  • rigorously exacted, afford a very sure revenue to the state. It is upon
  • this account that, in countries where the case, comfort, and security of
  • the inferior ranks of people are little attended to, capitation taxes are
  • very common. It is in general, however, but a small part of the public
  • revenue, which, in a great empire, has ever been drawn from such taxes;
  • and the greatest sum which they have ever afforded, might always have been
  • found in some other way much more convenient to the people.
  • Taxes upon Consumable Commodities.
  • The impossibility of taxing the people, in proportion to their revenue, by
  • any capitation, seems to have given occasion to the invention of taxes
  • upon consumable commodities. The state not knowing how to tax, directly
  • and proportionably, the revenue of its subjects, endeavours to tax it
  • indirectly by taxing their expense, which, it is supposed, will, in most
  • cases, be nearly in proportion to their revenue. Their expense is taxed,
  • by taxing the consumable commodities upon which it is laid out.
  • Consumable commodities are either necessaries or luxuries.
  • By necessaries I understand, not only the commodities which are
  • indispensibly necessary for the support of life, but whatever the custom
  • of the country renders it indecent for creditable people, even of the
  • lowest order, to be without. A linen shirt, for example, is, strictly
  • speaking, not a necessary of life. The Greeks and Romans lived, I suppose,
  • very comfortably, though they had no linen. But in the present times,
  • through the greater part of Europe, a creditable day-labourer would be
  • ashamed to appear in public without a linen shirt, the want of which would
  • be supposed to denote that disgraceful degree of poverty, which, it is
  • presumed, nobody can well fall into without extreme bad conduct. Custom,
  • in the same manner, has rendered leather shoes a necessary of life in
  • England. The poorest creditable person, of either sex, would be ashamed to
  • appear in public without them. In Scotland, custom has rendered them a
  • necessary of life to the lowest order of men; but not to the same order of
  • women, who may, without any discredit, walk about barefooted. In France,
  • they are necessaries neither to men nor to women; the lowest rank of both
  • sexes appearing there publicly, without any discredit, sometimes in wooden
  • shoes, and sometimes barefooted. Under necessaries, therefore, I
  • comprehend, not only those things which nature, but those things which the
  • established rules of decency have rendered necessary to the lowest rank of
  • people. All other things I call luxuries, without meaning, by this
  • appellation, to throw the smallest degree of reproach upon the temperate
  • use of them. Beer and ale, for example, in Great Britain, and wine, even
  • in the wine countries, I call luxuries. A man of any rank may, without any
  • reproach, abstain totally from tasting such liquors. Nature does not
  • render them necessary for the support of life; and custom nowhere renders
  • it indecent to live without them.
  • As the wages of labour are everywhere regulated, partly by the demand for
  • it, and partly by the average price of the necessary articles of
  • subsistence; whatever raises this average price must necessarily raise
  • those wages; so that the labourer may still be able to purchase that
  • quantity of those necessary articles which the state of the demand for
  • labour, whether increasing, stationary, or declining, requires that he
  • should have. {See book i.chap. 8} A tax upon those articles necessarily
  • raises their price somewhat higher than the amount of the tax, because the
  • dealer, who advances the tax, must generally get it back, with a profit.
  • Such a tax must, therefore, occasion a rise in the wages of labour,
  • proportionable to this rise of price.
  • It is thus that a tax upon the necessaries of life operates exactly in the
  • same manner as a direct tax upon the wages of labour. The labourer, though
  • he may pay it out of his hand, cannot, for any considerable time at least,
  • be properly said even to advance it. It must always, in the long-run, be
  • advanced to him by his immediate employer, in the advanced state of wages.
  • His employer, if he is a manufacturer, will charge upon the price of his
  • goods the rise of wages, together with a profit, so that the final payment
  • of the tax, together with this overcharge, will fall upon the consumer. If
  • his employer is a farmer, the final payment, together with a like
  • overcharge, will fall upon the rent of the landlord.
  • It is otherwise with taxes upon what I call luxuries, even upon those of
  • the poor. The rise in the price of the taxed commodities, will not
  • necessarily occasion any rise in the wages of labour. A tax upon tobacco,
  • for example, though a luxury of the poor, as well as of the rich, will not
  • raise wages. Though it is taxed in England at three times, and in France
  • at fifteen times its original price, those high duties seem to have no
  • effect upon the wages of labour. The same thing maybe said of the taxes
  • upon tea and sugar, which, in England and Holland, have become luxuries of
  • the lowest ranks of people; and of those upon chocolate, which, in Spain,
  • is said to have become so.
  • The different taxes which, in Great Britain, have, in the course of the
  • present century, been imposed upon spiritous liquors, are not supposed to
  • have had any effect upon the wages of labour. The rise in the price of
  • porter, occasioned by an additional tax of three shillings upon the barrel
  • of strong beer, has not raised the wages of common labour in London. These
  • were about eighteen pence or twenty pence a-day before the tax, and they
  • are not more now.
  • The high price of such commodities does not necessarily diminish the
  • ability of the inferior ranks of people to bring up families. Upon the
  • sober and industrious poor, taxes upon such commodities act as sumptuary
  • laws, and dispose them either to moderate, or to refrain altogether from
  • the use of superfluities which they can no longer easily afford. Their
  • ability to bring up families, in consequence of this forced frugality,
  • instead of being diminished, is frequently, perhaps, increased by the tax.
  • It is the sober and industrious poor who generally bring up the most
  • numerous families, and who principally supply the demand for useful
  • labour. All the poor, indeed, are not sober and industrious; and the
  • dissolute and disorderly might continue to indulge themselves in the use
  • of such commodities, after this rise of price, in the same manner as
  • before, without regarding the distress which this indulgence might bring
  • upon their families. Such disorderly persons, however, seldom rear up
  • numerous families, their children generally perishing from neglect,
  • mismanagement, and the scantiness or unwholesomeness of their food. If by
  • the strength of their constitution, they survive the hardships to which
  • the bad conduct of their parents exposes them, yet the example of that bad
  • conduct commonly corrupts their morals; so that, instead of being useful
  • to society by their industry, they become public nuisances by their vices
  • and disorders. Through the advanced price of the luxuries of the poor,
  • therefore, might increase somewhat the distress of such disorderly
  • families, and thereby diminish somewhat their ability to bring up
  • children, it would not probably diminish much the useful population of the
  • country.
  • Any rise in the average price of necessaries, unless it be compensated by
  • a proportionable rise in the wages of labour, must necessarily diminish,
  • more or less, the ability of the poor to bring up numerous families, and,
  • consequently, to supply the demand for useful labour; whatever may be the
  • state of that demand, whether increasing, stationary, or declining; or
  • such as requires an increasing, stationary, or declining population.
  • Taxes upon luxuries have no tendency to raise the price of any other
  • commodities, except that of the commodities taxed. Taxes upon necessaries,
  • by raising the wages of labour, necessarily tend to raise the price of all
  • manufactures, and consequently to diminish the extent of their sale and
  • consumption. Taxes upon luxuries are finally paid by the consumers of the
  • commodities taxed, without any retribution. They fall indifferently upon
  • every species of revenue, the wages of labour, the profits of stock, and
  • the rent of land. Taxes upon necessaries, so far as they affect the
  • labouring poor, are finally paid, partly by landlords, in the diminished
  • rent of their lands, and partly by rich consumers, whether landlords or
  • others, in the advanced price of manufactured goods; and always with a
  • considerable overcharge. The advanced price of such manufactures as are
  • real necessaries of life, and are destined for the consumption of the
  • poor, of coarse woollens, for example, must be compensated to the poor by
  • a farther advancement of their wages. The middling and superior ranks of
  • people, if they understood their own interest, ought always to oppose all
  • taxes upon the necessaries of life, as well as all taxes upon the wages of
  • labour. The final payment of both the one and the other falls altogether
  • upon themselves, and always with a considerable overcharge. They fall
  • heaviest upon the landlords, who always pay in a double capacity; in that
  • of landlords, by the reduction, of their rent; and in that of rich
  • consumers, by the increase of their expense. The observation of Sir
  • Matthew Decker, that certain taxes are, in the price of certain goods,
  • sometimes repeated and accumulated four or five times, is perfectly just
  • with regard to taxes upon the necessaries of life. In the price of
  • leather, for example, you must pay not only for the tax upon the leather
  • of your own shoes, but for a part of that upon those of the shoemaker and
  • the tanner. You must pay, too, for the tax upon the salt, upon the soap,
  • and upon the candles which those workmen consume while employed in your
  • service; and for the tax upon the leather, which the saltmaker, the
  • soap-maker, and the candle-maker consume, while employed in their service.
  • In Great Britain, the principal taxes upon the necessaries of life, are
  • those upon the four commodities just now mentioned, salt, leather, soap,
  • and candles.
  • Salt is a very ancient and a very universal subject of taxation. It was
  • taxed among the Romans, and it is so at present in, I believe, every part
  • of Europe. The quantity annually consumed by any individual is so small,
  • and may be purchased so gradually, that nobody, it seems to have been
  • thought, could feel very sensibly even a pretty heavy tax upon it. It is
  • in England taxed at three shillings and fourpence a bushel; about three
  • times the original price of the commodity. In some other countries, the
  • tax is still higher. Leather is a real necessary of life. The use of linen
  • renders soap such. In countries where the winter nights are long, candles
  • are a necessary instrument of trade. Leather and soap are in Great Britain
  • taxed at three halfpence a-pound; candles at a penny; taxes which, upon
  • the original price of leather, may amount to about eight or ten per cent.;
  • upon that of soap, to about twenty or five-and-twenty per cent.; and upon
  • that of candles to about fourteen or fifteen per cent.; taxes which,
  • though lighter than that upon salt, are still very heavy. As all those
  • four commodities are real necessaries of life, such heavy taxes upon them
  • must increase somewhat the expense of the sober and industrious poor, and
  • must consequently raise more or less the wages of their labour.
  • In a country where the winters are so cold as in Great Britain, fuel is,
  • during that season, in the strictest sense of the word, a necessary of
  • life, not only for the purpose of dressing victuals, but for the
  • comfortable subsistence of many different sorts of workmen who work within
  • doors; and coals are the cheapest of all fuel. The price of fuel has so
  • important an influence upon that of labour, that all over Great Britain,
  • manufactures have confined themselves principally to the coal counties;
  • other parts of the country, on account of the high price of this necessary
  • article, not being able to work so cheap. In some manufactures, besides,
  • coal is a necessary instrument of trade; as in those of glass, iron, and
  • all other metals. If a bounty could in any case be reasonable, it might
  • perhaps be so upon the transportation of coals from those parts of the
  • country in which they abound, to those in which they are wanted. But the
  • legislature, instead of a bounty, has imposed a tax of three shillings and
  • threepence a-ton upon coals carried coastways; which, upon most sorts of
  • coal, is more than sixty per cent. of the original price at the coal pit.
  • Coals carried, either by land or by inland navigation, pay no duty. Where
  • they are naturally cheap, they are consumed duty free; where they are
  • naturally dear, they are loaded with a heavy duty.
  • Such taxes, though they raise the price of subsistence, and consequently
  • the wages of labour, yet they afford a considerable revenue to government,
  • which it might not be easy to find in any other way. There may, therefore,
  • be good reasons for continuing them. The bounty upon the exportation of
  • corn, so far us it tends, in the actual state of tillage, to raise the
  • price of that necessary article, produces all the like bad effects; and
  • instead of affording any revenue, frequently occasions a very great
  • expense to government. The high duties upon the importation of foreign
  • corn, which, in years of moderate plenty, amount to a prohibition; and the
  • absolute prohibition of the importation, either of live cattle, or of salt
  • provisions, which takes place in the ordinary state of the law, and which,
  • on account of the scarcity, is at present suspended for a limited time
  • with regard to Ireland and the British plantations, have all had the bad
  • effects of taxes upon the necessaries of life, and produce no revenue to
  • government. Nothing seems necessary for the repeal of such regulations,
  • but to convince the public of the futility of that system in consequence
  • of which they have been established.
  • Taxes upon the necessaries of life are much higher in many other countries
  • than in Great Britain. Duties upon flour and meal when ground at the mill,
  • and upon bread when baked at the oven, take place in many countries. In
  • Holland the money-price of the: bread consumed in towns is supposed to be
  • doubled by means of such taxes. In lieu of a part of them, the people who
  • live in the country, pay every year so much a-head, according to the sort
  • of bread they are supposed to consume. Those who consume wheaten bread pay
  • three guilders fifteen stivers; about six shillings and ninepence
  • halfpenny. Those, and some other taxes of the same kind, by raising the
  • price of labour, are said to have ruined the greater part of the
  • manufactures of Holland {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. p. 210,
  • 211.}. Similar taxes, though not quite so heavy, take place in the
  • Milanese, in the states of Genoa, in the duchy of Modena, in the duchies
  • of Parma, Placentia, and Guastalla, and the Ecclesiastical state. A French
  • author {Le Reformateur} of some note, has proposed to reform the finances
  • of his country, by substituting in the room of the greater part of other
  • taxes, this most ruinous of all taxes. There is nothing so absurd, says
  • Cicero, which has not sometimes been asserted by some philosophers.
  • Taxes upon butcher’s meat are still more common than those upon bread. It
  • may indeed be doubted, whether butcher’s meat is any where a necessary of
  • life. Grain and other vegetables, with the help of milk, cheese, and
  • butter, or oil, where butter is not to be had, it is known from
  • experience, can, without any butcher’s meat, afford the most plentiful,
  • the most wholesome, the most nourishing, and the most invigorating diet.
  • Decency nowhere requires that any man should eat butcher’s meat, as it in
  • most places requires that he should wear a linen shirt or a pair of
  • leather shoes.
  • Consumable commodities, whether necessaries or luxuries, may be taxed in
  • two different ways. The consumer may either pay an annual sum on account
  • of his using or consuming goods of a certain kind; or the goods may be
  • taxed while they remain in the hands of the dealer, and before they are
  • delivered to the consumer. The consumable goods which last a considerable
  • time before they are consumed altogether, are most properly taxed in the
  • one way; those of which the consumption is either immediate or more
  • speedy, in the other. The coach-tax and plate tax are examples of the
  • former method of imposing; the greater part of the other duties of excise
  • and customs, of the latter.
  • A coach may, with good management, last ten or twelve years. It might be
  • taxed, once for all, before it comes out of the hands of the coach-maker.
  • But it is certainly more convenient for the buyer to pay four pounds
  • a-year for the privilege of keeping a coach, than to pay all at once forty
  • or forty-eight pounds additional price to the coach-maker; or a sum
  • equivalent to what the tax is likely to cost him during the time he uses
  • the same coach. A service of plate in the same manner, may last more than
  • a century. It is certainly-easier for the consumer to pay five shillings
  • a-year for every hundred ounces of plate, near one per cent. of the value,
  • than to redeem this long annuity at five-and-twenty or thirty years
  • purchase, which would enhance the price at least five-and-twenty or thirty
  • per cent. The different taxes which affect houses, are certainly more
  • conveniently paid by moderate annual payments, than by a heavy tax of
  • equal value upon the first building or sale of the house.
  • It was the well-known proposal of Sir Matthew Decker, that all
  • commodities, even those of which the consumption is either immediate or
  • speedy, should be taxed in this manner; the dealer advancing nothing, but
  • the consumer paying a certain annual sum for the licence to consume
  • certain goods. The object of his scheme was to promote all the different
  • branches of foreign trade, particularly the carrying trade, by taking away
  • all duties upon importation and exportation, and thereby enabling the
  • merchant to employ his whole capital and credit in the purchase of goods
  • and the freight of ships, no part of either being diverted towards the
  • advancing of taxes, The project, however, of taxing, in this manner, goods
  • of immediate or speedy consumption, seems liable to the four following
  • very important objections. First, the tax would be more unequal, or not so
  • well proportioned to the expense and consumption of the different
  • contributors, as in the way in which it is commonly imposed. The taxes
  • upon ale, wine, and spiritous liquors, which are advanced by the dealers,
  • are finally paid by the different consumers, exactly in proportion to
  • their respective consumption. But if the tax were to be paid by purchasing
  • a licence to drink those liquors, the sober would, in proportion to his
  • consumption, be taxed much more heavily than the drunken consumer. A
  • family which exercised great hospitality, would be taxed much more lightly
  • than one who entertained fewer guests. Secondly, this mode of taxation, by
  • paying for an annual, half-yearly, or quarterly licence to consume certain
  • goods, would diminish very much one of the principal conveniences of taxes
  • upon goods of speedy consumption; the piece-meal payment. In the price of
  • threepence halfpenny, which is at present paid for a pot of porter, the
  • different taxes upon malt, hops, and beer, together with the extraordinary
  • profit which the brewer charges for having advanced than, may perhaps
  • amount to about three halfpence. If a workman can conveniently spare those
  • three halfpence, he buys a pot of porter. If he cannot, he contents
  • himself with a pint; and, as a penny saved is a penny got, he thus gains a
  • farthing by his temperance. He pays the tax piece-meal, as he can afford
  • to pay it, and when he can afford to pay it, and every act of payment is
  • perfectly voluntary, and what he can avoid if he chuses to do so. Thirdly,
  • such taxes would operate less as sumptuary laws. When the licence was once
  • purchased, whether the purchaser drunk much or drunk little, his tax would
  • be the same. Fourthly, if a workman were to pay all at once, by yearly,
  • half-yearly, or quarterly payments, a tax equal to what he at present
  • pays, with little or no inconveniency, upon all the different pots and
  • pints of porter which he drinks in any such period of time, the sum might
  • frequently distress him very much. This mode of taxation, therefore, it
  • seems evident, could never, without the most grievous oppression, produce
  • a revenue nearly equal to what is derived from the present mode without
  • any oppression. In several countries, however, commodities of an immediate
  • or very speedy consumption are taxed in this manner. In Holland, people
  • pay so much a-head for a licence to drink tea. I have already mentioned a
  • tax upon bread, which, so far as it is consumed in farm houses and country
  • villages, is there levied in the same manner.
  • The duties of excise are imposed chiefly upon goods of home produce,
  • destined for home consumption. They are imposed only upon a few sorts of
  • goods of the most general use. There can never be any doubt, either
  • concerning the goods which are subject to those duties, or concerning the
  • particular duty which each species of goods is subject to. They fall
  • almost altogether upon what I call luxuries, excepting always the four
  • duties above mentioned, upon salt, soap, leather, candles, and perhaps
  • that upon green glass.
  • The duties of customs are much more ancient than those of excise. They
  • seem to have been called customs, as denoting customary payments, which
  • had been in use for time immemorial. They appear to have been originally
  • considered as taxes upon the profits of merchants. During the barbarous
  • times of feudal anarchy, merchants, like all the other inhabitants of
  • burghs, were considered as little better than emancipated bondmen, whose
  • persons were despised, and whose gains were envied. The great nobility,
  • who had consented that the king should tallage the profits of their own
  • tenants, were not unwilling that he should tallage likewise those of an
  • order of men whom it was much less their interest to protect. In those
  • ignorant times, it was not understood, that the profits of merchants are a
  • subject not taxable directly; or that the final payment of all such taxes
  • must fall, with a considerable overcharge, upon the consumers.
  • The gains of alien merchants were looked upon more unfavourably than those
  • of English merchants. It was natural, therefore, that those of the former
  • should be taxed more heavily than those of the latter. This distinction
  • between the duties upon aliens and those upon English merchants, which was
  • begun from ignorance, has been continued front the spirit of monopoly, or
  • in order to give our own merchants an advantage, both in the home and in
  • the foreign market.
  • With this distinction, the ancient duties of customs were imposed equally
  • upon all sorts of goods, necessaries as well its luxuries, goods exported
  • as well as goods imported. Why should the dealers in one sort of goods, it
  • seems to have been thought, be more favoured than those in another? or why
  • should the merchant exporter be more favoured than the merchant importer?
  • The ancient customs were divided into three branches. The first, and,
  • perhaps, the most ancient of all those duties, was that upon wool and
  • leather. It seems to have been chiefly or altogether an exportation duty.
  • When the woollen manufacture came to be established in England, lest the
  • king should lose any part of his customs upon wool by the exportation of
  • woollen cloths, a like duty was imposed upon them. The other two branches
  • were, first, a duty upon wine, which being imposed at so much a-ton, was
  • called a tonnage; and, secondly, a duty upon all other goods, which being
  • imposed at so much a-pound of their supposed value, was called a poundage.
  • In the forty-seventh year of Edward III., a duty of sixpence in the pound
  • was imposed upon all goods exported and imported, except wools,
  • wool-felts, leather, and wines which were subject to particular duties. In
  • the fourteenth of Richard II., this duty was raised to one shilling in the
  • pound; but, three years afterwards, it was again reduced to sixpence. It
  • was raised to eightpence in the second year of Henry IV.; and, in the
  • fourth of the same prince, to one shilling. From this time to the ninth
  • year of William III., this duty continued at one shilling in the pound.
  • The duties of tonnage and poundage were generally granted to the king by
  • one and the same act of parliament, and were called the subsidy of tonnage
  • and poundage. The subsidy of poundage having continued for so long a time
  • at one shilling in the pound, or at five per cent., a subsidy came, in the
  • language of the customs, to denote a general duty of this kind of five per
  • cent. This subsidy, which is now called the old subsidy, still continues
  • to be levied, according to the book of rates established by the twelfth of
  • Charles II. The method of ascertaining, by a book of rates, the value of
  • goods subject to this duty, is said to be older than the time of James I.
  • The new subsidy, imposed by the ninth and tenth of William III., was an
  • additional five per cent. upon the greater part of goods. The one-third
  • and the two-third subsidy made up between them another five per cent. of
  • which they were proportionable parts. The subsidy of 1747 made a fourth
  • five per cent. upon the greater part of goods; and that of 1759, a fifth
  • upon some particular sorts of goods. Besides those five subsidies, a great
  • variety of other duties have occasionally been imposed upon particular
  • sorts of goods, in order sometimes to relieve the exigencies of the
  • state, and sometimes to regulate the trade of the country, according to
  • the principles of the mercantile system.
  • That system has come gradually more and more into fashion. The old subsidy
  • was imposed indifferently upon exportation, as well as importation. The
  • four subsequent subsidies, as well as the other duties which have since
  • been occasionally imposed upon particular sorts of goods, have, with a few
  • exceptions, been laid altogether upon importation. The greater part of the
  • ancient duties which had been imposed upon the exportation of the goods of
  • home produce and manufacture, have either been lightened or taken away
  • altogether. In most cases, they have been taken away. Bounties have even
  • been given upon the exportation of some of them. Drawbacks, too, sometimes
  • of the whole, and, in most cases, of a part of the duties which are paid
  • upon the importation of foreign goods, have been granted upon their
  • exportation. Only half the duties imposed by the old subsidy upon
  • importation, are drawn back upon exportation; but the whole of those
  • imposed by the latter subsidies and other imposts are, upon the greater
  • parts of the goods, drawn back in the same manner. This growing favour of
  • exportation, and discouragement of importation, have suffered only a few
  • exceptions, which chiefly concern the materials of some manufactures.
