Quotations.ch
  Directory : The Economic Consequences of the Peace
GUIDE SUPPORT US BLOG
  • The Project Gutenberg eBook, The Economic Consequences of the Peace, by
  • John Maynard Keynes
  • This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere at no cost and with
  • almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or
  • re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included
  • with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.net
  • Title: The Economic Consequences of the Peace
  • Author: John Maynard Keynes
  • Release Date: May 6, 2005 [eBook #15776]
  • Most recently updated: July 15, 2013
  • Language: English
  • ***START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF THE
  • PEACE***
  • E-text prepared by Rick Niles, Jon King, and the Project Gutenberg Online
  • Distributed Proofreading Team
  • THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF THE PEACE
  • by
  • JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES, C.B.
  • Fellow of King's College, Cambridge
  • New York
  • Harcourt, Brace and Howe
  • 1920
  • PREFACE
  • The writer of this book was temporarily attached to the British
  • Treasury during the war and was their official representative at the
  • Paris Peace Conference up to June 7, 1919; he also sat as deputy for
  • the Chancellor of the Exchequer on the Supreme Economic Council. He
  • resigned from these positions when it became evident that hope could
  • no longer be entertained of substantial modification in the draft
  • Terms of Peace. The grounds of his objection to the Treaty, or rather
  • to the whole policy of the Conference towards the economic problems of
  • Europe, will appear in the following chapters. They are entirely of a
  • public character, and are based on facts known to the whole world.
  • J.M. Keynes.
  • King's College, Cambridge,
  • November, 1919.
  • CONTENTS
  • I. INTRODUCTORY
  • II. EUROPE BEFORE THE WAR
  • III. THE CONFERENCE
  • IV. THE TREATY
  • V. REPARATION
  • VI. EUROPE AFTER THE TREATY
  • VII. REMEDIES
  • THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF THE PEACE
  • CHAPTER I
  • INTRODUCTORY
  • The power to become habituated to his surroundings is a marked
  • characteristic of mankind. Very few of us realize with conviction the
  • intensely unusual, unstable, complicated, unreliable, temporary nature
  • of the economic organization by which Western Europe has lived for the
  • last half century. We assume some of the most peculiar and temporary of
  • our late advantages as natural, permanent, and to be depended on, and we
  • lay our plans accordingly. On this sandy and false foundation we scheme
  • for social improvement and dress our political platforms, pursue our
  • animosities and particular ambitions, and feel ourselves with enough
  • margin in hand to foster, not assuage, civil conflict in the European
  • family. Moved by insane delusion and reckless self-regard, the German
  • people overturned the foundations on which we all lived and built. But
  • the spokesmen of the French and British peoples have run the risk of
  • completing the ruin, which Germany began, by a Peace which, if it is
  • carried into effect, must impair yet further, when it might have
  • restored, the delicate, complicated organization, already shaken and
  • broken by war, through which alone the European peoples can employ
  • themselves and live.
  • In England the outward aspect of life does not yet teach us to feel or
  • realize in the least that an age is over. We are busy picking up the
  • threads of our life where we dropped them, with this difference only,
  • that many of us seem a good deal richer than we were before. Where we
  • spent millions before the war, we have now learnt that we can spend
  • hundreds of millions and apparently not suffer for it. Evidently we did
  • not exploit to the utmost the possibilities of our economic life. We
  • look, therefore, not only to a return to the comforts of 1914, but to an
  • immense broadening and intensification of them. All classes alike thus
  • build their plans, the rich to spend more and save less, the poor to
  • spend more and work less.
  • But perhaps it is only in England (and America) that it is possible to
  • be so unconscious. In continental Europe the earth heaves and no one but
  • is aware of the rumblings. There it is not just a matter of extravagance
  • or "labor troubles"; but of life and death, of starvation and existence,
  • and of the fearful convulsions of a dying civilization.
  • * * * * *
  • For one who spent in Paris the greater part of the six months which
  • succeeded the Armistice an occasional visit to London was a strange
  • experience. England still stands outside Europe. Europe's voiceless
  • tremors do not reach her. Europe is apart and England is not of her
  • flesh and body. But Europe is solid with herself. France, Germany,
  • Italy, Austria and Holland, Russia and Roumania and Poland, throb
  • together, and their structure and civilization are essentially one. They
  • flourished together, they have rocked together in a war, which we, in
  • spite of our enormous contributions and sacrifices (like though in a
  • less degree than America), economically stood outside, and they may fall
  • together. In this lies the destructive significance of the Peace of
  • Paris. If the European Civil War is to end with France and Italy abusing
  • their momentary victorious power to destroy Germany and Austria-Hungary
  • now prostrate, they invite their own destruction also, being so deeply
  • and inextricably intertwined with their victims by hidden psychic and
  • economic bonds. At any rate an Englishman who took part in the
  • Conference of Paris and was during those months a member of the Supreme
  • Economic Council of the Allied Powers, was bound to become, for him a
  • new experience, a European in his cares and outlook. There, at the nerve
  • center of the European system, his British preoccupations must largely
  • fall away and he must be haunted by other and more dreadful specters.
  • Paris was a nightmare, and every one there was morbid. A sense of
  • impending catastrophe overhung the frivolous scene; the futility and
  • smallness of man before the great events confronting him; the mingled
  • significance and unreality of the decisions; levity, blindness,
  • insolence, confused cries from without,--all the elements of ancient
  • tragedy were there. Seated indeed amid the theatrical trappings of the
  • French Saloons of State, one could wonder if the extraordinary visages
  • of Wilson and of Clemenceau, with their fixed hue and unchanging
  • characterization, were really faces at all and not the tragi-comic masks
  • of some strange drama or puppet-show.
  • The proceedings of Paris all had this air of extraordinary importance
  • and unimportance at the same time. The decisions seemed charged with
  • consequences to the future of human society; yet the air whispered that
  • the word was not flesh, that it was futile, insignificant, of no effect,
  • dissociated from events; and one felt most strongly the impression,
  • described by Tolstoy in _War and Peace_ or by Hardy in _The Dynasts_, of
  • events marching on to their fated conclusion uninfluenced and unaffected
  • by the cerebrations of Statesmen in Council:
  • _Spirit of the Years_
  • Observe that all wide sight and self-command
  • Deserts these throngs now driven to demonry
  • By the Immanent Unrecking. Nought remains
  • But vindictiveness here amid the strong,
  • And there amid the weak an impotent rage.
  • _Spirit of the Pities_
  • Why prompts the Will so senseless-shaped a doing?
  • _Spirit of the Years_
  • I have told thee that It works unwittingly,
  • As one possessed not judging.
  • In Paris, where those connected with the Supreme Economic Council,
  • received almost hourly the reports of the misery, disorder, and decaying
  • organization of all Central and Eastern Europe, allied and enemy alike,
  • and learnt from the lips of the financial representatives of Germany and
  • Austria unanswerable evidence, of the terrible exhaustion of their
  • countries, an occasional visit to the hot, dry room in the President's
  • house, where the Four fulfilled their destinies in empty and arid
  • intrigue, only added to the sense of nightmare. Yet there in Paris the
  • problems of Europe were terrible and clamant, and an occasional return
  • to the vast unconcern of London a little disconcerting. For in London
  • these questions were very far away, and our own lesser problems alone
  • troubling. London believed that Paris was making a great confusion of
  • its business, but remained uninterested. In this spirit the British
  • people received the Treaty without reading it. But it is under the
  • influence of Paris, not London, that this book has been written by one
  • who, though an Englishman, feels himself a European also, and, because
  • of too vivid recent experience, cannot disinterest himself from the
  • further unfolding of the great historic drama of these days which will
  • destroy great institutions, but may also create a new world.
  • CHAPTER II
  • EUROPE BEFORE THE WAR
  • Before 1870 different parts of the small continent of Europe had
  • specialized in their own products; but, taken as a whole, it was
  • substantially self-subsistent. And its population was adjusted to this
  • state of affairs.
  • After 1870 there was developed on a large scale an unprecedented
  • situation, and the economic condition of Europe became during the next
  • fifty years unstable and peculiar. The pressure of population on food,
  • which had already been balanced by the accessibility of supplies from
  • America, became for the first time in recorded history definitely
  • reversed. As numbers increased, food was actually easier to secure.
  • Larger proportional returns from an increasing scale of production
  • became true of agriculture as well as industry. With the growth of the
  • European population there were more emigrants on the one hand to till
  • the soil of the new countries, and, on the other, more workmen were
  • available in Europe to prepare the industrial products and capital goods
  • which were to maintain the emigrant populations in their new homes, and
  • to build the railways and ships which were to make accessible to Europe
  • food and raw products from distant sources. Up to about 1900 a unit of
  • labor applied to industry yielded year by year a purchasing power over
  • an increasing quantity of food. It is possible that about the year 1900
  • this process began to be reversed, and a diminishing yield of Nature to
  • man's effort was beginning to reassert itself. But the tendency of
  • cereals to rise in real cost was balanced by other improvements;
  • and--one of many novelties--the resources of tropical Africa then for
  • the first time came into large employ, and a great traffic in oil-seeds
  • began to bring to the table of Europe in a new and cheaper form one of
  • the essential foodstuffs of mankind. In this economic Eldorado, in this
  • economic Utopia, as the earlier economists would have deemed it, most of
  • us were brought up.
  • That happy age lost sight of a view of the world which filled with
  • deep-seated melancholy the founders of our Political Economy. Before the
  • eighteenth century mankind entertained no false hopes. To lay the
  • illusions which grew popular at that age's latter end, Malthus disclosed
  • a Devil. For half a century all serious economical writings held that
  • Devil in clear prospect. For the next half century he was chained up and
  • out of sight. Now perhaps we have loosed him again.
  • What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man that age
  • was which came to an end in August, 1914! The greater part of the
  • population, it is true, worked hard and lived at a low standard of
  • comfort, yet were, to all appearances, reasonably contented with this
  • lot. But escape was possible, for any man of capacity or character at
  • all exceeding the average, into the middle and upper classes, for whom
  • life offered, at a low cost and with the least trouble, conveniences,
  • comforts, and amenities beyond the compass of the richest and most
  • powerful monarchs of other ages. The inhabitant of London could order by
  • telephone, sipping his morning tea in bed, the various products of the
  • whole earth, in such quantity as he might see fit, and reasonably expect
  • their early delivery upon his doorstep; he could at the same moment and
  • by the same means adventure his wealth in the natural resources and new
  • enterprises of any quarter of the world, and share, without exertion or
  • even trouble, in their prospective fruits and advantages; or he could
  • decide to couple the security of his fortunes with the good faith of the
  • townspeople of any substantial municipality in any continent that fancy
  • or information might recommend. He could secure forthwith, if he wished
  • it, cheap and comfortable means of transit to any country or climate
  • without passport or other formality, could despatch his servant to the
  • neighboring office of a bank for such supply of the precious metals as
  • might seem convenient, and could then proceed abroad to foreign
  • quarters, without knowledge of their religion, language, or customs,
  • bearing coined wealth upon his person, and would consider himself
  • greatly aggrieved and much surprised at the least interference. But,
  • most important of all, he regarded this state of affairs as normal,
  • certain, and permanent, except in the direction of further improvement,
  • and any deviation from it as aberrant, scandalous, and avoidable. The
  • projects and politics of militarism and imperialism, of racial and
  • cultural rivalries, of monopolies, restrictions, and exclusion, which
  • were to play the serpent to this paradise, were little more than the
  • amusements of his daily newspaper, and appeared to exercise almost no
  • influence at all on the ordinary course of social and economic life, the
  • internationalization of which was nearly complete in practice.
  • It will assist us to appreciate the character and consequences of the
  • Peace which we have imposed on our enemies, if I elucidate a little
  • further some of the chief unstable elements already present when war
  • broke out, in the economic life of Europe.
  • I. _Population_
  • In 1870 Germany had a population of about 40,000,000. By 1892 this
  • figure had risen to 50,000,000, and by June 30, 1914, to about
  • 68,000,000. In the years immediately preceding the war the annual
  • increase was about 850,000, of whom an insignificant proportion
  • emigrated.[1] This great increase was only rendered possible by a
  • far-reaching transformation of the economic structure of the country.
  • From being agricultural and mainly self-supporting, Germany transformed
  • herself into a vast and complicated industrial machine, dependent for
  • its working on the equipoise of many factors outside Germany as well as
  • within. Only by operating this machine, continuously and at full blast,
  • could she find occupation at home for her increasing population and the
  • means of purchasing their subsistence from abroad. The German machine
  • was like a top which to maintain its equilibrium must spin ever faster
  • and faster.
  • In the Austro-Hungarian Empire, which grew from about 40,000,000 in 1890
  • to at least 50,000,000 at the outbreak of war, the same tendency was
  • present in a less degree, the annual excess of births over deaths being
  • about half a million, out of which, however, there was an annual
  • emigration of some quarter of a million persons.
  • To understand the present situation, we must apprehend with vividness
  • what an extraordinary center of population the development of the
  • Germanic system had enabled Central Europe to become. Before the war the
  • population of Germany and Austria-Hungary together not only
  • substantially exceeded that of the United States, but was about equal to
  • that of the whole of North America. In these numbers, situated within a
  • compact territory, lay the military strength of the Central Powers. But
  • these same numbers--for even the war has not appreciably diminished
  • them[2]--if deprived of the means of life, remain a hardly less danger
  • to European order.
  • European Russia increased her population in a degree even greater than
  • Germany--from less than 100,000,000 in 1890 to about 150,000,000 at the
  • outbreak of war;[3] and in the year immediately preceding 1914 the
  • excess of births over deaths in Russia as a whole was at the prodigious
  • rate of two millions per annum. This inordinate growth in the population
  • of Russia, which has not been widely noticed in England, has been
  • nevertheless one of the most significant facts of recent years.
  • The great events of history are often due to secular changes in the
  • growth of population and other fundamental economic causes, which,
  • escaping by their gradual character the notice of contemporary
  • observers, are attributed to the follies of statesmen or the fanaticism
  • of atheists. Thus the extraordinary occurrences of the past two years in
  • Russia, that vast upheaval of Society, which has overturned what seemed
  • most stable--religion, the basis of property, the ownership of land, as
  • well as forms of government and the hierarchy of classes--may owe more
  • to the deep influences of expanding numbers than to Lenin or to
  • Nicholas; and the disruptive powers of excessive national fecundity may
  • have played a greater part in bursting the bonds of convention than
  • either the power of ideas or the errors of autocracy.
  • II. _Organization_
  • The delicate organization by which these peoples lived depended partly
  • on factors internal to the system.
  • The interference of frontiers and of tariffs was reduced to a minimum,
  • and not far short of three hundred millions of people lived within the
  • three Empires of Russia, Germany, and Austria-Hungary. The various
  • currencies, which were all maintained on a stable basis in relation to
  • gold and to one another, facilitated the easy flow of capital and of
  • trade to an extent the full value of which we only realize now, when we
  • are deprived of its advantages. Over this great area there was an almost
  • absolute security of property and of person.
  • These factors of order, security, and uniformity, which Europe had never
  • before enjoyed over so wide and populous a territory or for so long a
  • period, prepared the way for the organization of that vast mechanism of
  • transport, coal distribution, and foreign trade which made possible an
  • industrial order of life in the dense urban centers of new population.
  • This is too well known to require detailed substantiation with figures.
  • But it may be illustrated by the figures for coal, which has been the
  • key to the industrial growth of Central Europe hardly less than of
  • England; the output of German coal grew from 30,000,000 tons in 1871 to
  • 70,000,000 tons in 1890, 110,000,000 tons in 1900, and 190,000,000 tons
  • in 1913.
  • Round Germany as a central support the rest of the European economic
  • system grouped itself, and on the prosperity and enterprise of Germany
  • the prosperity of the rest of the Continent mainly depended. The
  • increasing pace of Germany gave her neighbors an outlet for their
  • products, in exchange for which the enterprise of the German merchant
  • supplied them with their chief requirements at a low price.
  • The statistics of the economic interdependence of Germany and her
  • neighbors are overwhelming. Germany was the best customer of Russia,
  • Norway, Holland, Belgium, Switzerland, Italy, and Austria-Hungary; she
  • was the second best customer of Great Britain, Sweden, and Denmark; and
  • the third best customer of France. She was the largest source of supply
  • to Russia, Norway, Sweden, Denmark, Holland, Switzerland, Italy,
  • Austria-Hungary, Roumania, and Bulgaria; and the second largest source
  • of supply to Great Britain, Belgium, and France.
  • In our own case we sent more exports to Germany than to any other
  • country in the world except India, and we bought more from her than from
  • any other country in the world except the United States.
  • There was no European country except those west of Germany which did not
  • do more than a quarter of their total trade with her; and in the case of
  • Russia, Austria-Hungary, and Holland the proportion was far greater.
  • Germany not only furnished these countries with trade, but, in the case
  • of some of them, supplied a great part of the capital needed for their
  • own development. Of Germany's pre-war foreign investments, amounting in
  • all to about $6,250,000,000, not far short of $2,500,000,000 was
  • invested in Russia, Austria-Hungary, Bulgaria, Roumania, and Turkey.[4]
  • And by the system of "peaceful penetration" she gave these countries not
  • only capital, but, what they needed hardly less, organization. The whole
  • of Europe east of the Rhine thus fell into the German industrial orbit,
  • and its economic life was adjusted accordingly.
  • But these internal factors would not have been sufficient to enable the
  • population to support itself without the co-operation of external
  • factors also and of certain general dispositions common to the whole of
  • Europe. Many of the circumstances already treated were true of Europe as
  • a whole, and were not peculiar to the Central Empires. But all of what
  • follows was common to the whole European system.
  • III. _The Psychology of Society_
  • Europe was so organized socially and economically as to secure the
  • maximum accumulation of capital. While there was some continuous
  • improvement in the daily conditions of life of the mass of the
  • population, Society was so framed as to throw a great part of the
  • increased income into the control of the class least likely to consume
  • it. The new rich of the nineteenth century were not brought up to large
  • expenditures, and preferred the power which investment gave them to the
  • pleasures of immediate consumption. In fact, it was precisely the
  • _inequality_ of the distribution of wealth which made possible those
  • vast accumulations of fixed wealth and of capital improvements which
  • distinguished that age from all others. Herein lay, in fact, the main
  • justification of the Capitalist System. If the rich had spent their new
  • wealth on their own enjoyments, the world would long ago have found such
  • a rĂ©gime intolerable. But like bees they saved and accumulated, not less
  • to the advantage of the whole community because they themselves held
  • narrower ends in prospect.
  • The immense accumulations of fixed capital which, to the great benefit
  • of mankind, were built up during the half century before the war, could
  • never have come about in a Society where wealth was divided equitably.
  • The railways of the world, which that age built as a monument to
  • posterity, were, not less than the Pyramids of Egypt, the work of labor
  • which was not free to consume in immediate enjoyment the full equivalent
  • of its efforts.
  • Thus this remarkable system depended for its growth on a double bluff or
  • deception. On the one hand the laboring classes accepted from ignorance
  • or powerlessness, or were compelled, persuaded, or cajoled by custom,
  • convention, authority, and the well-established order of Society into
  • accepting, a situation in which they could call their own very little of
  • the cake that they and Nature and the capitalists were co-operating to
  • produce. And on the other hand the capitalist classes were allowed to
  • call the best part of the cake theirs and were theoretically free to
  • consume it, on the tacit underlying condition that they consumed very
  • little of it in practice. The duty of "saving" became nine-tenths of
  • virtue and the growth of the cake the object of true religion. There
  • grew round the non-consumption of the cake all those instincts of
  • puritanism which in other ages has withdrawn itself from the world and
  • has neglected the arts of production as well as those of enjoyment. And
  • so the cake increased; but to what end was not clearly contemplated.
  • Individuals would be exhorted not so much to abstain as to defer, and to
  • cultivate the pleasures of security and anticipation. Saving was for old
  • age or for your children; but this was only in theory,--the virtue of
  • the cake was that it was never to be consumed, neither by you nor by
  • your children after you.
  • In writing thus I do not necessarily disparage the practices of that
  • generation. In the unconscious recesses of its being Society knew what
  • it was about. The cake was really very small in proportion to the
  • appetites of consumption, and no one, if it were shared all round, would
  • be much the better off by the cutting of it. Society was working not
  • for the small pleasures of to-day but for the future security and
  • improvement of the race,--in fact for "progress." If only the cake were
  • not cut but was allowed to grow in the geometrical proportion predicted
  • by Malthus of population, but not less true of compound interest,
  • perhaps a day might come when there would at last be enough to go round,
  • and when posterity could enter into the enjoyment of _our_ labors. In
  • that day overwork, overcrowding, and underfeeding would have come to an
  • end, and men, secure of the comforts and necessities of the body, could
  • proceed to the nobler exercises of their faculties. One geometrical
  • ratio might cancel another, and the nineteenth century was able to
  • forget the fertility of the species in a contemplation of the dizzy
  • virtues of compound interest.
  • There were two pitfalls in this prospect: lest, population still
  • outstripping accumulation, our self-denials promote not happiness but
  • numbers; and lest the cake be after all consumed, prematurely, in war,
  • the consumer of all such hopes.
  • But these thoughts lead too far from my present purpose. I seek only to
  • point out that the principle of accumulation based on inequality was a
  • vital part of the pre-war order of Society and of progress as we then
  • understood it, and to emphasize that this principle depended on unstable
  • psychological conditions, which it may be impossible to recreate. It
  • was not natural for a population, of whom so few enjoyed the comforts of
  • life, to accumulate so hugely. The war has disclosed the possibility of
  • consumption to all and the vanity of abstinence to many. Thus the bluff
  • is discovered; the laboring classes may be no longer willing to forego
  • so largely, and the capitalist classes, no longer confident of the
  • future, may seek to enjoy more fully their liberties of consumption so
  • long as they last, and thus precipitate the hour of their confiscation.
  • IV. _The Relation of the Old World to the New_
  • The accumulative habits of Europe before the war were the necessary
  • condition of the greatest of the external factors which maintained the
  • European equipoise.
  • Of the surplus capital goods accumulated by Europe a substantial part
  • was exported abroad, where its investment made possible the development
  • of the new resources of food, materials, and transport, and at the same
  • time enabled the Old World to stake out a claim in the natural wealth
  • and virgin potentialities of the New. This last factor came to be of the
  • vastest importance. The Old World employed with an immense prudence the
  • annual tribute it was thus entitled to draw. The benefit of cheap and
  • abundant supplies resulting from the new developments which its surplus
  • capital had made possible, was, it is true, enjoyed and not postponed.
  • But the greater part of the money interest accruing on these foreign
  • investments was reinvested and allowed to accumulate, as a reserve (it
  • was then hoped) against the less happy day when the industrial labor of
  • Europe could no longer purchase on such easy terms the produce of other
  • continents, and when the due balance would be threatened between its
  • historical civilizations and the multiplying races of other climates and
  • environments. Thus the whole of the European races tended to benefit
  • alike from the development of new resources whether they pursued their
  • culture at home or adventured it abroad.