  • These our merchants and manufacturers are willing should come as cheap as
  • possible to themselves, and as dear as possible to their rivals and
  • competitors in other countries. Foreign materials are, upon this account,
  • sometimes allowed to be imported duty-free; spanish wool, for example,
  • flax, and raw linen yarn. The exportation of the materials of home
  • produce, and of those which are the particular produce of our colonies,
  • has sometimes been prohibited, and sometimes subjected to higher duties.
  • The exportation of English wool has been prohibited. That of beaver skins,
  • of beaver wool, and of gum-senega, has been subjected to higher duties;
  • Great Britain, by the conquests of Canada and Senegal, having got almost
  • the monopoly of those commodities.
  • That the mercantile system has not been very favourable to the revenue of
  • the great body of the people, to the annual produce of the land and labour
  • of the country, I have endeavoured to show in the fourth book of this
  • Inquiry. It seems not to have been more favourable to the revenue of the
  • sovereign; so far, at least, as that revenue depends upon the duties of
  • customs.
  • In consequence of that system, the importation of several sorts of goods
  • has been prohibited altogether. This prohibition has, in some cases,
  • entirely prevented, and in others has very much diminished, the
  • importation of those commodities, by reducing the importers to the
  • necessity of smuggling. It has entirely prevented the importation of
  • foreign wollens; and it has very much diminished that of foreign silks and
  • velvets, In both cases, it has entirely annihilated the revenue of customs
  • which might have been levied upon such importation.
  • The high duties which have been imposed upon the importation of many
  • different sorts of foreign goods in order to discourage their consumption
  • in Great Britain, have, in many cases, served only to encourage smuggling,
  • and, in all cases, have reduced the revenues of the customs below what
  • more moderate duties would have afforded. The saying of Dr. Swift, that in
  • the arithmetic of the customs, two and two, instead of making four, make
  • sometimes only one, holds perfectly true with regard to such heavy duties,
  • which never could have been imposed, had not the mercantile system taught
  • us, in many cases, to employ taxation as an instrument, not of revenue,
  • but of monopoly.
  • The bounties which are sometimes given upon the exportation of home
  • produce and manufactures, and the drawbacks which are paid upon the
  • re-exportation of the greater part of foreign goods, have given occasion
  • to many frauds, and to a species of smuggling, more destructive of the
  • public revenue than any other. In order to obtain the bounty or drawback,
  • the goods, it is well known, are sometimes shipped, and sent to sea, but
  • soon afterwards clandestinely re-landed in some other part of the country.
  • The defalcation of the revenue of customs occasioned by bounties and
  • drawbacks, of which a great part are obtained fraudulently, is very great.
  • The gross produce of the customs, in the year which ended on the 5th of
  • January 1755, amounted to £5,068,000. The bounties which were paid out of
  • this revenue, though in that year there was no bounty upon corn, amounted
  • to £167,806. The drawbacks which were paid upon debentures and
  • certificates, to £2,156,800. Bounties and drawbacks together amounted to
  • £2,324,600. In consequence of these deductions, the revenue of the customs
  • amounted only to £2,743,400; from which deducting £287,900 for the expense
  • of management, in salaries and other incidents, the neat revenue of the
  • customs for that year comes out to be £2,455,500. The expense of
  • management, amounts, in this manner, to between five and six per cent.
  • upon the gross revenue of the customs; and to something more than ten per
  • cent. upon what remains of that revenue, after deducting what is paid away
  • in bounties and drawbacks.
  • Heavy duties being imposed upon almost all goods imported, our merchant
  • importers smuggle as much, and make entry of as little as they can. Our
  • merchant exporters, on the contrary, make entry of more than they export;
  • sometimes out of vanity, and to pass for great dealers in goods which pay
  • no duty gain a bounty back. Our exports, in consequence of these different
  • frauds, appear upon the custom-house books greatly to overbalance our
  • imports, to the unspeakable comfort of those politicians, who measure the
  • national prosperity by what they call the balance of trade.
  • All goods imported, unless particularly exempted, and such exemptions are
  • not very numerous, are liable to some duties of customs. If any goods are
  • imported, not mentioned in the book of rates, they are taxed at 4s:9¾d.
  • for every twenty shillings value, according to the oath of the importer,
  • that is, nearly at five subsidies, or five poundage duties. The book of
  • rates is extremely comprehensive, and enumerates a great variety of
  • articles, many of them little used, and, therefore, not well known. It is,
  • upon this account, frequently uncertain under what article a particular
  • sort of goods ought to be classed, and, consequently what duty they ought
  • to pay. Mistakes with regard to this sometimes ruin the custom-house
  • officer, and frequently occasion much trouble, expense, and vexation to
  • the importer. In point of perspicuity, precision, and distinctness,
  • therefore, the duties of customs are much inferior to those of excise.
  • In order that the greater part of the members of any society should
  • contribute to the public revenue, in proportion to their respective
  • expense, it does not seem necessary that every single article of that
  • expense should be taxed. The revenue which is levied by the duties of
  • excise is supposed to fall as equally upon the contributors as that which
  • is levied by the duties of customs; and the duties of excise are imposed
  • upon a few articles only of the most general used and consumption. It has
  • been the opinion of many people, that, by proper management, the duties of
  • customs might likewise, without any loss to the public revenue, and with
  • great advantage to foreign trade, be confined to a few articles only.
  • The foreign articles, of the most general use and consumption in Great
  • Britain, seem at present to consist chiefly in foreign wines and brandies;
  • in some of the productions of America and the West Indies, sugar, rum,
  • tobacco, cocoa-nuts, etc. and in some of those of the East Indies, tea,
  • coffee, china-ware, spiceries of all kinds, several sorts of piece-goods,
  • etc. These different articles afford, the greater part of the perhaps, at
  • present, revenue which is drawn from the duties of customs. The taxes
  • which at present subsist upon foreign manufactures, if you except those
  • upon the few contained in the foregoing enumeration, have, the greater
  • part of them, been imposed for the purpose, not of revenue, but of
  • monopoly, or to give our own merchants an advantage in the home market. By
  • removing all prohibitions, and by subjecting all foreign manufactures to
  • such moderate taxes, as it was found from experience, afforded upon each
  • article the greatest revenue to the public, our own workmen might still
  • have a considerable advantage in the home market; and many articles, some
  • of which at present afford no revenue to government, and others a very
  • inconsiderable one, might afford a very great one.
  • High taxes, sometimes by diminishing the consumption of the taxed
  • commodities, and sometimes by encouraging smuggling frequently afford a
  • smaller revenue to government than what might be drawn from more moderate
  • taxes.
  • When the diminution of revenue is the effect of the diminution of
  • consumption, there can be but one remedy, and that is the lowering of the
  • tax. When the diminution of revenue is the effect of the encouragement
  • given to smuggling, it may, perhaps, be remedied in two ways; either by
  • diminishing the temptation to smuggle, or by increasing the difficulty of
  • smuggling. The temptation to smuggle can be diminished only by the
  • lowering of the tax; and the difficulty of smuggling can be increased only
  • by establishing that system of administration which is most proper for
  • preventing it.
  • The excise laws, it appears, I believe, from experience, obstruct and
  • embarrass the operations of the smuggler much more effectually than those
  • of the customs. By introducing into the customs a system of administration
  • as similar to that of the excise as the nature of the different duties
  • will admit, the difficulty of smuggling might be very much increased. This
  • alteration, it has been supposed by many people, might very easily be
  • brought about.
  • The importer of commodities liable to any duties of customs, it has been
  • said, might, at his option, be allowed either to carry them to his own
  • private warehouse; or to lodge them in a warehouse, provided either at his
  • own expense or at that of the public, but under the key of the
  • custom-house officer, and never to be opened but in his presence. If the
  • merchant carried them to his own private warehouse, the duties to be
  • immediately paid, and never afterwards to be drawn back; and that
  • warehouse to be at all times subject to the visit and examination of the
  • custom-house officer, in order to ascertain how far the quantity contained
  • in it corresponded with that for which the duty had been paid. If he
  • carried them to the public warehouse, no duty to be paid till they were
  • taken out for home consumption. If taken out for exportation, to be
  • duty-free; proper security being always given that they should be so
  • exported. The dealers in those particular commodities, either by wholesale
  • or retail, to be at all times subject to the visit and examination of the
  • custom-house officer; and to be obliged to justify, by proper
  • certificates, the payment of the duty upon the whole quantity contained in
  • their shops or warehouses. What are called the excise duties upon rum
  • imported, are at present levied in this manner; and the same system of
  • administration might, perhaps, be extended to all duties upon goods
  • imported; provided always that those duties were, like the duties of
  • excise, confined to a few sorts of goods of the most general use and
  • consumption. If they were extended to almost all sorts of goods, as at
  • present, public warehouses of sufficient extent could not easily be
  • provided; and goods of a very delicate nature, or of which the
  • preservation required much care and attention, could not safely be trusted
  • by the merchant in any warehouse but his own.
  • If, by such a system of administration, smuggling to any considerable
  • extent could be prevented, even under pretty high duties; and if every
  • duty was occasionally either heightened or lowered according as it was
  • most likely, either the one way or the other, to afford the greatest
  • revenue to the state; taxation being always employed as an instrument of
  • revenue, and never of monopoly; it seems not improbable that a revenue, at
  • least equal to the present neat revenue of the customs, might be drawn
  • from duties upon the importation of only a few sorts of goods of the most
  • general use and consumption; and that the duties of customs might thus be
  • brought to the same degree of simplicity, certainty, and precision, as
  • those of excise. What the revenue at present loses by drawbacks upon the
  • re-exportation of foreign goods, which are afterwards re-landed and
  • consumed at home, would, under this system, be saved altogether. If to
  • this saving, which would alone be very considerable, were added the
  • abolition of all bounties upon the exportation of home produce; in all
  • cases in which those bounties were not in reality drawbacks of some duties
  • of excise which had before been advanced; it cannot well be doubted, but
  • that the neat revenue of customs might, after an alteration of this kind,
  • be fully equal to what it had ever been before.
  • If, by such a change of system, the public revenue suffered no loss, the
  • trade and manufactures of the country would certainly gain a very
  • considerable advantage. The trade in the commodities not taxed, by far the
  • greatest number would be perfectly free, and might be carried on to and
  • from all parts of the world with every possible advantage. Among those
  • commodities would be comprehended all the necessaries of life, and all the
  • materials of manufacture. So far as the free importation of the
  • necessaries of life reduced their average money price in the home market,
  • it would reduce the money price of labour, but without reducing in any
  • respect its real recompence. The value of money is in proportion to the
  • quantity of the necessaries of life which it will purchase. That of the
  • necessaries of life is altogether independent of the quantity of money
  • which can be had for them. The reduction in the money price of labour
  • would necessarily be attended with a proportionable one in that of all
  • home manufactures, which would thereby gain some advantage in all foreign
  • markets. The price of some manufactures would be reduced, in a still
  • greater proportion, by the free importation of the raw materials. If raw
  • silk could be imported from China and Indostan, duty-free, the silk
  • manufacturers in England could greatly undersell those of both France and
  • Italy. There would be no occasion to prohibit the importation of foreign
  • silks and velvets. The cheapness of their goods would secure to our own
  • workmen, not only the possession of a home, but a very great command of
  • the foreign market. Even the trade in the commodities taxed, would be
  • carried on with much more advantage than at present. If those commodities
  • were delivered out of the public warehouse for foreign exportation, being
  • in this case exempted from all taxes, the trade in them would be perfectly
  • free. The carrying trade, in all sorts of goods, would, under this system,
  • enjoy every possible advantage. If these commodities were delivered out
  • for home consumption, the importer not being obliged to advance the tax
  • till he had an opportunity of selling his goods, either to some dealer, or
  • to some consumer, he could always afford to sell them cheaper than if he
  • had been obliged to advance it at the moment of importation. Under the
  • same taxes, the foreign trade of consumption, even in the taxed
  • commodities, might in this manner be carried on with much more advantage
  • than it is at present.
  • It was the object of the famous excise scheme of Sir Robert Walpole, to
  • establish, with regard to wine and tobacco, a system not very unlike that
  • which is here proposed. But though the bill which was then brought into
  • Parliament, comprehended those two commodities only, it was generally
  • supposed to be meant as an introduction to a more extensive scheme of the
  • same kind. Faction, combined with the interest of smuggling merchants,
  • raised so violent, though so unjust a clamour, against that bill, that the
  • minister thought proper to drop it; and, from a dread of exciting a
  • clamour of the same kind, none of his successors have dared to resume the
  • project.
  • The duties upon foreign luxuries, imported for home consumption, though
  • they sometimes fall upon the poor, fall principally upon people of
  • middling or more than middling fortune. Such are, for example, the duties
  • upon foreign wines, upon coffee, chocolate, tea, sugar, etc.
  • The duties upon the cheaper luxuries of home produce, destined for home
  • consumption, fall pretty equally upon people of all ranks, in proportion
  • to their respective expense. The poor pay the duties upon malt, hops,
  • beer, and ale, upon their own consumption; the rich, upon both their own
  • consumption and that of their servants.
  • The whole consumption of the inferior ranks of people, or of those below
  • the middling rank, it must be observed, is, in every country, much
  • greater, not only in quantity, but in value, than that of the middling,
  • and of those above the middling rank. The whole expense of the inferior is
  • much greater titan that of the superior ranks. In the first place, almost
  • the whole capital of every country is annually distributed among the
  • inferior ranks of people, as the wages of productive labour. Secondly, a
  • great part of the revenue, arising from both the rent of land and the
  • profits of stock, is annually distributed among the same rank, in the
  • wages and maintenance of menial servants, and other unproductive
  • labourers. Thirdly, some part of the profits of stock belongs to the same
  • rank, as a revenue arising from the employment of their small capitals.
  • The amount of the profits annually made by small shopkeepers, tradesmen,
  • and retailers of all kinds, is everywhere very considerable, and makes a
  • very considerable portion of the annual produce. Fourthly and lastly, some
  • part even of the rent of land belongs to the same rank; a considerable
  • part to those who are somewhat below the middling rank, and a small part
  • even to the lowest rank; common labourers sometimes possessing in property
  • an acre or two of land. Though the expense of those inferior ranks of
  • people, therefore, taking them individually, is very small, yet the whole
  • mass of it, taking them collectively, amounts always to by much the
  • largest portion of the whole expense of the society; what remains of the
  • annual produce of the land and labour of the country, for the consumption
  • of the superior ranks, being always much less, not only in quantity, but
  • in value. The taxes upon expense, therefore, which fall chiefly upon that
  • of the superior ranks of people, upon the smaller portion of the annual
  • produce, are likely to be much less productive than either those which
  • fall indifferently upon the expense of all ranks, or even those which fall
  • chiefly upon that of the inferior ranks, than either those which fall
  • indifferently upon the whole annual produce, or those which fall chiefly
  • upon the larger portion of it. The excise upon the materials and
  • manufacture of home-made fermented and spirituous liquors, is,
  • accordingly, of all the different taxes upon expense, by far the most
  • productive; and this branch of the excise falls very much, perhaps
  • principally, upon the expense of the common people. In the year which
  • ended on the 5th of July 1775, the gross produce of this branch of the
  • excise amounted to £3,341,837:9:9.
  • It must always be remembered, however, that it is the luxuries, and not
  • the necessary expense of the inferior ranks of people, that ought ever to
  • be taxed. The final payment of any tax upon their necessary expense, would
  • fall altogether upon the superior ranks of people; upon the smaller
  • portion of the annual produce, and not upon the greater. Such a tax must,
  • in all cases, either raise the wages of labour, or lessen the demand for
  • it. It could not raise the wages of labour, without throwing the final
  • payment of the tax upon the superior ranks of people. It could not lessen
  • the demand for labour, without lessening the annual produce of the land
  • and labour of the country, the fund upon which all taxes must be finally
  • paid. Whatever might be the state to which a tax of this kind reduced the
  • demand for labour, it must always raise wages higher than they otherwise
  • would be in that state; and the final payment of this enhancement of wages
  • must, in all cases, fall upon the superior ranks of people.
  • Fermented liquors brewed, and spiritous liquors distilled, not for sale,
  • but for private use, are not in Great Britain liable to any duties of
  • excise. This exemption, of which the object is to save private families
  • from the odious visit and examination of the tax-gatherer, occasions the
  • burden of those duties to fall frequently much lighter upon the rich than
  • upon the poor. It is not, indeed, very common to distil for private use,
  • though it is done sometimes. But in the country, many middling and almost
  • all rich and great families, brew their own beer. Their strong beer,
  • therefore, costs them eight shillings a-barrel less than it costs the
  • common brewer, who must have his profit upon the tax, as well as upon all
  • the other expense which he advances. Such families, therefore, must drink
  • their beer at least nine or ten shillings a-barrel cheaper than any liquor
  • of the same quality can be drank by the common people, to whom it is
  • everywhere more convenient to buy their beer, by little and little, from
  • the brewery or the ale-house. Malt, in the same manner, that is made for
  • the use of a private family, is not liable to the visit or examination of
  • the tax-gatherer but, in this case the family must compound at seven
  • shillings and sixpence a-head for the tax. Seven shillings and sixpence
  • are equal to the excise upon ten bushels of malt; a quantity fully equal
  • to what all the different members of any sober family, men, women, and
  • children, are, at an average, likely to consume. But in rich and great
  • families, where country hospitality is much practised, the malt liquors
  • consumed by the members of the family make but a small part of the
  • consmnption of the house. Either on account of this composition, however,
  • or for other reasons, it is not near so common to malt as to brew for
  • private use. It is difficult to imagine any equitable reason, why those
  • who either brew or distil for private use should not be subject to a
  • composition of the same kind.
  • A greater revenue than what is at present drawn from all the heavy taxes
  • upon malt, beer, and ale, might be raised, it has frequently been said, by
  • a much lighter tax upon malt; the opportunities of defrauding the revenue
  • being much greater in a brewery than in a malt-house; and those who brew
  • for private use being exempted from all duties or composition for duties,
  • which is not the case with those who malt for private use.
  • In the porter brewery of London, a quarter of malt is commonly brewed into
  • more than two barrels and a-half, sometimes into three barrels of porter.
  • The different taxes upon malt amount to six shillings a-quarter; those
  • upon strong ale and beer to eight shillings a-barrel. In the porter
  • brewery, therefore, the different taxes upon malt, beer, and ale, amount
  • to between twenty-six and thirty shillings upon the produce of a quarter
  • of malt. In the country brewery for common country sale, a quarter of malt
  • is seldom brewed into less than two barrels of strong, and one barrel of
  • small beer; frequently into two barrels and a-half of strong beer. The
  • different taxes upon small beer amount to one shilling and fourpence
  • a-barrel. In the country brewery, therefore, the different taxes upon
  • malt, beer, and ale, seldom amount to less than twenty-three shillings and
  • fourpence, frequently to twenty-six shillings, upon the produce of a
  • quarter of malt. Taking the whole kingdom at an average, therefore, the
  • whole amount of the duties upon malt, beer, and ale, cannot be estimated
  • at less than twenty-four or twenty-five shillings upon the produce of a
  • quarter of malt. But by taking off all the different duties upon beer and
  • ale, and by trebling the malt tax, or by raising it from six to eighteen
  • shillings upon the quarter of malt, a greater revenue, it is said, might
  • be raised by this single tax, than what is at present drawn from all those
  • heavier taxes.
  • In 1772, the old malt tax produced......... £722,023: 11: 11
  • The additional... £356,776: 7: 9¾
  • In 1775, the old tax produced............... £561,627: 3: 7½
  • The additional... £278,650: 15: 3¾
  • In 1774, the old tax produced ............ £624,614: 17: 5¾
  • The additional....£310,745: 2: 8½
  • In 1775, the old tax produced ............£657,357: 0: 8¼
  • The additional....£323,785: 12: 6¼
  • £5,855,580: 12: 0¾
  • Average of these four years .............. £958,895: 3: 0
  • In 1772, the country excise produced.......£1,243,120: 5: 3
  • The London brewery 408,260: 7: 2¾
  • In 1773, the country excise................£1,245,808: 3: 3
  • The London brewery 405,406: 17: 10½
  • In 1774, the country excise................£1,246,373: 14: 5½
  • The London brewery 320,601: 18: 0¼
  • In 1775, the country excise................£1,214,583: 6: 1¼
  • The London brewery 463,670: 7: 0¼
  • 4)£6,547,832: 19: 2¼
  • Average of these four years ..............£1,636,958: 4: 9½
  • To which adding the average malt tax........ 958,895: 3: 0¼
  • The whole amount of those different
  • taxes comes out to be........£2,595,835: 7: 10
  • But, by trebling the malt tax,
  • or by raising it from six to
  • eighteen shillings upon the quarter
  • of malt, that single tax would produce.....£2,876,685: 9: 0
  • A sum which exceeds the
  • foregoing by.... 280,832: 1: 3
  • Under the old malt tax, indeed, is comprehended a tax of four shillings
  • upon the hogshead of cyder, and another of ten shillings upon the barrel
  • of mum. In 1774, the tax upon cyder produced only £3,083:6:8. It probably
  • fell somewhat short of its usual amount; all the different taxes upon
  • cyder, having, that year, produced less than ordinary. The tax upon mum,
  • though much heavier, is still less productive, on account of the smaller
  • consumption of that liquor. But to balance whatever may be the ordinary
  • amount of those two taxes, there is comprehended under what is called the
  • country excise, first, the old excise of six shillings and eightpence upon
  • the hogshead of cyder; secondly, a like tax of six shillings and
  • eightpence upon the hogshead of verjuice; thirdly, another of eight
  • shillings and ninepence upon the hogshead of vinegar; and, lastly, a
  • fourth tax of elevenpence upon the gallon of mead or metheglin. The
  • produce of those different taxes will probably much more than
  • counterbalance that of the duties imposed, by what is called the annual
  • malt tax, upon cyder and mum.