  • Even before the war, however, the equilibrium thus established between
  • old civilizations and new resources was being threatened. The prosperity
  • of Europe was based on the facts that, owing to the large exportable
  • surplus of foodstuffs in America, she was able to purchase food at a
  • cheap rate measured in terms of the labor required to produce her own
  • exports, and that, as a result of her previous investments of capital,
  • she was entitled to a substantial amount annually without any payment in
  • return at all. The second of these factors then seemed out of danger,
  • but, as a result of the growth of population overseas, chiefly in the
  • United States, the first was not so secure.
  • When first the virgin soils of America came into bearing, the
  • proportions of the population of those continents themselves, and
  • consequently of their own local requirements, to those of Europe were
  • very small. As lately as 1890 Europe had a population three times that
  • of North and South America added together. But by 1914 the domestic
  • requirements of the United States for wheat were approaching their
  • production, and the date was evidently near when there would be an
  • exportable surplus only in years of exceptionally favorable harvest.
  • Indeed, the present domestic requirements of the United States are
  • estimated at more than ninety per cent of the average yield of the five
  • years 1909-1913.[5] At that time, however, the tendency towards
  • stringency was showing itself, not so much in a lack of abundance as in
  • a steady increase of real cost. That is to say, taking the world as a
  • whole, there was no deficiency of wheat, but in order to call forth an
  • adequate supply it was necessary to offer a higher real price. The most
  • favorable factor in the situation was to be found in the extent to which
  • Central and Western Europe was being fed from the exportable surplus of
  • Russia and Roumania.
  • In short, Europe's claim on the resources of the New World was becoming
  • precarious; the law of diminishing returns was at last reasserting
  • itself and was making it necessary year by year for Europe to offer a
  • greater quantity of other commodities to obtain the same amount of
  • bread; and Europe, therefore, could by no means afford the
  • disorganization of any of her principal sources of supply.
  • Much else might be said in an attempt to portray the economic
  • peculiarities of the Europe of 1914. I have selected for emphasis the
  • three or four greatest factors of instability,--the instability of an
  • excessive population dependent for its livelihood on a complicated and
  • artificial organization, the psychological instability of the laboring
  • and capitalist classes, and the instability of Europe's claim, coupled
  • with the completeness of her dependence, on the food supplies of the New
  • World.
  • The war had so shaken this system as to endanger the life of Europe
  • altogether. A great part of the Continent was sick and dying; its
  • population was greatly in excess of the numbers for which a livelihood
  • was available; its organization was destroyed, its transport system
  • ruptured, and its food supplies terribly impaired.
  • It was the task of the Peace Conference to honor engagements and to
  • satisfy justice; but not less to re-establish life and to heal wounds.
  • These tasks were dictated as much by prudence as by the magnanimity
  • which the wisdom of antiquity approved in victors. We will examine in
  • the following chapters the actual character of the Peace.
  • FOOTNOTES:
  • [1] In 1913 there were 25,843 emigrants from Germany, of whom
  • 19,124 went to the United States.
  • [2] The net decrease of the German population at the end of
  • 1918 by decline of births and excess of deaths as compared with the
  • beginning of 1914, is estimated at about 2,700,000.
  • [3] Including Poland and Finland, but excluding Siberia,
  • Central Asia, and the Caucasus.
  • [4] Sums of money mentioned in this book in terms of dollars
  • have been converted from pounds sterling at the rate of $5 to £1.
  • [5] Even since 1914 the population of the United States has
  • increased by seven or eight millions. As their annual consumption of
  • wheat per head is not less than 6 bushels, the pre-war scale of
  • production in the United States would only show a substantial surplus
  • over present domestic requirements in about one year out of five. We
  • have been saved for the moment by the great harvests of 1918 and 1919,
  • which have been called forth by Mr. Hoover's guaranteed price. But the
  • United States can hardly be expected to continue indefinitely to raise
  • by a substantial figure the cost of living in its own country, in order
  • to provide wheat for a Europe which cannot pay for it.
  • CHAPTER III
  • THE CONFERENCE
  • In Chapters IV. and V. I shall study in some detail the economic and
  • financial provisions of the Treaty of Peace with Germany. But it will be
  • easier to appreciate the true origin of many of these terms if we
  • examine here some of the personal factors which influenced their
  • preparation. In attempting this task, I touch, inevitably, questions of
  • motive, on which spectators are liable to error and are not entitled to
  • take on themselves the responsibilities of final judgment. Yet, if I
  • seem in this chapter to assume sometimes the liberties which are
  • habitual to historians, but which, in spite of the greater knowledge
  • with which we speak, we generally hesitate to assume towards
  • contemporaries, let the reader excuse me when he remembers how greatly,
  • if it is to understand its destiny, the world needs light, even if it is
  • partial and uncertain, on the complex struggle of human will and
  • purpose, not yet finished, which, concentrated in the persons of four
  • individuals in a manner never paralleled, made them, in the first months
  • of 1919, the microcosm of mankind.
  • In those parts of the Treaty with which I am here concerned, the lead
  • was taken by the French, in the sense that it was generally they who
  • made in the first instance the most definite and the most extreme
  • proposals. This was partly a matter of tactics. When the final result is
  • expected to be a compromise, it is often prudent to start from an
  • extreme position; and the French anticipated at the outset--like most
  • other persons--a double process of compromise, first of all to suit the
  • ideas of their allies and associates, and secondly in the course of the
  • Peace Conference proper with the Germans themselves. These tactics were
  • justified by the event. Clemenceau gained a reputation for moderation
  • with his colleagues in Council by sometimes throwing over with an air of
  • intellectual impartiality the more extreme proposals of his ministers;
  • and much went through where the American and British critics were
  • naturally a little ignorant of the true point at issue, or where too
  • persistent criticism by France's allies put them in a position which
  • they felt as invidious, of always appearing to take the enemy's part and
  • to argue his case. Where, therefore, British and American interests were
  • not seriously involved their criticism grew slack, and some provisions
  • were thus passed which the French themselves did not take very
  • seriously, and for which the eleventh-hour decision to allow no
  • discussion with the Germans removed the opportunity of remedy.
  • But, apart from tactics, the French had a policy. Although Clemenceau
  • might curtly abandon the claims of a Klotz or a Loucheur, or close his
  • eyes with an air of fatigue when French interests were no longer
  • involved in the discussion, he knew which points were vital, and these
  • he abated little. In so far as the main economic lines of the Treaty
  • represent an intellectual idea, it is the idea of France and of
  • Clemenceau.
  • Clemenceau was by far the most eminent member of the Council of Four,
  • and he had taken the measure of his colleagues. He alone both had an
  • idea and had considered it in all its consequences. His age, his
  • character, his wit, and his appearance joined to give him objectivity
  • and a, defined outline in an environment of confusion. One could not
  • despise Clemenceau or dislike him, but only take a different view as to
  • the nature of civilized man, or indulge, at least, a different hope.
  • The figure and bearing of Clemenceau are universally familiar. At the
  • Council of Four he wore a square-tailed coat of very good, thick black
  • broadcloth, and on his hands, which were never uncovered, gray suede
  • gloves; his boots were of thick black leather, very good, but of a
  • country style, and sometimes fastened in front, curiously, by a buckle
  • instead of laces. His seat in the room in the President's house, where
  • the regular meetings of the Council of Four were held (as distinguished
  • from their private and unattended conferences in a smaller chamber
  • below), was on a square brocaded chair in the middle of the semicircle
  • facing the fireplace, with Signor Orlando on his left, the President
  • next by the fireplace, and the Prime Minister opposite on the other side
  • of the fireplace on his right. He carried no papers and no portfolio,
  • and was unattended by any personal secretary, though several French
  • ministers and officials appropriate to the particular matter in hand
  • would be present round him. His walk, his hand, and his voice were not
  • lacking in vigor, but he bore nevertheless, especially after the attempt
  • upon him, the aspect of a very old man conserving his strength for
  • important occasions. He spoke seldom, leaving the initial statement of
  • the French case to his ministers or officials; he closed his eyes often
  • and sat back in his chair with an impassive face of parchment, his gray
  • gloved hands clasped in front of him. A short sentence, decisive or
  • cynical, was generally sufficient, a question, an unqualified
  • abandonment of his ministers, whose face would not be saved, or a
  • display of obstinacy reinforced by a few words in a piquantly delivered
  • English.[6] But speech and passion were not lacking when they were
  • wanted, and the sudden outburst of words, often followed by a fit of
  • deep coughing from the chest, produced their impression rather by force
  • and surprise than by persuasion.
  • Not infrequently Mr. Lloyd George, after delivering a speech in English,
  • would, during the period of its interpretation into French, cross the
  • hearthrug to the President to reinforce his case by some _ad hominem_
  • argument in private conversation, or to sound the ground for a
  • compromise,--and this would sometimes be the signal for a general
  • upheaval and disorder. The President's advisers would press round him, a
  • moment later the British experts would dribble across to learn the
  • result or see that all was well, and next the French would be there, a
  • little suspicious lest the others were arranging something behind them,
  • until all the room were on their feet and conversation was general in
  • both languages. My last and most vivid impression is of such a
  • scene--the President and the Prime Minister as the center of a surging
  • mob and a babel of sound, a welter of eager, impromptu compromises and
  • counter-compromises, all sound and fury signifying nothing, on what was
  • an unreal question anyhow, the great issues of the morning's meeting
  • forgotten and neglected; and Clemenceau silent and aloof on the
  • outskirts--for nothing which touched the security of France was
  • forward--throned, in his gray gloves, on the brocade chair, dry in soul
  • and empty of hope, very old and tired, but surveying the scene with a
  • cynical and almost impish air; and when at last silence was restored and
  • the company had returned to their places, it was to discover that he had
  • disappeared.
  • He felt about France what Pericles felt of Athens--unique value in her,
  • nothing else mattering; but his theory of politics was Bismarck's. He
  • had one illusion--France; and one disillusion--mankind, including
  • Frenchmen, and his colleagues not least. His principles for the peace
  • can be expressed simply. In the first place, he was a foremost believer
  • in the view of German psychology that the German understands and can
  • understand nothing but intimidation, that he is without generosity or
  • remorse in negotiation, that there is no advantage he will not take of
  • you, and no extent to which he will not demean himself for profit, that
  • he is without honor, pride, or mercy. Therefore you must never negotiate
  • with a German or conciliate him; you must dictate to him. On no other
  • terms will he respect you, or will you prevent him from cheating you.
  • But it is doubtful how far he thought these characteristics peculiar to
  • Germany, or whether his candid view of some other nations was
  • fundamentally different. His philosophy had, therefore, no place for
  • "sentimentality" in international relations. Nations are real things, of
  • whom you love one and feel for the rest indifference--or hatred. The
  • glory of the nation you love is a desirable end,--but generally to be
  • obtained at your neighbor's expense. The politics of power are
  • inevitable, and there is nothing very new to learn about this war or the
  • end it was fought for; England had destroyed, as in each preceding
  • century, a trade rival; a mighty chapter had been closed in the secular
  • struggle between the glories of Germany and of France. Prudence required
  • some measure of lip service to the "ideals" of foolish Americans and
  • hypocritical Englishmen; but it would be stupid to believe that there is
  • much room in the world, as it really is, for such affairs as the League
  • of Nations, or any sense in the principle of self-determination except
  • as an ingenious formula for rearranging the balance of power in one's
  • own interests.
  • These, however, are generalities. In tracing the practical details of
  • the Peace which he thought necessary for the power and the security of
  • France, we must go back to the historical causes which had operated
  • during his lifetime. Before the Franco-German war the populations of
  • France and Germany were approximately equal; but the coal and iron and
  • shipping of Germany were in their infancy, and the wealth of France was
  • greatly superior. Even after the loss of Alsace-Lorraine there was no
  • great discrepancy between the real resources of the two countries. But
  • in the intervening period the relative position had changed completely.
  • By 1914 the population of Germany was nearly seventy per cent in excess
  • of that of France; she had become one of the first manufacturing and
  • trading nations of the world; her technical skill and her means for the
  • production of future wealth were unequaled. France on the other hand had
  • a stationary or declining population, and, relatively to others, had
  • fallen seriously behind in wealth and in the power to produce it.
  • In spite, therefore, of France's victorious issue from the present
  • struggle (with the aid, this time, of England and America), her future
  • position remained precarious in the eyes of one who took the view that
  • European civil war is to be regarded as a normal, or at least a
  • recurrent, state of affairs for the future, and that the sort of
  • conflicts between organized great powers which have occupied the past
  • hundred years will also engage the next. According to this vision of the
  • future, European history is to be a perpetual prize-fight, of which
  • France has won this round, but of which this round is certainly not the
  • last. From the belief that essentially the old order does not change,
  • being based on human nature which is always the same, and from a
  • consequent skepticism of all that class of doctrine which the League of
  • Nations stands for, the policy of France and of Clemenceau followed
  • logically. For a Peace of magnanimity or of fair and equal treatment,
  • based on such "ideology" as the Fourteen Points of the President, could
  • only have the effect of shortening the interval of Germany's recovery
  • and hastening the day when she will once again hurl at France her
  • greater numbers and her superior resources and technical skill. Hence
  • the necessity of "guarantees"; and each guarantee that was taken, by
  • increasing irritation and thus the probability of a subsequent
  • _Revanche_ by Germany, made necessary yet further provisions to crush.
  • Thus, as soon as this view of the world is adopted and the other
  • discarded, a demand for a Carthaginian Peace is inevitable, to the full
  • extent of the momentary power to impose it. For Clemenceau made no
  • pretense of considering himself bound by the Fourteen Points and left
  • chiefly to others such concoctions as were necessary from time to time
  • to save the scruples or the face of the President.
  • So far as possible, therefore, it was the policy of France to set the
  • clock back and to undo what, since 1870, the progress of Germany had
  • accomplished. By loss of territory and other measures her population was
  • to be curtailed; but chiefly the economic system, upon which she
  • depended for her new strength, the vast fabric built upon iron, coal,
  • and transport must be destroyed. If France could seize, even in part,
  • what Germany was compelled to drop, the inequality of strength between
  • the two rivals for European hegemony might be remedied for many
  • generations.
  • Hence sprang those cumulative provisions for the destruction of highly
  • organized economic life which we shall examine in the next chapter.
  • This is the policy of an old man, whose most vivid impressions and most
  • lively imagination are of the past and not of the future. He sees the
  • issue in terms, of France and Germany not of humanity and of European
  • civilization struggling forwards to a new order. The war has bitten into
  • his consciousness somewhat differently from ours, and he neither expects
  • nor hopes that we are at the threshold of a new age.
  • It happens, however, that it is not only an ideal question that is at
  • issue. My purpose in this book is to show that the Carthaginian Peace is
  • not _practically_ right or possible. Although the school of thought from
  • which it springs is aware of the economic factor, it overlooks,
  • nevertheless, the deeper economic tendencies which are to govern the
  • future. The clock cannot be set back. You cannot restore Central Europe
  • to 1870 without setting up such strains in the European structure and
  • letting loose such human and spiritual forces as, pushing beyond
  • frontiers and races, will overwhelm not only you and your "guarantees,"
  • but your institutions, and the existing order of your Society.
  • By what legerdemain was this policy substituted for the Fourteen Points,
  • and how did the President come to accept it? The answer to these
  • questions is difficult and depends on elements of character and
  • psychology and on the subtle influence of surroundings, which are hard
  • to detect and harder still to describe. But, if ever the action of a
  • single individual matters, the collapse of The President has been one of
  • the decisive moral events of history; and I must make an attempt to
  • explain it. What a place the President held in the hearts and hopes of
  • the world when he sailed to us in the _George Washington!_ What a great
  • man came to Europe in those early days of our victory!
  • In November, 1918, the armies of Foch and the words of Wilson had
  • brought us sudden escape from what was swallowing up all we cared for.
  • The conditions seemed favorable beyond any expectation. The victory was
  • so complete that fear need play no part in the settlement. The enemy
  • had laid down his arms in reliance on a solemn compact as to the general
  • character of the Peace, the terms of which seemed to assure a settlement
  • of justice and magnanimity and a fair hope for a restoration of the
  • broken current of life. To make assurance certain the President was
  • coming himself to set the seal on his work.
  • When President Wilson left Washington he enjoyed a prestige and a moral
  • influence throughout the world unequaled in history. His bold and
  • measured words carried to the peoples of Europe above and beyond the
  • voices of their own politicians. The enemy peoples trusted him to carry
  • out the compact he had made with them; and the Allied peoples
  • acknowledged him not as a victor only but almost as a prophet. In
  • addition to this moral influence the realities of power were in his
  • hands. The American armies were at the height of their numbers,
  • discipline, and equipment. Europe was in complete dependence on the food
  • supplies of the United States; and financially she was even more
  • absolutely at their mercy. Europe not only already owed the United
  • States more than she could pay; but only a large measure of further
  • assistance could save her from starvation and bankruptcy. Never had a
  • philosopher held such weapons wherewith to bind the princes of this
  • world. How the crowds of the European capitals pressed about the
  • carriage of the President! With what curiosity, anxiety, and hope we
  • sought a glimpse of the features and bearing of the man of destiny who,
  • coming from the West, was to bring healing to the wounds of the ancient
  • parent of his civilization and lay for us the foundations of the future.
  • The disillusion was so complete, that some of those who had trusted most
  • hardly dared speak of it. Could it be true? they asked of those who
  • returned from Paris. Was the Treaty really as bad as it seemed? What had
  • happened to the President? What weakness or what misfortune had led to
  • so extraordinary, so unlooked-for a betrayal?
  • Yet the causes were very ordinary and human. The President was not a
  • hero or a prophet; he was not even a philosopher; but a generously
  • intentioned man, with many of the weaknesses of other human beings, and
  • lacking that dominating intellectual equipment which would have been
  • necessary to cope with the subtle and dangerous spellbinders whom a
  • tremendous clash of forces and personalities had brought to the top as
  • triumphant masters in the swift game of give and take, face to face in
  • Council,--a game of which he had no experience at all.
  • We had indeed quite a wrong idea of the President. We knew him to be
  • solitary and aloof, and believed him very strong-willed and obstinate.
  • We did not figure him as a man of detail, but the clearness with which
  • he had taken hold of certain main ideas would, we thought, in
  • combination with his tenacity, enable him to sweep through cobwebs.
  • Besides these qualities he would have the objectivity, the cultivation,
  • and the wide knowledge of the student. The great distinction of language
  • which had marked his famous Notes seemed to indicate a man of lofty and
  • powerful imagination. His portraits indicated a fine presence and a
  • commanding delivery. With all this he had attained and held with
  • increasing authority the first position in a country where the arts of
  • the politician are not neglected. All of which, without expecting the
  • impossible, seemed a fine combination of qualities for the matter in
  • hand.
  • The first impression of Mr. Wilson at close quarters was to impair some
  • but not all of these illusions. His head and features were finely cut
  • and exactly like his photographs, and the muscles of his neck and the
  • carriage of his head were distinguished. But, like Odysseus, the
  • President looked wiser when he was seated; and his hands, though capable
  • and fairly strong, were wanting in sensitiveness and finesse. The first
  • glance at the President suggested not only that, whatever else he might
  • be, his temperament was not primarily that of the student or the
  • scholar, but that he had not much even of that culture of the world
  • which marks M. Clemenceau and Mr. Balfour as exquisitely cultivated
  • gentlemen of their class and generation. But more serious than this, he
  • was not only insensitive to his surroundings in the external sense, he
  • was not sensitive to his environment at all. What chance could such a
  • man have against Mr. Lloyd George's unerring, almost medium-like,
  • sensibility to every one immediately round him? To see the British Prime
  • Minister watching the company, with six or seven senses not available to
  • ordinary men, judging character, motive, and subconscious impulse,
  • perceiving what each was thinking and even what each was going to say
  • next, and compounding with telepathic instinct the argument or appeal
  • best suited to the vanity, weakness, or self-interest of his immediate
  • auditor, was to realize that the poor President would be playing blind
  • man's buff in that party. Never could a man have stepped into the parlor
  • a more perfect and predestined victim to the finished accomplishments of
  • the Prime Minister. The Old World was tough in wickedness anyhow; the
  • Old World's heart of stone might blunt the sharpest blade of the bravest
  • knight-errant. But this blind and deaf Don Quixote was entering a cavern
  • where the swift and glittering blade was in the hands of the adversary.
  • But if the President was not the philosopher-king, what was he? After
  • all he was a man who had spent much of his life at a University. He was
  • by no means a business man or an ordinary party politician, but a man of
  • force, personality, and importance. What, then, was his temperament?
  • The clue once found was illuminating. The President was like a
  • Nonconformist minister, perhaps a Presbyterian. His thought and his
  • temperament wore essentially theological not intellectual, with all the
  • strength and the weakness of that manner of thought, feeling, and
  • expression. It is a type of which there are not now in England and
  • Scotland such magnificent specimens as formerly; but this description,
  • nevertheless, will give the ordinary Englishman the distinctest
  • impression of the President.
  • With this picture of him in mind, we can return to the actual course of
  • events. The President's program for the World, as set forth in his
  • speeches and his Notes, had displayed a spirit and a purpose so
  • admirable that the last desire of his sympathizers was to criticize
  • details,--the details, they felt, were quite rightly not filled in at
  • present, but would be in due course. It was commonly believed at the
  • commencement of the Paris Conference that the President had thought out,
  • with the aid of a large body of advisers, a comprehensive scheme not
  • only for the League of Nations, but for the embodiment of the Fourteen
  • Points in an actual Treaty of Peace. But in fact the President had
  • thought out nothing; when it came to practice his ideas were nebulous
  • and incomplete. He had no plan, no scheme, no constructive ideas
  • whatever for clothing with the flesh of life the commandments which he
  • had thundered from the White House. He could have preached a sermon on
  • any of them or have addressed a stately prayer to the Almighty for their
  • fulfilment; but he could not frame their concrete application to the
  • actual state of Europe.
  • He not only had no proposals in detail, but he was in many respects,
  • perhaps inevitably, ill-informed as to European conditions. And not only
  • was he ill-informed--that was true of Mr. Lloyd George also--but his
  • mind was slow and unadaptable. The President's slowness amongst the
  • Europeans was noteworthy. He could not, all in a minute, take in what
  • the rest were saying, size up the situation with a glance, frame a
  • reply, and meet the case by a slight change of ground; and he was
  • liable, therefore, to defeat by the mere swiftness, apprehension, and
  • agility of a Lloyd George. There can seldom have been a statesman of the
  • first rank more incompetent than the President in the agilities of the
  • council chamber. A moment often arrives when substantial victory is
  • yours if by some slight appearance of a concession you can save the face
  • of the opposition or conciliate them by a restatement of your proposal
  • helpful to them and not injurious to anything essential to yourself. The
  • President was not equipped with this simple and usual artfulness. His
  • mind was too slow and unresourceful to be ready with _any_ alternatives.
  • The President was capable of digging his toes in and refusing to budge,
  • as he did over Fiume. But he had no other mode of defense, and it needed
  • as a rule but little manoeuvering by his opponents to prevent matters
  • from coming to such a head until it was too late. By pleasantness and an
  • appearance of conciliation, the President would be manoeuvered off his
  • ground, would miss the moment for digging his toes in, and, before he
  • knew where he had been got to, it was too late. Besides, it is
  • impossible month after month in intimate and ostensibly friendly
  • converse between close associates, to be digging the toes in all the
  • time. Victory would only have been possible to one who had always a
  • sufficiently lively apprehension of the position as a whole to reserve
  • his fire and know for certain the rare exact moments for decisive
  • action. And for that the President was far too slow-minded and
  • bewildered.