  • Malt is consumed, not only in the brewery of beer and ale, but in the
  • manufacture of low wines and spirits. If the malt tax were to be raised to
  • eighteen shillings upon the quarter, it might be necessary to make some
  • abatement in the different excises which are imposed upon those particular
  • sorts of low wines and spirits, of which malt makes any part of the
  • materials. In what are called malt spirits, it makes commonly but a third
  • part of the materials; the other two-thirds being either raw barley, or
  • one-third barley and one-third wheat. In the distillery of malt spirits,
  • both the opportunity and the temptation to smuggle are much greater than
  • either in a brewery or in a malt-house; the opportunity, on account of the
  • smaller bulk and greater value of the commodity, and the temptation, on
  • account of the superior height of the duties, which amounted to 3s. 10
  • 2/3d. upon the gallon of spirits. {Though the duties directly imposed upon
  • proof spirits amount only to 2s. 6d per gallon, these, added to the duties
  • upon the low wines, from which they are distilled, amount to 3s 10 2/3d.
  • Both low wines and proof spirits are, to prevent frauds, now rated
  • according to what they gauge in the wash.}
  • By increasing the duties upon malt, and reducing those upon the
  • distillery, both the opportunities and the temptation to smuggle would be
  • diminished, which might occasion a still further augmentation of revenue.
  • It has for some time past been the policy of Great Britain to discourage
  • the consumption of spiritous liquors, on account of their supposed
  • tendency to ruin the health and to corrupt the morals of the common
  • people. According to this policy, the abatement of the taxes upon the
  • distillery ought not to be so great as to reduce, in any respect, the
  • price of those liquors. Spiritous liquors might remain as dear as ever;
  • while, at the same time, the wholesome and invigorating liquors of beer
  • and ale might be considerably reduced in their price. The people might
  • thus be in part relieved from one of the burdens of which they at present
  • complain the most; while, at the same time, the revenue might be
  • considerably augmented.
  • The objections of Dr. Davenant to this alteration in the present system of
  • excise duties, seem to be without foundation. Those objections are, that
  • the tax, instead of dividing itself, as at present, pretty equally upon
  • the profit of the maltster, upon that of the brewer and upon that of the
  • retailer, would so far as it affected profit, fall altogether upon that of
  • the maltster; that the maltster could not so easily get back the amount of
  • the tax in the advanced price of his malt, as the brewer and retailer in
  • the advanced price of their liquor; and that so heavy a tax upon malt
  • might reduce the rent and profit of barley land.
  • No tax can ever reduce, for any considerable time, the rate of profit in
  • any particular trade, which must always keep its level with other trades
  • in the neighbourhood. The present duties upon malt, beer, and ale, do not
  • affect the profits of the dealers in those commodities, who all get back
  • the tax with an additional profit, in the enhanced price of their goods. A
  • tax, indeed, may render the goods upon which it is imposed so dear, as to
  • diminish the consumption of them. But the consumption of malt is in malt
  • liquors; and a tax of eighteen shillings upon the quarter of malt could
  • not well render those liquors dearer than the different taxes, amounting
  • to twenty-four or twenty-five shillings, do at present. Those liquors, on
  • the contrary, would probably become cheaper, and the consumption of them
  • would be more likely to increase than to diminish.
  • It is not very easy to understand why it should be more difficult for the
  • maltster to get back eighteen shillings in the advanced price of his malt,
  • than it is at present for the brewer to get back twenty-four or
  • twenty-five, sometimes thirty shillings, in that of his liquor. The
  • maltster, indeed, instead of a tax of six shillings, would be obliged to
  • advance one of eighteen shilling upon every quarter of malt. But the
  • brewer is at present obliged to advance a tax of twenty-four or
  • twenty-five, sometimes thirty shillings, upon every quarter of malt which
  • he brews. It could not be more inconvenient for the maltster to advance a
  • lighter tax, than it is at present for the brewer to advance a heavier
  • one. The maltster does not always keep in his granaries a stock of malt,
  • which it will require a longer time to dispose of than the stock of beer
  • and ale which the brewer frequently keeps in his cellars. The former,
  • therefore, may frequently get the returns of his money as soon as the
  • latter. But whatever inconveniency might arise to the maltster from being
  • obliged to advance a heavier tax, it could easily be remedied, by granting
  • him a few months longer credit than is at present commonly given to the
  • brewer.
  • Nothing could reduce the rent and profit of barley land, which did not
  • reduce the demand for barley. But a change of system, which reduced the
  • duties upon a quarter of malt brewed into beer and ale, from twentyfour
  • and twenty-five shillings to eighteen shillings, would be more likely to
  • increase than diminish that demand. The rent and profit of barley land,
  • besides, must always be nearly equal to those of other equally fertile and
  • equally well cultivated land. If they were less, some part of the barley
  • land would soon be turned to some other purpose; and if they were greater,
  • more land would soon be turned to the raising of barley. When the ordinary
  • price of any particular produce of land is at what may be called a
  • monopoly price, a tax upon it necessarily reduces the rent and profit of
  • the land which grows it. A tax upon the produce of those precious
  • vineyards, of which the wine falls so much short of the effectual demand,
  • that its price is always above the natural proportion to that of the
  • produce of other equally fertile and equally well cultivated land, would
  • necessarily reduce the rent and profit of those vineyards. The price of
  • the wines being already the highest that could be got for the quantity
  • commonly sent to market, it could not be raised higher without diminishing
  • that quantity; and the quantity could not be diminished without still
  • greater loss, because the lands could not be turned to any other equally
  • valuable produce. The whole weight of the tax, therefore, would fall upon
  • the rent and profit; properly upon the rent of the vineyard. When it has
  • been proposed to lay any new tax upon sugar, our sugar planters have
  • frequently complained that the whole weight of such taxes fell not upon
  • the consumer, but upon the producer; they never having been able to raise
  • the price of their sugar after the tax higher than it was before. The
  • price had, it seems, before the tax, been a monopoly price; and the
  • arguments adduced to show that sugar was an improper subject of taxation,
  • demonstrated perhaps that it was a proper one; the gains of monopolists,
  • whenever they can be come at, being certainly of all subjects the most
  • proper. But the ordinary price of barley has never been a monopoly price;
  • and the rent and profit of barley land have never been above their natural
  • proportion to those of other equally fertile and equally well cultivated
  • land. The different taxes which have been imposed upon malt, beer, and
  • ale, have never lowered the price of barley; have never reduced the rent
  • and profit of barley land. The price of malt to the brewer has constantly
  • risen in proportion to the taxes imposed upon it; and those taxes,
  • together with the different duties upon beer and ale, have constantly
  • either raised the price, or, what comes to the same thing, reduced the
  • quality of those commodities to the consumer. The final payment of those
  • taxes has fallen constantly upon the consumer, and not upon the producer.
  • The only people likely to suffer by the change of system here proposed,
  • are those who brew for their own private use. But the exemption, which
  • this superior rank of people at present enjoy, from very heavy taxes which
  • are paid by the poor labourer and artificer, is surely most unjust and
  • unequal, and ought to be taken away, even though this change was never to
  • take place. It has probably been the interest of this superior order of
  • people, however, which has hitherto prevented a change of system that
  • could not well fail both to increase the revenue and to relieve the
  • people.
  • Besides such duties as those of custom and excise above mentioned, there
  • are several others which affect the price of goods more unequally and more
  • indirectly. Of this kind are the duties, which, in French, are called
  • peages, which in old Saxon times were called the duties of passage, and
  • which seem to have been originally established for the same purpose as our
  • turnpike tolls, or the tolls upon our canals and navigable rivers, for the
  • maintenance of the road or of the navigation. Those duties, when applied
  • to such purposes, are most properly imposed according to the bulk or
  • weight of the goods. As they were originally local and provincial duties,
  • applicable to local and provincial purposes, the administration of them
  • was, in most cases, entrusted to the particular town, parish, or lordship,
  • in which they were levied; such communities being, in some way or other,
  • supposed to be accountable for the application. The sovereign, who is
  • altogether unaccountable, has in many countries assumed to himself the
  • administration of those duties; and though he has in most cases enhanced
  • very much the duty, he has in many entirely neglected the application. If
  • the turnpike tolls of Great Britain should ever become one of the
  • resources of government, we may learn, by the example of many other
  • nations, what would probably be the consequence. Such tolls, no doubt, are
  • finally paid by the consumer; but the consumer is not taxed in proportion
  • to his expense, when he pays, not according to the value, but according to
  • the bulk or weight of what he consumes. When such duties are imposed, not
  • according to the bulk or weight, but according to the supposed value of
  • the goods, they become properly a sort of inland customs or excise, which
  • obstruct very much the most important of all branches of commerce, the
  • interior commerce of the country.
  • In some small states, duties similar to those passage duties are imposed
  • upon goods carried across the territory, either by land or by water, from
  • one foreign country to another. These are in some countries called
  • transit-duties. Some of the little Italian states which are situated upon
  • the Po, and the rivers which run into it, derive some revenue from duties
  • of this kind, which are paid altogether by foreigners, and which, perhaps,
  • are the only duties that one state can impose upon the subjects of
  • another, without obstruction in any respect, the industry or commerce of
  • its own. The most important transit-duty in the world, is that levied by
  • the king of Denmark upon all merchant ships which pass through the Sound.
  • Such taxes upon luxuries, as the greater part of the duties of customs and
  • excise, though they all fall indifferently upon every different species of
  • revenue, and are paid finally, or without any retribution, by whoever
  • consumes the commodities upon which they are imposed; yet they do not
  • always fall equally or proportionally upon the revenue of every
  • individual. As every man’s humour regulates the degree of his consumption,
  • every man contributes rather according to his humour, than proportion to
  • his revenue: the profuse contribute more, the parsimonious less, than
  • their proper proportion. During the minority of a man of great fortune, he
  • contributes commonly very little, by his consumption, towards the support
  • of that state from whose protection he derives a great revenue. Those who
  • live in another country, contribute nothing by their consumption towards
  • the support of the government of that country, in which is situated the
  • source of their revenue. If in this latter country there should be no land
  • tax, nor any considerable duty upon the transference either of moveable or
  • immoveable property, as is the case in Ireland, such absentees may derive
  • a great revenue from the protection of a government, to the support of
  • which they do not contribute a single shilling. This inequality is likely
  • to be greatest in a country of which the government is, in some respects,
  • subordinate and dependant upon that of some other. The people who possess
  • the most extensive property in the dependant, will, in this case,
  • generally chuse to live in the governing country. Ireland is precisely in
  • this situation; and we cannot therefore wonder, that the proposal of a tax
  • upon absentees should be so very popular in that country. It might,
  • perhaps, be a little difficult to ascertain either what sort, or what
  • degree of absence, would subject a man to be taxed as an absentee, or at
  • what precise time the tax should either begin or end. If you except,
  • however, this very peculiar situation, any inequality in the contribution
  • of individuals which can arise from such taxes, is much more than
  • compensated by the very circumstance which occasions that inequality; the
  • circumstance that every man’s contribution is altogether voluntary; it
  • being altogether in his power, either to consume, or not to consume, the
  • commodity taxed. Where such taxes, therefore, are properly assessed, and
  • upon proper commodities, they are paid with less grumbling than any other.
  • When they are advanced by the merchant or manufacturer, the consumer, who
  • finally pays them, soon comes to confound them with the price of the
  • commodities, and almost forgets that he pays any tax. Such taxes are, or
  • may be, perfectly certain; or may be assessed, so as to leave no doubt
  • concerning either what ought to be paid, or when it ought to be paid;
  • concerning either the quantity or the time of payment. What ever
  • uncertainty there may sometimes be, either in the duties of customs in
  • Great Britain, or in other duties of the same kind in other countries, it
  • cannot arise from the nature of those duties, but from the inaccurate or
  • unskilful manner in which the law that imposes them is expressed.
  • Taxes upon luxuries generally are, and always may be, paid piece-meal, or
  • in proportion as the contributors have occasion to purchase the goods upon
  • which they are imposed. In the time and mode of payment, they are, or may
  • be, of all taxes the most convenient. Upon the whole, such taxes,
  • therefore, are perhaps as agreeable to the three first of the four general
  • maxims concerning taxation, as any other. They offend in every respect
  • against the fourth.
  • Such taxes, in proportion to what they bring into the public treasury of
  • the state, always take out, or keep out, of the pockets of the people,
  • more than almost any other taxes. They seem to do this in all the four
  • different ways in which it is possible to do it.
  • First, the levying of such taxes, even when imposed in the most judicious
  • manner, requires a great number of custom-house and excise officers, whose
  • salaries and perquisites are a real tax upon the people, which brings
  • nothing into the treasury of the state. This expense, however, it must be
  • acknowledged, is more moderate in Great Britain than in most other
  • countries. In the year which ended on the 5th of July, 1775, the gross
  • produce of the different duties, under the management of the commissioners
  • of excise in England, amounted to £5,507,308:18:8¼, which was levied at an
  • expense of little more than five and a-half per cent. From this gross
  • produce, however, there must be deducted what was paid away in bounties
  • and drawbacks upon the exportation of exciseable goods, which will reduce
  • the neat produce below five millions. {The neat produce of that year,
  • after deducting all expenses and allowances, amounted to £4,975,652:19:6.}
  • The levying of the salt duty, and excise duty, but under a different
  • management, is much more expensive. The neat revenue of the customs does
  • not amount to two millions and a-half, which is levied at an expense of
  • more than ten per cent., in the salaries of officers and other incidents.
  • But the perquisites of custom-house officers are everywhere much greater
  • than their salaries; at some ports more than double or triple those
  • salaries. If the salaries of officers, and other incidents, therefore,
  • amount to more than ten per cent. upon the neat revenue of the customs,
  • the whole expense of levying that revenue may amount, in salaries and
  • perquisites together, to more than twenty or thirty per cent. The officers
  • of excise receive few or no perquisites; and the administration of that
  • branch of the revenue being of more recent establishment, is in general
  • less corrupted than that of the customs, into which length of time has
  • introduced and authorised many abuses. By charging upon malt the whole
  • revenue which is at present levied by the different duties upon malt and
  • malt liquors, a saving, it is supposed, of more than £50,000, might be
  • made in the annual expense of the excise. By confining the duties of
  • customs to a few sorts of goods, and by levying those duties according to
  • the excise laws, a much greater saving might probably be made in the
  • annual expense of the customs.
  • Secondly, such taxes necessarily occasion some obstruction or
  • discouragement to certain branches of industry. As they always raise the
  • price of the commodity taxed, they so far discourage its consumption, and
  • consequently its production. If it is a commodity of home growth or
  • manufacture, less labour comes to be employed in raising and producing it.
  • If it is a foreign commodity of which the tax increases in this manner the
  • price, the commodities of the same kind which are made at home may
  • thereby, indeed, gain some advantage in the home market, and a greater
  • quantity of domestic industry may thereby be turned toward preparing them.
  • But though this rise of price in a foreign commodity, may encourage
  • domestic industry in one particular branch, it necessarily discourages
  • that industry in almost every other. The dearer the Birmingham
  • manufacturer buys his foreign wine, the cheaper he necessarily sells that
  • part of his hardware with which, or, what comes to the same thing, with
  • the price of which, he buys it. That part of his hardware, therefore,
  • becomes of less value to him, and he has less encouragement to work at it.
  • The dearer the consumers in one country pay for the surplus produce of
  • another, the cheaper they necessarily sell that part of their own surplus
  • produce with which, or, what comes to the same thing, with the price of
  • which, they buy it. That part of their own surplus produce becomes of less
  • value to them, and they have less encouragement to increase its quantity.
  • All taxes upon consumable commodities, therefore, tend to reduce the
  • quantity of productive labour below what it otherwise would be, either in
  • preparing the commodities taxed, if they are home commodities, or in
  • preparing those with which they are purchased, if they are foreign
  • commodities. Such taxes, too, always alter, more or less, the natural
  • direction of national industry, and turn it into a channel always
  • different from, and generally less advantageous, than that in which it
  • would have run of its own accord.
  • Thirdly, the hope of evading such taxes by smuggling, gives frequent
  • occasion to forfeitures and other penalties, which entirely ruin the
  • smuggler; a person who, though no doubt highly blameable for violating the
  • laws of his country, is frequently incapable of violating those of natural
  • justice, and would have been, in every respect, an excellent citizen, had
  • not the laws of his country made that a crime which nature never meant to
  • be so. In those corrupted governments, where there is at least a general
  • suspicion of much unnecessary expense, and great misapplication of the
  • public revenue, the laws which guard it are little respected. Not many
  • people are scrupulous about smuggling, when, without perjury, they can
  • find an easy and safe opportunity of doing so. To pretend to have any
  • scruple about buying smuggled goods, though a manifest encouragement to
  • the violation of the revenue laws, and to the perjury which almost always
  • attends it, would, in most countries, be regarded as one of those pedantic
  • pieces of hypocrisy which, instead of gaining credit with anybody, serve
  • only to expose the person who affects to practise them to the suspicion of
  • being a greater knave than most of his neighbours. By this indulgence of
  • the public, the smuggler is often encouraged to continue a trade, which he
  • is thus taught to consider as in some measure innocent; and when the
  • severity of the revenue laws is ready to fall upon him, he is frequently
  • disposed to defend with violence, what he has been accustomed to regard as
  • his just property. From being at first, perhaps, rather imprudent than
  • criminal, he at last too often becomes one of the hardiest and most
  • determined violators of the laws of society. By the ruin of the smuggler,
  • his capital, which had before been employed in maintaining productive
  • labour, is absorbed either in the revenue of the state, or in that of the
  • revenue officer; and is employed in maintaining unproductive, to the
  • diminution of the general capital of the society, and of the useful
  • industry which it might otherwise have maintained.
  • Fourthly, such taxes, by subjecting at least the dealers in the taxed
  • commodities, to the frequent visits and odious examination of the
  • tax-gatherers, expose them sometimes, no doubt, to some degree of
  • oppression, and always to much trouble and vexation; and though vexation,
  • as has already been said, is not strictly speaking expense, it is
  • certainly equivalent to the expense at which every man would be willing to
  • redeem himself from it. The laws of excise, though more effectual for the
  • purpose for which they were instituted, are, in this respect, more
  • vexatious than those of the customs. When a merchant has imported goods
  • subject to certain duties of customs; when he has paid those duties, and
  • lodged the goods in his warehouse; he is not, in most cases, liable to any
  • further trouble or vexation from the custom-house officer. It is otherwise
  • with goods subject to duties of excise. The dealers have no respite from
  • the continual visits and examination of the excise officers. The duties of
  • excise are, upon this account, more unpopular than those of the customs;
  • and so are the officers who levy them. Those officers, it is pretended,
  • though in general, perhaps, they do their duty fully as well as those of
  • the customs; yet, as that duty obliges them to be frequently very
  • troublesome to some of their neighbours, commonly contract a certain
  • hardness of character, which the others frequently have not. This
  • observation, however, may very probably be the mere suggestion of
  • fraudulent dealers, whose smuggling is either prevented or detected by
  • their diligence.
  • The inconveniencies, however, which are, perhaps, in some degree
  • inseparable from taxes upon consumable communities, fall as light upon the
  • people of Great Britain as upon those of any other country of which the
  • government is nearly as expensive. Our state is not perfect, and might be
  • mended; but it is as good, or better, than that of most of our neighbours.
  • In consequence of the notion, that duties upon consumable goods were taxes
  • upon the profits of merchants, those duties have, in some countries, been
  • repeated upon every successive sale of the goods. If the profits of the
  • merchant-importer or merchant-manufacturer were taxed, equality seemed to
  • require that those of all the middle buyers, who intervened between either
  • of them and the consumer, should likewise be taxed. The famous alcavala of
  • Spain seems to have been established upon this principle. It was at first
  • a tax of ten per cent. afterwards of fourteen per cent. and it is at
  • present only six per cent. upon the sale of every sort of property whether
  • moveable or immoveable; and it is repeated every time the property is
  • sold. {Memoires concernant les Droits, etc. tom. i, p. 15} The levying of
  • this tax requires a multitude of revenue officers, sufficient to guard the
  • transportation of goods, not only from one province to another, but from
  • one shop to another. It subjects, not only the dealers in some sorts of
  • goods, but those in all sorts, every farmer, every manufacturer, every
  • merchant and shopkeeper, to the continual visit and examination of the
  • tax-gatherers. Through the greater part of the country in which a tax of
  • this kind is established, nothing can be produced for distant sale. The
  • produce of every part of the country must be proportioned to the
  • consumption of the neighbourhood. It is to the alcavala, accordingly, that
  • Ustaritz imputes the ruin of the manufactures of Spain. He might have
  • imputed to it, likewise, the declension of agriculture, it being imposed
  • not only upon manufactures, but upon the rude produce of the land.
  • In the kingdom of Naples, there is a similar tax of three per cent. upon
  • the value of all contracts, and consequently upon that of all contracts of
  • sale. It is both lighter than the Spanish tax, and the greater part of
  • towns and parishes are allowed to pay a composition in lieu of it. They
  • levy this composition in what manner they please, generally in a way that
  • gives no interruption to the interior commerce of the place. The
  • Neapolitan tax, therefore, is not near so ruinous as the Spanish one.
  • The uniform system of taxation, which, with a few exception of no great
  • consequence, takes place in all the different parts of the united kingdom
  • of Great Britain, leaves the interior commerce of the country, the inland
  • and coasting trade, almost entirely free. The inland trade is almost
  • perfectly free; and the greater part of goods may be carried from one end
  • of the kingdom to the other, without requiring any permit or let-pass,
  • without being subject to question, visit or examination, from the revenue
  • officers. There are a few exceptions, but they are such as can give no
  • interruption to any important branch of inland commerce of the country.
  • Goods carried coastwise, indeed, require certificates or coast-cockets. If
  • you except coals, however, the rest are almost all duty-free. This freedom
  • of interior commerce, the effect of the uniformity of the system of
  • taxation, is perhaps one of the principal causes of the prosperity of
  • Great Britain; every great country being necessarily the best and most
  • extensive market for the greater part of the productions of its own
  • industry. If the same freedom in consequence of the same uniformity, could
  • be extended to Ireland and the plantations, both the grandeur of the
  • state, and the prosperity of every part of the empire, would probably be
  • still greater than at present.