  • He did not remedy these defects by seeking aid from the collective
  • wisdom of his lieutenants. He had gathered round him for the economic
  • chapters of the Treaty a very able group of business men; but they were
  • inexperienced in public affairs, and knew (with one or two exceptions)
  • as little of Europe as he did, and they were only called in irregularly
  • as he might need them for a particular purpose. Thus the aloofness which
  • had been found effective in Washington was maintained, and the abnormal
  • reserve of his nature did not allow near him any one who aspired to
  • moral equality or the continuous exercise of influence. His
  • fellow-plenipotentiaries were dummies; and even the trusted Colonel
  • House, with vastly more knowledge of men and of Europe than the
  • President, from whose sensitiveness the President's dullness had gained
  • so much, fell into the background as time went on. All this was
  • encouraged by his colleagues on the Council of Four, who, by the
  • break-up of the Council of Ten, completed the isolation which the
  • President's own temperament had initiated. Thus day after day and week
  • after week, he allowed himself to be closeted, unsupported, unadvised,
  • and alone, with men much sharper than himself, in situations of supreme
  • difficulty, where he needed for success every description of resource,
  • fertility, and knowledge. He allowed himself to be drugged by their
  • atmosphere, to discuss on the basis of their plans and of their data,
  • and to be led along their paths.
  • These and other various causes combined to produce the following
  • situation. The reader must remember that the processes which are here
  • compressed into a few pages took place slowly, gradually, insidiously,
  • over a period of about five months.
  • As the President had thought nothing out, the Council was generally
  • working on the basis of a French or British draft. He had to take up,
  • therefore, a persistent attitude of obstruction, criticism, and
  • negation, if the draft was to become at all in line with his own ideas
  • and purpose. If he was met on some points with apparent generosity (for
  • there was always a safe margin of quite preposterous suggestions which
  • no one took seriously), it was difficult for him not to yield on others.
  • Compromise was inevitable, and never to compromise on the essential,
  • very difficult. Besides, he was soon made to appear to be taking the
  • German part and laid himself open to the suggestion (to which he was
  • foolishly and unfortunately sensitive) of being "pro-German."
  • After a display of much principle and dignity in the early days of the
  • Council of Ten, he discovered that there were certain very important
  • points in the program of his French, British, or Italian colleague, as
  • the case might be, of which he was incapable of securing the surrender
  • by the methods of secret diplomacy. What then was he to do in the last
  • resort? He could let the Conference drag on an endless length by the
  • exercise of sheer obstinacy. He could break it up and return to America
  • in a rage with nothing settled. Or he could attempt an appeal to the
  • world over the heads of the Conference. These were wretched
  • alternatives, against each of which a great deal could be said. They
  • were also very risky,--especially for a politician. The President's
  • mistaken policy over the Congressional election had weakened his
  • personal position in his own country, and it was by no means certain
  • that the American public would support him in a position of
  • intransigeancy. It would mean a campaign in which the issues would be
  • clouded by every sort of personal and party consideration, and who could
  • say if right would triumph in a struggle which would certainly not be
  • decided on its merits? Besides, any open rupture with his colleagues
  • would certainly bring upon his head the blind passions of "anti-German"
  • resentment with which the public of all allied countries were still
  • inspired. They would not listen to his arguments. They would not be cool
  • enough to treat the issue as one of international morality or of the
  • right governance of Europe. The cry would simply be that, for various
  • sinister and selfish reasons, the President wished "to let the Hun off."
  • The almost unanimous voice of the French and British Press could be
  • anticipated. Thus, if he threw down the gage publicly he might be
  • defeated. And if he were defeated, would not the final Peace be far
  • worse than if he were to retain his prestige and endeavor to make it as
  • good as the limiting conditions of European politics would allow, him?
  • But above all, if he were defeated, would he not lose the League of
  • Nations? And was not this, after all, by far the most important issue
  • for the future happiness of the world? The Treaty would be altered and
  • softened by time. Much in it which now seemed so vital would become
  • trifling, and much which was impracticable would for that very reason
  • never happen. But the League, even in an imperfect form, was permanent;
  • it was the first commencement of a new principle in the government of
  • the world; Truth and Justice in international relations could not be
  • established in a few months,--they must be born in due course by the
  • slow gestation of the League. Clemenceau had been clever enough to let
  • it be seen that he would swallow the League at a price.
  • At the crisis of his fortunes the President was a lonely man. Caught up
  • in the toils of the Old World, he stood in great need of sympathy, of
  • moral support, of the enthusiasm of masses. But buried in the
  • Conference, stifled in the hot and poisoned atmosphere of Paris, no echo
  • reached him from the outer world, and no throb of passion, sympathy, or
  • encouragement from his silent constituents in all countries. He felt
  • that the blaze of popularity which had greeted his arrival in Europe
  • was already dimmed; the Paris Press jeered at him openly; his political
  • opponents at home were taking advantage of his absence to create an
  • atmosphere against him; England was cold, critical, and unresponsive. He
  • had so formed his _entourage_ that he did not receive through private
  • channels the current of faith and enthusiasm of which the public sources
  • seemed dammed up. He needed, but lacked, the added strength of
  • collective faith. The German terror still overhung us, and even the
  • sympathetic public was very cautious; the enemy must not be encouraged,
  • our friends must be supported, this was not the time for discord or
  • agitations, the President must be trusted to do his best. And in this
  • drought the flower of the President's faith withered and dried up.
  • Thus it came to pass that the President countermanded the _George
  • Washington_, which, in a moment of well-founded rage, he had ordered to
  • be in readiness to carry him from the treacherous halls of Paris back to
  • the seat of his authority, where he could have felt himself again. But
  • as soon, alas, as he had taken the road of compromise, the defects,
  • already indicated, of his temperament and of his equipment, were fatally
  • apparent. He could take the high line; he could practise obstinacy; he
  • could write Notes from Sinai or Olympus; he could remain unapproachable
  • in the White House or even in the Council of Ten and be safe. But if he
  • once stepped down to the intimate equality of the Four, the game was
  • evidently up.
  • Now it was that what I have called his theological or Presbyterian
  • temperament became dangerous. Having decided that some concessions were
  • unavoidable, he might have sought by firmness and address and the use of
  • the financial power of the United States to secure as much as he could
  • of the substance, even at some sacrifice of the letter. But the
  • President was not capable of so clear an understanding with himself as
  • this implied. He was too conscientious. Although compromises were now
  • necessary, he remained a man of principle and the Fourteen Points a
  • contract absolutely binding upon him. He would do nothing that was not
  • honorable; he would do nothing that was not just and right; he would do
  • nothing that was contrary to his great profession of faith. Thus,
  • without any abatement of the verbal inspiration of the Fourteen Points,
  • they became a document for gloss and interpretation and for all the
  • intellectual apparatus of self-deception, by which, I daresay, the
  • President's forefathers had persuaded themselves that the course they
  • thought it necessary to take was consistent with every syllable of the
  • Pentateuch.
  • The President's attitude to his colleagues had now become: I want to
  • meet you so far as I can; I see your difficulties and I should like to
  • be able to agree to what you propose; but I can do nothing that is not
  • just and right, and you must first of all show me that what you want
  • does really fall within the words of the pronouncements which are
  • binding on me. Then began the weaving of that web of sophistry and
  • Jesuitical exegesis that was finally to clothe with insincerity the
  • language and substance of the whole Treaty. The word was issued to the
  • witches of all Paris:
  • Fair is foul, and foul is fair,
  • Hover through the fog and filthy air.
  • The subtlest sophisters and most hypocritical draftsmen were set to
  • work, and produced many ingenious exercises which might have deceived
  • for more than an hour a cleverer man than the President.
  • Thus instead of saying that German-Austria is prohibited from uniting
  • with Germany except by leave of France (which would be inconsistent with
  • the principle of self-determination), the Treaty, with delicate
  • draftsmanship, states that "Germany acknowledges and will respect
  • strictly the independence of Austria, within the frontiers which may be
  • fixed in a Treaty between that State and the Principal Allied and
  • Associated Powers; she agrees that this independence shall be
  • inalienable, except with the consent of the Council of the League of
  • Nations," which sounds, but is not, quite different. And who knows but
  • that the President forgot that another part of the Treaty provides that
  • for this purpose the Council of the League must be _unanimous_.
  • Instead of giving Danzig to Poland, the Treaty establishes Danzig as a
  • "Free" City, but includes this "Free" City within the Polish Customs
  • frontier, entrusts to Poland the control of the river and railway
  • system, and provides that "the Polish Government shall undertake the
  • conduct of the foreign relations of the Free City of Danzig as well as
  • the diplomatic protection of citizens of that city when abroad."
  • In placing the river system of Germany under foreign control, the Treaty
  • speaks of declaring international those "river systems which naturally
  • provide more than one State with access to the sea, with or without
  • transhipment from one vessel to another."
  • Such instances could be multiplied. The honest and intelligible purpose
  • of French policy, to limit the population of Germany and weaken her
  • economic system, is clothed, for the President's sake, in the august
  • language of freedom and international equality.
  • But perhaps the most decisive moment, in the disintegration of the
  • President's moral position and the clouding of his mind, was when at
  • last, to the dismay of his advisers, he allowed himself to be persuaded
  • that the expenditure of the Allied Governments on pensions and
  • separation allowances could be fairly regarded as "damage done to the
  • civilian population of the Allied and Associated Powers by German
  • aggression by land, by sea, and from the air," in a sense in which the
  • other expenses of the war could not be so regarded. It was a long
  • theological struggle in which, after the rejection of many different
  • arguments, the President finally capitulated before a masterpiece of the
  • sophist's art.
  • At last the work was finished; and the President's conscience was still
  • intact. In spite of everything, I believe that his temperament allowed
  • him to leave Paris a really sincere man; and it is probable that to this
  • day he is genuinely convinced that the Treaty contains practically
  • nothing inconsistent with his former professions.
  • But the work was too complete, and to this was due the last tragic
  • episode of the drama. The reply of Brockdorff-Rantzau inevitably took
  • the line that Germany had laid down her arms on the basis of certain
  • assurances, and that the Treaty in many particulars was not consistent
  • with these assurances. But this was exactly what the President could not
  • admit; in the sweat of solitary contemplation and with prayers to God
  • he had done _nothing_ that was not just and right; for the President to
  • admit that the German reply had force in it was to destroy his
  • self-respect and to disrupt the inner equipoise of his soul; and every
  • instinct of his stubborn nature rose in self-protection. In the language
  • of medical psychology, to suggest to the President that the Treaty was
  • an abandonment of his professions was to touch on the raw a Freudian
  • complex. It was a subject intolerable to discuss, and every subconscious
  • instinct plotted to defeat its further exploration.
  • Thus it was that Clemenceau brought to success, what had seemed to be, a
  • few months before, the extraordinary and impossible proposal that the
  • Germans should not be heard. If only the President had not been so
  • conscientious, if only he had not concealed from himself what he had
  • been doing, even at the last moment he was in, a position to have
  • recovered lost ground and to have achieved some very considerable
  • successes. But the President was set. His arms and legs had been spliced
  • by the surgeons to a certain posture, and they must be broken again
  • before they could be altered. To his horror, Mr. Lloyd George, desiring
  • at the last moment all the moderation he dared, discovered that he could
  • not in five days persuade the President of error in what it had taken
  • five months to prove to him to be just and right. After all, it was
  • harder to de-bamboozle this old Presbyterian than it had been to
  • bamboozle him; for the former involved his belief in and respect for
  • himself.
  • Thus in the last act the President stood for stubbornness and a refusal
  • of conciliations.
  • FOOTNOTES:
  • [6] He alone amongst the Four could speak and understand both
  • languages, Orlando knowing only French and the Prime Minister and
  • President only English; and it is of historical importance that Orlando
  • and the President had no direct means of communication.
  • CHAPTER IV
  • THE TREATY
  • The thoughts which I have expressed in the second chapter were not
  • present to the mind of Paris. The future life of Europe was not their
  • concern; its means of livelihood was not their anxiety. Their
  • preoccupations, good and bad alike, related to frontiers and
  • nationalities, to the balance of power, to imperial aggrandizements, to
  • the future enfeeblement of a strong and dangerous enemy, to revenge, and
  • to the shifting by the victors of their unbearable financial burdens on
  • to the shoulders of the defeated.
  • Two rival schemes for the future polity of the world took the
  • field,--the Fourteen Points of the President, and the Carthaginian Peace
  • of M. Clemenceau. Yet only one of these was entitled to take the field;
  • for the enemy had not surrendered unconditionally, but on agreed terms
  • as to the general character of the Peace.
  • This aspect of what happened cannot, unfortunately, be passed over with
  • a word, for in the minds of many Englishmen at least it has been a
  • subject of very great misapprehension. Many persons believe that the
  • Armistice Terms constituted the first Contract concluded between the
  • Allied and Associated Powers and the German Government, and that we
  • entered the Conference with our hands, free, except so far as these
  • Armistice Terms might bind us. This was not the case. To make the
  • position plain, it is necessary briefly to review the history, of the
  • negotiations which began with the German Note of October 5, 1918, and
  • concluded with President Wilson's Note of November 5, 1918.
  • On October 5, 1918, the German Government addressed a brief Note to the
  • President accepting the Fourteen Points and asking for Peace
  • negotiations. The President's reply of October 8 asked if he was to
  • understand definitely that the German Government accepted "the terms
  • laid down" in Fourteen Points and in his subsequent Addresses and "that
  • its object in entering into discussion would be only to agree upon the
  • practical details of their application." He added that the evacuation of
  • invaded territory must be a prior condition of an Armistice. On October
  • 12 the German Government returned an unconditional affirmative to these
  • questions;-"its object in entering into discussions would be only to
  • agree upon practical details of the application of these terms." On
  • October 14, having received this affirmative answer, the President made
  • a further communication to make clear the points: (1) that the details
  • of the Armistice would have to be left to the military advisers of the
  • United States and the Allies, and must provide absolutely against the
  • possibility of Germany's resuming hostilities; (2) that submarine
  • warfare must cease if these conversations were to continue; and (3) that
  • he required further guarantees of the representative character of the
  • Government with which he was dealing. On October 20 Germany accepted
  • points (1) and (2), and pointed out, as regards (3), that she now had a
  • Constitution and a Government dependent for its authority on the
  • Reichstag. On October 23 the President announced that, "having received
  • the solemn and explicit assurance of the German Government that it
  • unreservedly accepts the terms of peace laid down in his Address to the
  • Congress of the United States on January 8, 1918 (the Fourteen Points),
  • and the principles of settlement enunciated in his subsequent Addresses,
  • particularly the Address of September 27, and that it is ready to
  • discuss the details of their application," he has communicated the above
  • correspondence to the Governments of the Allied Powers "with the
  • suggestion that, if these Governments are disposed to effect peace upon
  • the terms and principles indicated," they will ask their military
  • advisers to draw up Armistice Terms of such a character as to "ensure to
  • the Associated Governments the unrestricted power to safeguard and
  • enforce the details of the peace to which the German Government has
  • agreed." At the end of this Note the President hinted more openly than
  • in that of October 14 at the abdication of the Kaiser. This completes
  • the preliminary negotiations to which the President alone was a party,
  • adding without the Governments of the Allied Powers.
  • On November 5, 1918, the President transmitted to Germany the reply he
  • had received from the Governments associated with him, and added that
  • Marshal Foch had been authorized to communicate the terms of an
  • armistice to properly accredited representatives. In this reply the
  • Allied Governments, "subject to the qualifications which follow, declare
  • their willingness to make peace with the Government of Germany on the
  • terms of peace laid down in the President's Address to Congress of
  • January 8, 1918, and the principles of settlement enunciated in his
  • subsequent Addresses." The qualifications in question were two in
  • number. The first related to the Freedom of the Seas, as to which they
  • "reserved to themselves complete freedom." The second related to
  • Reparation and ran as follows:--"Further, in the conditions of peace
  • laid down in his Address to Congress on the 8th January, 1918 the
  • President declared that invaded territories must be restored as well as
  • evacuated and made free. The Allied Governments feel that no doubt
  • ought to be allowed to exist as to what this provision implies. By it
  • they understand that compensation will be made by Germany for all damage
  • done to the civilian population of the Allies and to their property by
  • the aggression of Germany by land, by sea, and from the air."[7]
  • The nature of the Contract between Germany and the Allies resulting from
  • this exchange of documents is plain and unequivocal. The terms of the
  • peace are to be in accordance with the Addresses of the President, and
  • the purpose of the Peace Conference is "to discuss the details of their
  • application." The circumstances of the Contract were of an unusually
  • solemn and binding character; for one of the conditions of it was that
  • Germany should agree to Armistice Terms which were to be such as would
  • leave her helpless. Germany having rendered herself helpless in reliance
  • on the Contract, the honor of the Allies was peculiarly involved in
  • fulfilling their part and, if there were ambiguities, in not using their
  • position to take advantage of them.
  • What, then, was the substance of this Contract to which the Allies had
  • bound themselves? An examination of the documents shows that, although a
  • large part of the Addresses is concerned with spirit, purpose, and
  • intention, and not with concrete solutions, and that many questions
  • requiring a settlement in the Peace Treaty are not touched on,
  • nevertheless, there are certain questions which they settle definitely.
  • It is true that within somewhat wide limits the Allies still had a free
  • hand. Further, it is difficult to apply on a contractual basis those
  • passages which deal with spirit, purpose, and intention;--every man must
  • judge for himself whether, in view of them, deception or hypocrisy has
  • been practised. But there remain, as will be seen below, certain
  • important issues on which the Contract is unequivocal.
  • In addition to the Fourteen Points of January 18, 1918, the Addresses of
  • the President which form part of the material of the Contract are four
  • in number,--before the Congress on February 11; at Baltimore on April 6;
  • at Mount Vernon on July 4; and at New York on September 27, the last of
  • these being specially referred to in the Contract. I venture to select
  • from these Addresses those engagements of substance, avoiding
  • repetitions, which are most relevant to the German Treaty. The parts I
  • omit add to, rather than detract from, those I quote; but they chiefly
  • relate to intention, and are perhaps too vague and general to be
  • interpreted contractually.[8]
  • _The Fourteen Points_.--(3). "The removal, so far as possible, of all
  • economic barriers and the establishment of an equality of trade
  • conditions among _all_ the nations consenting to the Peace and
  • associating themselves for its maintenance." (4). "Adequate guarantees
  • _given and taken_ that national armaments will be reduced to the lowest
  • point consistent with domestic safety." (5). "A free, open-minded, and
  • absolutely impartial adjustment of all colonial claims," regard being
  • had to the interests of the populations concerned. (6), (7), (8), and
  • (11). The evacuation and "restoration" of all invaded territory,
  • especially of Belgium. To this must be added the rider of the Allies,
  • claiming compensation for all damage done to civilians and their
  • property by land, by sea, and from the air (quoted in full above). (8).
  • The righting of "the wrong done to France by Prussia in 1871 in the
  • matter of Alsace-Lorraine." (13). An independent Poland, including "the
  • territories inhabited by indisputably Polish populations" and "assured a
  • free and secure access to the sea." (14). The League of Nations.
  • _Before the Congress, February 11_.--"There shall be no annexations, _no
  • contributions, no punitive damages_.... Self-determination is not a
  • mere phrase. It is an imperative principle of action which statesmen
  • will henceforth ignore at their peril.... Every territorial settlement
  • involved in this war must be made in the interest and for the benefit of
  • the populations concerned, and not as a part of any mere adjustment or
  • compromise of claims amongst rival States."
  • _New York, September 27_.--(1) "The impartial justice meted out must
  • involve no discrimination between those to whom we wish to be just and
  • those to whom we do not wish to be just." (2) "No special or separate
  • interest of any single nation or any group of nations can be made the
  • basis of any part of the settlement which is not consistent with the
  • common interest of all." (3) "There can be no leagues or alliances or
  • special covenants and understandings within the general and common
  • family of the League of Nations." (4) "There can be no special selfish
  • economic combinations within the League and no employment of any form of
  • economic boycott or exclusion, except as the power of economic penalty
  • by exclusion from the markets of the world may be vested in the League
  • of Nations itself as a means of discipline and control." (5) "All
  • international agreements and treaties of every kind must be made known
  • in their entirety to the rest of the world."
  • This wise and magnanimous program for the world had passed on November
  • 5, 1918 beyond the region of idealism and aspiration, and had become
  • part of a solemn contract to which all the Great Powers of the world had
  • put their signature. But it was lost, nevertheless, in the morass of
  • Paris;--the spirit of it altogether, the letter in parts ignored and in
  • other parts distorted.
  • The German observations on the draft Treaty of Peace were largely a
  • comparison between the terms of this understanding, on the basis of
  • which the German nation had agreed to lay down its arms, and the actual
  • provisions of the document offered them for signature thereafter. The
  • German commentators had little difficulty in showing that the draft
  • Treaty constituted a breach of engagements and of international morality
  • comparable with their own offense in the invasion of Belgium.
  • Nevertheless, the German reply was not in all its parts a document fully
  • worthy of the occasion, because in spite of the justice and importance
  • of much of its contents, a truly broad treatment and high dignity of
  • outlook were a little wanting, and the general effect lacks the simple
  • treatment, with the dispassionate objectivity of despair which the deep
  • passions of the occasion might have evoked. The Allied governments gave
  • it, in any case, no serious consideration, and I doubt if anything which
  • the German delegation could have said at that stage of the proceedings
  • would have much influenced the result.
  • The commonest virtues of the individual are often lacking in the
  • spokesmen of nations; a statesman representing not himself but his
  • country may prove, without incurring excessive blame--as history often
  • records--vindictive, perfidious, and egotistic. These qualities are
  • familiar in treaties imposed by victors. But the German delegation did
  • not succeed in exposing in burning and prophetic words the quality which
  • chiefly distinguishes this transaction from all its historical
  • predecessors--its insincerity.
  • This theme, however, must be for another pen than mine. I am mainly
  • concerned in what follows, not with the justice of the Treaty,--neither
  • with the demand for penal justice against the enemy, nor with the
  • obligation of contractual justice on the victor,--but with its wisdom
  • and with its consequences.
  • I propose, therefore, in this chapter to set forth baldly the principal
  • economic provisions of the Treaty, reserving, however, for the next my
  • comments on the Reparation Chapter and on Germany's capacity to meet the
  • payments there demanded from her.
  • The German economic system as it existed before the war depended on
  • three main factors: I. Overseas commerce as represented by her
  • mercantile marine, her colonies, her foreign investments, her exports,
  • and the overseas connections of her merchants; II. The exploitation of
  • her coal and iron and the industries built upon them; III. Her transport
  • and tariff system. Of these the first, while not the least important,
  • was certainly the most vulnerable. The Treaty aims at the systematic
  • destruction of all three, but principally of the first two.