  • In France, the different revenue laws which take place in the different
  • provinces, require a multitude of revenue officers to surround, not only
  • the frontiers of the kingdom, but those of almost each particular
  • province, in order either to prevent the importation of certain goods, or
  • to subject it to the payment of certain duties, to the no small
  • interruption of the interior commerce of the country. Some provinces are
  • allowed to compound for the gabelle, or salt tax; others are exempted from
  • it altogether. Some provinces are exempted from the exclusive sale of
  • tobacco, which the farmers-general enjoy through the greater part of the
  • kingdom. The aides, which correspond to the excise in England, are very
  • different in different provinces. Some provinces are exempted from them,
  • and pay a composition or equivalent. In those in which they take place,
  • and are in farm, there are many local duties which do not extend beyond a
  • particular town or district. The traites, which correspond to our customs,
  • divide the kingdom into three great parts; first, the provinces subject to
  • the tariff of 1664, which are called the provinces of the five great
  • farms, and under which are comprehended Picardy, Normandy, and the greater
  • part of the interior provinces of the kingdom; secondly, the provinces
  • subject to the tariff of 1667, which are called the provinces reckoned
  • foreign, and under which are comprehended the greater part of the frontier
  • provinces; and, thirdly, those provinces which are said to be treated as
  • foreign, or which, because they are allowed a free commerce with foreign
  • countries, are, in their commerce with the other provinces of France,
  • subjected to the same duties as other foreign countries. These are Alsace,
  • the three bishoprics of Mentz, Toul, and Verdun, and the three cities of
  • Dunkirk, Bayonne, and Marseilles. Both in the provinces of the five great
  • farms (called so on account of an ancient division of the duties of
  • customs into five great branches, each of which was originally the subject
  • of a particular farm, though they are now all united into one), and in
  • those which are said to be reckoned foreign, there are many local duties
  • which do not extend beyond a particular town or district. There are some
  • such even in the provinces which are said to be treated as foreign,
  • particularly in the city of Marseilles. It is unnecessary to observe how
  • much both the restraints upon the interior commerce of the country, and
  • the number of the revenue officers, must be multiplied, in order to guard
  • the frontiers of those different provinces and districts which are subject
  • to such different systems of taxation.
  • Over and above the general restraints arising from this complicated system
  • of revenue laws, the commerce of wine (after corn, perhaps, the most
  • important production of France) is, in the greater part of the provinces,
  • subject to particular restraints arising from the favour which has been
  • shown to the vineyards of particular provinces and districts above those
  • of others. The provinces most famous for their wines, it will be found, I
  • believe, are those in which the trade in that article is subject to the
  • fewest restraints of this kind. The extensive market which such provinces
  • enjoy, encourages good management both in the cultivation of their
  • vineyards, and in the subsequent preparation of their wines.
  • Such various and complicated revenue laws are not peculiar to France. The
  • little duchy of Milan is divided into six provinces, in each of which
  • there is a different system of taxation, with regard to several different
  • sorts of consumable goods. The still smaller territories of the duke of
  • Parma are divided into three or four, each of which has, in the same
  • manner, a system of its own. Under such absurd management, nothing but the
  • great fertility of the soil, and happiness of the climate, could preserve
  • such countries from soon relapsing into the lowest state of poverty and
  • barbarism.
  • Taxes upon consumable commodities may either he levied by an
  • administration, of which the officers are appointed by govermnent, and are
  • immediately accountable to government, of which the revenue must, in this
  • case, vary from year to year, according to the occasional variations in
  • the produce of the tax; or they may be let in farm for a rent certain, the
  • farmer being allowed to appoint his own officers, who, though obliged to
  • levy the tax in the manner directed by the law, are under his immediate
  • inspection, and are immediately accountable to him. The best and most
  • frugal way of levying a tax can never be by farm. Over and above what is
  • necessary for paying the stipulated rent, the salaries of the officers,
  • and the whole expense of administration, the farmer must always draw from
  • the produce of the tax a certain profit, proportioned at least to the
  • advance which he makes, to the risk which he runs, to the trouble which he
  • is at, and to the knowledge and skill which it requires to manage so very
  • complicated a concern. Government, by establishing an administration under
  • their own immediate inspection, of the same kind with that which the
  • farmer establishes, might at least save this profit, which is almost
  • always exorbitant. To farm any considerable branch of the public revenue
  • requires either a great capital, or a great credit; circumstances which
  • would alone restrain the competition for such an undertaking to a very
  • small number of people. Of the few who have this capital or credit, a
  • still smaller number have the necessary knowledge or experience; another
  • circumstance which restrains the competition still further. The very few
  • who are in condition to become competitors, find it more for their
  • interest to combine together; to become copartners, instead of
  • competitors; and, when the farm is set up to auction, to offer no rent but
  • what is much below the real value. In countries where the public revenues
  • are in farm, the farmers are generally the most opulent people. Their
  • wealth would alone excite the public indignation; and the vanity which
  • almost always accompanies such upstart fortunes, the foolish ostentation
  • with which they commonly display that wealth, excite that indignation
  • still more.
  • The farmers of the public revenue never find the laws too severe, which
  • punish any attempt to evade the payment of a tax. They have no bowels for
  • the contributors, who are not their subjects, and whose universal
  • bankruptcy, if it should happen the day after the farm is expired, would
  • not much affect their interest. In the greatest exigencies of the state,
  • when the anxiety of the sovereign for the exact payment of his revenue is
  • necessarily the greatest, they seldom fail to complain, that without laws
  • more rigorous than those which actually took place, it will be impossible
  • for them to pay even the usual rent. In those moments of public distress,
  • their commands cannot be disputed. The revenue laws, therefore, become
  • gradually more and more severe. The most sanguinary are always to be found
  • in countries where the greater part of the public revenue is in farm; the
  • mildest, in countries where it is levied under the immediate inspection of
  • the sovereign. Even a bad sovereign feels more compassion for his people
  • than can ever be expected from the farmers of his revenue. He knows that
  • the permanent grandeur of his family depends upon the prosperity of his
  • people, and he will never knowingly ruin that prosperity for the sake of
  • any momentary interest of his own. It is otherwise with the farmers of his
  • revenue, whose grandeur may frequently be the effect of the ruin, and not
  • of the prosperity, of his people.
  • A tax is sometimes not only farmed for a certain rent, but the farmer has,
  • besides, the monopoly of the commodity taxed. In France, the duties upon
  • tobacco and salt are levied in this manner. In such cases, the farmer,
  • instead of one, levies two exorbitant profits upon the people; the profit
  • of the farmer, and the still more exorbitant one of the monopolist.
  • Tobacco being a luxury, every man is allowed to buy or not to buy as he
  • chuses; but salt being a necessary, every man is obliged to buy of the
  • farmer a certain quantity of it; because, if he did not buy this quantity
  • of the farmer, he would, it is presumed, buy it of some smuggler. The
  • taxes upon both commodities are exorbitant. The temptation to smuggle,
  • consequently, is to many people irresistible; while, at the same time, the
  • rigour of the law, and the vigilance of the farmer’s officers, render the
  • yielding to the temptation almost certainly ruinous. The smuggling of salt
  • and tobacco sends every year several hundred people to the galleys,
  • besides a very considerable number whom it sends to the gibbet. Those
  • taxes, levied in this manner, yield a very considerable revenue to
  • government. In 1767, the farm of tobacco was let for twenty-two millions
  • five hundred and forty-one thousand two hundred and seventy-eight livres
  • a-year; that of salt for thirty-six millions four hundred and ninety-two
  • thousand four hundred and four livres. The farm, in both cases, was to
  • commence in 1768, and to last for six years. Those who consider the blood
  • of the people as nothing, in comparison with the revenue of the prince,
  • may, perhaps, approve of this method of levying taxes. Similar taxes and
  • monopolies of salt and tobacco have been established in many other
  • countries, particularly in the Austrian and Prussian dominions, and in the
  • greater part of the states of Italy.
  • In France, the greater part of the actual revenue of the crown is derived
  • from eight different sources; the taille, the capitation, the two
  • vingtiemes, the gabelles, the aides, the traites, the domaine, and the
  • farm of tobacco. The live last are, in the greater part of the provinces,
  • under farm. The three first are everywhere levied by an administration,
  • under the immediate inspection and direction of government; and it is
  • universally acknowledged, that in proportion to what they take out of the
  • pockets of the people, they bring more into the treasury of the prince
  • than the other five, of which the administration is much more wasteful and
  • expensive.
  • The finances of France seem, in their present state, to admit of three
  • very obvious reformations. First, by abolishing the taille and the
  • capitation, and by increasing the number of the vingtiemes, so as to
  • produce an additional revenue equal to the amount of those other taxes,
  • the revenue of the crown might be preserved; the expense of collection
  • might be much diminished; the vexation of the inferior ranks of people,
  • which the taille and capitation occasion, might be entirely prevented; and
  • the superior ranks might not be more burdened than the greater part of
  • them are at present. The vingtieme, I have already observed, is a tax very
  • nearly of the same kind with what is called the land tax of England. The
  • burden of the taille, it is acknowledged, falls finally upon the
  • proprietors of land; and as the greater part of the capitation is assessed
  • upon those who are subject to the taille, at so much a-pound of that other
  • tax, the final payment of the greater part of it must likewise fall upon
  • the same order of people. Though the number of the vingtiemes, therefore,
  • was increased, so as to produce an additional revenue equal to the amount
  • of both those taxes, the superior ranks of people might not be more
  • burdened than they are at present; many individuals, no doubt, would, on
  • account of the great inequalities with which the taille is commonly
  • assessed upon the estates and tenants of different individuals. The
  • interest and opposition of such favoured subjects, are the obstacles most
  • likely to prevent this, or any other reformation of the same kind.
  • Secondly, by rendering the gabelle, the aides, the traites, the taxes upon
  • tobacco, all the different customs and excises, uniform in all the
  • different parts of the kingdom, those taxes might be levied at much less
  • expense, and the interior commerce of the kingdom might be rendered as
  • free as that of England. Thirdly, and lastly, by subjecting all those
  • taxes to an administration under the immediate inspection and direction or
  • government, the exorbitant profits of the farmers-general might be added
  • to the revenue of the state. The opposition arising from the private
  • interest of individuals, is likely to be as effectual for preventing the
  • two last as the first-mentioned scheme of reformation.
  • The French system of taxation seems, in every respect, inferior to the
  • British. In Great Britain, ten millions sterling are annually levied upon
  • less than eight millions of people, without its being possible to say that
  • any particular order is oppressed. From the Collections of the Abbé
  • Expilly, and the observations of the author of the Essay upon the
  • Legislation and Commerce of Corn, it appears probable that France,
  • including the provinces of Lorraine and Bar, contains about twenty-three
  • or twenty-four millions of people; three times the number, perhaps,
  • contained in Great Britain. The soil and climate of France are better than
  • those of Great Britain. The country has been much longer in a state of
  • improvement and cultivation, and is, upon that account, better stocked
  • with all those things which it requires a long time to raise up and
  • accumulate; such as great towns, and convenient and well-built houses,
  • both in town and country. With these advantages, it might be expected,
  • that in France a revenue of thirty millions might be levied for the
  • support of the state, with as little inconvenience as a revenue of ten
  • millions is in Great Britain. In 1765 and 1766, the whole revenue paid
  • into the treasury of France, according to the best, though, I acknowledge,
  • very imperfect accounts which I could get of it, usually run between 308
  • and 325 millions of livres; that is, it did not amount to fifteen millions
  • sterling; not the half of what might have been expected, had the people
  • contributed in the same proportion to their numbers as the people of Great
  • Britain. The people of France, however, it is generally acknowledged, are
  • much more oppressed by taxes than the people of Great Britain. France,
  • however, is certainly the great empire in Europe, which, after that of
  • Great Britain, enjoys the mildest and most indulgent government.
  • In Holland, the heavy taxes upon the necessaries of life have ruined, it
  • is said, their principal manufacturers, and are likely to discourage,
  • gradually, even their fisheries and their trade in ship-building. The
  • taxes upon the necessaries of life are inconsiderable in Great Britain,
  • and no manufacture has hitherto been ruined by them. The British taxes
  • which bear hardest on manufactures, are some duties upon the importation
  • of raw materials, particularly upon that of raw silk. The revenue of the
  • States-General and of the different cities, however, is said to amount to
  • more than five millions two hundred and fifty thousand pounds sterling;
  • and as the inhabitants of the United Provinces cannot well be supposed to
  • amount to more than a third part of those of Great Britain, they must, in
  • proportion to their number, be much more heavily taxed.
  • After all the proper subjects of taxation have been exhausted, if the
  • exigencies of the state still continue to require new taxes, they must be
  • imposed upon improper ones. The taxes upon the necessaries of life,
  • therefore, may be no impeachment of the wisdom of that republic, which, in
  • order to acquire and to maintain its independency, has, in spite of its
  • meat frugality, been involved in such expensive wars as have obliged it to
  • contract great debts. The singular countries of Holland and Zealand,
  • besides, require a considerable expense even to preserve their existence,
  • or to prevent their being swallowed up by the sea, which must have
  • contributed to increase considerably the load of taxes in those two
  • provinces. The republican form of government seems to be the principal
  • support of the present grandeur of Holland. The owners of great capitals,
  • the great mercantile families, have generally either some direct share, or
  • some indirect influence, in the administration of that government. For the
  • sake of the respect and authority which they derive from this situation,
  • they are willing to live in a country where their capital, if they employ
  • it themselves, will bring them less profit, and if they lend it to
  • another, less interest; and where the very moderate revenue which they can
  • draw from it will purchase less of the necessaries and conveniencies of
  • life than in any other part of Europe. The residence of such wealthy
  • people necessarily keeps alive, in spite of all disadvantages, a certain
  • degree of industry in the country. Any public calamity which should
  • destroy the republican form of government, which should throw the whole
  • administration into the hands of nobles and of soldiers, which should
  • annihilate altogether the importance of those wealthy merchants, would
  • soon render it disagreeable to them to live in a country where they were
  • no longer likely to be much respected. They would remove both their
  • residence and their capital to some other country, and the industry and
  • commerce of Holland would soon follow the capitals which supported them.
  • CHAPTER III.
  • OF PUBLIC DEBTS.
  • In that rude state of society which precedes the extension of commerce and
  • the improvement of manufactures; when those expensive luxuries, which
  • commerce and manufactures can alone introduce, are altogether unknown; the
  • person who possesses a large revenue, I have endeavoured to show in the
  • third book of this Inquiry, can spend or enjoy that revenue in no other
  • way than by maintaining nearly as many people as it can maintain. A large
  • revenue may at all times be said to consist in the command of a large
  • quantity of the necessaries of life. In that rude state of things, it is
  • commonly paid in a large quantity of those necessaries, in the materials
  • of plain food and coarse clothing, in corn and cattle, in wool and raw
  • hides. When neither commerce nor manufactures furnish any thing for which
  • the owner can exchange the greater part of those materials which are over
  • and above his own consumption, he can do nothing with the surplus, but
  • feed and clothe nearly as many people as it will feed and clothe. A
  • hospitality in which there is no luxury, and a liberality in which there
  • is no ostentation, occasion, in this situation of things, the principal
  • expenses of the rich and the great. But these I have likewise endeavoured
  • to show, in the same book, are expenses by which people are not very apt
  • to ruin themselves. There is not, perhaps, any selfish pleasure so
  • frivolous, of which the pursuit has not sometimes ruined even sensible
  • men. A passion for cock-fighting has ruined many. But the instances, I
  • believe, are not very numerous, of people who have been ruined by a
  • hospitality or liberality of this kind; though the hospitality of luxury,
  • and the liberality of ostentation have ruined many. Among our feudal
  • ancestors, the long time during which estates used to continue in the same
  • family, sufficiently demonstrates the general disposition of people to
  • live within their income. Though the rustic hospitality, constantly
  • exercised by the great landholders, may not, to us in the present times,
  • seem consistent with that order which we are apt to consider as
  • inseparably connected with good economy; yet we must certainly allow them
  • to have been at least so far frugal, as not commonly to have spent their
  • whole income. A part of their wool and raw hides, they had generally an
  • opportunity of selling for money. Some part of this money, perhaps, they
  • spent in purchasing the few objects of vanity and luxury, with which the
  • circumstances of the times could furnish them; but some part of it they
  • seem commonly to have hoarded. They could not well, indeed, do any thing
  • else but hoard whatever money they saved. To trade, was disgraceful to a
  • gentleman; and to lend money at interest, which at that time was
  • considered as usury, and prohibited bylaw, would have been still more so.
  • In those times of violence and disorder, besides, it was convenient to
  • have a hoard of money at hand, that in case they should be driven from
  • their own home, they might have something of known value to carry with
  • them to some place of safety. The same violence which made it convenient
  • to hoard, made it equally convenient to conceal the hoard. The frequency
  • of treasure-trove, or of treasure found, of which no owner was known,
  • sufficiently demonstrates the frequency, in those times, both of hoarding
  • and of concealing the hoard. Treasure-trove was then considered as an
  • important branch of the revenue of the sovereign. All the treasure-trove
  • of the kingdom would scarce, perhaps, in the present times, make an
  • important branch of the revenue of a private gentleman of a good estate.
  • The same disposition, to save and to hoard, prevailed in the sovereign, as
  • well as in the subjects. Among nations, to whom commerce and manufacture
  • are little known, the sovereign, it has already been observed in the
  • Fourth book, is in a situation which naturally disposes him to the
  • parsimony requisite for accumulation. In that situation, the expense, even
  • of a sovereign, cannot be directed by that vanity which delights in the
  • gaudy finery of a court. The ignorance of the times affords but few of the
  • trinkets in which that finery consists. Standing armies are not then
  • necessary; so that the expense, even of a sovereign, like that of any
  • other great lord can be employed in scarce any thing but bounty to his
  • tenants, and hospitality to his retainers. But bounty and hospitality very
  • seldom lead to extravagance; though vanity almost always does. All the
  • ancient sovereigns of Europe, accordingly, it has already been observed,
  • had treasures. Every Tartar chief, in the present times, is said to have
  • one.
  • In a commercial country, abounding with every sort of expensive luxury,
  • the sovereign, in the same manner as almost all the great proprietors in
  • his dominions, naturally spends a great part of his revenue in purchasing
  • those luxuries. His own and the neighbouring countries supply him
  • abundantly with all the costly trinkets which compose the splendid, but
  • insignificant, pageantry of a court. For the sake of an inferior pageantry
  • of the same kind, his nobles dismiss their retainers, make their tenants
  • independent, and become gradually themselves as insignificant as the
  • greater part of the wealthy burghers in his dominions. The same frivolous
  • passions, which influence their conduct, influence his. How can it be
  • supposed that he should be the only rich man in his dominions who is
  • insensible to pleasures of this kind? If he does not, what he is very
  • likely to do, spend upon those pleasures so great a part of his revenue as
  • to debilitate very much the defensive power of the state, it cannot well
  • be expected that he should not spend upon them all that part of it which
  • is over and above what is necessary for supporting that defensive power.
  • His ordinary expense becomes equal to his ordinary revenue, and it is well
  • if it does not frequently exceed it. The amassing of treasure can no
  • longer be expected; and when extraordinary exigencies require
  • extraordinary expenses, he must necessarily call upon his subjects for an
  • extraordinary aid. The present and the late king of Prussia are the only
  • great princes of Europe, who, since the death of Henry IV. of France, in
  • 1610, are supposed to have amassed any considerable treasure. The
  • parsimony which leads to accumulation has become almost as rare in
  • republican as in monarchical governments. The Italian republics, the
  • United Provinces of the Netherlands, are all in debt. The canton of Berne
  • is the single republic in Europe which has amassed any considerable
  • treasure. The other Swiss republics have not. The taste for some sort of
  • pageantry, for splendid buildings, at least, and other public ornaments,
  • frequently prevails as much in the apparently sober senate-house of a
  • little republic, as in the dissipated court of the greatest king.
  • The want of parsimony, in time of peace, imposes the necessity of
  • contracting debt in time of war. When war comes, there is no money in the
  • treasury, but what is necessary for carrying on the ordinary expense of
  • the peace establishment. In war, an establishment of three or four times
  • that expense becomes necessary for the defence of the state; and
  • consequently, a revenue three or four times greater than the peace
  • revenue. Supposing that the sovereign should have, what he scarce ever
  • has, the immediate means of augmenting his revenue in proportion to the
  • augmentation of his expense; yet still the produce of the taxes, from
  • which this increase of revenue must be drawn, will not begin to come into
  • the treasury, till perhaps ten or twelve months after they are imposed.
  • But the moment in which war begins, or rather the moment in which it
  • appears likely to begin, the army must be augmented, the fleet must be
  • fitted out, the garrisoned towns must be put into a posture of defence;
  • that army, that fleet, those garrisoned towns, must be furnished with
  • arms, ammunition, and provisions. An immediate and great expense must be
  • incurred in that moment of immediate danger, which will not wait for the
  • gradual and slow returns of the new taxes. In this exigency, government
  • can have no other resource but in borrowing.
  • The same commercial state of society which, by the operation of moral
  • causes, brings government in this manner into the necessity of borrowing,
  • produces in the subjects both an ability and an inclination to lend. If it
  • commonly brings along with it the necessity of borrowing, it likewise
  • brings with it the facility of doing so.
  • A country abounding with merchants and manufacturers, necessarily abounds
  • with a set of people through whose hands, not only their own capitals, but
  • the capitals of all those who either lend them money, or trust them with
  • goods, pass as frequently, or more frequently, than the revenue of a
  • private man, who, without trade or business, lives upon his income, passes
  • through his hands. The revenue of such a man can regularly pass through
  • his hands only once in a year. But the whole amount of the capital and
  • credit of a merchant, who deals in a trade of which the returns are very
  • quick, may sometimes pass through his hands two, three, or four times in a
  • year. A country abounding with merchants and manufacturers, therefore,
  • necessarily abounds with a set of people, who have it at all times in
  • their power to advance, if they chuse to do so, a very large sum of money
  • to government. Hence the ability in the subjects of a commercial state to
  • lend.
  • Commerce and manufactures can seldom flourish long in any state which does
  • not enjoy a regular administration of justice; in which the people do not
  • feel themselves secure in the possession of their property; in which the
  • faith of contracts is not supported by law; and in which the authority of
  • the state is not supposed to be regularly employed in enforcing the
  • payment of debts from all those who are able to pay. Commerce and
  • manufactures, in short, can seldom flourish in any state, in which there
  • is not a certain degree of confidence in the justice of government. The
  • same confidence which disposes great merchants and manufacturers upon
  • ordinary occasions, to trust their property to the protection of a
  • particular government, disposes them, upon extraordinary occasions, to
  • trust that government with the use of their property. By lending money to
  • government, they do not even for a moment diminish their ability to carry
  • on their trade and manufactures; on the contrary, they commonly augment
  • it. The necessities of the state render government, upon most occasions
  • willing to borrow upon terms extremely advantageous to the lender. The
  • security which it grants to the original creditor, is made transferable to
  • any other creditor; and from the universal confidence in the justice of
  • the state, generally sells in the market for more than was originally paid
  • for it. The merchant or monied man makes money by lending money to
  • government, and instead of diminishing, increases his trading capital. He
  • generally considers it as a favour, therefore, when the administration
  • admits him to a share in the first subscription for a new loan. Hence the
  • inclination or willingness in the subjects of a commercial state to lend.