  • I
  • (1) Germany has ceded to the Allies _all_ the vessels of her mercantile
  • marine exceeding 1600 tons gross, half the vessels between 1000 tons and
  • 1600 tons, and one quarter of her trawlers and other fishing boats.[9]
  • The cession is comprehensive, including not only vessels flying the
  • German flag, but also all vessels owned by Germans but flying other
  • flags, and all vessels under construction as well as those afloat.[10]
  • Further, Germany undertakes, if required, to build for the Allies such
  • types of ships as they may specify up to 200,000 tons[11] annually for
  • five years, the value of these ships being credited to Germany against
  • what is due from her for Reparation.[12]
  • Thus the German mercantile marine is swept from the seas and cannot be
  • restored for many years to come on a scale adequate to meet the
  • requirements of her own commerce. For the present, no lines will run
  • from Hamburg, except such as foreign nations may find it worth while to
  • establish out of their surplus tonnage. Germany will have to pay to
  • foreigners for the carriage of her trade such charges as they may be
  • able to exact, and will receive only such conveniences as it may suit
  • them to give her. The prosperity of German ports and commerce can only
  • revive, it would seem, in proportion as she succeeds in bringing under
  • her effective influence the merchant marines of Scandinavia and of
  • Holland.
  • (2) Germany has ceded to the Allies "all her rights and titles over her
  • oversea possessions."[13] This cession not only applies to sovereignty
  • but extends on unfavorable terms to Government property, all of which,
  • including railways, must be surrendered without payment, while, on the
  • other hand, the German Government remains liable for any debt which may
  • have been incurred for the purchase or construction of this property, or
  • for the development of the colonies generally.[14]
  • In distinction from the practice ruling in the case of most similar
  • cessions in recent history, the property and persons of private German
  • nationals, as distinct from their Government, are also injuriously
  • affected. The Allied Government exercising authority in any former
  • German colony "may make such provisions as it thinks fit with reference
  • to the repatriation from them of German nationals and to the conditions
  • upon which German subjects of European origin shall, or shall not, be
  • allowed to reside, hold property, trade or exercise a profession in
  • them."[15] All contracts and agreements in favor of German nationals for
  • the construction or exploitation of public works lapse to the Allied
  • Governments as part of the payment due for Reparation.
  • But these terms are unimportant compared with the more comprehensive
  • provision by which "the Allied and Associated Powers reserve the right
  • to retain and liquidate _all_ property, rights, and interests belonging
  • at the date of the coming into force of the present Treaty to German
  • nationals, or companies controlled by them," within the former German
  • colonies.[16] This wholesale expropriation of private property is to
  • take place without the Allies affording any compensation to the
  • individuals expropriated, and the proceeds will be employed, first, to
  • meet private debts due to Allied nationals from any German nationals,
  • and second, to meet claims due from Austrian, Hungarian, Bulgarian, or
  • Turkish nationals. Any balance may either be returned by the liquidating
  • Power direct to Germany, or retained by them. If retained, the proceeds
  • must be transferred to the Reparation Commission for Germany's credit in
  • the Reparation account.[17]
  • In short, not only are German sovereignty and German influence
  • extirpated from the whole of her former oversea possessions, but the
  • persons and property of her nationals resident or owning property in
  • those parts are deprived of legal status and legal security.
  • (3) The provisions just outlined in regard to the private property of
  • Germans in the ex-German colonies apply equally to private German
  • property in Alsace-Lorraine, except in so far as the French Government
  • may choose to grant exceptions.[18] This is of much greater practical
  • importance than the similar expropriation overseas because of the far
  • higher value of the property involved and the closer interconnection,
  • resulting from the great development of the mineral wealth of these
  • provinces since 1871, of German economic interests there with those in
  • Germany itself. Alsace-Lorraine has been part of the German Empire for
  • nearly fifty years--a considerable majority of its population is German
  • speaking--and it has been the scene of some of Germany's most important
  • economic enterprises. Nevertheless, the property of those Germans who
  • reside there, or who have invested in its industries, is now entirely at
  • the disposal of the French Government without compensation, except in so
  • far as the German Government itself may choose to afford it. The French
  • Government is entitled to expropriate without compensation the personal
  • property of private German citizens and German companies resident or
  • situated within Alsace-Lorraine, the proceeds being credited in part
  • satisfaction of various French claims. The severity of this provision is
  • only mitigated to the extent that the French Government may expressly
  • permit German nationals to continue to reside, in which case the above
  • provision is not applicable. Government, State, and Municipal property,
  • on the other hand, is to be ceded to France without any credit being
  • given for it. This includes the railway system of the two provinces,
  • together with its rolling-stock.[19] But while the property is taken
  • over, liabilities contracted in respect of it in the form of public
  • debts of any kind remain the liability of Germany.[20] The provinces
  • also return to French sovereignty free and quit of their share of German
  • war or pre-war dead-weight debt; nor does Germany receive a credit on
  • this account in respect of Reparation.
  • (4) The expropriation of German private property is not limited,
  • however, to the ex-German colonies and Alsace-Lorraine. The treatment of
  • such property forms, indeed, a very significant and material section of
  • the Treaty, which has not received as much attention as it merits,
  • although it was the subject of exceptionally violent objection on the
  • part of the German delegates at Versailles. So far as I know, there is
  • no precedent in any peace treaty of recent history for the treatment of
  • private property set forth below, and the German representatives urged
  • that the precedent now established strikes a dangerous and immoral blow
  • at the security of private property everywhere. This is an exaggeration,
  • and the sharp distinction, approved by custom and convention during the
  • past two centuries, between the property and rights of a State and the
  • property and rights of its nationals is an artificial one, which is
  • being rapidly put out of date by many other influences than the Peace
  • Treaty, and is inappropriate to modern socialistic conceptions of the
  • relations between the State and its citizens. It is true, however, that
  • the Treaty strikes a destructive blow at a conception which lies at the
  • root of much of so-called international law, as this has been expounded
  • hitherto.
  • The principal provisions relating to the expropriation of German private
  • property situated outside the frontiers of Germany, as these are now
  • determined, are overlapping in their incidence, and the more drastic
  • would seem in some cases to render the others unnecessary. Generally
  • speaking, however, the more drastic and extensive provisions are not so
  • precisely framed as those of more particular and limited application.
  • They are as follows:--
  • (_a_) The Allies "reserve the right to retain and liquidate all
  • property, rights and interests belonging at the date of the coming into
  • force of the present Treaty to German nationals, or companies controlled
  • by them, within their territories, colonies, possessions and
  • protectorates, including territories ceded to them by the present
  • Treaty."[21]
  • This is the extended version of the provision which has been discussed
  • already in the case of the colonies and of Alsace-Lorraine. The value of
  • the property so expropriated will be applied, in the first instance, to
  • the satisfaction of private debts due from Germany to the nationals of
  • the Allied Government within whose jurisdiction the liquidation takes
  • place, and, second, to the satisfaction of claims arising out of the
  • acts of Germany's former allies. Any balance, if the liquidating
  • Government elects to retain it, must be credited in the Reparation
  • account.[22] It is, however, a point of considerable importance that the
  • liquidating Government is not compelled to transfer the balance to the
  • Reparation Commission, but can, if it so decides, return the proceeds
  • direct to Germany. For this will enable the United States, if they so
  • wish, to utilize the very large balances, in the hands of their
  • enemy-property custodian, to pay for the provisioning of Germany,
  • without regard to the views of the Reparation Commission.
  • These provisions had their origin in the scheme for the mutual
  • settlement of enemy debts by means of a Clearing House. Under this
  • proposal it was hoped to avoid much trouble and litigation by making
  • each of the Governments lately at war responsible for the collection of
  • private _debts_ due from its nationals to the nationals of any of the
  • other Governments (the normal process of collection having been
  • suspended by reason of the war), and for the distribution of the funds
  • so collected to those of its nationals who had _claims_ against the
  • nationals of the other Governments, any final balance either way being
  • settled in cash. Such a scheme could have been completely bilateral and
  • reciprocal. And so in part it is, the scheme being mainly reciprocal as
  • regards the collection of commercial debts. But the completeness of
  • their victory permitted the Allied Governments to introduce in their own
  • favor many divergencies from reciprocity, of which the following are the
  • chief: Whereas the property of Allied nationals within German
  • jurisdiction reverts under the Treaty to Allied ownership on the
  • conclusion of Peace, the property of Germans within Allied jurisdiction
  • is to be retained and liquidated as described above, with the result
  • that the whole of German property over a large part of the world can be
  • expropriated, and the large properties now within the custody of Public
  • Trustees and similar officials in the Allied countries may be retained
  • permanently. In the second place, such German assets are chargeable, not
  • only with the liabilities of Germans, but also, if they run to it, with
  • "payment of the amounts due in respect of claims by the nationals of
  • such Allied or Associated Power with regard to their property, rights,
  • and interests in the territory of other Enemy Powers," as, for example,
  • Turkey, Bulgaria, and Austria.[23] This is a remarkable provision,
  • which is naturally non-reciprocal. In the third place, any final balance
  • due to Germany on private account need not be paid over, but can be held
  • against the various liabilities of the German Government.[24] The
  • effective operation of these Articles is guaranteed by the delivery of
  • deeds, titles, and information.[25] In the fourth place, pre-war
  • contracts between Allied and German nationals may be canceled or revived
  • at the option of the former, so that all such contracts which are in
  • Germany's favor will be canceled, while, on the other hand, she will be
  • compelled to fulfil those which are to her disadvantage.
  • (_b_) So far we have been concerned with German property within Allied
  • jurisdiction. The next provision is aimed at the elimination of German
  • interests in the territory of her neighbors and former allies, and of
  • certain other countries. Under Article 260 of the Financial Clauses it
  • is provided that the Reparation Commission may, within one year of the
  • coming into force of the Treaty, demand that the German Government
  • expropriate its nationals and deliver to the Reparation Commission "any
  • rights and interests of German nationals in any public utility
  • undertaking or in any concession[26] operating in Russia, China, Turkey,
  • Austria, Hungary, and Bulgaria, or in the possessions or dependencies of
  • these States, or in any territory formerly belonging to Germany or her
  • allies, to be ceded by Germany or her allies to any Power or to be
  • administered by a Mandatory under the present Treaty." This is a
  • comprehensive description, overlapping in part the provisions dealt with
  • under (_a_) above, but including, it should be noted, the new States and
  • territories carved out of the former Russian, Austro-Hungarian, and
  • Turkish Empires. Thus Germany's influence is eliminated and her capital
  • confiscated in all those neighboring countries to which she might
  • naturally look for her future livelihood, and for an outlet for her
  • energy, enterprise, and technical skill.
  • The execution of this program in detail will throw on the Reparation
  • Commission a peculiar task, as it will become possessor of a great
  • number of rights and interests over a vast territory owing dubious
  • obedience, disordered by war, disruption, and Bolshevism. The division
  • of the spoils between the victors will also provide employment for a
  • powerful office, whose doorsteps the greedy adventurers and jealous
  • concession-hunters of twenty or thirty nations will crowd and defile.
  • Lest the Reparation Commission fail by ignorance to exercise its rights
  • to the full, it is further provided that the German Government shall
  • communicate to it within six months of the Treaty's coming into force a
  • list of all the rights and interests in question, "whether already
  • granted, contingent or not yet exercised," and any which are not so
  • communicated within this period will automatically lapse in favor of the
  • Allied Governments.[27] How far an edict of this character can be made
  • binding on a German national, whose person and property lie outside the
  • jurisdiction of his own Government, is an unsettled question; but all
  • the countries specified in the above list are open to pressure by the
  • Allied authorities, whether by the imposition of an appropriate Treaty
  • clause or otherwise.
  • (_c_) There remains a third provision more sweeping than either of the
  • above, neither of which affects German interests in _neutral_
  • countries. The Reparation Commission is empowered up to May 1, 1921, to
  • demand payment up to $5,000,000,000 _in such manner as they may fix_,
  • "whether in gold, commodities, ships, securities or otherwise."[28] This
  • provision has the effect of intrusting to the Reparation Commission for
  • the period in question dictatorial powers over all German property of
  • every description whatever. They can, under this Article, point to any
  • specific business, enterprise, or property, whether within or outside
  • Germany, and demand its surrender; and their authority would appear to
  • extend not only to property existing at the date of the Peace, but also
  • to any which may be created or acquired at any time in the course of the
  • next eighteen months. For example, they could pick out--as presumably
  • they will as soon as they are established--the fine and powerful German
  • enterprise in South America known as the _Deutsche Ueberseeische
  • Elektrizitätsgesellschaft_ (the D.U.E.G.), and dispose of it to Allied
  • interests. The clause is unequivocal and all-embracing. It is worth
  • while to note in passing that it introduces a quite novel principle in
  • the collection of indemnities. Hitherto, a sum has been fixed, and the
  • nation mulcted has been left free to devise and select for itself the
  • means of payment. But in this case the payees can (for a certain
  • period) not only demand a certain sum but specify the particular kind of
  • property in which payment is to be effected. Thus the powers of the
  • Reparation Commission, with which I deal more particularly in the next
  • chapter, can be employed to destroy Germany's commercial and economic
  • organization as well as to exact payment.
  • The cumulative effect of (_a_), (_b_), and (_c_) (as well as of certain
  • other minor provisions on which I have not thought it necessary to
  • enlarge) is to deprive Germany (or rather to empower the Allies so to
  • deprive her at their will--it is not yet accomplished) of everything she
  • possesses outside her own frontiers as laid down in the Treaty. Not only
  • are her oversea investments taken and her connections destroyed, but the
  • same process of extirpation is applied in the territories of her former
  • allies and of her immediate neighbors by land.
  • (5) Lest by some oversight the above provisions should overlook any
  • possible contingencies, certain other Articles appear in the Treaty,
  • which probably do not add very much in practical effect to those already
  • described, but which deserve brief mention as showing the spirit of
  • completeness in which the victorious Powers entered upon the economic
  • subjection of their defeated enemy.
  • First of all there is a general clause of barrer and renunciation: "In
  • territory outside her European frontiers as fixed by the present Treaty,
  • Germany renounces all rights, titles and privileges whatever in or over
  • territory which belonged to her or to her allies, and all rights, titles
  • and privileges whatever their origin which she held as against the
  • Allied and Associated Powers...."[29]
  • There follow certain more particular provisions. Germany renounces all
  • rights and privileges she may have acquired in China.[30] There are
  • similar provisions for Siam,[31] for Liberia,[32] for Morocco,[33] and
  • for Egypt.[34] In the case of Egypt not only are special privileges
  • renounced, but by Article 150 ordinary liberties are withdrawn, the
  • Egyptian Government being accorded "complete liberty of action in
  • regulating the status of German nationals and the conditions under which
  • they may establish themselves in Egypt."
  • By Article 258 Germany renounces her right to any participation in any
  • financial or economic organizations of an international character
  • "operating in any of the Allied or Associated States, or in Austria,
  • Hungary, Bulgaria or Turkey, or in the dependencies of these States, or
  • in the former Russian Empire."
  • Generally speaking, only those pre-war treaties and conventions are
  • revived which it suits the Allied Governments to revive, and those in
  • Germany's favor may be allowed to lapse.[35]
  • It is evident, however, that none of these provisions are of any real
  • importance, as compared with those described previously. They represent
  • the logical completion of Germany's outlawry and economic subjection to
  • the convenience of the Allies; but they do not add substantially to her
  • effective disabilities.
  • II
  • The provisions relating to coal and iron are more important in respect
  • of their ultimate consequences on Germany's internal industrial economy
  • than for the money value immediately involved. The German Empire has
  • been built more truly on coal and iron than on blood and iron. The
  • skilled exploitation of the great coalfields of the Ruhr, Upper Silesia,
  • and the Saar, alone made possible the development of the steel,
  • chemical, and electrical industries which established her as the first
  • industrial nation of continental Europe. One-third of Germany's
  • population lives in towns of more than 20,000 inhabitants, an industrial
  • concentration which is only possible on a foundation of coal and iron.
  • In striking, therefore, at her coal supply, the French politicians were
  • not mistaking their target. It is only the extreme immoderation, and
  • indeed technical impossibility, of the Treaty's demands which may save
  • the situation in the long-run.
  • (1) The Treaty strikes at Germany's coal supply in four ways:--
  • (i.) "As compensation for the destruction of the coal-mines in the north
  • of France, and as part payment towards the total reparation due from
  • Germany for the damage resulting from the war, Germany cedes to France
  • in full and absolute possession, with exclusive rights of exploitation,
  • unencumbered, and free from all debts and charges of any kind, the
  • coal-mines situated in the Saar Basin."[36] While the administration of
  • this district is vested for fifteen years in the League of Nations, it
  • is to be observed that the mines are ceded to France absolutely. Fifteen
  • years hence the population of the district will be called upon to
  • indicate by plebiscite their desires as to the future sovereignty of the
  • territory; and, in the event of their electing for union with Germany,
  • Germany is to be entitled to repurchase the mines at a price payable in
  • gold.[37]
  • The judgment of the world has already recognized the transaction of the
  • Saar as an act of spoliation and insincerity. So far as compensation for
  • the destruction of French coal-mines is concerned, this is provided for,
  • as we shall see in a moment, elsewhere in the Treaty. "There is no
  • industrial region in Germany," the German representatives have said
  • without contradiction, "the population of which is so permanent, so
  • homogeneous, and so little complex as that of the Saar district. Among
  • more than 650,000 inhabitants, there were in 1918 less than 100 French.
  • The Saar district has been German for more than 1,000 years. Temporary
  • occupation as a result of warlike operations on the part of the French
  • always terminated in a short time in the restoration of the country upon
  • the conclusion of peace. During a period of 1048 years France has
  • possessed the country for not quite 68 years in all. When, on the
  • occasion of the first Treaty of Paris in 1814, a small portion of the
  • territory now coveted was retained for France, the population raised the
  • most energetic opposition and demanded 'reunion with their German
  • fatherland,' to which they were 'related by language, customs, and
  • religion.' After an occupation of one year and a quarter, this desire
  • was taken into account in the second Treaty of Paris in 1815. Since then
  • the country has remained uninterruptedly attached to Germany, and owes
  • its economic development to that connection."
  • The French wanted the coal for the purpose of working the ironfields of
  • Lorraine, and in the spirit of Bismarck they have taken it. Not
  • precedent, but the verbal professions of the Allies, have rendered it
  • indefensible.[38]
  • (ii.) Upper Silesia, a district without large towns, in which, however,
  • lies one of the major coalfields of Germany with a production of about
  • 23 per cent of the total German output of hard coal, is, subject to a
  • plebiscite,[39] to be ceded to Poland. Upper Silesia was never part of
  • historic Poland; but its population is mixed Polish, German, and
  • Czecho-Slovakian, the precise proportions of which are disputed.[40]
  • Economically it is intensely German; the industries of Eastern Germany
  • depend upon it for their coal; and its loss would be a destructive blow
  • at the economic structure of the German State.[41]
  • With the loss of the fields of Upper Silesia and the Saar, the coal
  • supplies of Germany are diminished by not far short of one-third.
  • (iii.) Out of the coal that remains to her, Germany is obliged to make
  • good year by year the estimated loss which France has incurred by the
  • destruction and damage of war in the coalfields of her northern
  • Provinces. In para. 2 of Annex V. to the Reparation Chapter, "Germany
  • undertakes to deliver to France annually, for a period not exceeding ten
  • years, an amount of coal equal to the difference between the annual
  • production before the war of the coal-mines of the Nord and Pas de
  • Calais, destroyed as a result of the war, and the production of the
  • mines of the same area during the year in question: such delivery not to
  • exceed 20,000,000 tons in any one year of the first five years, and
  • 8,000,000 tons in any one year of the succeeding five years."
  • This is a reasonable provision if it stood by itself, and one which
  • Germany should be able to fulfil if she were left her other resources to
  • do it with.
  • (iv.) The final provision relating to coal is part of the general scheme
  • of the Reparation Chapter by which the sums due for Reparation are to be
  • partly paid in kind instead of in cash. As a part of the payment due for
  • Reparation, Germany is to make the following deliveries of coal or
  • equivalent in coke (the deliveries to France being wholly additional to
  • the amounts available by the cession of the Saar or in compensation for
  • destruction in Northern France):--
  • (i.) To France 7,000,000 tons annually for ten years;[42]
  • (ii.) To Belgium 8,000,000 tons annually for ten years;
  • (iii.) To Italy an annual quantity, rising by annual increments from
  • 4,500,000 tons in 1919-1920 to 8,500,000 tons in each of the six years,
  • 1923-1924 to 1928-1929;
  • (iv.) To Luxemburg, if required, a quantity of coal equal to the
  • pre-war annual consumption of German coal in Luxemburg.
  • This amounts in all to an annual average of about 25,000,000 tons.
  • * * * * *
  • These figures have to be examined in relation to Germany's probable
  • output. The maximum pre-war figure was reached in 1913 with a total of
  • 191,500,000 tons. Of this, 19,000,000 tons were consumed at the mines,
  • and on balance (_i.e._ exports less imports) 33,500,000 tons were
  • exported, leaving 139,000,000 tons for domestic consumption. It is
  • estimated that this total was employed as follows:--
  • Railways 18,000,000 tons.
  • Gas, water, and electricity 12,500,000 "
  • Bunkers 6,500,000 "
  • House-fuel, small industry
  • and agriculture 24,000,000 "
  • Industry 78,000,000 "
  • -----------
  • 139,000,000 "
  • The diminution of production due to loss of territory is:--
  • Alsace-Lorraine 3,800,000 tons.
  • Saar Basin 13,200,000 "
  • Upper Silesia 43,800,000 "
  • -----------
  • 60,800,000 "
  • There would remain, therefore, on the basis of the 1913 output,
  • 130,700,000 tons, or, deducting consumption at the mines themselves,
  • (say) 118,000,000 tons. For some years there must be sent out of this
  • supply upwards of 20,000,000 tons to France as compensation for damage
  • done to French mines, and 25,000,000 tons to France, Belgium, Italy, and
  • Luxemburg;[43] as the former figure is a maximum, and the latter figure
  • is to be slightly less in the earliest years, we may take the total
  • export to Allied countries which Germany has undertaken to provide as
  • 40,000,000 tons, leaving, on the above basis, 78,000,000 tons for her
  • own use as against a pre-war consumption of 139,000,000 tons.
  • This comparison, however, requires substantial modification to make it
  • accurate. On the one hand, it is certain that the figures of pre-war
  • output cannot be relied on as a basis of present output. During 1918 the
  • production was 161,500,000 tons as compared with 191,500,000 tons in
  • 1913; and during the first half of 1919 it was less than 50,000,000
  • tons, exclusive of Alsace-Lorraine and the Saar but including Upper
  • Silesia, corresponding to an annual production of about 100,000,000
  • tons.[44] The causes of so low an output were in part temporary and
  • exceptional but the German authorities agree, and have not been
  • confuted, that some of them are bound to persist for some time to come.
  • In part they are the same as elsewhere; the daily shift has been
  • shortened from 8-1/2 to 7 hours, and it is improbable that the powers of
  • the Central Government will be adequate to restore them to their former
  • figure. But in addition, the mining plant is in bad condition (due to
  • the lack of certain essential materials during the blockade), the
  • physical efficiency of the men is greatly impaired by malnutrition
  • (which cannot be cured if a tithe of the reparation demands are to be
  • satisfied,--the standard of life will have rather to be lowered), and
  • the casualties of the war have diminished the numbers of efficient
  • miners. The analogy of English conditions is sufficient by itself to
  • tell us that a pre-war level of output cannot be expected in Germany.
  • German authorities put the loss of output at somewhat above 30 per
  • cent, divided about equally between the shortening of the shift and the
  • other economic influences. This figure appears on general grounds to be
  • plausible, but I have not the knowledge to endorse or to criticize it.
  • The pre-war figure of 118,000,000 tons net (_i.e._ after allowing for
  • loss of territory and consumption at the mines) is likely to fall,
  • therefore, at least as low as to 100,000,000[45] tons, having regard to
  • the above factors. If 40,000,000 tons of this are to be exported to the
  • Allies, there remain 60,000,000 tons for Germany herself to meet her own
  • domestic consumption. Demand as well as supply will be diminished by
  • loss of territory, but at the most extravagant estimate this could not
  • be put above 29,000,000 tons.[46] Our hypothetical calculations,
  • therefore, leave us with post-war German domestic requirements, on the
  • basis of a pre-war efficiency of railways and industry, of 110,000,000
  • tons against an output not exceeding 100,000,000 tons, of which
  • 40,000,000 tons are mortgaged to the Allies.
  • The importance of the subject has led me into a somewhat lengthy
  • statistical analysis. It is evident that too much significance must not
  • be attached to the precise figures arrived at, which are hypothetical
  • and dubious.[47] But the general character of the facts presents itself
  • irresistibly. Allowing for the loss of territory and the loss of
  • efficiency, Germany cannot export coal in the near future (and will even
  • be dependent on her Treaty rights to purchase in Upper Silesia), if she
  • is to continue as an industrial nation. Every million tons she is forced
  • to export must be at the expense of closing down an industry. With
  • results to be considered later this within certain limits is _possible_.
  • But it is evident that Germany cannot and will not furnish the Allies
  • with a contribution of 40,000,000 tons annually. Those Allied Ministers,
  • who have told their peoples that she can, have certainly deceived them
  • for the sake of allaying for the moment the misgivings of the European
  • peoples as to the path along which they are being led.
  • The presence of these illusory provisions (amongst others) in the
  • clauses of the Treaty of Peace is especially charged with danger for
  • the future. The more extravagant expectations as to Reparation
  • receipts, by which Finance Ministers have deceived their publics, will
  • be heard of no more when they have served their immediate purpose of
  • postponing the hour of taxation and retrenchment. But the coal clauses
  • will not be lost sight of so easily,--for the reason that it will be
  • absolutely vital in the interests of France and Italy that these
  • countries should do everything in their power to exact their bond. As a
  • result of the diminished output due to German destruction in France, of
  • the diminished output of mines in the United Kingdom and elsewhere, and
  • of many secondary causes, such as the breakdown of transport and of
  • organization and the inefficiency of new governments, the coal position
  • of all Europe is nearly desperate;[48] and France and Italy, entering
  • the scramble with certain Treaty rights, will not lightly surrender
  • them.
  • As is generally the case in real dilemmas, the French and Italian case
  • will possess great force, indeed unanswerable force from a certain point
  • of view. The position will be truly represented as a question between
  • German industry on the one hand and French and Italian industry on the
  • other. It may be admitted that the surrender of the coal will destroy
  • German industry, but it may be equally true that its non-surrender will
  • jeopardize French and Italian industry. In such a case must not the
  • victors with their Treaty rights prevail, especially when much of the
  • damage has been ultimately due to the wicked acts of those who are now
  • defeated? Yet if these feelings and these rights are allowed to prevail
  • beyond what wisdom would recommend, the reactions on the social and
  • economic life of Central Europe will be far too strong to be confined
  • within their original limits.
  • But this is not yet the whole problem. If France and Italy are to make
  • good their own deficiencies in coal from the output of Germany, then
  • Northern Europe, Switzerland, and Austria, which previously drew their
  • coal in large part from Germany's exportable surplus, must be starved of
  • their supplies. Before the war 13,600,000 tons of Germany's coal exports
  • went to Austria-Hungary. Inasmuch as nearly all the coalfields of the
  • former Empire lie outside what is now German-Austria, the industrial
  • ruin of this latter state, if she cannot obtain coal from Germany, will
  • be complete. The case of Germany's neutral neighbors, who were formerly
  • supplied in part from Great Britain but in large part from Germany,
  • will be hardly less serious. They will go to great lengths in the
  • direction of making their own supplies to Germany of materials which are
  • essential to her, conditional on these being paid for in coal. Indeed
  • they are already doing so.[49] With the breakdown of money economy the
  • practice of international barter is becoming prevalent. Nowadays money
  • in Central and South-Eastern Europe is seldom a true measure of value in
  • exchange, and will not necessarily buy anything, with the consequence
  • that one country, possessing a commodity essential to the needs of
  • another, sells it not for cash but only against a reciprocal engagement
  • on the part of the latter country to furnish in return some article not
  • less necessary to the former. This is an extraordinary complication as
  • compared with the former almost perfect simplicity of international
  • trade. But in the no less extraordinary conditions of to-day's industry
  • it is not without advantages as a means of stimulating production. The
  • butter-shifts of the Ruhr[50] show how far modern Europe has
  • retrograded in the direction of barter, and afford a picturesque
  • illustration of the low economic organization to which the breakdown of
  • currency and free exchange between individuals and nations is quickly
  • leading us. But they may produce the coal where other devices would
  • fail.[51]
  • Yet if Germany can find coal for the neighboring neutrals, France and
  • Italy may loudly claim that in this case she can and must keep her
  • treaty obligations. In this there will be a great show of justice, and
  • it will be difficult to weigh against such claims the possible facts
  • that, while German miners will work for butter, there is no available
  • means of compelling them to get coal, the sale of which will bring in
  • nothing, and that if Germany has no coal to send to her neighbors she
  • may fail to secure imports essential to her economic existence.
  • If the distribution of the European coal supplies is to be a scramble in
  • which France is satisfied first, Italy next, and every one else takes
  • their chance, the industrial future of Europe is black and the prospects
  • of revolution very good. It is a case where particular interests and
  • particular claims, however well founded in sentiment or in justice,
  • must yield to sovereign expediency. If there is any approximate truth in
  • Mr. Hoover's calculation that the coal output of Europe has fallen by
  • one-third, a situation confronts us where distribution must be effected
  • with even-handed impartiality in accordance with need, and no incentive
  • can be neglected towards increased production and economical methods of
  • transport. The establishment by the Supreme Council of the Allies in
  • August, 1919, of a European Coal Commission, consisting of delegates
  • from Great Britain, France, Italy, Belgium, Poland, and Czecho-Slovakia
  • was a wise measure which, properly employed and extended, may prove of
  • great assistance. But I reserve constructive proposals for Chapter VII.
  • Here I am only concerned with tracing the consequences, _per
  • impossibile_, of carrying out the Treaty _au pied de lettre_.[52]
  • (2) The provisions relating to iron-ore require less detailed attention,
  • though their effects are destructive. They require less attention,
  • because they are in large measure inevitable. Almost exactly 75 per cent
  • of the iron-ore raised in Germany in 1913 came from Alsace-Lorraine.[53]
  • In this the chief importance of the stolen provinces lay.
  • There is no question but that Germany must lose these ore-fields. The
  • only question is how far she is to be allowed facilities for purchasing
  • their produce. The German Delegation made strong efforts to secure the
  • inclusion of a provision by which coal and coke to be furnished by them
  • to France should be given in exchange for _minette_ from Lorraine. But
  • they secured no such stipulation, and the matter remains at France's
  • option.
  • The motives which will govern France's eventual policy are not entirely
  • concordant. While Lorraine comprised 75 per cent of Germany's iron-ore,
  • only 25 per cent of the blast furnaces lay within Lorraine and the Saar
  • basin together, a large proportion of the ore being carried into Germany
  • proper. Approximately the same proportion of Germany's iron and steel
  • foundries, namely 25 per cent, were situated in Alsace-Lorraine. For
  • the moment, therefore, the most economical and profitable course would
  • certainly be to export to Germany, as hitherto, a considerable part of
  • the output of the mines.
  • On the other hand, France, having recovered the deposits of Lorraine,
  • may be expected to aim at replacing as far as possible the industries,
  • which Germany had based on them, by industries situated within her own
  • frontiers. Much time must elapse before the plant and the skilled labor
  • could be developed within France, and even so she could hardly deal with
  • the ore unless she could rely on receiving the coal from Germany. The
  • uncertainty, too, as to the ultimate fate of the Saar will be disturbing
  • to the calculations of capitalists who contemplate the establishment of
  • new industries in France.
  • In fact, here, as elsewhere, political considerations cut disastrously
  • across economic. In a rĂ©gime of Free Trade and free economic intercourse
  • it would be of little consequence that iron lay on one side of a
  • political frontier, and labor, coal, and blast furnaces on the other.
  • But as it is, men have devised ways to impoverish themselves and one
  • another; and prefer collective animosities to individual happiness. It
  • seems certain, calculating on the present passions and impulses of
  • European capitalistic society, that the effective iron output of Europe
  • will be diminished by a new political frontier (which sentiment and
  • historic justice require), because nationalism and private interest are
  • thus allowed to impose a new economic frontier along the same lines.
  • These latter considerations are allowed, in the present governance of
  • Europe, to prevail over the intense need of the Continent for the most
  • sustained and efficient production to repair the destructions of war,
  • and to satisfy the insistence of labor for a larger reward.[54]
  • The same influences are likely to be seen, though on a lesser scale, in
  • the event of the transference of Upper Silesia to Poland. While Upper
  • Silesia contains but little iron, the presence of coal has led to the
  • establishment of numerous blast furnaces. What is to be the fate of
  • these? If Germany is cut off from her supplies of ore on the west, will
  • she export beyond her frontiers on the east any part of the little which
  • remains to her? The efficiency and output of the industry seem certain
  • to diminish.
  • Thus the Treaty strikes at organization, and by the destruction of
  • organization impairs yet further the reduced wealth of the whole
  • community. The economic frontiers which are to be established between
  • the coal and the iron, upon which modern industrialism is founded, will
  • not only diminish the production of useful commodities, but may possibly
  • occupy an immense quantity of human labor in dragging iron or coal, as
  • the case may be, over many useless miles to satisfy the dictates of a
  • political treaty or because obstructions have been established to the
  • proper localization of industry.
  • III
  • There remain those Treaty provisions which relate to the transport and
  • the tariff systems of Germany. These parts of the Treaty have not nearly
  • the importance and the significance of those discussed hitherto. They
  • are pin-pricks, interferences and vexations, not so much objectionable
  • for their solid consequences, as dishonorable to the Allies in the light
  • of their professions. Let the reader consider what follows in the light
  • of the assurances already quoted, in reliance on which Germany laid down
  • her arms.
  • (i.) The miscellaneous Economic Clauses commence with a number of
  • provisions which would be in accordance with the spirit of the third of
  • the Fourteen Points,--if they were reciprocal. Both for imports and
  • exports, and as regards tariffs, regulations, and prohibitions, Germany
  • binds herself for five years to accord most-favored-nation treatment to
  • the Allied and Associated States.[55] But she is not entitled herself to
  • receive such treatment.
  • For five years Alsace-Lorraine shall be free to export into Germany,
  • without payment of customs duty, up to the average amount sent annually
  • into Germany from 1911 to 1913.[56] But there is no similar provision
  • for German exports into Alsace-Lorraine.
  • For three years Polish exports to Germany, and for five years
  • Luxemburg's exports to Germany, are to have a similar privilege,[57]--
  • but not German exports to Poland or to Luxemburg. Luxemburg also, which
  • for many years has enjoyed the benefits of inclusion within the German
  • Customs Union, is permanently excluded from it henceforward.[58]
  • For six months after the Treaty has come into force Germany may not
  • impose duties on imports from the Allied and Associated States higher
  • than the most favorable duties prevalent before the war and for a
  • further two years and a half (making three years in all) this
  • prohibition continues to apply to certain commodities, notably to some
  • of those as to which special agreements existed before the war, and also
  • to wine, to vegetable oils, to artificial silk, and to washed or scoured
  • wool.[59] This is a ridiculous and injurious provision, by which Germany
  • is prevented from taking those steps necessary to conserve her limited
  • resources for the purchase of necessaries and the discharge of
  • Reparation. As a result of the existing distribution of wealth in
  • Germany, and of financial wantonness amongst individuals, the offspring
  • of uncertainty, Germany is threatened with a deluge of luxuries and
  • semi-luxuries from abroad, of which she has been starved for years,
  • which would exhaust or diminish her small supplies of foreign exchange.
  • These provisions strike at the authority of the German Government to
  • ensure economy in such consumption, or to raise taxation during a
  • critical period. What an example of senseless greed overreaching itself,
  • to introduce, after taking from Germany what liquid wealth she has and
  • demanding impossible payments for the future, a special and
  • particularized injunction that she must allow as readily as in the days
  • of her prosperity the import of champagne and of silk!
  • One other Article affects the Customs RĂ©gime of Germany which, if it was
  • applied, would be serious and extensive in its consequences. The Allies
  • have reserved the right to apply a special customs rĂ©gime to the
  • occupied area on the bank of the Rhine, "in the event of such a measure
  • being necessary in their opinion in order to safeguard the economic
  • interests of the population of these territories."[60] This provision
  • was probably introduced as a possibly useful adjunct to the French
  • policy of somehow detaching the left bank provinces from Germany during
  • the years of their occupation. The project of establishing an
  • independent Republic under French clerical auspices, which would act as
  • a buffer state and realize the French ambition of driving Germany proper
  • beyond the Rhine, has not yet been abandoned. Some believe that much may
  • be accomplished by a rĂ©gime of threats, bribes, and cajolery extended
  • over a period of fifteen years or longer.[61] If this Article is acted
  • upon, and the economic system of the left bank of the Rhine is
  • effectively severed from the rest of Germany, the effect would be
  • far-reaching. But the dreams of designing diplomats do not always
  • prosper, and we must trust the future.
  • (ii.) The clauses relating to Railways, as originally presented to
  • Germany, were substantially modified in the final Treaty, and are now
  • limited to a provision by which goods, coming from Allied territory to
  • Germany, or in transit through Germany, shall receive the most favored
  • treatment as regards rail freight rates, etc., applied to goods of the
  • same kind carried on _any_ German lines "under similar conditions of
  • transport, for example, as regards length of route."[62] As a
  • non-reciprocal provision this is an act of interference in internal
  • arrangements which it is difficult to justify, but the practical effect
  • of this,[63] and of an analogous provision relating to passenger
  • traffic,[64] will much depend on the interpretation of the phrase,
  • "similar conditions of transport."[65]
  • For the time being Germany's transport system will be much more
  • seriously disordered by the provisions relating to the cession of
  • rolling-stock. Under paragraph 7 of the Armistice conditions Germany was
  • called on to surrender 5000 locomotives and 150,000 wagons, "in good
  • working order, with all necessary spare parts and fittings." Under the
  • Treaty Germany is required to confirm this surrender and to recognize
  • the title of the Allies to the material.[66] She is further required, in
  • the case of railway systems in ceded territory, to hand over these
  • systems complete with their full complement of rolling-stock "in a
  • normal state of upkeep" as shown in the last inventory before November
  • 11, 1918.[67] That is to say, ceded railway systems are not to bear any
  • share in the general depletion and deterioration of the German
  • rolling-stock as a whole.
  • This is a loss which in course of time can doubtless be made good. But
  • lack of lubricating oils and the prodigious wear and tear of the war,
  • not compensated by normal repairs, had already reduced the German
  • railway system to a low state of efficiency. The further heavy losses
  • under the Treaty will confirm this state of affairs for some time to
  • come, and are a substantial aggravation of the difficulties of the coal
  • problem and of export industry generally.
  • (iii.) There remain the clauses relating to the river system of Germany.
  • These are largely unnecessary and are so little related to the supposed
  • aims of the Allies that their purport is generally unknown. Yet they
  • constitute an unprecedented interference with a country's domestic
  • arrangements and are capable of being so operated as to take from
  • Germany all effective control over her own transport system. In their
  • present form they are incapable of justification; but some simple
  • changes might transform them into a reasonable instrument.
  • Most of the principal rivers of Germany have their source or their
  • outlet in non-German territory. The Rhine, rising in Switzerland, is now
  • a frontier river for a part of its course, and finds the sea in Holland;
  • the Danube rises in Germany but flows over its greater length elsewhere;
  • the Elbe rises in the mountains of Bohemia, now called Czecho-Slovakia;
  • the Oder traverses Lower Silesia; and the Niemen now bounds the frontier
  • of East Prussia and has its source in Russia. Of these, the Rhine and
  • the Niemen are frontier rivers, the Elbe is primarily German but in its
  • upper reaches has much importance for Bohemia, the Danube in its German
  • parts appears to have little concern for any country but Germany, and
  • the Oder is an almost purely German river unless the result of the
  • plebiscite is to detach all Upper Silesia.
  • Rivers which, in the words of the Treaty, "naturally provide more than
  • one State with access to the sea," properly require some measure of
  • international regulation and adequate guarantees against discrimination.
  • This principle has long been recognized in the International Commissions
  • which regulate the Rhine and the Danube. But on such Commissions the
  • States concerned should be represented more or less in proportion to
  • their interests. The Treaty, however, has made the international
  • character of these rivers a pretext for taking the river system of
  • Germany out of German control.
  • After certain Articles which provide suitably against discrimination and
  • interference with freedom of transit,[68] the Treaty proceeds to hand
  • over the administration of the Elbe, the Oder, the Danube, and the Rhine
  • to International Commissions.[69] The ultimate powers of these
  • Commissions are to be determined by "a General Convention drawn up by
  • the Allied and Associated Powers, and approved by the League of
  • Nations."[70] In the meantime the Commissions are to draw up their own
  • constitutions and are apparently to enjoy powers of the most extensive
  • description, "particularly in regard to the execution of works of
  • maintenance, control, and improvement on the river system, the financial
  • rĂ©gime, the fixing and collection of charges, and regulations for
  • navigation."[71]
  • So far there is much to be said for the Treaty. Freedom of through
  • transit is a not unimportant part of good international practice and
  • should be established everywhere. The objectionable feature of the
  • Commissions lies in their membership. In each case the voting is so
  • weighted as to place Germany in a clear minority. On the Elbe Commission
  • Germany has four votes out of ten; on the Oder Commission three out of
  • nine; on the Rhine Commission four out of nineteen; on the Danube
  • Commission, which is not yet definitely constituted, she will be
  • apparently in a small minority. On the government of all these rivers
  • France and Great Britain are represented; and on the Elbe for some
  • undiscoverable reason there are also representatives of Italy and
  • Belgium.
  • Thus the great waterways of Germany are handed over to foreign bodies
  • with the widest powers; and much of the local and domestic business of
  • Hamburg, Magdeburg, Dresden, Stettin, Frankfurt, Breslan, and Ulm will
  • be subject to a foreign jurisdiction. It is almost as though the Powers
  • of Continental Europe were to be placed in a majority on the Thames
  • Conservancy or the Port of London.
  • Certain minor provisions follow lines which in our survey of the Treaty
  • are now familiar. Under Annex III. of the Reparation Chapter Germany is
  • to cede up to 20 per cent of her inland navigation tonnage. Over and
  • above this she must cede such proportion of her river craft upon the
  • Elbe, the Oder, the Niemen, and the Danube as an American arbitrator may
  • determine, "due regard being had to the legitimate needs of the parties
  • concerned, and particularly to the shipping traffic during the five
  • years preceding the war," the craft so ceded to be selected from those
  • most recently built.[72] The same course is to be followed with German
  • vessels and tugs on the Rhine and with German property in the port of
  • Rotterdam.[73] Where the Rhine flows between France and Germany, France
  • is to have all the rights of utilizing the water for irrigation or for
  • power and Germany is to have none;[74] and all the bridges are to be
  • French property as to their whole length.[75] Finally the administration
  • of the purely German Rhine port of Kehl lying on the eastern bank of the
  • river is to be united to that of Strassburg for seven years and managed
  • by a Frenchman to be nominated by the new Rhine Commission.
  • Thus the Economic Clauses of the Treaty are comprehensive, and little
  • has been overlooked which might impoverish Germany now or obstruct her
  • development in future. So situated, Germany is to make payments of
  • money, on a scale and in a manner to be examined in the next chapter.
  • FOOTNOTES:
  • [7] The precise force of this reservation is discussed in
  • detail in Chapter V.
  • [8] I also omit those which have no special relevance to the
  • German Settlement. The second of the Fourteen Points, which relates to
  • the Freedom of the Seas, is omitted because the Allies did not accept
  • it. Any italics are mine.
  • [9] Part VIII. Annex III. (1).
  • [10] Part VIII. Annex III. (3).
  • [11] In the years before the war the average shipbuilding
  • output of Germany was about 350,000 tons annually, exclusive of
  • warships.
  • [12] Part VIII. Annex III. (5).
  • [13] Art. 119.
  • [14] Arts. 120 and 257.
  • [15] Art. 122.
  • [16] Arts. 121 and 297(b). The exercise or non-exercise of this
  • option of expropriation appears to lie, not with the Reparation
  • Commission, but with the particular Power in whose territory the
  • property has become situated by cession or mandation.
  • [17] Art. 297 (h) and para. 4 of Annex to Part X. Section IV.
  • [18] Arts. 53 and 74.
  • [19] In 1871 Germany granted France credit for the railways of
  • Alsace-Lorraine but not for State property. At that time, however, the
  • railways were private property. As they afterwards became the property
  • of the German Government, the French Government have held, in spite of
  • the large additional capital which Germany has sunk in them, that their
  • treatment must follow the precedent of State property generally.
  • [20] Arts. 55 and 255. This follows the precedent of 1871.
  • [21] Art. 297 (_b_).
  • [22] Part X. Sections III. and IV. and Art. 243.
  • [23] The interpretation of the words between inverted commas is
  • a little dubious. The phrase is so wide as to seem to include private
  • debts. But in the final draft of the Treaty private debts are not
  • explicitly referred to.
  • [24] This provision is mitigated in the case of German property
  • in Poland and the other new States, the proceeds of liquidation in these
  • areas being payable direct to the owner (Art. 92.)
  • [25] Part X. Section IV. Annex, para. 10: "Germany will, within
  • six months from the coming into force of the present Treaty, deliver to
  • each Allied or Associated Power all securities, certificates, deeds, or
  • other documents of title held by its nationals and relating to property,
  • rights, or interests situated in the territory of that Allied or
  • Associated Power.... Germany will at any time on demand of any Allied or
  • Associated Power furnish such information as may be required with regard
  • to the territory, rights, and interests of German nationals within the
  • territory of such Allied or Associated Power, or with regard to any
  • transactions concerning such property, rights, or interests effected
  • since July 1, 1914."
  • [26] "Any public utility undertaking or concession" is a vague
  • phrase, the precise interpretation of which is not provided for.
  • [27] Art. 260.