  • The government of such a state is very apt to repose itself upon this
  • ability and willingness of its subjects to lend it their money on
  • extraordinary occasions. It foresees the facility of borrowing, and
  • therefore dispenses itself from the duty of saving.
  • In a rude state of society, there are no great mercantile or manufacturing
  • capitals. The individuals, who hoard whatever money they can save, and who
  • conceal their hoard, do so from a distrust of the justice of government;
  • from a fear, that if it was known that they had a hoard, and where that
  • hoard was to be found, they would quickly be plundered. In such a state of
  • things, few people would be able, and nobody would be willing to lend
  • their money to government on extraordinary exigencies. The sovereign feels
  • that he must provide for such exigencies by saving, because he foresees
  • the absolute impossibility of borrowing. This foresight increases still
  • further his natural disposition to save.
  • The progress of the enormous debts which at present oppress, and will in
  • the long-run probably ruin, all the great nations of Europe, has been
  • pretty uniform. Nations, like private men, have generally begun to borrow
  • upon what may be called personal credit, without assigning or mortgaging
  • any particular fund for the payment of the debt; and when this resource
  • has failed them, they have gone on to borrow upon assignments or mortgages
  • of particular funds.
  • What is called the unfunded debt of Great Britain, is contracted in the
  • former of those two ways. It consists partly in a debt which bears, or is
  • supposed to bear, no interest, and which resembles the debts that a
  • private man contracts upon account; and partly in a debt which bears
  • interest, and which resembles what a private man contracts upon his bill
  • or promissory-note. The debts which are due, either for extraordinary
  • services, or for services either not provided for, or not paid at the time
  • when they are performed; part of the extraordinaries of the army, navy,
  • and ordnance, the arrears of subsidies to foreign princes, those of
  • seamen’s wages, etc. usually constitute a debt of the first kind. Navy and
  • exchequer bills, which are issued sometimes in payment of a part of such
  • debts, and sometimes for other purposes, constitute a debt of the second
  • kind; exchequer bills bearing interest from the day on which they are
  • issued, and navy bills six months after they are issued. The bank of
  • England, either by voluntarily discounting those bills at their current
  • value, or by agreeing with government for certain considerations to
  • circulate exchequer bills, that is, to receive them at par, paying the
  • interest which happens to be due upon them, keeps up their value, and
  • facilitates their circulation, and thereby frequently enables government
  • to contract a very large debt of this kind. In France, where there is no
  • bank, the state bills (billets d’etat {See Examen des Reflections
  • Politiques sur les Finances.}) have sometimes sold at sixty and seventy
  • per cent. discount. During the great recoinage in king William’s time,
  • when the bank of England thought proper to put a stop to its usual
  • transactions, exchequer bills and tallies are said to have sold from
  • twenty-five to sixty per cent. discount; owing partly, no doubt, to the
  • supposed instability of the new government established by the Revolution,
  • but partly, too, to the want of the support of the bank of England.
  • When this resource is exhausted, and it becomes necessary, in order to
  • raise money, to assign or mortgage some particular branch of the public
  • revenue for the payment of the debt, government has, upon different
  • occasions, done this in two different ways. Sometimes it has made this
  • assignment or mortgage for a short period of time only, a year, or a few
  • years, for example; and sometimes for perpetuity. In the one case, the
  • fund was supposed sufficient to pay, within the limited time, both
  • principal and interest of the money borrowed. In the other, it was
  • supposed sufficient to pay the interest only, or a perpetual annuity
  • equivalent to the interest, government being at liberty to redeem, at any
  • time, this annuity, upon paying back the principal sum borrowed. When
  • money was raised in the one way, it was said to be raised by anticipation;
  • when in the other, by perpetual funding, or, more shortly, by funding.
  • In Great Britain, the annual land and malt taxes are regularly anticipated
  • every year, by virtue of a borrowing clause constantly inserted into the
  • acts which impose them. The bank of England generally advances at an
  • interest, which, since the Revolution, has varied from eight to three per
  • cent., the sums of which those taxes are granted, and receives payment as
  • their produce gradually comes in. If there is a deficiency, which there
  • always is, it is provided for in the supplies of the ensuing year. The
  • only considerable branch of the public revenue which yet remains
  • unmortgaged, is thus regularly spent before it comes in. Like an
  • improvident spendthrift, whose pressing occasions will not allow him to
  • wait for the regular payment of his revenue, the state is in the constant
  • practice of borrowing of its own factors and agents, and of paying
  • interest for the use of its own money.
  • In the reign of king William, and during a great part of that of queen
  • Anne, before we had become so familiar as we are now with the practice of
  • perpetual funding, the greater part of the new taxes were imposed but for
  • a short period of time (for four, five, six, or seven years only), and a
  • great part of the grants of every year consisted in loans upon
  • anticipations of the produce of those taxes. The produce being frequently
  • insufficient for paying, within the limited term, the principal and
  • interest of the money borrowed, deficiencies arose; to make good which, it
  • became necessary to prolong the term.
  • In 1697, by the 8th of William III., c. 20, the deficiencies of several
  • taxes were charged upon what was then called the first general mortgage or
  • fund, consisting of a prolongation to the first of August 1706, of several
  • different taxes, which would have expired within a shorter term, and of
  • which the produce was accumulated into one general fund. The deficiencies
  • charged upon this prolonged term amounted to £5,160,459: 14: 9½.
  • In 1701, those duties, with some others, were still further prolonged, for
  • the like purposes, till the first of August 1710, and were called the
  • second general mortgage or fund. The deficiencies charged upon it amounted
  • to £2,055,999: 7: 11½.
  • In 1707, those duties were still further prolonged, as a fund for new
  • loans, to the first of August 1712, and were called the third general
  • mortgage or fund. The sum borrowed upon it was £983,254:11:9¼.
  • In 1708, those duties were all (except the old subsidy of tonnage and
  • poundage, of which one moiety only was made a part of this fund, and a
  • duty upon the importation of Scotch linen, which had been taken off by the
  • articles of union) still further continued, as a fund for new loans, to
  • the first of August 1714, and were called the fourth general mortgage or
  • fund. The sum borrowed upon it was £925,176:9:2¼.
  • In 1709, those duties were all ( except the old subsidy of tonnage and
  • poundage, which was now left out of this fund altogether ) still further
  • continued, for the same purpose, to the first of August 1716, and were
  • called the fifth general mortgage or fund. The sum borrowed upon it was
  • £922,029:6s.
  • In 1710, those duties were again prolonged to the first of August 1720,
  • and were called the sixth general mortgage or fund. The sum borrowed upon
  • it was £1,296,552:9:11¾.
  • In 1711, the same duties (which at this time were thus subject to four
  • different anticipations), together with several others, were continued for
  • ever, and made a fund for paying the interest of the capital of the
  • South-sea company, which had that year advanced to government, for paying
  • debts, and making good deficiencies, the sum of £9,177,967:15:4d, the
  • greatest loan which at that time had ever been made.
  • Before this period, the principal, so far as I have been able to observe,
  • the only taxes, which, in order to pay the interest of a debt, had been
  • imposed for perpetuity, were those for paying the interest of the money
  • which had been advanced to government by the bank and East-India company,
  • and of what it was expected would be advanced, but which was never
  • advanced, by a projected land bank. The bank fund at this time amounted to
  • £3,375,027:17:10½, for which was paid an annuity or interest of
  • £206,501:15:5d. The East-India fund amounted to £3,200,000, for which was
  • paid an annuity or interest of £160,000; the bank fund being at six per
  • cent., the East-India fund at five per cent. interest.
  • In 1715, by the first of George I., c. 12, the different taxes which had
  • been mortgaged for paying the bank annuity, together with several others,
  • which, by this act, were likewise rendered perpetual, were accumulated
  • into one common fund, called the aggregate fund, which was charged not
  • only with the payment of the bank annuity, but with several other
  • annuities and burdens of different kinds. This fund was afterwards
  • augmented by the third of George I., c.8., and by the fifth of George I.,
  • c. 3, and the different duties which were then added to it were likewise
  • rendered perpetual.
  • In 1717, by the third of George I., c. 7, several other taxes were
  • rendered perpetual, and accumulated into another common fund, called the
  • general fund, for the payment of certain annuities, amounting in the whole
  • to £724,849:6:10½.
  • In consequence of those different acts, the greater part of the taxes,
  • which before had been anticipated only for a short term of years were
  • rendered perpetual, as a fund for paying, not the capital, but the
  • interest only, of the money which had been borrowed upon them by different
  • successive anticipations.
  • Had money never been raised but by anticipation, the course of a few years
  • would have liberated the public revenue, without any other attention of
  • government besides that of not overloading the fund, by charging it with
  • more debt than it could pay within the limited term, and not of
  • anticipating a second time before the expiration of the first
  • anticipation. But the greater part of European governments have been
  • incapable of those attentions. They have frequently overloaded the fund,
  • even upon the first anticipation; and when this happened not to be the
  • case, they have generally taken care to overload it, by anticipating a
  • second and a third time, before the expiration of the first anticipation.
  • The fund becoming in this manner altogether insufficient for paying both
  • principal and interest of the money borrowed upon it, it became necessary
  • to charge it with the interest only, or a perpetual annuity equal to the
  • interest; and such improvident anticipations necessarily gave birth to the
  • more ruinous practice of perpetual funding. But though this practice
  • necessarily puts off the liberation of the public revenue from a fixed
  • period, to one so indefinite that it is not very likely ever to arrive;
  • yet, as a greater sum can, in all cases, be raised by this new practice
  • than by the old one of anticipation, the former, when men have once become
  • familiar with it, has, in the great exigencies of the state, been
  • universally preferred to the latter. To relieve the present exigency, is
  • always the object which principally interests those immediately concerned
  • in the administration of public affairs. The future liberation of the
  • public revenue they leave to the care of posterity.
  • During the reign of queen Anne, the market rate of interest had fallen
  • from six to five per cent.; and, in the twelfth year of her reign, five
  • per cent. was declared to be the highest rate which could lawfully be
  • taken for money borrowed upon private security. Soon after the greater
  • part of the temporary taxes of Great Britain had been rendered perpetual,
  • and distributed into the aggregate, South-sea, and general funds, the
  • creditors of the public, like those of private persons, were induced to
  • accept of five per cent. for the interest of their money, which occasioned
  • a saving of one per cent. upon the capital of the greater part or the
  • debts which had been thus funded for perpetuity, or of one-sixth of the
  • greater part of the annuities which were paid out of the three great funds
  • above mentioned. This saving left a considerable surplus in the produce of
  • the different taxes which had been accumulated into those funds, over and
  • above what was necessary for paying the annuities which were now charged
  • upon them, and laid the foundation of what has since been called the
  • sinking fund. In 1717, it amounted to £523,454:7:7½. In 1727, the interest
  • of the greater part of the public debts was still further reduced to four
  • per cent.; and, in 1753 and 1757, to three and a-half, and three per
  • cent., which reductions still further augmented the sinking fund.
  • A sinking fund, though instituted for the payment of old, facilitates very
  • much the contracting of new debts. It is a subsidiary fund, always at
  • hand, to be mortgaged in aid of any other doubtful fund, upon which money
  • is proposed to be raised in any exigency of the state. Whether the sinking
  • fund of Great Britain has been more frequently applied to the one or to
  • other of those two purposes, will sufficiently appear by and by.
  • Besides those two methods of borrowing, by anticipations and by a
  • perpetual funding, there are two other methods, which hold a sort of
  • middle place between them; these are, that of borrowing upon annuities for
  • terms of years, and that of borrowing upon annuities for lives.
  • During the reigns of king William and queen Anne, large sums were
  • frequently borrowed upon annuities for terms of years, which were
  • sometimes longer and sometimes shorter. In 1695, an act was passed for
  • borrowing one million upon an annuity of fourteen per cent., or £140,000
  • a-year, for sixteen years. In 1691, an act was passed for borrowing a
  • million upon annuities for lives, upon terms which, in the present times,
  • would appear very advantageous; but the subscription was not filled up. In
  • the following year, the deficiency was made good, by borrowing upon
  • annuities for lives, at fourteen per cent. or a little more than seven
  • years purchase. In 1695, the persons who had purchased those annuities
  • were allowed to exchange them for others of ninety-six years, upon paying
  • into the exchequer sixty-three pounds in the hundred; that is, the
  • difference between fourteen per cent. for life, and fourteen per cent. for
  • ninety-six years, was sold for sixty-three pounds, or for four and a-half
  • years purchase. Such was the supposed instability of government, that even
  • these terms procured few purchasers. In the reign of queen Anne, money
  • was, upon different occasions, borrowed both upon annuities for lives, and
  • upon annuities for terms of thirty-two, of eighty-nine, of ninety-eight,
  • and of ninety-nine years. In 1719, the proprietors of the annuities for
  • thirty-two years were induced to accept, in lieu of them, South-sea stock
  • to the amount of eleven and a-half years purchase of the annuities,
  • together with an additional quantity of stock, equal to the arrears which
  • happened then to be due upon them. In 1720, the greater part of the other
  • annuities for terms of years, both long and short, were subscribed into
  • the same fund. The long annuities, at that time, amounted to £666,821:
  • 8:3½ a-year. On the 5th of January 1775, the remainder of them, or what
  • was not subscribed at that time, amounted only to £136,453:12:8d.
  • During the two wars which began in 1739 and in 1755, little money was
  • borrowed, either upon annuities for terms of years, or upon those for
  • lives. An annuity for ninety-eight or ninety-nine years, however, is worth
  • nearly as much as a perpetuity, and should therefore, one might think, be
  • a fund for borrowing nearly as much. But those who, in order to make
  • family settlements, and to provide for remote futurity, buy into the
  • public stocks, would not care to purchase into one of which the value was
  • continually diminishing; and such people make a very considerable
  • proportion, both of the proprietors and purchasers of stock. An annuity
  • for a long term of years, therefore, though its intrinsic value may be
  • very nearly the same with that of a perpetual annuity, will not find
  • nearly the same number of purchasers. The subscribers to a new loan, who
  • mean generally to sell their subscription as soon as possible, prefer
  • greatly a perpetual annuity, redeemable by parliament, to an irredeemable
  • annuity, for a long term of years, of only equal amount. The value of the
  • former may be supposed always the same, or very nearly the same; and it
  • makes, therefore, a more convenient transferable stock than the latter.
  • During the two last-mentioned wars, annuities, either for terms of years
  • or for lives, were seldom granted, but as premiums to the subscribers of a
  • new loan, over and above the redeemable annuity or interest, upon the
  • credit of which the loan was supposed to be made. They were granted, not
  • as the proper fund upon which the money was borrowed, but as an additional
  • encouragement to the lender.
  • Annuities for lives have occasionally been granted in two different ways;
  • either upon separate lives, or upon lots of lives, which, in French, are
  • called tontines, from the name of their inventor. When annuities are
  • granted upon separate lives, the death of every individual annuitant
  • disburdens the public revenue, so far as it was affected by his annuity.
  • When annuities are granted upon tontines, the liberation of the public
  • revenue does not commence till the death of all the annuitants
  • comprehended in one lot, which may sometimes consist of twenty or thirty
  • persons, of whom the survivors succeed to the annuities of all those who
  • die before them; the last survivor succeeding to the annuities of the
  • whole lot. Upon the same revenue, more money can always be raised by
  • tontines than by annuities for separate lives. An annuity, with a right of
  • survivorship, is really worth more than an equal annuity for a separate
  • life; and, from the confidence which every man naturally has in his own
  • good fortune, the principle upon which is founded the success of all
  • lotteries, such an annuity generally sells for something more than it is
  • worth. In countries where it is usual for government to raise money by
  • granting annuities, tontines are, upon this account, generally preferred
  • to annuities for separate lives. The expedient which will raise most
  • money, is almost always preferred to that which is likely to bring about,
  • in the speediest manner, the liberation of the public revenue.
  • In France, a much greater proportion of the public debts consists in
  • annuities for lives than in England. According to a memoir presented by
  • the parliament of Bourdeaux to the king, in 1764, the whole public debt of
  • France is estimated at twenty-four hundred millions of livres; of which
  • the capital, for which annuities for lives had been granted, is supposed
  • to amount to three hundred millions, the eighth part of the whole public
  • debt. The annuities themselves are computed to amount to thirty millions
  • a-year, the fourth part of one hundred and twenty millions, the supposed
  • interest of that whole debt. These estimations, I know very well, are not
  • exact; but having been presented by so very respectable a body as
  • approximations to the truth, they may, I apprehend, be considered as such.
  • It is not the different degrees of anxiety in the two governments of
  • France and England for the liberation of the public revenue, which
  • occasions this difference in their respective modes of borrowing; it
  • arises altogether from the different views and interests of the lenders.
  • In England, the seat of government being in the greatest mercantile city
  • in the world, the merchants are generally the people who advance money to
  • government. By advancing it, they do not mean to diminish, but, on the
  • contrary, to increase their mercantile capitals; and unless they expected
  • to sell, with some profit, their share in the subscription for a new loan,
  • they never would subscribe. But if, by advancing their money, they were to
  • purchase, instead of perpetual annuities, annuities for lives only,
  • whether their own or those of other people, they would not always be so
  • likely to sell them with a profit. Annuities upon their own lives they
  • would always sell with loss; because no man will give for an annuity upon
  • the life of another, whose age and state of health are nearly the same
  • with his own, the same price which he would give for one upon his own. An
  • annuity upon the life of a third person, indeed, is, no doubt, of equal
  • value to the buyer and the seller; but its real value begins to diminish
  • from the moment it is granted, and continues to do so, more and more, as
  • long as it subsists. It can never, therefore, make so convenient a
  • transferable stock as a perpetual annuity, of which the real value may be
  • supposed always the same, or very nearly the same.
  • In France, the seat of government not being in a great mercantile city,
  • merchants do not make so great a proportion of the people who advance
  • money to government. The people concerned in the finances, the
  • farmers-general, the receivers of the taxes which are not in farm, the
  • court-bankers, etc. make the greater part of those who advance their money
  • in all public exigencies. Such people are commonly men of mean birth, but
  • of great wealth, and frequently of great pride. They are too proud to
  • marry their equals, and women of quality disdain to marry them. They
  • frequently resolve, therefore, to live bachelors; and having neither any
  • families of their own, nor much regard for those of their relations, whom
  • they are not always very fond of acknowledging, they desire only to live
  • in splendour during their own time, and are not unwilling that their
  • fortune should end with themselves. The number of rich people, besides,
  • who are either averse to marry, or whose condition of life renders it
  • either improper or inconvenient for them to do so, is much greater in
  • France than in England. To such people, who have little or no care for
  • posterity, nothing can be more convenient than to exchange their capital
  • for a revenue, which is to last just as long, and no longer, than they
  • wish it to do.
  • The ordinary expense of the greater part of modern governments, in time of
  • peace, being equal, or nearly equal, to their ordinary revenue, when war
  • comes, they are both unwilling and unable to increase their revenue in
  • proportion to the increase of their expense. They are unwilling, for fear
  • of offending the people, who, by so great and so sudden an increase of
  • taxes, would soon be disgusted with the war; and they are unable, from not
  • well knowing what taxes would be sufficient to produce the revenue wanted.
  • The facility of borrowing delivers them from the embarrassment which this
  • fear and inability would otherwise occasion. By means of borrowing, they
  • are enabled, with a very moderate increase of taxes, to raise, from year
  • to year, money sufficient for carrying on the war; and by the practice of
  • perpetual funding, they are enabled, with the smallest possible increase
  • of taxes, to raise annually the largest possible sum of money. In great
  • empires, the people who live in the capital, and in the provinces remote
  • from the scene of action, feel, many of them, scarce any inconveniency
  • from the war, but enjoy, at their ease, the amusement of reading in the
  • newspapers the exploits of their own fleets and armies. To them this
  • amusement compensates the small difference between the taxes which they
  • pay on account of the war, and those which they had been accustomed to pay
  • in time of peace. They are commonly dissatisfied with the return of peace,
  • which puts an end to their amusement, and to a thousand visionary hopes of
  • conquest and national glory, from a longer continuance of the war.
  • The return of peace, indeed, seldom relieves them from the greater part of
  • the taxes imposed during the war. These are mortgaged for the interest of
  • the debt contracted, in order to carry it on. If, over and above paying
  • the interest of this debt, and defraying the ordinary expense of
  • government, the old revenue, together with the new taxes, produce some
  • surplus revenue, it may, perhaps, be converted into a sinking fund for
  • paying off the debt. But, in the first place, this sinking fund, even
  • supposing it should be applied to no other purpose, is generally
  • altogether inadequate for paying, in the course of any period during which
  • it can reasonably be expected that peace should continue, the whole debt
  • contracted during the war; and, in the second place, this fund is almost
  • always applied to other purposes.
  • The new taxes were imposed for the sole purpose of paying the interest of
  • the money borrowed upon them. If they produce more, it is generally
  • something which was neither intended nor expected, and is, therefore,
  • seldom very considerable. Sinking funds have generally arisen, not so much
  • from any surplus of the taxes which was over and above what was necessary
  • for paying the interest or annuity originally charged upon them, as from a
  • subsequent reduction of that interest; that of Holland in 1655, and that
  • of the ecclesiastical state in 1685, were both formed in this manner.
  • Hence the usual insufficiency of such funds.
  • During the most profound peace, various events occur, which require an
  • extraordinary expense; and government finds it always more convenient to
  • defray this expense by misapplying the sinking fund, than by imposing a
  • new tax. Every new tax is immediately felt more or less by the people. It
  • occasions always some murmur, and meets with some opposition. The more
  • taxes may have been multiplied, the higher they may have been raised upon
  • every different subject of taxation; the more loudly the people complain
  • of every new tax, the more difficult it becomes, too, either to find out
  • new subjects of taxation, or to raise much higher the taxes already
  • imposed upon the old. A momentary suspension of the payment of debt is not
  • immediately felt by the people, and occasions neither murmur nor
  • complaint. To borrow of the sinking fund is always an obvious and easy
  • expedient for getting out of the present difficulty. The more the public
  • debts may have been accumulated, the more necessary it may have become to
  • study to reduce them; the more dangerous, the more ruinous it may be to
  • misapply any part of the sinking fund; the less likely is the public debt
  • to be reduced to any considerable degree, the more likely, the more
  • certainly, is the sinking fund to be misapplied towards defraying all the
  • extraordinary expenses which occur in time of peace. When a nation is
  • already overburdened with taxes, nothing but the necessities of a new war,
  • nothing but either the animosity of national vengeance, or the anxiety for
  • national security, can induce the people to submit, with tolerable
  • patience, to a new tax. Hence the usual misapplication of the sinking
  • fund.