  • [28] Art. 235.
  • [29] Art. 118.
  • [30] Arts. 129 and 132.
  • [31] Arts. 135-137.
  • [32] Arts. 135-140.
  • [33] Art. 141: "Germany renounces all rights, titles and
  • privileges conferred on her by the General Act of Algeciras of April 7,
  • 1906, and by the Franco-German Agreements, of Feb. 9, 1909, and Nov. 4,
  • 1911...."
  • [34] Art. 148: "All treaties, agreements, arrangements and
  • contracts concluded by Germany with Egypt are regarded as abrogated from
  • Aug. 4, 1914." Art. 153: "All property and possessions in Egypt of the
  • German Empire and the German States pass to the Egyptian Government
  • without payment."
  • [35] Art. 289.
  • [36] Art. 45.
  • [37] Part IV. Section IV. Annex, Chap. III.
  • [38] "We take over the ownership of the Sarre mines, and in
  • order not to be inconvenienced in the exploitation of these coal
  • deposits, we constitute a distinct little estate for the 600,000 Germans
  • who inhabit this coal basin, and in fifteen years we shall endeavor by a
  • plebiscite to bring them to declare that they want to be French. We know
  • what that means. During fifteen years we are going to work on them, to
  • attack them from every point, till we obtain from them a declaration of
  • love. It is evidently a less brutal proceeding than the _coup de force_
  • which detached from us our Alsatians and Lorrainers. But if less brutal,
  • it is more hypocritical. We know quite well between ourselves that it is
  • an attempt to annex these 600,000 Germans. One can understand very well
  • the reasons of an economic nature which have led Clemenceau to wish to
  • give us these Sarre coal deposits, but in order to acquire them must we
  • give ourselves the appearance of wanting to juggle with 600,000 Germans
  • in order to make Frenchmen of them in fifteen years?" (M. HervĂ© in _La
  • Victorie_, May 31, 1919).
  • [39] This plebiscite is the most important of the concessions
  • accorded to Germany in the Allies' Final Note, and one for which Mr.
  • Lloyd George, who never approved the Allies' policy on the Eastern
  • frontiers of Germany, can claim the chief credit. The vote cannot take
  • place before the spring of 1920, and may be postponed until 1921. In the
  • meantime the province will be governed by an Allied Commission. The vote
  • will be taken by communes, and the final frontiers will be determined by
  • the Allies, who shall have regard, partly to the results of the vote in
  • each commune, and partly "to the geographical and economic conditions of
  • the locality." It would require great local knowledge to predict the
  • result. By voting Polish, a locality can escape liability for the
  • indemnity, and for the crushing taxation consequent on voting German, a
  • factor not to be neglected. On the other hand, the bankruptcy and
  • incompetence of the new Polish State might deter those who were disposed
  • to vote on economic rather than on racial grounds. It has also been
  • stated that the conditions of life in such matters as sanitation and
  • social legislation are incomparably better in Upper Silesia than in the
  • adjacent districts of Poland, where similar legislation is in its
  • infancy. The argument in the text assumes that Upper Silesia will cease
  • to be German. But much may happen in a year, and the assumption is not
  • certain. To the extent that it proves erroneous the conclusions must be
  • modified.
  • [40] German authorities claim, not without contradiction, that
  • to judge from the votes cast at elections, one-third of the population
  • would elect in the Polish interest, and two-thirds in the German.
  • [41] It must not be overlooked, however, that, amongst the
  • other concessions relating to Silesia accorded in the Allies' Final
  • Note, there has been included Article 90, by which "Poland undertakes to
  • permit for a period of fifteen years the exportation to Germany of the
  • products of the mines in any part of Upper Silesia transferred to Poland
  • in accordance with the present Treaty. Such products shall be free from
  • all export duties or other charges or restrictions on exportation.
  • Poland agrees to take such steps as may be necessary to secure that any
  • such products shall be available for sale to purchasers in Germany on
  • terms as favorable as are applicable to like products sold under similar
  • conditions to purchasers in Poland or in any other country." This does
  • not apparently amount to a right of preemption, and it is not easy to
  • estimate its effective practical consequences. It is evident, however,
  • that in so far as the mines are maintained at their former efficiency,
  • and in so far as Germany is in a position to purchase substantially her
  • former supplies from that source, the loss is limited to the effect on
  • her balance of trade, and is without the more serious repercussions on
  • her economic life which are contemplated in the text. Here is an
  • opportunity for the Allies to render more tolerable the actual operation
  • of the settlement. The Germans, it should be added, have pointed out
  • that the same economic argument which adds the Saar fields to France
  • allots Upper Silesia to Germany. For whereas the Silesian mines are
  • essential to the economic life of Germany, Poland does not need them. Of
  • Poland's pre-war annual demand of 10,500,000 tons, 6,800,000 tons were
  • supplied by the indisputably Polish districts adjacent to Upper Silesia.
  • 1,500,000 tons from Upper Silesia (out of a total Upper Silesian output
  • of 43,500,000 tons), and the balance from what is now Czecho-Slovakia.
  • Even without any supply from Upper Silesia and Czecho-Slovakia, Poland
  • could probably meet her requirements by the fuller exploitation of her
  • own coalfields which are not yet scientifically developed, or from the
  • deposits of Western Galicia which are now to be annexed to her.
  • [42] France is also to receive annually for three years 35,000
  • tons of benzol, 60,000 tons of coal tar, and 30,000 tons of sulphate of
  • ammonia.
  • [43] The Reparation Commission is authorized under the Treaty
  • (Part VIII Annex V. para. 10) "to postpone or to cancel deliveries" if
  • they consider "that the full exercise of the foregoing options would
  • interfere unduly with the industrial requirements of Germany." In the
  • event of such postponements or cancellations "the coal to replace coal
  • from destroyed mines shall receive priority over other deliveries." This
  • concluding clause is of the greatest importance, if, as will be seen, it
  • is physically impossible for Germany to furnish the full 45,000,000; for
  • it means that France will receive 20,000,000 tons before Italy receives
  • anything. The Reparation Commission has no discretion to modify this.
  • The Italian Press has not failed to notice the significance of the
  • provision, and alleges that this clause was inserted during the absence
  • of the Italian representatives from Paris (_Corriere della Sera_, July
  • 19, 1919).
  • [44] It follows that the current rate of production in Germany
  • has sunk to about 60 per cent of that of 1913. The effect on reserves
  • has naturally been disastrous, and the prospects for the coming winter
  • are dangerous.
  • [45] This assumes a loss of output of 15 per cent as compared
  • with the estimate of 30 per cent quoted above.
  • [46] This supposes a loss of 23 per cent of Germany's
  • industrial undertaking and a diminution of 13 per cent in her other
  • requirements.
  • [47] The reader must be reminded in particular that the above
  • calculations take no account of the German production of lignite, which
  • yielded in 1913 13,000,000 tons of rough lignite in addition to an
  • amount converted into 21,000,000 tons of briquette. This amount of
  • lignite, however, was required in Germany before the war _in addition
  • to_ the quantities of coal assumed above. I am not competent to speak on
  • the extent to which the loss of coal can be made good by the extended
  • use of lignite or by economies in its present employment; but some
  • authorities believe that Germany may obtain substantial compensation for
  • her loss of coal by paying more attention to her deposits of lignite.
  • [48] Mr. Hoover, in July, 1919, estimated that the coal output
  • of Europe, excluding Russia and the Balkans, had dropped from
  • 679,500,000 tons to 443,000,000 tons,--as a result in a minor degree of
  • loss of material and labor, but owing chiefly to a relaxation of
  • physical effort after the privations and sufferings of the war, a lack
  • of rolling-stock and transport, and the unsettled political fate of some
  • of the mining districts.
  • [49] Numerous commercial agreements during the war ware
  • arranged on these lines. But in the month of June, 1919, alone, minor
  • agreements providing for payment in coal were made by Germany with
  • Denmark, Norway, and Switzerland. The amounts involved were not large,
  • but without them Germany could not have obtained butter from Denmark,
  • fats and herrings from Norway, or milk and cattle from Switzerland.
  • [50] "Some 60,000 Ruhr miners have agreed to work extra
  • shifts--so-called butter-shifts--for the purpose of furnishing coal for
  • export to Denmark hence butter will be exported in return. The butter
  • will benefit the miners in the first place, as they have worked
  • specially to obtain it" (_Kölnische Zeitung_, June 11, 1919).
  • [51] What of the prospects of whisky-shifts in England?
  • [52] As early as September, 1919, the Coal Commission had to
  • face the physical impracticability of enforcing the demands of the
  • Treaty, and agreed to modify them as follows:--"Germany shall in the
  • next six months make deliveries corresponding to an annual delivery of
  • 20 million tons as compared with 43 millions as provided in the Peace
  • Treaty. If Germany's total production exceeds the present level of about
  • 108 millions a year, 60 per cent of extra production, up to 128
  • millions, shall be delivered to the Entente and 50 per cent of any extra
  • beyond that, until the figure provided in the Peace Treaty is reached.
  • If the total production falls below 108 millions the Entente will
  • examine the situation, after hearing Germany, and take account of it."
  • [53] 21,136,265 tons out of a total of 28,607,903 tons. The
  • loss of iron-ore in respect of Upper Silesia is insignificant. The
  • exclusion of the iron and steel of Luxemburg from the German Customs
  • Union is, however, important, especially when this loss is added to that
  • of Alsace-Lorraine. It may be added in passing that Upper Silesia
  • includes 75 per cent of the zinc production of Germany.
  • [54] In April, 1919, the British Ministry of Munitions
  • despatched an expert Commission to examine the conditions of the iron
  • and steel works in Lorraine and the occupied areas of Germany. The
  • Report states that the iron and steel works in Lorraine, and to a lesser
  • extent in the Saar Valley, are dependent on supplies of coal and coke
  • from Westphalia. It is necessary to mix Westphalian coal with Saar coal
  • to obtain a good furnace coke. The entire dependence of all the Lorraine
  • iron and steel works upon Germany for fuel supplies "places them," says
  • the Report, "in a very unenviable position."
  • [55] Arts. 264, 265, 266, and 267. These provisions can only be
  • extended beyond five years by the Council of the League of Nations.
  • [56] Art. 268 (_a_).
  • [57] Art. 268 (_b_) and (_c_).
  • [58] The Grand Duchy is also deneutralized and Germany binds
  • herself to "accept in advance all international arrangements which may
  • be concluded by the Allied and Associated Powers relating to the Grand
  • Duchy" (Art. 40). At the end of September, 1919, a plebiscite was held
  • to determine whether Luxemburg should join the French or the Belgian
  • Customs Union, which decided by a substantial majority in favour of the
  • former. The third alternative of the maintenance of the union with
  • Germany was not left open to the electorate.
  • [59] Art. 269.
  • [60] Art. 270.
  • [61] The occupation provisions may be conveniently summarized
  • at this point. German territory situated west of the Rhine, together
  • with the bridge-heads, is subject to occupation for a period of fifteen
  • years (Art. 428). If, however, "the conditions of the present Treaty are
  • faithfully carried out by Germany," the Cologne district will be
  • evacuated after five years, and the Coblenz district after ten years
  • (Art. 429). It is, however, further provided that if at the expiration
  • of fifteen years "the guarantees against unprovoked aggression by
  • Germany are not considered sufficient by the Allied and Associated
  • Governments, the evacuation of the occupying troops may be delayed to
  • the extent regarded as necessary for the purpose of obtaining the
  • required guarantees" (Art. 429); and also that "in case either during
  • the occupation or after the expiration of the fifteen years, the
  • Reparation Commission finds that Germany refuses to observe the whole or
  • part of her obligations under the present Treaty with regard to
  • Reparation, the whole or part of the areas specified in Article 429 will
  • be re-occupied immediately by the Allied and Associated Powers" (Art.
  • 430). Since it will be impossible for Germany to fulfil the whole of her
  • Reparation obligations, the effect of the above provisions will be in
  • practice that the Allies will occupy the left bank of the Rhine just so
  • long as they choose. They will also govern it in such manner as they may
  • determine (_e.g._ not only as regards customs, but such matters as the
  • respective authority of the local German representatives and the Allied
  • Governing Commission), since "all matters relating to the occupation and
  • not provided for by the present Treaty shall be regulated by subsequent
  • agreements, which Germany hereby undertakes to observe" (Art. 432). The
  • actual Agreement under which the occupied areas are to be administered
  • for the present has been published as a White Paper [Cd. 222]. The
  • supreme authority is to be in the hands of an Inter-Allied Rhineland
  • Commission, consisting of a Belgian, a French, a British, and an
  • American member. The articles of this Agreement are very fairly and
  • reasonably drawn.
  • [62] Art. 365. After five years this Article is subject to
  • revision by the Council of the League of Nations.
  • [63] The German Government withdrew, as from September 1, 1919,
  • all preferential railway tariffs for the export of iron and steel goods,
  • on the ground that these privileges would have been more than
  • counterbalanced by the corresponding privileges which, under this
  • Article of the Treaty, they would have been forced to give to Allied
  • traders.
  • [64] Art. 367.
  • [65] Questions of interpretation and application are to be
  • referred to the League of Nations (Art. 376).
  • [66] Art. 250.
  • [67] Art 371. This provision is even applied "to the lines of
  • former Russian Poland converted by Germany to the German gage, such
  • lines being regarded as detached from the Prussian State System."
  • [68] Arts. 332-337. Exception may be taken, however, to the
  • second paragraph of Art. 332, which allows the vessels of other nations
  • to trade between German towns but forbids German vessels to trade
  • between non-German towns except with special permission; and Art. 333,
  • which prohibits Germany from making use of her river system as a source
  • of revenue, may be injudicious.
  • [69] The Niemen and the Moselle are to be similarly treated at
  • a later date if required.
  • [70] Art. 338.
  • [71] Art. 344. This is with particular reference to the Elbe
  • and the Oder; the Danube and the Rhine are dealt with in relation to the
  • existing Commissions.
  • [72] Art. 339.
  • [73] Art. 357.
  • [74] Art. 358. Germany is, however, to be allowed some payment
  • or credit in respect of power so taken by France.
  • [75] Art. 66.
  • CHAPTER V
  • REPARATION
  • I. _Undertakings given prior to the Peace Negotiations_
  • The categories of damage in respect of which the Allies were entitled to
  • ask for Reparation are governed by the relevant passages in President
  • Wilson's Fourteen Points of January 8, 1918, as modified by the Allied
  • Governments in their qualifying Note, the text of which the President
  • formally communicated to the German Government as the basis of peace on
  • November 5, 1918. These passages have been quoted in full at the
  • beginning of Chapter IV. That is to say, "compensation will be made by
  • Germany for all damage done to the civilian population of the Allies and
  • to their property by the aggression of Germany by land, by sea, and from
  • the air." The limiting quality of this sentence is reinforced by the
  • passage in the President's speech before Congress on February 11, 1918
  • (the terms of this speech being an express part of the contract with the
  • enemy), that there shall be "no contributions" and "no punitive
  • damages."
  • It has sometimes been argued that the preamble to paragraph 19[76] of
  • the Armistice Terms, to the effect "that any future claims and demands
  • of the Allies and the United States of America remain unaffected," wiped
  • out all precedent conditions, and left the Allies free to make whatever
  • demands they chose. But it is not possible to maintain that this casual
  • protective phrase, to which no one at the time attached any particular
  • importance, did away with all the formal communications which passed
  • between the President and the German Government as to the basis of the
  • Terms of Peace during the days preceding the Armistice, abolished the
  • Fourteen Points, and converted the German acceptance of the Armistice
  • Terms into unconditional surrender, so far as it affects the Financial
  • Clauses. It is merely the usual phrase of the draftsman, who, about to
  • rehearse a list of certain claims, wishes to guard himself from the
  • implication that such list is exhaustive. In any case, this contention
  • is disposed of by the Allied reply to the German observations on the
  • first draft of the Treaty, where it is admitted that the terms of the
  • Reparation Chapter must be governed by the President's Note of November
  • 5.
  • Assuming then that the terms of this Note are binding, we are left to
  • elucidate the precise force of the phrase--"all damage done to the
  • civilian population of the Allies and to their property by the
  • aggression of Germany by land, by sea, and from the air." Few sentences
  • in history have given so much work to the sophists and the lawyers, as
  • we shall see in the next section of this chapter, as this apparently
  • simple and unambiguous statement. Some have not scrupled to argue that
  • it covers the entire cost of the war; for, they point out, the entire
  • cost of the war has to be met by taxation, and such taxation is
  • "damaging to the civilian population." They admit that the phrase is
  • cumbrous, and that it would have been simpler to have said "all loss and
  • expenditure of whatever description"; and they allow that the apparent
  • emphasis of damage to the persons and property of _civilians_ is
  • unfortunate; but errors of draftsmanship should not, in their opinion,
  • shut off the Allies from the rights inherent in victors.
  • But there are not only the limitations of the phrase in its natural
  • meaning and the emphasis on civilian damages as distinct from military
  • expenditure generally; it must also be remembered that the context of
  • the term is in elucidation of the meaning of the term "restoration" in
  • the President's Fourteen Points. The Fourteen Points provide for damage
  • in invaded territory--Belgium, France, Roumania, Serbia, and Montenegro
  • (Italy being unaccountably omitted)--but they do not cover losses at sea
  • by submarine, bombardments from the sea (as at Scarborough), or damage
  • done by air raids. It was to repair these omissions, which involved
  • losses to the life and property of civilians not really distinguishable
  • in kind from those effected in occupied territory, that the Supreme
  • Council of the Allies in Paris proposed to President Wilson their
  • qualifications. At that time--the last days of October, 1918--I do not
  • believe that any responsible statesman had in mind the exaction from
  • Germany of an indemnity for the general costs of the war. They sought
  • only to make it clear (a point of considerable importance to Great
  • Britain) that reparation for damage done to non-combatants and their
  • property was not limited to invaded territory (as it would have been by
  • the Fourteen Points unqualified), but applied equally to _all_ such
  • damage, whether "by land, by sea, or from the air" It was only at a
  • later stage that a general popular demand for an indemnity, covering
  • the full costs of the war, made it politically desirable to practise
  • dishonesty and to try to discover in the written word what was not
  • there.
  • What damages, then, can be claimed from the enemy on a strict
  • interpretation of our engagements?[77] In the case of the United Kingdom
  • the bill would cover the following items:--
  • (a) Damage to civilian life and property by the acts of an enemy
  • Government including damage by air raids, naval bombardments, submarine
  • warfare, and mines.
  • (b) Compensation for improper treatment of interned civilians.
  • It would not include the general costs of the war, or (_e.g._) indirect
  • damage due to loss of trade.
  • The French claim would include, as well as items corresponding to the
  • above:--
  • (c) Damage done to the property and persons of civilians in the war
  • area, and by aerial warfare behind the enemy lines.
  • (d) Compensation for loot of food, raw materials, live-stock, machinery,
  • household effects, timber, and the like by the enemy Governments or
  • their nationals in territory occupied by them.
  • (e) Repayment of fines and requisitions levied by the enemy Governments
  • or their officers on French municipalities or nationals.
  • (f) Compensation to French nationals deported or compelled to do forced
  • labor.
  • In addition to the above there is a further item of more doubtful
  • character, namely--
  • (g) The expenses of the Relief Commission in providing necessary food
  • and clothing to maintain the civilian French population in the
  • enemy-occupied districts.
  • The Belgian claim would include similar items.[78] If it were argued
  • that in the case of Belgium something more nearly resembling an
  • indemnity for general war costs can be justified, this could only be on
  • the ground of the breach of International Law involved in the invasion
  • of Belgium, whereas, as we have seen, the Fourteen Points include no
  • special demands on this ground.[79] As the cost of Belgian Belief under
  • (g), as well as her general war costs, has been met already by advances
  • from the British, French, and United States Governments, Belgium would
  • presumably employ any repayment of them by Germany in part discharge of
  • her debt to these Governments, so that any such demands are, in effect,
  • an addition to the claims of the three lending Governments.
  • The claims of the other Allies would be compiled on similar lines. But
  • in their case the question arises more acutely how far Germany can be
  • made contingently liable for damage done, not by herself, but by her
  • co-belligerents, Austria-Hungary, Bulgaria, and Turkey. This is one of
  • the many questions to which the Fourteen Points give no clear answer; on
  • the one hand, they cover explicitly in Point 11 damage done to Roumania,
  • Serbia, and Montenegro, without qualification as to the nationality of
  • the troops inflicting the damage; on the other hand, the Note of the
  • Allies speaks of "German" aggression when it might have spoken of the
  • aggression of "Germany and her allies." On a strict and literal
  • interpretation, I doubt if claims lie against Germany for damage
  • done,--_e.g._ by the Turks to the Suez Canal, or by Austrian submarines
  • in the Adriatic. But it is a case where, if the Allies wished to strain
  • a point, they could impose contingent liability on Germany without
  • running seriously contrary to the general intention of their
  • engagements.
  • As between the Allies themselves the case is quite different. It would
  • be an act of gross unfairness and infidelity if France and Great Britain
  • were to take what Germany could pay and leave Italy and Serbia to get
  • what they could out of the remains of Austria-Hungary. As amongst the
  • Allies themselves it is clear that assets should be pooled and shared
  • out in proportion to aggregate claims.
  • In this event, and if my estimate is accepted, as given below, that
  • Germany's capacity to pay will be exhausted by the direct and legitimate
  • claims which the Allies hold against her, the question of her contingent
  • liability for her allies becomes academic. Prudent and honorable
  • statesmanship would therefore have given her the benefit of the doubt,
  • and claimed against her nothing but the damage she had herself caused.
  • What, on the above basis of claims, would the aggregate demand amount
  • to? No figures exist on which to base any scientific or exact estimate,
  • and I give my own guess for what it is worth, prefacing it with the
  • following observations.
  • The amount of the material damage done in the invaded districts has been
  • the subject of enormous, if natural, exaggeration. A journey through the
  • devastated areas of France is impressive to the eye and the imagination
  • beyond description. During the winter of 1918-19, before Nature had
  • cast over the scene her ameliorating mantle, the horror and desolation
  • of war was made visible to sight on an extraordinary scale of blasted
  • grandeur. The completeness of the destruction was evident. For mile
  • after mile nothing was left. No building was habitable and no field fit
  • for the plow. The sameness was also striking. One devastated area was
  • exactly like another--a heap of rubble, a morass of shell-holes, and a
  • tangle of wire.[80] The amount of human labor which would be required to
  • restore such a countryside seemed incalculable; and to the returned
  • traveler any number of milliards of dollars was inadequate to express in
  • matter the destruction thus impressed upon his spirit. Some Governments
  • for a variety of intelligible reasons have not been ashamed to exploit
  • these feelings a little.
  • Popular sentiment is most at fault, I think, in the case of Belgium. In
  • any event Belgium is a small country, and in its case the actual area of
  • devastation is a small proportion of the whole. The first onrush of the
  • Germans in 1914 did some damage locally; after that the battle-line in
  • Belgium did not sway backwards and forwards, as in France, over a deep
  • belt of country. It was practically stationary, and hostilities were
  • confined to a small corner of the country, much of which in recent times
  • was backward, poor, and sleepy, and did not include the active industry
  • of the country. There remains some injury in the small flooded area, the
  • deliberate damage done by the retreating Germans to buildings, plant,
  • and transport, and the loot of machinery, cattle, and other movable
  • property. But Brussels, Antwerp, and even Ostend are substantially
  • intact, and the great bulk of the land, which is Belgium's chief wealth,
  • is nearly as well cultivated as before. The traveler by motor can pass
  • through and from end to end of the devastated area of Belgium almost
  • before he knows it; whereas the destruction in France is on a different
  • kind of scale altogether. Industrially, the loot has been serious and
  • for the moment paralyzing; but the actual money cost of replacing
  • machinery mounts up slowly, and a few tens of millions would have
  • covered the value of every machine of every possible description that
  • Belgium ever possessed. Besides, the cold statistician must not overlook
  • the fact that the Belgian people possess the instinct of individual
  • self-protection unusually well developed; and the great mass of German
  • bank-notes[81] held in the country at the date of the Armistice, shows
  • that certain classes of them at least found a way, in spite of all the
  • severities and barbarities of German rule, to profit at the expense of
  • the invader. Belgian claims against Germany such as I have seen,
  • amounting to a sum in excess of the total estimated pre-war wealth of
  • the whole country, are simply irresponsible.[82]
  • It will help to guide our ideas to quote the official survey of Belgian
  • wealth, published in 1913 by the Finance Ministry of Belgium, which was
  • as follows:
  • Land $1,320,000,000
  • Buildings 1,175,000,000
  • Personal wealth 2,725,000,000
  • Cash 85,000,000
  • Furniture, etc 600,000,000
  • --------------
  • $5,905,000,000
  • This total yields an average of $780 per inhabitant, which Dr. Stamp,
  • the highest authority on the subject, is disposed to consider as _prima
  • facie_ too low (though he does not accept certain much higher estimates
  • lately current), the corresponding wealth per head (to take Belgium's
  • immediate neighbors) being $835 for Holland, $1,220 for Germany, and
  • $1,515 for France.[83] A total of $7,500,000,000, giving an average of
  • about $1,000 per head, would, however, be fairly liberal. The official
  • estimate of land and buildings is likely to be more accurate than the
  • rest. On the other hand, allowance has to be made for the increased
  • costs of construction.
  • Having regard to all these considerations, I do not put the money value
  • of the actual _physical_ loss of Belgian property by destruction and
  • loot above $750,000,000 _as a maximum_, and while I hesitate to put yet
  • lower an estimate which differs so widely from those generally current,
  • I shall be surprised if it proves possible to substantiate claims even
  • to this amount. Claims in respect of levies, fines, requisitions, and so
  • forth might possibly amount to a further $500,000,000. If the sums
  • advanced to Belgium by her allies for the general costs of the war are
  • to be included, a sum of about $1,250,000,000 has to be added (which
  • includes the cost of relief), bringing the total to $2,500,000,000.
  • The destruction in France was on an altogether more significant scale,
  • not only as regards the length of the battle line, but also on account
  • of the immensely deeper area of country over which the battle swayed
  • from time to time. It is a popular delusion to think of Belgium as the
  • principal victim of the war; it will turn out, I believe, that taking
  • account of casualties, loss of property and burden of future debt,
  • Belgium has made the least relative sacrifice of all the belligerents
  • except the United States. Of the Allies, Serbia's sufferings and loss
  • have been proportionately the greatest, and after Serbia, France. France
  • in all essentials was just as much the victim of German ambition as was
  • Belgium, and France's entry into the war was just as unavoidable.
  • France, in my judgment, in spite of her policy at the Peace Conference,
  • a policy largely traceable to her sufferings, has the greatest claims on
  • our generosity.
  • The special position occupied by Belgium in the popular mind is due, of
  • course, to the fact that in 1914 her sacrifice was by far the greatest
  • of any of the Allies. But after 1914 she played a minor rĂ´le.
  • Consequently, by the end of 1918, her relative sacrifices, apart from
  • those sufferings from invasion which cannot be measured in money, had
  • fallen behind, and in some respects they were not even as great, for
  • example, as Australia's. I say this with no wish to evade the
  • obligations towards Belgium under which the pronouncements of our
  • responsible statesmen at many different dates have certainly laid us.
  • Great Britain ought not to seek any payment at all from Germany for
  • herself until the just claims of Belgium have been fully satisfied. But
  • this is no reason why we or they should not tell the truth about the
  • amount.
  • While the French claims are immensely greater, here too there has been
  • excessive exaggeration, as responsible French statisticians have
  • themselves pointed out. Not above 10 per cent of the area of France was
  • effectively occupied by the enemy, and not above 4 per cent lay within
  • the area of substantial devastation. Of the sixty French towns having a
  • population exceeding 35,000, only two were destroyed--Reims (115,178)
  • and St. Quentin (55,571); three others were occupied--Lille, Roubaix,
  • and Douai--and suffered from loot of machinery and other property, but
  • were not substantially injured otherwise. Amiens, Calais, Dunkerque, and
  • Boulogne suffered secondary damage by bombardment and from the air; but
  • the value of Calais and Boulogne must have been increased by the new
  • works of various kinds erected for the use of the British Army.
  • The _Annuaire Statistique de la France, 1917_, values the entire house
  • property of France at $11,900,000,000 (59.5 milliard francs).[84] An
  • estimate current in France of $4,000,000,000 (20 milliard francs) for
  • the destruction of house property alone is, therefore, obviously wide of
  • the mark.[85] $600,000,000 at pre-war prices, or say $1,250,000,000 at
  • the present time, is much nearer the right figure. Estimates of the
  • value of the land of France (apart from buildings) vary from
  • $12,400,000,000 to $15,580,000,000, so that it would be extravagant to
  • put the damage on this head as high as $500,000,000. Farm Capital for
  • the whole of France has not been put by responsible authorities above
  • $2,100,000,000.[86] There remain the loss of furniture and machinery,
  • the damage to the coal-mines and the transport system, and many other
  • minor items. But these losses, however serious, cannot be reckoned in
  • value by hundreds of millions of dollars in respect of so small a part
  • of France. In short, it will be difficult to establish a bill exceeding
  • $2,500,000,000 for _physical and material_ damage in the occupied and
  • devastated areas of Northern France.[87] I am confirmed in this estimate
  • by the opinion of M. RenĂ© Pupin, the author of the most comprehensive
  • and scientific estimate of the pre-war wealth of France,[88] which I did
  • not come across until after my own figure had been arrived at. This
  • authority estimates the material losses of the invaded regions at from
  • $2,000,000,000 to $3,000,000,000 (10 to 15 milliards),[89] between which
  • my own figure falls half-way.
  • Nevertheless, M. Dubois, speaking on behalf of the Budget Commission of
  • the Chamber, has given the figure of $13,000,000,000 (65 milliard
  • francs) "as a minimum" without counting "war levies, losses at sea, the
  • roads, or the loss of public monuments." And M. Loucheur, the Minister
  • of Industrial Reconstruction, stated before the Senate on the 17th
  • February, 1919, that the reconstitution of the devastated regions would
  • involve an expenditure of $15,000,000,000 (75 milliard francs),--more
  • than double M. Pupin's estimate of the entire wealth of their
  • inhabitants. But then at that time M. Loucheur was taking a prominent
  • part in advocating the claims of France before the Peace Conference,
  • and, like others, may have found strict veracity inconsistent with the
  • demands of patriotism.[90]
  • The figure discussed so far is not, however, the totality of the French
  • claims. There remain, in particular, levies and requisitions on the
  • occupied areas and the losses of the French mercantile marine at sea
  • from the attacks of German cruisers and submarines. Probably
  • $1,000,000,000 would be ample to cover all such claims; but to be on the
  • safe side, we will, somewhat arbitrarily, make an addition to the French
  • claim of $1,500,000,000 on all heads, bringing it to $4,000,000,000 in
  • all.
  • The statements of M. Dubois and M. Loucheur were made in the early
  • spring of 1919. A speech delivered by M. Klotz before the French Chamber
  • six months later (Sept. 5, 1919) was less excusable. In this speech the
  • French Minister of Finance estimated the total French claims for damage
  • to property (presumably inclusive of losses at sea, etc., but apart from
  • pensions and allowances) at $26,800,000,000 (134 milliard francs), or
  • more than six times my estimate. Even if my figure prove erroneous, M.
  • Klotz's can never have been justified. So grave has been the deception
  • practised on the French people by their Ministers that when the
  • inevitable enlightenment comes, as it soon must (both as to their own
  • claims and as to Germany's capacity to meet them), the repercussions
  • will strike at more than M. Klotz, and may even involve the order of
  • Government and Society for which he stands.
  • British claims on the present basis would be practically limited to
  • losses by sea--losses of hulls and losses of cargoes. Claims would lie,
  • of course, for damage to civilian property in air raids and by
  • bombardment from the sea, but in relation to such figures as we are now
  • dealing with, the money value involved is insignificant,--$25,000,000
  • might cover them all, and $50,000,000 would certainly do so.
  • The British mercantile vessels lost by enemy action, excluding fishing
  • vessels, numbered 2479, with an aggregate of 7,759,090 tons gross.[91]
  • There is room for considerable divergence of opinion as to the proper
  • rate to take for replacement cost; at the figure of $150 per gross ton,
  • which with the rapid growth of shipbuilding may soon be too high but can
  • be replaced by any other which better authorities[92] may prefer, the
  • aggregate claim is $1,150,000,000. To this must be added the loss of
  • cargoes, the value of which is almost entirely a matter of guesswork. An
  • estimate of $200 per ton of shipping lost may be as good an
  • approximation as is possible, that is to say $1,550,000,000, making
  • $2,700,000,000 altogether.
  • An addition to this of $150,000,000, to cover air raids, bombardments,
  • claims of interned civilians, and miscellaneous items of every
  • description, should be more than sufficient,--making a total claim for
  • Great Britain of $2,850,000,000. It is surprising, perhaps, that the
  • money value of Great Britain's claim should be so little short of that
  • of France and actually in excess of that of Belgium. But, measured
  • either by pecuniary loss or real loss to the economic power of the
  • country, the injury to her mercantile marine was enormous.
  • There remain the claims of Italy, Serbia, and Roumania for damage by
  • invasion and of these and other countries, as for example Greece,[93]
  • for losses at sea. I will assume for the present argument that these
  • claims rank against Germany, even when they were directly caused not by
  • her but by her allies; but that it is not proposed to enter any such
  • claims on behalf of Russia.[94] Italy's losses by invasion and at sea
  • cannot be very heavy, and a figure of from $250,000,000 to $500,000,000
  • would be fully adequate to cover them. The losses of Serbia, although
  • from a human point of view her sufferings were the greatest of all,[95]
  • are not measured _pecuniarily_ by very great figures, on account of her
  • low economic development. Dr. Stamp (_loc. cit._) quotes an estimate by
  • the Italian statistician Maroi, which puts the national wealth of Serbia
  • at $2,400,000,000 or $525 per head,[96] and the greater part of this
  • would be represented by land which has sustained no permanent
  • damage.[97] In view of the very inadequate data for guessing at more
  • than the _general magnitude_ of the legitimate claims of this group of
  • countries, I prefer to make one guess rather than several and to put the
  • figure for the whole group at the round sum of $1,250,000,000.
  • We are finally left with the following--
  • Belgium $ 2,500,000,000[98]
  • France 4,000,000,000
  • Great Britain 2,850,000,000
  • Other Allies 1,250,000,000
  • ---------------
  • Total $10,600,000,000
  • I need not impress on the reader that there is much guesswork in the
  • above, and the figure for France in particular is likely to be
  • criticized. But I feel some confidence that the _general magnitude_, as
  • distinct from the precise figures, is not hopelessly erroneous; and this
  • may be expressed by the statement that a claim against Germany, based on
  • the interpretation of the pre-Armistice engagements of the Allied
  • Powers which is adopted above, would assuredly be found to exceed
  • $8,000,000,000 and to fall short of $15,000,000,000.
  • This is the amount of the claim which we were entitled to present to the
  • enemy. For reasons which will appear more fully later on, I believe that
  • it would have been a wise and just act to have asked the German
  • Government at the Peace Negotiations to agree to a sum of
  • $10,000,000,000 in final settlement, without further examination of
  • particulars. This would have provided an immediate and certain solution,
  • and would have required from Germany a sum which, if she were granted
  • certain indulgences, it might not have proved entirely impossible for
  • her to pay. This sum should have been divided up amongst the Allies
  • themselves on a basis of need and general equity.
  • But the question was not settled on its merits.
  • II. _The Conference and the Terms of the Treaty_
  • I do not believe that, at the date of the Armistice, responsible
  • authorities in the Allied countries expected any indemnity from Germany
  • beyond the cost of reparation for the direct material damage which had
  • resulted from the invasion of Allied territory and from the submarine
  • campaign. At that time there were serious doubts as to whether Germany
  • intended to accept our terms, which in other respects were inevitably
  • very severe, and it would have been thought an unstatesmanlike act to
  • risk a continuance of the war by demanding a money payment which Allied
  • opinion was not then anticipating and which probably could not be
  • secured in any case. The French, I think, never quite accepted this
  • point of view; but it was certainly the British attitude; and in this
  • atmosphere the pre-Armistice conditions were framed.
  • A month later the atmosphere had changed completely. We had discovered
  • how hopeless the German position really was, a discovery which some,
  • though not all, had anticipated, but which no one had dared reckon on as
  • a certainty. It was evident that we could have secured unconditional
  • surrender if we had determined to get it.
  • But there was another new factor in the situation which was of greater
  • local importance. The British Prime Minister had perceived that the
  • conclusion of hostilities might soon bring with it the break-up of the
  • political _bloc_ upon which he was depending for his personal
  • ascendency, and that the domestic difficulties which would be attendant
  • on demobilization, the turn-over of industry from war to peace
  • conditions, the financial situation, and the general psychological
  • reactions of men's minds, would provide his enemies with powerful
  • weapons, if he were to leave them time to mature. The best chance,
  • therefore, of consolidating his power, which was personal and exercised,
  • as such, independently of party or principle, to an extent unusual in
  • British politics, evidently lay in active hostilities before the
  • prestige of victory had abated, and in an attempt to found on the
  • emotions of the moment a new basis of power which might outlast the
  • inevitable reactions of the near future. Within a brief period,
  • therefore, after the Armistice, the popular victor, at the height of his
  • influence and his authority, decreed a General Election. It was widely
  • recognized at the time as an act of political immorality. There were no
  • grounds of public interest which did not call for a short delay until
  • the issues of the new age had a little defined themselves and until the
  • country had something more specific before it on which to declare its
  • mind and to instruct its new representatives. But the claims of private
  • ambition determined otherwise.
  • For a time all went well. But before the campaign was far advanced
  • Government candidates were finding themselves handicapped by the lack of
  • an effective cry. The War Cabinet was demanding a further lease of
  • authority on the ground of having won the war. But partly because the
  • new issues had not yet defined themselves, partly out of regard for the
  • delicate balance of a Coalition Party, the Prime Minister's future
  • policy was the subject of silence or generalities. The campaign seemed,
  • therefore, to fall a little flat. In the light of subsequent events it
  • seems improbable that the Coalition Party was ever in real danger. But
  • party managers are easily "rattled." The Prime Minister's more neurotic
  • advisers told him that he was not safe from dangerous surprises, and the
  • Prime Minister lent an ear to them. The party managers demanded more
  • "ginger." The Prime Minister looked about for some.
  • On the assumption that the return of the Prime Minister to power was the
  • primary consideration, the rest followed naturally. At that juncture
  • there was a clamor from certain quarters that the Government had given
  • by no means sufficiently clear undertakings that they were not going "to
  • let the Hun off." Mr. Hughes was evoking a good deal of attention by his
  • demands for a very large indemnity,[99] and Lord Northcliffe was lending
  • his powerful aid to the same cause. This pointed the Prime Minister to
  • a stone for two birds. By himself adopting the policy of Mr. Hughes and
  • Lord Northcliffe, he could at the same time silence those powerful
  • critics and provide his party managers with an effective platform cry to
  • drown the increasing voices of criticism from other quarters.
  • The progress of the General Election of 1918 affords a sad, dramatic
  • history of the essential weakness of one who draws his chief inspiration
  • not from his own true impulses, but from the grosser effluxions of the
  • atmosphere which momentarily surrounds him. The Prime Minister's natural
  • instincts, as they so often are, were right and reasonable. He himself
  • did not believe in hanging the Kaiser or in the wisdom or the
  • possibility of a great indemnity. On the 22nd of November he and Mr.
  • Bonar Law issued their Election Manifesto. It contains no allusion of
  • any kind either to the one or to the other but, speaking, rather, of
  • Disarmament and the League of Nations, concludes that "our first task
  • must be to conclude a just and lasting peace, and so to establish the
  • foundations of a new Europe that occasion for further wars may be for
  • ever averted." In his speech at Wolverhampton on the eve of the
  • Dissolution (November 24), there is no word of Reparation or Indemnity.
  • On the following day at Glasgow, Mr. Bonar Law would promise nothing.
  • "We are going to the Conference," he said, "as one of a number of
  • allies, and you cannot expect a member of the Government, whatever he
  • may think, to state in public before he goes into that Conference, what
  • line he is going to take in regard to any particular question." But a
  • few days later at Newcastle (November 29) the Prime Minister was warming
  • to his work: "When Germany defeated France she made France pay. That is
  • the principle which she herself has established. There is absolutely no
  • doubt about the principle, and that is the principle we should proceed
  • upon--that Germany must pay the costs of the war up to the limit of her
  • capacity to do so." But he accompanied this statement of principle with
  • many "words of warning" as to the practical difficulties of the case:
  • "We have appointed a strong Committee of experts, representing every
  • shade of opinion, to consider this question very carefully and to advise
  • us. There is no doubt as to the justice of the demand. She ought to pay,
  • she must pay as far as she can, but we are not going to allow her to pay
  • in such a way as to wreck our industries." At this stage the Prime
  • Minister sought to indicate that he intended great severity, without
  • raising excessive hopes of actually getting the money, or committing
  • himself to a particular line of action at the Conference. It was
  • rumored that a high city authority had committed himself to the opinion
  • that Germany could certainly pay $100,000,000,000 and that this
  • authority for his part would not care to discredit a figure of twice
  • that sum. The Treasury officials, as Mr. Lloyd George indicated, took a
  • different view. He could, therefore, shelter himself behind the wide
  • discrepancy between the opinions of his different advisers, and regard
  • the precise figure of Germany's capacity to pay as an open question in
  • the treatment of which he must do his best for his country's interests.
  • As to our engagements under the Fourteen Points he was always silent.
  • On November 30, Mr. Barnes, a member of the War Cabinet, in which he was
  • supposed to represent Labor, shouted from a platform, "I am for hanging
  • the Kaiser."
  • On December 6, the Prime Minister issued a statement of policy and aims
  • in which he stated, with significant emphasis on the word _European_,
  • that "All the European Allies have accepted the principle that the
  • Central Powers must pay the cost of the war up to the limit of their
  • capacity."
  • But it was now little more than a week to Polling Day, and still he had
  • not said enough to satisfy the appetites of the moment. On December 8,
  • the _Times_, providing as usual a cloak of ostensible decorum for the
  • lesser restraint of its associates, declared in a leader entitled
  • "Making Germany Pay," that "The public mind was still bewildered by the
  • Prime Minister's various statements." "There is too much suspicion,"
  • they added, "of influences concerned to let the Germans off lightly,
  • whereas the only possible motive in determining their capacity to pay
  • must be the interests of the Allies." "It is the candidate who deals
  • with the issues of to-day," wrote their Political Correspondent, "who
  • adopts Mr. Barnes's phrase about 'hanging the Kaiser' and plumps for the
  • payment of the cost of the war by Germany, who rouses his audience and
  • strikes the notes to which they are most responsive."
  • On December 9, at the Queen's Hall, the Prime Minister avoided the
  • subject. But from now on, the debauchery of thought and speech
  • progressed hour by hour. The grossest spectacle was provided by Sir Eric
  • Geddes in the Guildhall at Cambridge. An earlier speech in which, in a
  • moment of injudicious candor, he had cast doubts on the possibility of
  • extracting from Germany the whole cost of the war had been the object of
  • serious suspicion, and he had therefore a reputation to regain. "We will
  • get out of her all you can squeeze out of a lemon and a bit more," the
  • penitent shouted, "I will squeeze her until you can hear the pips
  • squeak"; his policy was to take every bit of property belonging to
  • Germans in neutral and Allied countries, and all her gold and silver and
  • her jewels, and the contents of her picture-galleries and libraries, to
  • sell the proceeds for the Allies' benefit. "I would strip Germany," he
  • cried, "as she has stripped Belgium."
  • By December 11 the Prime Minister had capitulated. His Final Manifesto
  • of Six Points issued on that day to the electorate furnishes a
  • melancholy comparison with his program of three weeks earlier. I quote
  • it in full:
  • "1. Trial of the Kaiser.
  • 2. Punishment of those responsible for atrocities.
  • 3. Fullest Indemnities from Germany.
  • 4. Britain for the British, socially and industrially.
  • 5. Rehabilitation of those broken in the war.
  • 6. A happier country for all."
  • Here is food for the cynic. To this concoction of greed and sentiment,
  • prejudice and deception, three weeks of the platform had reduced the
  • powerful governors of England, who but a little while before had spoken
  • not ignobly of Disarmament and a League of Nations and of a just and
  • lasting peace which should establish the foundations of a new Europe.
  • On the same evening the Prime Minister at Bristol withdrew in effect his
  • previous reservations and laid down four principles to govern his
  • Indemnity Policy, of which the chief were: First, we have an absolute
  • right to demand the whole cost of the war; second, we propose to demand
  • the whole cost of the war; and third, a Committee appointed by direction
  • of the Cabinet believe that it can be done.[100] Four days later he went
  • to the polls.
  • The Prime Minister never said that he himself believed that Germany
  • could pay the whole cost of the war. But the program became in the
  • mouths of his supporters on the hustings a great deal more than
  • concrete. The ordinary voter was led to believe that Germany could
  • certainly be made to pay the greater part, if not the whole cost of the
  • war. Those whose practical and selfish fears for the future the expenses
  • of the war had aroused, and those whose emotions its horrors had
  • disordered, were both provided for. A vote for a Coalition candidate
  • meant the Crucifixion of Anti-Christ and the assumption by Germany of
  • the British National Debt.
  • It proved an irresistible combination, and once more Mr. George's
  • political instinct was not at fault. No candidate could safely denounce
  • this program, and none did so. The old Liberal Party, having nothing
  • comparable to offer to the electorate, was swept out of existence.[101]
  • A new House of Commons came into being, a majority of whose members had
  • pledged themselves to a great deal more than the Prime Minister's
  • guarded promises. Shortly after their arrival at Westminster I asked a
  • Conservative friend, who had known previous Houses, what he thought of
  • them. "They are a lot of hard-faced men," he said, "who look as if they
  • had done very well out of the war."