  • In Great Britain, from the time that we had first recourse to the ruinous
  • expedient of perpetual funding, the reduction of the public debt, in time
  • of peace, has never borne any proportion to its accumulation in time of
  • war. It was in the war which began in 1668, and was concluded by the
  • treaty of Ryswick, in 1697, that the foundation of the present enormous
  • debt of Great Britain was first laid.
  • On the 31st of December 1697, the public debts of Great Britain, funded
  • and unfunded, amounted to £21,515,742:13:8½. A great part of those debts
  • had been contracted upon short anticipations, and some part upon annuities
  • for lives; so that, before the 31st of December 1701, in less than four
  • years, there had partly been paid off; and partly reverted to the public,
  • the sum of £5,121,041:12:0¾d; a greater reduction of the public debt than
  • has ever since been brought about in so short a period of time. The
  • remaining debt, therefore, amounted only to £16,394,701:1:7¼d.
  • In the war which began in 1702, and which was concluded by the treaty of
  • Utrecht, the public debts were still more accumulated. On the 31st of
  • December 1714, they amounted to £53,681,076:5:6½. The subscription into
  • the South-sea fund, of the short and long annuities, increased the capital
  • of the public debt; so that, on the 31st of December 1722, it amounted to
  • £55,282,978:1:3 5/6. The reduction of the debt began in 1723, and went on
  • so slowly, that, on the 31st of December 1739, during seventeen years-of
  • profound peace, the whole sum paid off was no more than £8,328,554:17:11
  • 3/12, the capital of the public debt, at that time, amounting to
  • £46,954,623:3:4 7/12.
  • The Spanish war, which began in 1739, and the French war which soon
  • followed it, occasioned a further increase of the debt, which, on the 31st
  • of December 1748, after the war had been concluded by the treaty of
  • Aix-la-Chapelle, amounted to £78,293,313:1:10¾. The most profound peace,
  • of 17 years continuance, had taken no more than £8,328,354, 17:11¼ from
  • it. A war, of less than nine years continuance, added £31,338,689:18: 6
  • 1/6 to it. {See James Postlethwaite’s History of the Public Revenue.}
  • During the administration of Mr. Pelham, the interest of the public debt
  • was reduced, or at least measures were taken for reducing it, from four to
  • three per cent.; the sinking fund was increased, and some part of the
  • public debt was paid off. In 1755, before the breaking out of the late
  • war, the funded debt of Great Britain amounted to £72,289,675. On the 5th
  • of January 1763, at the conclusion of the peace, the funded debt amounted
  • debt to £122,603,336:8:2¼. The unfunded debt has been stated at
  • £13,927,589:2:2. But the expense occasioned by the war did not end with
  • the conclusion of the peace; so that, though on the 5th of January 1764,
  • the funded debt was increased (partly by a new loan, and partly by funding
  • a part of the unfunded debt) to £129,586,789:10:1¾, there still remained
  • (according to the very well informed author of Considerations on the Trade
  • and Finances of Great Britain) an unfunded debt, which was brought to
  • account in that and the following year, of £9,975,017: 12:2 15/44d. In
  • 1764, therefore, the public debt of Great Britain, funded and unfunded
  • together, amounted, according to this author, to £139,561,807:2:4. The
  • annuities for lives, too, which had been granted as premiums to the
  • subscribers to the new loans in 1757, estimated at fourteen years
  • purchase, were valued at £472,500; and the annuities for long terms of
  • years, granted as premiums likewise, in 1761 and 1762, estimated at
  • twenty-seven and a-half years purchase, were valued at £6,826,875. During
  • a peace of about seven years continuance, the prudent and truly patriotic
  • administration of Mr. Pelham was not able to pay off an old debt of six
  • millions. During a war of nearly the same continuance, a new debt of more
  • than seventy-five millions was contracted.
  • On the 5th of January 1775, the funded debt of Great Britain amounted to
  • £124,996,086, 1:6¼d. The unfunded, exclusive of a large civil-list debt,
  • to £4,150,236:3:11 7/8. Both together, to £129,146,322:5:6. According to
  • this account, the whole debt paid off, during eleven years of profound
  • peace, amounted only to £10,415,476:16:9 7/8. Even this small reduction of
  • debt, however, has not been all made from the savings out of the ordinary
  • revenue of the state. Several extraneous sums, altogether independent of
  • that ordinary revenue, have contributed towards it. Amongst these we may
  • reckon an additional shilling in the pound land tax, for three years; the
  • two millions received from the East-India company, as indemnification for
  • their territorial acquisitions; and the one hundred and ten thousand
  • pounds received from the bank for the renewal of their charter. To these
  • must be added several other sums, which, as they arose out of the late
  • war, ought perhaps to be considered as deductions from the expenses of it.
  • The principal are,
  • The produce of French prizes.............. £690,449: 18: 9
  • Composition for French prisoners......... 670,000: 0: 0
  • What has been received from the sale
  • of the ceded islands......................... 95,500: 0: 0
  • Total, .....................................£1,455,949: 18: 9
  • If we add to this sum the balance of the earl of Chatham’s and Mr.
  • Calcraft’s accounts, and other army savings of the same kind, together
  • with what has been received from the bank, the East-India company, and the
  • additional shilling in the pound land tax, the whole must be a good deal
  • more than five millions. The debt, therefore, which, since the peace, has
  • been paid out of the savings from the ordinary revenue of the state, has
  • not, one year with another, amounted to half a million a-year. The sinking
  • fund has, no doubt, been considerably augmented since the peace, by the
  • debt which had been paid off, by the reduction of the redeemable four per
  • cents to three per cents, and by the annuities for lives which have fallen
  • in; and, if peace were to continue, a million, perhaps, might now be
  • annually spared out of it towards the discharge of the debt. Another
  • million, accordingly, was paid in the course of last year; but at the same
  • time, a large civil-list debt was left unpaid, and we are now involved in
  • a new war, which, in its progress, may prove as expensive as any of our
  • former wars. {It has proved more expensive than any one of our former
  • wars, and has involved us in an additional debt of more than one hundred
  • millions. During a profound peace of eleven years, little more than ten
  • millions of debt was paid; during a war of seven years, more than one
  • hundred millions was contracted.} The new debt which will probably be
  • contracted before the end of the next campaign, may, perhaps, be nearly
  • equal to all the old debt which has been paid off from the savings out of
  • the ordinary revenue of the state. It would be altogether chimerical,
  • therefore, to expect that the public debt should ever be completely
  • discharged, by any savings which are likely to be made from that ordinary
  • revenue as it stands at present.
  • The public funds of the different indebted nations of Europe, particularly
  • those of England, have, by one author, been represented as the
  • accumulation of a great capital, superadded to the other capital of the
  • country, by means of which its trade is extended, its manufactures are
  • multiplied, and its lands cultivated and improved, much beyond what they
  • could have been by means of that other capital only. He does not consider
  • that the capital which the first creditors of the public advanced to
  • government, was, from the moment in which he advanced it, a certain
  • portion of the annual produce, turned away from serving in the function of
  • a capital, to serve in that of a revenue; from maintaining productive
  • labourers, to maintain unproductive ones, and to be spent and wasted,
  • generally in the course of the year, without even the hope of any future
  • reproduction. In return for the capital which they advanced, they
  • obtained, indeed, an annuity of the public funds, in most cases, of more
  • than equal value. This annuity, no doubt, replaced to them their capital,
  • and enabled them to carry on their trade and business to the same, or,
  • perhaps, to a greater extent than before; that is, they were enabled,
  • either to borrow of other people a new capital, upon the credit of this
  • annuity or, by selling it, to get from other people a new capital of their
  • own, equal, or superior, to that which they had advanced to government.
  • This new capital, however, which they in this manner either bought or
  • borrowed of other people, must have existed in the country before, and
  • must have been employed, as all capitals are, in maintaining productive
  • labour. When it came into the hands of those who had advanced their money
  • to government, though it was, in some respects, a new capital to them, it
  • was not so to the country, but was only a capital withdrawn from certain
  • employments, in order to be turned towards others. Though it replaced to
  • them what they had advanced to government, it did not replace it to the
  • country. Had they not advanced this capital to government, there would
  • have been in the country two capitals, two portions of the annual produce,
  • instead of one, employed in maintaining productive labour.
  • When, for defraying the expense of government, a revenue is raised within
  • the year, from the produce of free or unmortgaged taxes, a certain portion
  • of the revenue of private people is only turned away from maintaining one
  • species of unproductive labour, towards maintaining another. Some part of
  • what they pay in those taxes, might, no doubt, have been accumulated into
  • capital, and consequently employed in maintaining productive labour; but
  • the greater part would probably have been spent, and consequently employed
  • in maintaining unproductive labour. The public expense, however, when
  • defrayed in this manner, no doubt hinders, more or less, the further
  • accumulation of new capital; but it does not necessarily occasion the
  • destruction of any actually-existing capital.
  • When the public expense is defrayed by funding, it is defrayed by the
  • annual destruction of some capital which had before existed in the
  • country; by the perversion of some portion of the annual produce which had
  • before been destined for the maintenance of productive labour, towards
  • that of unproductive labour. As in this case, however, the taxes are
  • lighter than they would have been, had a revenue sufficient for defraying
  • the same expense been raised within the year; the private revenue of
  • individuals is necessarily less burdened, and consequently their ability
  • to save and accumulate some part of that revenue into capital, is a good
  • deal less impaired. If the method of funding destroys more old capital,
  • it, at the same time, hinders less the accumulation or acquisition of new
  • capital, than that of defraying the public expense by a revenue raised
  • within the year. Under the system of funding, the frugality and industry
  • of private people can more easily repair the breaches which the waste and
  • extravagance of government may occasionally make in the general capital of
  • the society.
  • It is only during the continuance of war, however, that the system of
  • funding has this advantage over the other system. Were the expense of war
  • to be defrayed always by a revenue raised within the year, the taxes from
  • which that extraordinary revenue was drawn would last no longer than the
  • war. The ability of private people to accumulate, though less during the
  • war, would have been greater during the peace, than under the system of
  • funding. War would not necessarily have occasioned the destruction of any
  • old capitals, and peace would have occasioned the accumulation of many
  • more new. Wars would, in general, be more speedily concluded, and less
  • wantonly undertaken. The people feeling, during continuance of war, the
  • complete burden of it, would soon grow weary of it; and government, in
  • order to humour them, would not be under the necessity of carrying it on
  • longer than it was necessary to do so. The foresight of the heavy and
  • unavoidable burdens of war would hinder the people from wantonly calling
  • for it when there was no real or solid interest to fight for. The seasons
  • during which the ability of private people to accumulate was somewhat
  • impaired, would occur more rarely, and be of shorter continuance. Those,
  • on the contrary, during which that ability was in the highest vigour would
  • be of much longer duration than they can well be under the system of
  • funding.
  • When funding, besides, has made a certain progress, the multiplication of
  • taxes which it brings along with it, sometimes impairs as much the ability
  • of private people to accumulate, even in time of peace, as the other
  • system would in time of war. The peace revenue of Great Britain amounts at
  • present to more than ten millions a-year. If free and unmortgaged, it
  • might be sufficient, with proper management, and without contracting a
  • shilling of new debt, to carry on the most vigorous war. The private
  • revenue of the inhabitants of Great Britain is at present as much
  • incumbered in time of peace, their ability to accumulate is as much
  • impaired, as it would have been in the time of the most expensive war, had
  • the pernicious system of funding never been adopted.
  • In the payment of the interest of the public debt, it has been said, it is
  • the right hand which pays the left. The money does not go out of the
  • country. It is only a part of the revenue of one set of the inhabitants
  • which is transferred to another; and the nation is not a farthing the
  • poorer. This apology is founded altogether in the sophistry of the
  • mercantile system; and, after the long examination which I have already
  • bestowed upon that system, it may, perhaps, be unnecessary to say anything
  • further about it. It supposes, besides, that the whole public debt is
  • owing to the inhabitants of the country, which happens not to be true; the
  • Dutch, as well as several other foreign nations, having a very
  • considerable share in our public funds. But though the whole debt were
  • owing to the inhabitants of the country, it would not, upon that account,
  • be less pernicious.
  • Land and capital stock are the two original sources of all revenue, both
  • private and public. Capital stock pays the wages of productive labour,
  • whether employed in agriculture, manufactures, or commerce. The management
  • of those two original sources of revenue belongs to two different sets of
  • people; the proprietors of land, and the owners or employers of capital
  • stock.
  • The proprietor of land is interested, for the sake of his own revenue, to
  • keep his estate in as good condition as he can, by building and repairing
  • his tenants houses, by making and maintaining the necessary drains and
  • inclosures, and all those other expensive improvements which it properly
  • belongs to the landlord to make and maintain. But, by different land
  • taxes, the revenue of the landlord may be so much diminished, and, by
  • different duties upon the necessaries and conveniencies of life, that
  • diminished revenue may be rendered of so little real value, that he may
  • find himself altogether unable to make or maintain those expensive
  • improvements. When the landlord, however, ceases to do his part, it is
  • altogether impossible that the tenant should continue to do his. As the
  • distress of the landlord increases, the agriculture of the country must
  • necessarily decline.
  • When, by different taxes upon the necessaries and conveniencies of life,
  • the owners and employers of capital stock find, that whatever revenue they
  • derive from it, will not, in a particular country, purchase the same
  • quantity of those necessaries and conveniencies which an equal revenue
  • would in almost any other, they will be disposed to remove to some other.
  • And when, in order to raise those taxes, all or the greater part of
  • merchants and manufacturers, that is, all or the greater part of the
  • employers of great capitals, come to be continually exposed to the
  • mortifying and vexatious visits of the tax-gatherers, this disposition to
  • remove will soon be changed into an actual removing. The industry of the
  • country will necessarily fall with the removal of the capital which
  • supported it, and the ruin of trade and manufactures will follow the
  • declension of agriculture.
  • To transfer from the owners of those two great sources of revenue, land,
  • and capital stock, from the persons immediately interested in the good
  • condition of every particular portion of land, and in the good management
  • of every particular portion of capital stock, to another set of persons
  • (the creditors of the public, who have no such particular interest ), the
  • greater part of the revenue arising from either, must, in the long-run,
  • occasion both the neglect of land, and the waste or removal of capital
  • stock. A creditor of the public has, no doubt, a general interest in the
  • prosperity of the agriculture, manufactures, and commerce of the country;
  • and consequently in the good condition of its land, and in the good
  • management of its capital stock. Should there be any general failure or
  • declension in any of these things, the produce of the different taxes
  • might no longer be sufficient to pay him the annuity or interest which is
  • due to him. But a creditor of the public, considered merely as such, has
  • no interest in the good condition of any particular portion of land, or in
  • the good management of any particular portion of capital stock. As a
  • creditor of the public, he has no knowledge of any such particular
  • portion. He has no inspection of it. He can have no care about it. Its
  • ruin may in some cases be unknown to him, and cannot directly affect him.
  • The practice of funding has gradually enfeebled every state which has
  • adopted it. The Italian republics seem to have begun it. Genoa and Venice,
  • the only two remaining which can pretend to an independent existence, have
  • both been enfeebled by it. Spain seems to have learned the practice from
  • the Italian republics, and (its taxes being probably less judicious than
  • theirs) it has, in proportion to its natural strength, been-still more
  • enfeebled. The debts of Spain are of very old standing. It was deeply in
  • debt before the end of the sixteenth century, about a hundred years before
  • England owed a shilling. France, notwithstanding all its natural
  • resources, languishes under an oppressive load of the same kind. The
  • republic of the United Provinces is as much enfeebled by its debts as
  • either Genoa or Venice. Is it likely that, in Great Britain alone, a
  • practice, which has brought either weakness or dissolution into every
  • other country, should prove altogether innocent?
  • The system of taxation established in those different countries, it may be
  • said, is inferior to that of England. I believe it is so. But it ought to
  • be remembered, that when the wisest government has exhausted all the
  • proper subjects of taxation, it must, in cases of urgent necessity, have
  • recourse to improper ones. The wise republic of Holland has, upon some
  • occasions, been obliged to have recourse to taxes as inconvenient as the
  • greater part of those of Spain. Another war, begun before any considerable
  • liberation of the public revenue had been brought about, and growing in
  • its progress as expensive as the last war, may, from irresistible
  • necessity, render the British system of taxation as oppressive as that of
  • Holland, or even as that of Spain. To the honour of our present system of
  • taxation, indeed, it has hitherto given so little embarrassment to
  • industry, that, during the course even of the most expensive wars, the
  • frugality and good conduct of individuals seem to have been able, by
  • saving and accumulation, to repair all the breaches which the waste and
  • extravagance of government had made in the general capital of the society.
  • At the conclusion of the late war, the most expensive that Great Britain
  • ever waged, her agriculture was as flourishing, her manufacturers as
  • numerous and as fully employed, and her commerce as extensive, as they had
  • ever been before. The capital, therefore, which supported all those
  • different branches of industry, must have been equal to what it had ever
  • been before. Since the peace, agriculture has been still further improved;
  • the rents of houses have risen in every town and village of the country, a
  • proof of the increasing wealth and revenue of the people; and the annual
  • amount of the greater part of the old taxes, of the principal branches of
  • the excise and customs, in particular, has been continually increasing, an
  • equally clear proof of an increasing consumption, and consequently of an
  • increasing produce, which could alone support that consumption. Great
  • Britain seems to support with ease, a burden which, half a century ago,
  • nobody believed her capable of supporting, Let us not, however, upon this
  • account, rashly conclude that she is capable of supporting any burden; nor
  • even be too confident that she could support, without great distress, a
  • burden a little greater than what has already been laid upon her.
  • When national debts have once been accumulated to a certain degree, there
  • is scarce, I believe, a single instance of their having been fairly and
  • completely paid. The liberation of the public revenue, if it has ever been
  • brought about at all, has always been brought about by a bankruptcy;
  • sometimes by an avowed one, though frequently by a pretended payment.
  • The raising of the denomination of the coin has been the most usual
  • expedient by which a real public bankruptcy has been disguised under the
  • appearance of a pretended payment. If a sixpence, for example, should,
  • either by act of parliament or royal proclamation, be raised to the
  • denomination of a shilling, and twenty sixpences to that of a pound
  • sterling; the person who, under the old denomination, had borrowed twenty
  • shillings, or near four ounces of silver, would, under the new, pay with
  • twenty sixpences, or with something less than two ounces. A national debt
  • of about a hundred and twenty-eight millions, near the capital of the
  • funded and unfunded debt of Great Britain, might, in this manner, be paid
  • with about sixty-four millions of our present money. It would, indeed, be
  • a pretended payment only, and the creditors of the public would really be
  • defrauded of ten shillings in the pound of what was due to them. The
  • calamity, too, would extend much further than to the creditors of the
  • public, and those of every private person would suffer a proportionable
  • loss; and this without any advantage, but in most cases with a great
  • additional loss, to the creditors of the public. If the creditors of the
  • public, indeed, were generally much in debt to other people, they might in
  • some measure compensate their loss by paying their creditors in the same
  • coin in which the public had paid them. But in most countries, the
  • creditors of the public are, the greater part of them, wealthy people, who
  • stand more in the relation of creditors than in that of debtors, towards
  • the rest of their fellow citizens. A pretended payment of this kind,
  • therefore, instead of alleviating, aggravates, in most cases, the loss of
  • the creditors of the public; and, without any advantage to the public,
  • extends the calamity to a great number of other innocent people. It
  • occasions a general and most pernicious subversion of the fortunes of
  • private people; enriching, in most cases, the idle and profuse debtor, at
  • the expense of the industrious and frugal creditor; and transporting a
  • great part of the national capital from the hands which were likely to
  • increase and improve it, to those who are likely to dissipate and destroy
  • it. When it becomes necessary for a state to declare itself bankrupt, in
  • the same manner as when it becomes necessary for an individual to do so, a
  • fair, open, and avowed bankruptcy, is always the measure which is both
  • least dishonourable to the debtor, and least hurtful to the creditor. The
  • honour of a state is surely very poorly provided for, when, in order to
  • cover the disgrace of a real bankruptcy, it has recourse to a juggling
  • trick of this kind, so easily seen through, and at the same time so
  • extremely pernicious.
  • Almost all states, however, ancient as well as modern, when reduced to
  • this necessity, have, upon some occasions, played this very juggling
  • trick. The Romans, at the end of the first Punic war, reduced the As, the
  • coin or denomination by which they computed the value of all their other
  • coins, from containing twelve ounces of copper, to contain only two
  • ounces; that is, they raised two ounces of copper to a denomination which
  • had always before expressed the value of twelve ounces. The republic was,
  • in this manner, enabled to pay the great debts which it had contracted
  • with the sixth part of what it really owed. So sudden and so great a
  • bankruptcy, we should in the present times be apt to imagine, must have
  • occasioned a very violent popular clamour. It does not appear to have
  • occasioned any. The law which enacted it was, like all other laws relating
  • to the coin, introduced and carried through the assembly of the people by
  • a tribune, and was probably a very popular law. In Rome, as in all other
  • ancient republics, the poor people were constantly in debt to the rich and
  • the great, who, in order to secure their votes at the annual elections,
  • used to lend them money at exorbitant interest, which, being never paid,
  • soon accumulated into a sum too great either for the debtor to pay, or for
  • any body else to pay for him. The debtor, for fear of a very severe
  • execution, was obliged, without any further gratuity, to vote for the
  • candidate whom the creditor recommended. In spite of all the laws against
  • bribery and corruption, the bounty of the candidates, together with the
  • occasional distributions of coin which were ordered by the senate, were
  • the principal funds from which, during the latter times of the Roman
  • republic, the poorer citizens derived their subsistence. To deliver
  • themselves from this subjection to their creditors, the poorer citizens
  • were continually calling out, either for an entire abolition of debts, or
  • for what they called new tables; that is, for a law which should entitle
  • them to a complete acquittance, upon paying only a certain proportion of
  • their accumulated debts. The law which reduced the coin of all
  • denominations to a sixth part of its former value, as it enabled them to
  • pay their debts with a sixth part of what they really owed, was equivalent
  • to the most advantageous new tables. In order to satisfy the people, the
  • rich and the great were, upon several different occasions, obliged to
  • consent to laws, both for abolishing debts, and for introducing new
  • tables; and they probably were induced to consent to this law, partly for
  • the same reason, and partly that, by liberating the public revenue, they
  • might restore vigour to that government, of which they themselves had the
  • principal direction. An operation of this kind would at once reduce a debt
  • of £128,000,000 to £21,333,333:6:8. In the course of the second Punic war,
  • the As was still further reduced, first, from two ounces of copper to one
  • ounce, and afterwards from one ounce to half an ounce; that is, to the
  • twenty-fourth part of its original value. By combining the three Roman
  • operations into one, a debt of a hundred and twenty-eight millions of our
  • present money, might in this manner be reduced all at once to a debt of
  • £5,333,333:6:8. Even the enormous debt of Great Britain might in this
  • manner soon be paid.
  • By means of such expedients, the coin of, I believe, all nations, has been
  • gradually reduced more and more below its original value, and the same
  • nominal sum has been gradually brought to contain a smaller and a smaller
  • quantity of silver.
  • Nations have sometimes, for the same purpose, adulterated the standard of
  • their coin; that is, have mixed a greater quantity of alloy in it. If in
  • the pound weight of our silver coin, for example, instead of eighteen
  • penny-weight, according to the present standard, there were mixed eight
  • ounces of alloy; a pound sterling, or twenty shillings of such coin, would
  • be worth little more than six shillings and eightpence of our present
  • money. The quantity of silver contained in six shillings and eightpence of
  • our present money, would thus be raised very nearly to the denomination of
  • a pound sterling. The adulteration of the standard has exactly the same
  • effect with what the French call an augmentation, or a direct raising of
  • the denomination of the coin.
  • An augmentation, or a direct raising of the denomination of the coin,
  • always is, and from its nature must be, an open and avowed operation. By
  • means of it, pieces of a smaller weight and bulk are called by the same
  • name, which had before been given to pieces of a greater weight and bulk.
  • The adulteration of the standard, on the contrary, has generally been a
  • concealed operation. By means of it, pieces are issued from the mint, of
  • the same denomination, and, as nearly as could be contrived, of the same
  • weight, bulk, and appearance, with pieces which had been current before of
  • much greater value. When king John of France, {See Du Cange Glossary, voce
  • Moneta; the Benedictine Edition.} in order to pay his debts, adulterated
  • his coin, all the officers of his mint were sworn to secrecy. Both
  • operations are unjust. But a simple augmentation is an injustice of open
  • violence; whereas an adulteration is an injustice of treacherous fraud.
  • This latter operation, therefore, as soon as it has been discovered, and
  • it could never be concealed very long, has always excited much greater
  • indignation than the former. The coin, after any considerable
  • augmentation, has very seldom been brought back to its former weight; but
  • after the greatest adulterations, it has almost always been brought back
  • to its former fineness. It has scarce ever happened, that the fury and
  • indignation of the people could otherwise be appeased.
  • In the end of the reign of Henry VIII., and in the beginning of that of
  • Edward VI., the English coin was not only raised in its denomination, but
  • adulterated in its standard. The like frauds were practised in Scotland
  • during the minority of James VI. They have occasionally been practised in
  • most other countries.
  • That the public revenue of Great Britain can never be completely
  • liberated, or even that any considerable progress can ever be made towards
  • that liberation, while the surplus of that revenue, or what is over and
  • above defraying the annual expense of the peace establishment, is so very
  • small, it seems altogether in vain to expect. That liberation, it is
  • evident, can never be brought about, without either some very considerable
  • augmentation of the public revenue, or some equally considerable reduction
  • of the public expense.
  • A more equal land tax, a more equal tax upon the rent of houses, and such
  • alterations in the present system of customs and excise as those which
  • have been mentioned in the foregoing chapter, might, perhaps, without
  • increasing the burden of the greater part of the people, but only
  • distributing the weight of it more equally upon the whole, produce a
  • considerable augmentation of revenue. The most sanguine projector,
  • however, could scarce flatter himself, that any augmentation of this kind
  • would be such as could give any reasonable hopes, either of liberating the
  • public revenue altogether, or even of making such progress towards that
  • liberation in time of peace, as either to prevent or to compensate the
  • further accumulation of the public debt in the next war.
  • By extending the British system of taxation to all the different provinces
  • of the empire, inhabited by people either of British or European
  • extraction, a much greater augmentation of revenue might be expected.
  • This, however, could scarce, perhaps, be done, consistently with the
  • principles of the British constitution, without admitting into the British
  • parliament, or, if you will, into the states-general of the British
  • empire, a fair and equal representation of all those different provinces;
  • that of each province bearing the same proportion to the produce of its
  • taxes, as the representation of Great Britain might bear to the produce of
  • the taxes levied upon Great Britain. The private interest of many powerful
  • individuals, the confirmed prejudices of great bodies of people, seem,
  • indeed, at present, to oppose to so great a change, such obstacles as it
  • may be very difficult, perhaps altogether impossible, to surmount.
  • Without, however, pretending to determine whether such a union be
  • practicable or impracticable, it may not, perhaps, be improper, in a
  • speculative work of this kind, to consider how far the British system of
  • taxation might be applicable to all the different provinces of the empire;
  • what revenue might be expected from it, if so applied; and in what manner
  • a general union of this kind might be likely to affect the happiness and
  • prosperity of the differrent provinces comprehended within it. Such a
  • speculation, can, at worst, be regarded but as a new Utopia, less amusing,
  • certainly, but no more useless and chimerical than the old one.
  • The land-tax, the stamp duties, and the different duties of customs and
  • excise, constitute the four principal branches of the British taxes.
  • Ireland is certainly as able, and our American and West India plantations
  • more able, to pay a land tax, than Great Britain. Where the landlord is
  • subject neither to tythe nor poor’s rate, he must certainly be more able
  • to pay such a tax, than where he is subject to both those other burdens.
  • The tythe, where there is no modus, and where it is levied in kind,
  • diminishes more what would otherwise be the rent of the landlord, than a
  • land tax which really amounted to five shillings in the pound. Such a
  • tythe will be found, in most cases, to amount to more than a fourth part
  • of the real rent of the land, or of what remains after replacing
  • completely the capital of the farmer, together with his reasonable profit.
  • If all moduses and all impropriations were taken away, the complete church
  • tythe of Great Britain and Ireland could not well be estimated at less
  • than six or seven millions. If there was no tythe either in Great Britain
  • or Ireland, the landlords could afford to pay six or seven millions
  • additional land tax, without being more burdened than a very great part of
  • them are at present. America pays no tythe, and could, therefore, very
  • well afford to pay a land tax. The lands in America and the West Indies,
  • indeed, are, in general, not tenanted nor leased out to farmers. They
  • could not, therefore, be assessed according to any rent roll. But neither
  • were the lands of Great Britain, in the 4th of William and Mary, assessed
  • according to any rent roll, but according to a very loose and inaccurate
  • estimation. The lands in America might be assessed either in the same
  • manner, or according to an equitable valuation, in consequence of an
  • accurate survey, like that which was lately made in the Milanese, and in
  • the dominions of Austria, Prussia, and Sardinia.
  • Stamp duties, it is evident, might be levied without any variation, in all
  • countries where the forms of law process, and the deeds by which property,
  • both real and personal, is transferred, are the same, or nearly the same.
  • The extension of the custom-house laws of Great Britain to Ireland and the
  • plantations, provided it was accompanied, as in justice it ought to be,
  • with an extension of the freedom of trade, would be in the highest degree
  • advantageous to both. All the invidious restraints which at present
  • oppress the trade of Ireland, the distinction between the enumerated and
  • non-enumerated commodities of America, would be entirely at an end. The
  • countries north of Cape Finisterre would be as open to every part of the
  • produce of America, as those south of that cape are to some parts of that
  • produce at present. The trade between all the different parts of the
  • British empire would, in consequence of this uniformity in the
  • custom-house laws, be as free as the coasting trade of Great Britain is at
  • present. The British empire would thus afford, within itself, an immense
  • internal market for every part of the produce of all its different
  • provinces. So great an extension of market would soon compensate, both to
  • Ireland and the plantations, all that they could suffer from the increase
  • of the duties of customs.
  • The excise is the only part of the British system of taxation, which would
  • require to be varied in any respect, according as it was applied to the
  • different provinces of the empire. It might be applied to Ireland without
  • any variation; the produce and consumption of that kingdom being exactly
  • of the same nature with those of Great Britain. In its application to
  • America and the West Indies, of which the produce and consumption are so
  • very different from those of Great Britain, some modification might be
  • necessary, in the same manner as in its application to the cyder and beer
  • counties of England.
  • A fermented liquor, for example, which is called beer, but which, as it is
  • made of molasses, bears very little resemblance to our beer, makes a
  • considerable part of the common drink of the people in America. This
  • liquor, as it can be kept only for a few days, cannot, like our beer, be
  • prepared and stored up for sale in great breweries; but every private
  • family must brew it for their own use, in the same manner as they cook
  • their victuals. But to subject every private family to the odious visits
  • and examination of the tax-gatherers, in the same manner as we subject the
  • keepers of ale-houses and the brewers for public sale, would be altogether
  • inconsistent with liberty. If, for the sake of equality, it was thought
  • necessary to lay a tax upon this liquor, it might be taxed by taxing the
  • material of which it is made, either at the place of manufacture, or, if
  • the circumstances of the trade rendered such an excise improper, by laying
  • a duty upon its importation into the colony in which it was to be
  • consumed. Besides the duty of one penny a-gallon imposed by the British
  • parliament upon the importation of molasses into America, there is a
  • provincial tax of this kind upon their importation into Massachusetts Bay,
  • in ships belonging to any other colony, of eight-pence the hogshead; and
  • another upon their importation from the northern colonies into South
  • Carolina, of five-pence the gallon. Or, if neither of these methods was
  • found convenient, each family might compound for its consumption of this
  • liquor, either according to the number of persons of which it consisted,
  • in the same manner as private families compound for the malt tax in
  • England; or according to the different ages and sexes of those persons, in
  • the same manner as several different taxes are levied in Holland; or,
  • nearly as Sir Matthew Decker proposes, that all taxes upon consumable
  • commodities should be levied in England. This mode of taxation, it has
  • already been observed, when applied to objects of a speedy consumption, is
  • not a very convenient one. It might be adopted, however, in cases where no
  • better could be done.
  • Sugar, rum, and tobacco, are commodities which are nowhere necessaries of
  • life, which are become objects of almost universal consumption, and which
  • are, therefore, extremely proper subjects of taxation. If a union with the
  • colonies were to take place, those commodities might be taxed, either
  • before they go out of the hands of the manufacturer or grower; or, if this
  • mode of taxation did not suit the circumstances of those persons, they
  • might be deposited in public warehouses, both at the place of manufacture,
  • and at all the different ports of the empire, to which they might
  • afterwards be transported, to remain there, under the joint custody of the
  • owner and the revenue officer, till such time as they should be delivered
  • out, either to the consumer, to the merchant-retailer for home
  • consumption, or to the merchant-exporter; the tax not to be advanced till
  • such delivery. When delivered out for exportation, to go duty-free, upon
  • proper security being given, that they should really be exported out of
  • the empire. These are, perhaps, the principal commodities, with regard to
  • which the union with the colonies might require some considerable change
  • in the present system of British taxation.
  • What might be the amount of the revenue which this system of taxation,
  • extended to all the different provinces of the empire, might produce, it
  • must, no doubt, be altogether impossible to ascertain with tolerable
  • exactness. By means of this system, there is annually levied in Great
  • Britain, upon less than eight millions of people, more than ten millions
  • of revenue. Ireland contains more than two millions of people, and,
  • according to the accounts laid before the congress, the twelve associated
  • provinces of America contain more than three. Those accounts, however, may
  • have been exaggerated, in order, perhaps, either to encourage their own
  • people, or to intimidate those of this country; and we shall suppose,
  • therefore, that our North American and West Indian colonies, taken
  • together, contain no more than three millions; or that the whole British
  • empire, in Europe and America, contains no more than thirteen millions of
  • inhabitants. If, upon less than eight millions of inhabitants, this system
  • of taxation raises a revenue of more than ten millions sterling; it ought,
  • upon thirteen millions of inhabitants, to raise a revenue of more than
  • sixteen millions two hundred and fifty thousand pounds sterling. From this
  • revenue, supposing that this system could produce it, must be deducted the
  • revenue usually raised in Ireland and the plantations, for defraying the
  • expense of the respective civil governments. The expense of the civil and
  • military establishment of Ireland, together with the interest of the
  • public debt, amounts, at a medium of the two years which ended March 1775,
  • to something less than seven hundred and fifty thousand pounds a year. By
  • a very exact account of the revenue of the principal colonies of America
  • and the West Indies, it amounted, before the commencement of the present
  • disturbances, to a hundred and forty-one thousand eight hundred pounds. In
  • this account, however, the revenue of Maryland, of North Carolina, and of
  • all our late acquisitions, both upon the continent, and in the islands, is
  • omitted; which may, perhaps, make a difference of thirty or forty thousand
  • pounds. For the sake of even numbers, therefore, let us suppose that the
  • revenue necessary for supporting the civil government of Ireland and the
  • plantations may amount to a million. There would remain, consequently, a
  • revenue of fifteen millions two hundred and fifty thousand pounds, to be
  • applied towards defraying the general expense of the empire, and towards
  • paying the public debt. But if, from the present revenue of Great Britain,
  • a million could, in peaceable times, be spared towards the payment of that
  • debt, six millions two hundred and fifty thousand pounds could very well
  • be spared from this improved revenue. This great sinking fund, too, might
  • be augmented every year by the interest of the debt which had been
  • discharged the year before; and might, in this manner, increase so very
  • rapidly, as to be sufficient in a few years to discharge the whole debt,
  • and thus to restore completely the at-present debilitated and languishing
  • vigour of the empire. In the meantime, the people might be relieved from
  • some of the most burdensome taxes; from those which are imposed either
  • upon the necessaries of life, or upon the materials of manufacture. The
  • labouring poor would thus be enabled to live better, to work cheaper, and
  • to send their goods cheaper to market. The cheapness of their goods would
  • increase the demand for them, and consequently for the labour of those who
  • produced them. This increase in the demand for labour would both increase
  • the numbers, and improve the circumstances of the labouring poor. Their
  • consumption would increase, and, together with it, the revenue arising
  • from all those articles of their consumption upon which the taxes might be
  • allowed to remain.
  • The revenue arising from this system of taxation, however, might not
  • immediately increase in proportion to the number of people who were
  • subjected to it. Great indulgence would for some time be due to those
  • provinces of the empire which were thus subjected to burdens to which they
  • had not before been accustomed; and even when the same taxes came to be
  • levied everywhere as exactly as possible, they would not everywhere
  • produce a revenue proportioned to the numbers of the people. In a poor
  • country, the consumption of the principal commodities subject to the
  • duties of customs and excise, is very small; and in a thinly inhabited
  • country, the opportunities of smuggling are very great. The consumption of
  • malt liquors among the inferior ranks of people in Scotland is very small;
  • and the excise upon malt, beer, and ale, produces less there than in
  • England, in proportion to the numbers of the people and the rate of the
  • duties, which upon malt is different, on account of a supposed difference
  • of quality. In these particular branches of the excise, there is not, I
  • apprehend, much more smuggling in the one country than in the other. The
  • duties upon the distillery, and the greater part of the duties of customs,
  • in proportion to the numbers of people in the respective countries,
  • produce less in Scotland than in England, not only on account of the
  • smaller consumption of the taxed commodities, but of the much greater
  • facility of smuggling. In Ireland, the inferior ranks of people are still
  • poorer than in Scotland, and many parts of the country are almost as
  • thinly inhabited. In Ireland, therefore, the consumption of the taxed
  • commodities might, in proportion to the number of the people, be still
  • less than in Scotland, and the facility of smuggling nearly the same. In
  • America and the West Indies, the white people, even of the lowest rank,
  • are in much better circumstances than those of the same rank in England;
  • and their consumption of all the luxuries in which they usually indulge
  • themselves, is probably much greater. The blacks, indeed, who make the
  • greater part of the inhabitants, both of the southern colonies upon the
  • continent and of the West India islands, as they are in a state of
  • slavery, are, no doubt, in a worse condition than the poorest people
  • either in Scotland or Ireland. We must not, however, upon that account,
  • imagine that they are worse fed, or that their consumption of articles
  • which might be subjected to moderate duties, is less than that even of the
  • lower ranks of people in England. In order that they may work well, it is
  • the interest of their master that they should be fed well, and kept in
  • good heart, in the same manner as it is his interest that his working
  • cattle should be so. The blacks, accordingly, have almost everywhere their
  • allowance of rum, and of molasses or spruce-beer, in the same manner as
  • the white servants; and this allowance would not probably be withdrawn,
  • though those articles should be subjected to moderate duties. The
  • consumption of the taxed commodities, therefore, in proportion to the
  • number of inhabitants, would probably be as great in America and the West
  • Indies as in any part of the British empire. The opportunities of
  • smuggling, indeed, would be much greater; America, in proportion to the
  • extent of the country, being much more thinly inhabited than either
  • Scotland or Ireland. If the revenue, however, which is at present raised
  • by the different duties upon malt and malt liquors, were to be levied by a
  • single duty upon malt, the opportunity of smuggling in the most important
  • branch of the excise would be almost entirely taken away; and if the
  • duties of customs, instead of being imposed upon almost all the different
  • articles of importation, were confined to a few of the most general use
  • and consumption, and if the levying of those duties were subjected to the
  • excise laws, the opportunity of smuggling, though not so entirely taken
  • away, would be very much diminished. In consequence of those two
  • apparently very simple and easy alterations, the duties of customs and
  • excise might probably produce a revenue as great, in proportion to the
  • consumption of the most thinly inhabited province, as they do at present,
  • in proportion to that of the most populous.
  • The Americans, it has been said, indeed, have no gold or silver money, the
  • interior commerce of the country being carried on by a paper currency; and
  • the gold and silver, which occasionally come among them, being all sent to
  • Great Britain, in return for the commodities which they receive from us.
  • But without gold and silver, it is added, there is no possibility of
  • paying taxes. We already get all the gold and silver which they have. How
  • is it possible to draw from them what they have not?
  • The present scarcity of gold and silver money in America, is not the
  • effect of the poverty of that country, or of the inability of the people
  • there to purchase those metals. In a country where the wages of labour are
  • so much higher, and the price of provisions so much lower than in England,
  • the greater part of the people must surely have wherewithal to purchase a
  • greater quantity, if it were either necessary or convenient for them to do
  • so. The scarcity of those metals, therefore, must be the effect of choice,
  • and not of necessity.
  • It is for transacting either domestic or foreign business, that gold or
  • silver money is either necessary or convenient.
  • The domestic business of every country, it has been shewn in the second
  • book of this Inquiry, may, at least in peaceable times, be transacted by
  • means of a paper currency, with nearly the same degree of conveniency as
  • by gold and silver money. It is convenient for the Americans, who could
  • always employ with profit, in the improvement of their lands, a greater
  • stock than they can easily get, to save as much as possible the expense of
  • so costly an instrument of commerce as gold and silver; and rather to
  • employ that part of their surplus produce which would be necessary for
  • purchasing those metals, in purchasing the instruments of trade, the
  • materials of clothing, several parts of household furniture, and the iron
  • work necessary for building and extending their settlements and
  • plantations; in purchasing not dead stock, but active and productive
  • stock. The colony governments find it for their interest to supply the
  • people with such a quantity of paper money as is fully sufficient, and
  • generally more than sufficient, for transacting their domestic business.
  • Some of those governments, that of Pennsylvania, particularly, derive a
  • revenue from lending this paper money to their subjects, at an interest of
  • so much per cent. Others, like that of Massachusetts Bay, advance, upon
  • extraordinary emergencies, a paper money of this kind for defraying the
  • public expense; and afterwards, when it suits the conveniency of the
  • colony, redeem it at the depreciated value to which it gradually falls. In
  • 1747, {See Hutchinson’s History of Massachusetts Bay vol. ii. page 436 et
  • seq.} that colony paid in this manner the greater part of its public
  • debts, with the tenth part of the money for which its bills had been
  • granted. It suits the conveniency of the planters, to save the expense of
  • employing gold and silver money in their domestic transactions; and it
  • suits the conveniency of the colony governments, to supply them with a
  • medium, which, though attended with some very considerable disadvantages,
  • enables them to save that expense. The redundancy of paper money
  • necessarily banishes gold and silver from the domestic transactions of the
  • colonies, for the same reason that it has banished those metals from the
  • greater part of the domestic transactions in Scotland; and in both
  • countries, it is not the poverty, but the enterprizing and projecting
  • spirit of the people, their desire of employing all the stock which they
  • can get, as active and productive stock, which has occasioned this
  • redundancy of paper money.
  • In the exterior commerce which the different colonies carry on with Great
  • Britain, gold and silver are more or less employed, exactly in proportion
  • as they are more or less necessary. Where those metals are not necessary,
  • they seldom appear. Where they are necessary, they are generally found.
  • In the commerce between Great Britain and the tobacco colonies, the
  • British goods are generally advanced to the colonists at a pretty long
  • credit, and are afterwards paid for in tobacco, rated at a certain price.
  • It is more convenient for the colonists to pay in tobacco than in gold and
  • silver. It would be more convenient for any merchant to pay for the goods
  • which his correspondents had sold to him, in some other sort of goods
  • which he might happen to deal in, than in money. Such a merchant would
  • have no occasion to keep any part of his stock by him unemployed, and in
  • ready money, for answering occasional demands. He could have, at all
  • times, a larger quantity of goods in his shop or warehouse, and he could
  • deal to a greater extent. But it seldom happens to be convenient for all
  • the correspondents of a merchant to receive payment for the goods which
  • they sell to him, in goods of some other kind which he happens to deal in.
  • The British merchants who trade to Virginia and Maryland, happen to be a
  • particular set of correspondents, to whom it is more convenient to receive
  • payment for the goods which they sell to those colonies in tobacco, than
  • in gold and silver. They expect to make a profit by the sale of the
  • tobacco; they could make none by that of the gold and silver. Gold and
  • silver, therefore, very seldom appear in the commerce between Great
  • Britain and the tobacco colonies. Maryland and Virginia have as little
  • occasion for those metals in their foreign, as in their domestic commerce.
  • They are said, accordingly, to have less gold and silver money than any
  • other colonies in America. They are reckoned, however, as thriving, and
  • consequently as rich, as any of their neighbours.
  • In the northern colonies, Pennsylvania, New York, New Jersey, the four
  • governments of New England, etc. the value of their own produce which they
  • export to Great Britain is not equal to that of the manufactures which
  • they import for their own use, and for that of some of the other colonies,
  • to which they are the carriers. A balance, therefore, must be paid to the
  • mother-country in gold and silver and this balance they generally find.
  • In the sugar colonies, the value of the produce annually exported to Great
  • Britain is much greater than that of all the goods imported from thence.
  • If the sugar and rum annually sent to the mother-country were paid for in
  • those colonies, Great Britain would be obliged to send out, every year, a
  • very large balance in money; and the trade to the West Indies would, by a
  • certain species of politicians, be considered as extremely
  • disadvantageous. But it so happens, that many of the principal proprietors
  • of the sugar plantations reside in Great Britain. Their rents are remitted
  • to them in sugar and rum, the produce of their estates. The sugar and rum
  • which the West India merchants purchase in those colonies upon their own
  • account, are not equal in value to the goods which they annually sell
  • there. A balance, therefore, must necessarily be paid to them in gold and
  • silver, and this balance, too, is generally found.
  • The difficulty and irregularity of payment from the different colonies to
  • Great Britain, have not been at all in proportion to the greatness or
  • smallness of the balances which were respectively due from them. Payments
  • have, in general, been more regular from the northern than from the
  • tobacco colonies, though the former have generally paid a pretty large
  • balance in money, while the latter have either paid no balance, or a much
  • smaller one. The difficulty of getting payment from our different sugar
  • colonies has been greater or less in proportion, not so much to the extent
  • of the balances respectively due from them, as to the quantity of
  • uncultivated land which they contained; that is, to the greater or smaller
  • temptation which the planters have been under of over-trading, or of
  • undertaking the settlement and plantation of greater quantities of waste
  • land than suited the extent of their capitals. The returns from the great
  • island of Jamaica, where there is still much uncultivated land, have, upon
  • this account, been, in general, more irregular and uncertain than those
  • from the smaller islands of Barbadoes, Antigua, and St. Christopher’s,
  • which have, for these many years, been completely cultivated, and have,
  • upon that account, afforded less field for the speculations of the
  • planter. The new acquisitions of Grenada, Tobago, St. Vincent’s, and
  • Dominica, have opened a new field for speculations of this kind; and the
  • returns front those islands have of late been as irregular and uncertain
  • as those from the great island of Jamaica.
  • It is not, therefore, the poverty of the colonies which occasions, in the
  • greater part of them, the present scarcity of gold and silver money. Their
  • great demand for active and productive stock makes it convenient for them
  • to have as little dead stock as possible, and disposes them, upon that
  • account, to content themselves with a cheaper, though less commodious
  • instrument of commerce, than gold and silver. They are thereby enabled to
  • convert the value of that gold and silver into the instruments of trade,
  • into the materials of clothing, into household furniture, and into the
  • iron work necessary for building and extending their settlements and
  • plantations. In those branches of business which cannot be transacted
  • without gold and silver money, it appears, that they can always find the
  • necessary quantity of those metals; and if they frequently do not find it,
  • their failure is generally the effect, not of their necessary poverty, but
  • of their unnecessary and excessive enterprise. It is not because they are
  • poor that their payments are irregular and uncertain, but because they are
  • too eager to become excessively rich. Though all that part of the produce
  • of the colony taxes, which was over and above what was necessary for
  • defraying the expense of their own civil and military establishments, were
  • to be remitted to Great Britain in gold and silver, the colonies have
  • abundantly wherewithal to purchase the requisite quantity of those metals.
  • They would in this case be obliged, indeed, to exchange a part of their
  • surplus produce, with which they now purchase active and productive stock,
  • for dead stock. In transacting their domestic business, they would be
  • obliged to employ a costly, instead of a cheap instrument of commerce; and
  • the expense of purchasing this costly instrument might damp somewhat the
  • vivacity and ardour of their excessive enterprise in the improvement of
  • land. It might not, however, be necessary to remit any part of the
  • American revenue in gold and silver. It might be remitted in bills drawn
  • upon, and accepted by, particular merchants or companies in Great Britain,
  • to whom a part of the surplus produce of America had been consigned, who
  • would pay into the treasury the American revenue in money, after having
  • themselves received the value of it in goods; and the whole business might
  • frequently be transacted without exporting a single ounce of gold or
  • silver from America.
  • It is not contrary to justice, that both Ireland and America should
  • contribute towards the discharge of the public debt of Great Britain. That
  • debt has been contracted in support of the government established by the
  • Revolution; a government to which the protestants of Ireland owe, not only
  • the whole authority which they at present enjoy in their own country, but
  • every security which they possess for their liberty, their property, and
  • their religion; a government to which several of the colonies of America
  • owe their present charters, and consequently their present constitution;
  • and to which all the colonies of America owe the liberty, security, and
  • property, which they have ever since enjoyed. That public debt has been
  • contracted in the defence, not of Great Britain alone, but of all the
  • different provinces of the empire. The immense debt contracted in the late
  • war in particular, and a great part of that contracted in the war before,
  • were both properly contracted in defence of America.
  • By a union with Great Britain, Ireland would gain, besides the freedom of
  • trade, other advantages much more important, and which would much more
  • than compensate any increase of taxes that might accompany that union. By
  • the union with England, the middling and inferior ranks of people in
  • Scotland gained a complete deliverance from the power of an aristocracy,
  • which had always before oppressed them. By a union with Great Britain, the
  • greater part of people of all ranks in Ireland would gain an equally
  • complete deliverance from a much more oppressive aristocracy; an
  • aristocracy not founded, like that of Scotland, in the natural and
  • respectable distinctions of birth and fortune, but in the most odious of
  • all distinctions, those of religious and political prejudices;
  • distinctions which, more than any other, animate both the insolence of the
  • oppressors, and the hatred and indignation of the oppressed, and which
  • commonly render the inhabitants of the same country more hostile to one
  • another than those of different countries ever are. Without a union with
  • Great Britain, the inhabitants of Ireland are not likely, for many ages,
  • to consider themselves as one people.
  • No oppressive aristocracy has ever prevailed in the colonies. Even they,
  • however, would, in point of happiness and tranquillity, gain considerably
  • by a union with Great Britain. It would, at least, deliver them from those
  • rancourous and virulent factions which are inseparable from small
  • democracies, and which have so frequently divided the affections of their
  • people, and disturbed the tranquillity of their governments, in their form
  • so nearly democratical. In the case of a total separation from Great
  • Britain, which, unless prevented by a union of this kind, seems very
  • likely to take place, those factions would be ten times more virulent than
  • ever. Before the commencement of the present disturbances, the coercive
  • power of the mother-country had always been able to restrain those
  • factions from breaking out into any thing worse than gross brutality and
  • insult. If that coercive power were entirely taken away, they would
  • probably soon break out into open violence and bloodshed. In all great
  • countries which are united under one uniform government, the spirit of
  • party commonly prevails less in the remote provinces than in the centre of
  • the empire. The distance of those provinces from the capital, from the
  • principal seat of the great scramble of faction and ambition, makes them
  • enter less into the views of any of the contending parties, and renders
  • them more indifferent and impartial spectators of the conduct of all. The
  • spirit of party prevails less in Scotland than in England. In the case of
  • a union, it would probably prevail less in Ireland than in Scotland; and
  • the colonies would probably soon enjoy a degree of concord and unanimity,
  • at present unknown in any part of the British empire. Both Ireland and the
  • colonies, indeed, would be subjected to heavier taxes than any which they
  • at present pay. In consequence, however, of a diligent and faithful
  • application of the public revenue towards the discharge of the national
  • debt, the greater part of those taxes might not be of long continuance,
  • and the public revenue of Great Britain might soon be reduced to what was
  • necessary for maintaining a moderate peace-establishment.
  • The territorial acquisitions of the East India Company, the undoubted
  • right of the Crown, that is, of the state and people of Great Britain,
  • might be rendered another source of revenue, more abundant, perhaps, than
  • all those already mentioned. Those countries are represented as more
  • fertile, more extensive, and, in proportion to their extent, much richer
  • and more populous than Great Britain. In order to draw a great revenue
  • from them, it would not probably be necessary to introduce any new system
  • of taxation into countries which are already sufficiently, and more than
  • sufficiently, taxed. It might, perhaps, be more proper to lighten than to
  • aggravate the burden of those unfortunate countries, and to endeavour to
  • draw a revenue from them, not by imposing new taxes, but by preventing the
  • embezzlement and misapplication of the greater part of those which they
  • already pay.
  • If it should be found impracticable for Great Britain to draw any
  • considerable augmentation of revenue from any of the resources above
  • mentioned, the only resource which can remain to her, is a diminution of
  • her expense. In the mode of collecting and in that of expending the public
  • revenue, though in both there may be still room for improvement, Great
  • Britain seems to be at least as economical as any of her neighbours. The
  • military establishment which she maintains for her own defence in time of
  • peace, is more moderate than that of any European state, which can pretend
  • to rival her either in wealth or in power. None of these articles,
  • therefore, seem to admit of any considerable reduction of expense. The
  • expense of the peace-establishment of the colonies was, before the
  • commencement of the present disturbances, very considerable, and is an
  • expense which may, and, if no revenue can be drawn from them, ought
  • certainly to be saved altogether. This constant expense in time of peace,
  • though very great, is insignificant in comparison with what the defence of
  • the colonies has cost us in time of war. The last war, which was
  • undertaken altogether on account of the colonies, cost Great Britain, it
  • has already been observed, upwards of ninety millions. The Spanish war of
  • 1739 was principally undertaken on their account; in which, and in the
  • French war that was the consequence of it, Great Britain, spent upwards of
  • forty millions; a great part of which ought justly to be charged to the
  • colonies. In those two wars, the colonies cost Great Britain much more
  • than double the sum which the national debt amounted to before the
  • commencement of the first of them. Had it not been for those wars, that
  • debt might, and probably would by this time, have been completely paid;
  • and had it not been for the colonies, the former of those wars might not,
  • and the latter certainly would not, have been undertaken. It was because
  • the colonies were supposed to be provinces of the British Empire, that
  • this expense was laid out upon them. But countries which contribute
  • neither revenue nor military force towards the support of the empire,
  • cannot be considered as provinces. They may, perhaps, be considered as
  • appendages, as a sort of splendid and shewy equipage of the empire. But if
  • the empire can no longer support the expense of keeping up this equipage,
  • it ought certainly to lay it down; and if it cannot raise its revenue in
  • proportion to its expense, it ought at least to accommodate its expense to
  • its revenue. If the colonies, notwithstanding their refusal to submit to
  • British taxes, are still to be considered as provinces of the British
  • empire, their defence, in some future war, may cost Great Britain as great
  • an expense as it ever has done in any former war. The rulers of Great
  • Britain have, for more than a century past, amused the people with the
  • imagination that they possessed a great empire on the west side of the
  • Atlantic. This empire, however, has hitherto existed in imagination only.
  • It has hitherto been, not an empire, but the project of an empire; not a
  • gold mine, but the project of a gold mine; a project which has cost, which
  • continues to cost, and which, if pursued in the same way as it has been
  • hitherto, is likely to cost, immense expense, without being likely to
  • bring any profit; for the effects of the monopoly of the colony trade, it
  • has been shewn, are to the great body of the people, mere loss instead of
  • profit. It is surely now time that our rulers should either realize this
  • golden dream, in which they have been indulging themselves, perhaps, as
  • well as the people; or that they should awake from it themselves, and
  • endeavour to awaken the people. If the project cannot be completed, it
  • ought to be given up. If any of the provinces of the British empire cannot
  • be made to contribute towards the support of the whole empire, it is
  • surely time that Great Britain should free herself from the expense of
  • defending those provinces in time of war, and of supporting any part of
  • their civil or military establishment in time of peace; and endeavour to
  • accommodate her future views and designs to the real mediocrity of her
  • circumstances.
  • End of the Project Gutenberg EBook of An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes
  • of the Wealth of Nations, by Adam Smith
  • *** END OF THIS PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK NATURE AND CAUSES OF THE WEALTH OF NATIONS ***
  • ***** This file should be named 3300-0.txt or 3300-0.zip *****
  • This and all associated files of various formats will be found in:
  • http://www.gutenberg.org/3/3/0/3300/
  • Produced by Colin Muir, and David Widger
  • Updated editions will replace the previous one--the old editions
  • will be renamed.
  • Creating the works from public domain print editions means that no
  • one owns a United States copyright in these works, so the Foundation
  • (and you!) can copy and distribute it in the United States without
  • permission and without paying copyright royalties. Special rules,
  • set forth in the General Terms of Use part of this license, apply to
  • copying and distributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works to
  • protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm concept and trademark. Project
  • Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and may not be used if you
  • charge for the eBooks, unless you receive specific permission. If you
  • do not charge anything for copies of this eBook, complying with the
  • rules is very easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose
  • such as creation of derivative works, reports, performances and
  • research. They may be modified and printed and given away--you may do
  • practically ANYTHING with public domain eBooks. Redistribution is
  • subject to the trademark license, especially commercial
  • redistribution.
  • *** START: FULL LICENSE ***
  • THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
  • PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK
  • To protect the Project Gutenberg-tm mission of promoting the free
  • distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work
  • (or any other work associated in any way with the phrase "Project
  • Gutenberg"), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full Project
  • Gutenberg-tm License (available with this file or online at
  • http://gutenberg.org/license).
  • Section 1. General Terms of Use and Redistributing Project Gutenberg-tm
  • electronic works
  • 1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg-tm
  • electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree to
  • and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
  • (trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
  • the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or destroy
  • all copies of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works in your possession.
  • If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic work and you do not agree to be bound by the
  • terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from the person or
  • entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in paragraph 1.E.8.
  • 1.B. "Project Gutenberg" is a registered trademark. It may only be
  • used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people who
  • agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a few
  • things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works
  • even without complying with the full terms of this agreement. See
  • paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic works if you follow the terms of this agreement
  • and help preserve free future access to Project Gutenberg-tm electronic
  • works. See paragraph 1.E below.
  • 1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation ("the Foundation"
  • or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the collection of Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic works. Nearly all the individual works in the
  • collection are in the public domain in the United States. If an
  • individual work is in the public domain in the United States and you are
  • located in the United States, we do not claim a right to prevent you from
  • copying, distributing, performing, displaying or creating derivative
  • works based on the work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg
  • are removed. Of course, we hope that you will support the Project
  • Gutenberg-tm mission of promoting free access to electronic works by
  • freely sharing Project Gutenberg-tm works in compliance with the terms of
  • this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg-tm name associated with
  • the work. You can easily comply with the terms of this agreement by
  • keeping this work in the same format with its attached full Project
  • Gutenberg-tm License when you share it without charge with others.
  • 1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also govern
  • what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most countries are in
  • a constant state of change. If you are outside the United States, check
  • the laws of your country in addition to the terms of this agreement
  • before downloading, copying, displaying, performing, distributing or
  • creating derivative works based on this work or any other Project
  • Gutenberg-tm work. The Foundation makes no representations concerning
  • the copyright status of any work in any country outside the United
  • States.
  • 1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:
  • 1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other immediate
  • access to, the full Project Gutenberg-tm License must appear prominently
  • whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg-tm work (any work on which the
  • phrase "Project Gutenberg" appears, or with which the phrase "Project
  • Gutenberg" is associated) is accessed, displayed, performed, viewed,
  • copied or distributed:
  • This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere at no cost and with
  • almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or
  • re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included
  • with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org
  • 1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work is derived
  • from the public domain (does not contain a notice indicating that it is
  • posted with permission of the copyright holder), the work can be copied
  • and distributed to anyone in the United States without paying any fees
  • or charges. If you are redistributing or providing access to a work
  • with the phrase "Project Gutenberg" associated with or appearing on the
  • work, you must comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1
  • through 1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the
  • Project Gutenberg-tm trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or
  • 1.E.9.
  • 1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work is posted
  • with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
  • must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any additional
  • terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms will be linked
  • to the Project Gutenberg-tm License for all works posted with the
  • permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of this work.
  • 1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project Gutenberg-tm
  • License terms from this work, or any files containing a part of this
  • work or any other work associated with Project Gutenberg-tm.
  • 1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this
  • electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
  • prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
  • active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
  • Gutenberg-tm License.
  • 1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
  • compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form, including any
  • word processing or hypertext form. However, if you provide access to or
  • distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg-tm work in a format other than
  • "Plain Vanilla ASCII" or other format used in the official version
  • posted on the official Project Gutenberg-tm web site (www.gutenberg.org),
  • you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense to the user, provide a
  • copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means of obtaining a copy upon
  • request, of the work in its original "Plain Vanilla ASCII" or other
  • form. Any alternate format must include the full Project Gutenberg-tm
  • License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.
  • 1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,
  • performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg-tm works
  • unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.
  • 1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing
  • access to or distributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works provided
  • that
  • - You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
  • the use of Project Gutenberg-tm works calculated using the method
  • you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The fee is
  • owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark, but he
  • has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to the
  • Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty payments
  • must be paid within 60 days following each date on which you
  • prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your periodic tax
  • returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked as such and
  • sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation at the
  • address specified in Section 4, "Information about donations to
  • the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation."
  • - You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who notifies
  • you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that s/he
  • does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg-tm
  • License. You must require such a user to return or
  • destroy all copies of the works possessed in a physical medium
  • and discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of
  • Project Gutenberg-tm works.
  • - You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of any
  • money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in the
  • electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90 days
  • of receipt of the work.
  • - You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
  • distribution of Project Gutenberg-tm works.
  • 1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg-tm
  • electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
  • forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
  • both the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation and Michael
  • Hart, the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark. Contact the
  • Foundation as set forth in Section 3 below.
  • 1.F.
  • 1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend considerable
  • effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe and proofread
  • public domain works in creating the Project Gutenberg-tm
  • collection. Despite these efforts, Project Gutenberg-tm electronic
  • works, and the medium on which they may be stored, may contain
  • "Defects," such as, but not limited to, incomplete, inaccurate or
  • corrupt data, transcription errors, a copyright or other intellectual
  • property infringement, a defective or damaged disk or other medium, a
  • computer virus, or computer codes that damage or cannot be read by
  • your equipment.
  • 1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except for the "Right
  • of Replacement or Refund" described in paragraph 1.F.3, the Project
  • Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner of the Project
  • Gutenberg-tm trademark, and any other party distributing a Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic work under this agreement, disclaim all
  • liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including legal
  • fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT
  • LIABILITY, BREACH OF WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
  • PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH F3. YOU AGREE THAT THE FOUNDATION, THE
  • TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE
  • LIABLE TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE OR
  • INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH
  • DAMAGE.
  • 1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you discover a
  • defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it, you can
  • receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by sending a
  • written explanation to the person you received the work from. If you
  • received the work on a physical medium, you must return the medium with
  • your written explanation. The person or entity that provided you with
  • the defective work may elect to provide a replacement copy in lieu of a
  • refund. If you received the work electronically, the person or entity
  • providing it to you may choose to give you a second opportunity to
  • receive the work electronically in lieu of a refund. If the second copy
  • is also defective, you may demand a refund in writing without further
  • opportunities to fix the problem.
  • 1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
  • in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you 'AS-IS' WITH NO OTHER
  • WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO
  • WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTIBILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
  • 1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied
  • warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
  • If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
  • law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
  • interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted by
  • the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
  • provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.
  • 1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the Foundation, the
  • trademark owner, any agent or employee of the Foundation, anyone
  • providing copies of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works in accordance
  • with this agreement, and any volunteers associated with the production,
  • promotion and distribution of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works,
  • harmless from all liability, costs and expenses, including legal fees,
  • that arise directly or indirectly from any of the following which you do
  • or cause to occur: (a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg-tm
  • work, (b) alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any
  • Project Gutenberg-tm work, and (c) any Defect you cause.
  • Section 2. Information about the Mission of Project Gutenberg-tm
  • Project Gutenberg-tm is synonymous with the free distribution of
  • electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of computers
  • including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers. It exists
  • because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and donations from
  • people in all walks of life.
  • Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the
  • assistance they need, are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg-tm's
  • goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg-tm collection will
  • remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
  • Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a secure
  • and permanent future for Project Gutenberg-tm and future generations.
  • To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
  • and how your efforts and donations can help, see Sections 3 and 4
  • and the Foundation web page at http://www.pglaf.org.
  • Section 3. Information about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
  • Foundation
  • The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non profit
  • 501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
  • state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
  • Revenue Service. The Foundation's EIN or federal tax identification
  • number is 64-6221541. Its 501(c)(3) letter is posted at
  • http://pglaf.org/fundraising. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
  • Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
  • permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state's laws.
  • The Foundation's principal office is located at 4557 Melan Dr. S.
  • Fairbanks, AK, 99712., but its volunteers and employees are scattered
  • throughout numerous locations. Its business office is located at
  • 809 North 1500 West, Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887, email
  • business@pglaf.org. Email contact links and up to date contact
  • information can be found at the Foundation's web site and official
  • page at http://pglaf.org
  • For additional contact information:
  • Dr. Gregory B. Newby
  • Chief Executive and Director
  • gbnewby@pglaf.org
  • Section 4. Information about Donations to the Project Gutenberg
  • Literary Archive Foundation
  • Project Gutenberg-tm depends upon and cannot survive without wide
  • spread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
  • increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can be
  • freely distributed in machine readable form accessible by the widest
  • array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small donations
  • ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax exempt
  • status with the IRS.
  • The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating
  • charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
  • States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
  • considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and keep up
  • with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in locations
  • where we have not received written confirmation of compliance. To
  • SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of compliance for any
  • particular state visit http://pglaf.org
  • While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where we
  • have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no prohibition
  • against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in such states who
  • approach us with offers to donate.
  • International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make
  • any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
  • outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.
  • Please check the Project Gutenberg Web pages for current donation
  • methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of other
  • ways including checks, online payments and credit card donations.
  • To donate, please visit: http://pglaf.org/donate
  • Section 5. General Information About Project Gutenberg-tm electronic
  • works.
  • Professor Michael S. Hart is the originator of the Project Gutenberg-tm
  • concept of a library of electronic works that could be freely shared
  • with anyone. For thirty years, he produced and distributed Project
  • Gutenberg-tm eBooks with only a loose network of volunteer support.
  • Project Gutenberg-tm eBooks are often created from several printed
  • editions, all of which are confirmed as Public Domain in the U.S.
  • unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not necessarily
  • keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper edition.
  • Most people start at our Web site which has the main PG search facility:
  • http://www.gutenberg.org
  • This Web site includes information about Project Gutenberg-tm,
  • including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
  • Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how to
  • subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.