  • This was the atmosphere in which the Prime Minister left for Paris, and
  • these the entanglements he had made for himself. He had pledged himself
  • and his Government to make demands of a helpless enemy inconsistent with
  • solemn engagements on our part, on the faith of which this enemy had
  • laid down his arms. There are few episodes in history which posterity
  • will have less reason to condone,--a war ostensibly waged in defense of
  • the sanctity of international engagements ending in a definite breach of
  • one of the most sacred possible of such engagements on the part of
  • victorious champions of these ideals.[102]
  • Apart from other aspects of the transaction, I believe that the
  • campaign for securing out of Germany the general costs of the war was
  • one of the most serious acts of political unwisdom for which our
  • statesmen have ever been responsible. To what a different future Europe
  • might have looked forward if either Mr. Lloyd George or Mr. Wilson had
  • apprehended that the most serious of the problems which claimed their
  • attention were not political or territorial but financial and economic,
  • and that the perils of the future lay not in frontiers or sovereignties
  • but in food, coal, and transport. Neither of them paid adequate
  • attention to these problems at any stage of the Conference. But in any
  • event the atmosphere for the wise and reasonable consideration of them
  • was hopelessly befogged by the commitments of the British delegation on
  • the question of Indemnities. The hopes to which the Prime Minister had
  • given rise not only compelled him to advocate an unjust and unworkable
  • economic basis to the Treaty with Germany, but set him at variance with
  • the President, and on the other hand with competing interests to those
  • of France and Belgium. The clearer it became that but little could be
  • expected from Germany, the more necessary it was to exercise patriotic
  • greed and "sacred egotism" and snatch the bone from the juster claims
  • and greater need of France or the well-founded expectations of Belgium.
  • Yet the financial problems which were about to exercise Europe could not
  • be solved by greed. The possibility of _their_ cure lay in magnanimity.
  • Europe, if she is to survive her troubles, will need so much magnanimity
  • from America, that she must herself practice it. It is useless for the
  • Allies, hot from stripping Germany and one another, to turn for help to
  • the United States to put the States of Europe, including Germany, on to
  • their feet again. If the General Election of December, 1918, had been
  • fought on lines of prudent generosity instead of imbecile greed, how
  • much better the financial prospect of Europe might now be. I still
  • believe that before the main Conference, or very early in its
  • proceedings, the representatives of Great Britain should have entered
  • deeply, with those of the United States, into the economic and financial
  • situation as a whole, and that the former should have been authorized to
  • make concrete proposals on the general lines (1) that all inter-allied
  • indebtedness be canceled outright; (2) that the sum to be paid by
  • Germany be fixed at $10,000,000,000; (3) that Great Britain renounce all
  • claim to participation in this sum and that any share to which she
  • proves entitled be placed at the disposal of the Conference for the
  • purpose of aiding the finances of the New States about to be
  • established; (4) that in order to make some basis of credit immediately
  • available an appropriate proportion of the German obligations
  • representing the sum to be paid by her should be guaranteed by all
  • parties to the Treaty; and (5) that the ex-enemy Powers should also be
  • allowed, with a view to their economic restoration, to issue a moderate
  • amount of bonds carrying a similar guarantee. Such proposals involved an
  • appeal to the generosity of the United States. But that was inevitable;
  • and, in view of her far less financial sacrifices, it was an appeal
  • which could fairly have been made to her. Such proposals would have been
  • practicable. There is nothing in them quixotic or Utopian. And they
  • would have opened up for Europe some prospect of financial stability and
  • reconstruction.
  • The further elaboration of these ideas, however, must be left to Chapter
  • VII., and we must return to Paris. I have described the entanglements
  • which Mr. Lloyd George took with him. The position of the Finance
  • Ministers of the other Allies was even worse. We in Great Britain had
  • not based our financial arrangements on any expectations of an
  • indemnity. Receipts from such a source would have been more or less in
  • the nature of a windfall; and, in spite of subsequent developments,
  • there was an expectation at that time of balancing our budget by normal
  • methods. But this was not the case with France or Italy. Their peace
  • budgets made no pretense of balancing and had no prospects of doing so,
  • without some far-reaching revision of the existing policy. Indeed, the
  • position was and remains nearly hopeless. These countries were heading
  • for national bankruptcy. This fact could only be concealed by holding
  • out the expectation of vast receipts from the enemy. As soon as it was
  • admitted that it was in fact impossible to make Germany pay the expenses
  • of both sides, and that the unloading of their liabilities upon the
  • enemy was not practicable, the position of the Ministers of Finance of
  • France and Italy became untenable.
  • Thus a scientific consideration of Germany's capacity to pay was from
  • the outset out of court. The expectations which the exigencies of
  • politics had made it necessary to raise were so very remote from the
  • truth that a slight distortion of figures was no use, and it was
  • necessary to ignore the facts entirely. The resulting unveracity was
  • fundamental. On a basis of so much falsehood it became impossible to
  • erect any constructive financial policy which was workable. For this
  • reason amongst others, a magnanimous financial policy was essential. The
  • financial position of France and Italy was so bad that it was impossible
  • to make them listen to reason on the subject of the German Indemnity,
  • unless one could at the same time point out to them some alternative
  • mode of escape from their troubles.[103] The representatives of the
  • United States were greatly at fault, in my judgment, for having no
  • constructive proposals whatever to offer to a suffering and distracted
  • Europe.
  • It is worth while to point out in passing a further element in the
  • situation, namely, the opposition which existed between the "crushing"
  • policy of M. Clemenceau and the financial necessities of M. Klotz.
  • Clemenceau's aim was to weaken and destroy Germany in every possible
  • way, and I fancy that he was always a little contemptuous about the
  • Indemnity; he had no intention of leaving Germany in a position to
  • practise a vast commercial activity. But he did not trouble his head to
  • understand either the indemnity or poor M. Klotz's overwhelming
  • financial difficulties. If it amused the financiers to put into the
  • Treaty some very large demands, well there was no harm in that; but the
  • satisfaction of these demands must not be allowed to interfere with the
  • essential requirements of a Carthaginian Peace. The combination of the
  • "real" policy of M. Clemenceau on unreal issues, with M. Klotz's policy
  • of pretense on what were very real issues indeed, introduced into the
  • Treaty a whole set of incompatible provisions, over and above the
  • inherent impracticabilities of the Reparation proposals.
  • I cannot here describe the endless controversy and intrigue between the
  • Allies themselves, which at last after some months culminated in the
  • presentation to Germany of the Reparation Chapter in its final form.
  • There can have been few negotiations in history so contorted, so
  • miserable, so utterly unsatisfactory to all parties. I doubt if any one
  • who took much part in that debate can look back on it without shame. I
  • must be content with an analysis of the elements of the final compromise
  • which is known to all the world.
  • The main point to be settled was, of course, that of the items for which
  • Germany could fairly be asked to make payment. Mr. Lloyd George's
  • election pledge to the effect that the Allies were _entitled_ to demand
  • from Germany the entire costs of the war was from the outset clearly
  • untenable; or rather, to put it more impartially, it was clear that to
  • persuade the President of the conformity of this demand with our
  • pro-Armistice engagements was beyond the powers of the most plausible.
  • The actual compromise finally reached is to be read as follows in the
  • paragraphs of the Treaty as it has been published to the world.
  • Article 231 reads: "The Allied and Associated Governments affirm and
  • Germany accepts the responsibility of Germany and her allies for causing
  • all the loss and damage to which the Allied and Associated Governments
  • and their nationals have been subjected as a consequence of the war
  • imposed upon them by the aggression of Germany and her allies." This is
  • a well and carefully drafted Article; for the President could read it as
  • statement of admission on Germany's part of _moral_ responsibility for
  • bringing about the war, while the Prime Minister could explain it as an
  • admission of _financial_ liability for the general costs of the war.
  • Article 232 continues: "The Allied and Associated Governments recognize
  • that the resources of Germany are not adequate, after taking into
  • account permanent diminutions of such resources which will result from
  • other provisions of the present Treaty, to make complete reparation for
  • all such loss and damage." The President could comfort himself that this
  • was no more than a statement of undoubted fact, and that to recognize
  • that Germany _cannot_ pay a certain claim does not imply that she is
  • _liable_ to pay the claim; but the Prime Minister could point out that
  • in the context it emphasizes to the reader the assumption of Germany's
  • theoretic liability asserted in the preceding Article. Article 232
  • proceeds: "The Allied and Associated Governments, however, require, and
  • Germany undertakes, that _she will make compensation for all damage done
  • to the civilian population of the Allied and Associated Powers and to
  • their property_ during the period of the belligerency of each as an
  • Allied or Associated Power against Germany _by such aggression by land,
  • by sea, and from the air_, and in general all damage as defined in Annex
  • I. hereto."[104] The words italicized being practically a quotation from
  • the pre-Armistice conditions, satisfied the scruples of the President,
  • while the addition of the words "and in general all damage as defined in
  • Annex I. hereto" gave the Prime Minister a chance in Annex I.
  • So far, however, all this is only a matter of words, of virtuosity in
  • draftsmanship, which does no one any harm, and which probably seemed
  • much more important at the time than it ever will again between now and
  • Judgment Day. For substance we must turn to Annex I.
  • A great part of Annex I. is in strict conformity with the pre-Armistice
  • conditions, or, at any rate, does not strain them beyond what is fairly
  • arguable. Paragraph 1 claims damage done for injury to the persons of
  • civilians, or, in the case of death, to their dependents, as a direct
  • consequence of acts of war; Paragraph 2, for acts of cruelty, violence,
  • or maltreatment on the part of the enemy towards civilian victims;
  • Paragraph 3, for enemy acts injurious to health or capacity to work or
  • to honor towards civilians in occupied or invaded territory; Paragraph
  • 8, for forced labor exacted by the enemy from civilians; Paragraph 9,
  • for damage done to property "with the exception of naval and military
  • works or materials" as a direct consequence of hostilities; and
  • Paragraph 10, for fines and levies imposed by the enemy upon the
  • civilian population. All these demands are just and in conformity with
  • the Allies' rights.
  • Paragraph 4, which claims for "damage caused by any kind of maltreatment
  • of prisoners of war," is more doubtful on the strict letter, but may be
  • justifiable under the Hague Convention and involves a very small sum.
  • In Paragraphs 5, 6, and 7, however, an issue of immensely greater
  • significance is involved. These paragraphs assert a claim for the amount
  • of the Separation and similar Allowances granted during the war by the
  • Allied Governments to the families of mobilized persons, and for the
  • amount of the pensions and compensations in respect of the injury or
  • death of combatants payable by these Governments now and hereafter.
  • Financially this adds to the Bill, as we shall see below, a very large
  • amount, indeed about twice as much again as all the other claims added
  • together.
  • The reader will readily apprehend what a plausible case can be made out
  • for the inclusion of these items of damage, if only on sentimental
  • grounds. It can be pointed out, first of all, that from the point of
  • view of general fairness it is monstrous that a woman whose house is
  • destroyed should be entitled to claim from the enemy whilst a woman
  • whose husband is killed on the field of battle should not be so
  • entitled; or that a farmer deprived of his farm should claim but that a
  • woman deprived of the earning power of her husband should not claim. In
  • fact the case for including Pensions and Separation Allowances largely
  • depends on exploiting the rather _arbitrary_ character of the criterion
  • laid down in the pre-Armistice conditions. Of all the losses caused by
  • war some bear more heavily on individuals and some are more evenly
  • distributed over the community as a whole; but by means of compensations
  • granted by the Government many of the former are in fact converted into
  • the latter. The most logical criterion for a limited claim, falling
  • short of the entire costs of the war, would have been in respect of
  • enemy acts contrary to International engagements or the recognized
  • practices of warfare. But this also would have been very difficult to
  • apply and unduly unfavorable to French interests as compared with
  • Belgium (whose neutrality Germany had guaranteed) and Great Britain (the
  • chief sufferer from illicit acts of submarines).
  • In any case the appeals to sentiment and fairness outlined above are
  • hollow; for it makes no difference to the recipient of a separation
  • allowance or a pension whether the State which pays them receives
  • compensation on this or on another head, and a recovery by the State out
  • of indemnity receipts is just as much in relief of the general taxpayer
  • as a contribution towards the general costs of the war would have been.
  • But the main consideration is that it was too late to consider whether
  • the pre-Armistice conditions were perfectly judicious and logical or to
  • amend them; the only question at issue was whether these conditions were
  • not in fact limited to such classes of direct damage to civilians and
  • their property as are set forth in Paragraphs 1, 2, 3, 8, 9, and 10 of
  • Annex I. If words have any meaning, or engagements any force, we had no
  • more right to claim for those war expenses of the State, which arose out
  • of Pensions and Separation Allowances, than for any other of the general
  • costs of the war. And who is prepared to argue in detail that we were
  • entitled to demand the latter?
  • What had really happened was a compromise between the Prime Minister's
  • pledge to the British electorate to claim the entire costs of the war
  • and the pledge to the contrary which the Allies had given to Germany at
  • the Armistice. The Prime Minister could claim that although he had not
  • secured the entire costs of the war, he had nevertheless secured an
  • important contribution towards them, that he had always qualified his
  • promises by the limiting condition of Germany's capacity to pay, and
  • that the bill as now presented more than exhausted this capacity as
  • estimated by the more sober authorities. The President, on the other
  • hand, had secured a formula, which was not too obvious a breach of
  • faith, and had avoided a quarrel with his Associates on an issue where
  • the appeals to sentiment and passion would all have been against him, in
  • the event of its being made a matter of open popular controversy. In
  • view of the Prime Minister's election pledges, the President could
  • hardly hope to get him to abandon them in their entirety without a
  • struggle in public; and the cry of pensions would have had an
  • overwhelming popular appeal in all countries. Once more the Prime
  • Minister had shown himself a political tactician of a high order.
  • A further point of great difficulty may be readily perceived between the
  • lines of the Treaty. It fixes no definite sum as representing Germany's
  • liability. This feature has been the subject of very general
  • criticism,--that it is equally inconvenient to Germany and to the Allies
  • themselves that she should not know what she has to pay or they what
  • they are to receive. The method, apparently contemplated by the Treaty,
  • of arriving at the final result over a period of many months by an
  • addition of hundreds of thousands of individual claims for damage to
  • land, farm buildings, and chickens, is evidently impracticable; and the
  • reasonable course would have been for both parties to compound for a
  • round sum without examination of details. If this round sum had been
  • named in the Treaty, the settlement would have been placed on a more
  • business-like basis.
  • But this was impossible for two reasons. Two different kinds of false
  • statements had been widely promulgated, one as to Germany's capacity to
  • pay, the other as to the amount of the Allies' just claims in respect of
  • the devastated areas. The fixing of either of these figures presented a
  • dilemma. A figure for Germany's prospective capacity to pay, not too
  • much in excess of the estimates of most candid and well-informed
  • authorities, would have fallen hopelessly far short of popular
  • expectations both in England and in France. On the other hand, a
  • definitive figure for damage done which would not disastrously
  • disappoint the expectations which had been raised in France and Belgium
  • might have been incapable of substantiation under challenge,[105] and
  • open to damaging criticism on the part of the Germans, who were believed
  • to have been prudent enough to accumulate considerable evidence as to
  • the extent of their own misdoings.
  • By far the safest course for the politicians was, therefore, to mention
  • no figure at all; and from this necessity a great deal of the
  • complication of the Reparation Chapter essentially springs.
  • The reader may be interested, however, to have my estimate of the claim
  • which can in fact be substantiated under Annex I. of the Reparation
  • Chapter. In the first section of this chapter I have already guessed the
  • claims other than those for Pensions and Separation Allowances at
  • $15,000,000,000 (to take the extreme upper limit of my estimate). The
  • claim for Pensions and Separation Allowances under Annex I. is not to be
  • based on the _actual_ cost of these compensations to the Governments
  • concerned, but is to be a computed figure calculated on the basis of the
  • scales in force in France at the date of the Treaty's coming into
  • operation. This method avoids the invidious course of valuing an
  • American or a British life at a higher figure than a French or an
  • Italian. The French rate for Pensions and Allowances is at an
  • intermediate rate, not so high as the American or British, but above the
  • Italian, the Belgian, or the Serbian. The only data required for the
  • calculation are the actual French rates and the numbers of men mobilized
  • and of the casualties in each class of the various Allied Armies. None
  • of these figures are available in detail, but enough is known of the
  • general level of allowances, of the numbers involved, and of the
  • casualties suffered to allow of an estimate which may not be _very wide_
  • of the mark. My guess as to the amount to be added in respect of
  • Pensions and Allowances is as follows:
  • British Empire $ 7,000,000,000[106]
  • France 12,000,000,000[106]
  • Italy 2,500,000,000
  • Others (including United States) 3,500,000,000
  • ---------------
  • Total $ 25,000,000,000
  • I feel much more confidence in the approximate accuracy of the total
  • figure[107] than in its division between the different claimants. The
  • reader will observe that in any case the addition of Pensions and
  • Allowances enormously increases the aggregate claim, raising it indeed
  • by nearly double. Adding this figure to the estimate under other heads,
  • we have a total claim against Germany of $40,000,000,000.[108] I believe
  • that this figure is fully high enough, and that the actual result may
  • fall somewhat short of it.[109] In the next section of this chapter the
  • relation of this figure to Germany's capacity to pay will be examined.
  • It is only necessary here to remind the reader of certain other
  • particulars of the Treaty which speak for themselves:
  • 1. Out of the total amount of the claim, whatever it eventually turns
  • out to be, a sum of $5,000,000,000 must be paid before May 1, 1921. The
  • possibility of this will be discussed below. But the Treaty itself
  • provides certain abatements. In the first place, this sum is to include
  • the expenses of the Armies of Occupation since the Armistice (a large
  • charge of the order of magnitude of $1,000,000,000 which under another
  • Article of the Treaty--No. 249--is laid upon Germany).[110] But further,
  • "such supplies of food and raw materials as may be judged by the
  • Governments of the Principal Allied and Associated Powers to be
  • essential to enable Germany to meet her obligations for Reparation may
  • also, with the approval of the said Governments, be paid for out of the
  • above sum."[111] This is a qualification of high importance. The clause,
  • as it is drafted, allows the Finance Ministers of the Allied countries
  • to hold out to their electorates the hope of substantial payments at an
  • early date, while at the same time it gives to the Reparation Commission
  • a discretion, which the force of facts will compel them to exercise, to
  • give back to Germany what is required for the maintenance of her
  • economic existence. This discretionary power renders the demand for an
  • immediate payment of $5,000,000,000 less injurious than it would
  • otherwise be, but nevertheless it does not render it innocuous. In the
  • first place, my conclusions in the next section of this chapter indicate
  • that this sum cannot be found within the period indicated, even if a
  • large proportion is in practice returned to Germany for the purpose of
  • enabling her to pay for imports. In the second place, the Reparation
  • Commission can only exercise its discretionary power effectively by
  • taking charge of the entire foreign trade of Germany, together with the
  • foreign exchange arising out of it, which will be quite beyond the
  • capacity of any such body. If the Reparation Commission makes any
  • serious attempt to administer the collection of this sum of
  • $5,000,000,000 and to authorize the return to Germany of a part it, the
  • trade of Central Europe will be strangled by bureaucratic regulation in
  • its most inefficient form.
  • 2. In addition to the early payment in cash or kind of a sum of
  • $5,000,000,000, Germany is required to deliver bearer bonds to a further
  • amount of $10,000,000,000, or, in the event of the payments in cash or
  • kind before May 1, 1921, available for Reparation, falling short of
  • $5,000,000,000 by reason of the permitted deductions, to such further
  • amount as shall bring the total payments by Germany in cash, kind, and
  • bearer bonds up to May 1, 1921, to a figure of $15,000,000,000
  • altogether.[112] These bearer bonds carry interest at 2-1/2 per cent per
  • annum from 1921 to 1925, and at 5 per cent _plus_ 1 per cent for
  • amortization thereafter. Assuming, therefore, that Germany is not able
  • to provide any appreciable surplus towards Reparation before 1921, she
  • will have to find a sum of $375,000,000 annually from 1921 to 1925, and
  • $900,000,000 annually thereafter.[113]
  • 3. As soon as the Reparation Commission is satisfied that Germany can do
  • better than this, 5 per cent bearer bonds are to be issued for a further
  • $10,000,000,000, the rate of amortization being determined by the
  • Commission hereafter. This would bring the annual payment to
  • $1,400,000,000 without allowing anything for the discharge of the
  • capital of the last $10,000,000,000.
  • 4. Germany's liability, however, is not limited to $25,000,000,000, and
  • the Reparation Commission is to demand further instalments of bearer
  • bonds until the total enemy liability under Annex I. has been provided
  • for. On the basis of my estimate of $40,000,000,000 for the total
  • liability, which is more likely to be criticized as being too low than
  • as being too high, the amount of this balance will be $15,000,000,000.
  • Assuming interest at 5 per cent, this will raise the annual payment to
  • $2,150,000,000 without allowance for amortization.
  • 5. But even this is not all. There is a further provision of devastating
  • significance. Bonds representing payments in excess of $15,000,000,000
  • are not to be issued until the Commission is satisfied that Germany can
  • meet the interest on them. But this does not mean that interest is
  • remitted in the meantime. As from May 1, 1921, interest is to be debited
  • to Germany on such part of her outstanding debt as has not been covered
  • by payment in cash or kind or by the issue of bonds as above,[114] and
  • "the rate of interest shall be 5 per cent unless the Commission shall
  • determine at some future time that circumstances justify a variation of
  • this rate." That is to say, the capital sum of indebtedness is rolling
  • up all the time at compound interest. The effect of this provision
  • towards increasing the burden is, on the assumption that Germany cannot
  • pay very large sums at first, enormous. At 5 per cent compound interest
  • a capital sum doubles itself in fifteen years. On the assumption that
  • Germany cannot pay more than $750,000,000 annually until 1936 (_i.e._ 5
  • per cent interest on $15,000,000,000) the $25,000,000,000 on which
  • interest is deferred will have risen to $50,000,000,000, carrying an
  • annual interest charge of $2,500,000,000. That is to say, even if
  • Germany pays $750,000,000 annually up to 1936, she will nevertheless owe
  • us at that date more than half as much again as she does now
  • ($65,000,000,000 as compared with $40,000,000,000). From 1936 onwards
  • she will have to pay to us $3,250,000,000 annually in order to keep pace
  • with the interest alone. At the end of any year in which she pays less
  • than this sum she will owe more than she did at the beginning of it. And
  • if she is to discharge the capital sum in thirty years from 1930, _i.e._
  • in forty-eight years from the Armistice, she must pay an additional
  • $650,000,000 annually, making $3,900,000,000 in all.[115]
  • It is, in my judgment, as certain as anything can be, for reasons which
  • I will elaborate in a moment, that Germany cannot pay anything
  • approaching this sum. Until the Treaty is altered, therefore, Germany
  • has in effect engaged herself to hand over to the Allies the whole of
  • her surplus production in perpetuity.
  • 6. This is not less the case because the Reparation Commission has been
  • given discretionary powers to vary the rate of interest, and to postpone
  • and even to cancel the capital indebtedness. In the first place, some of
  • these powers can only be exercised if the Commission or the Governments
  • represented on it are _unanimous_.[116] But also, which is perhaps more
  • important, it will be the _duty_ of the Reparation Commission, until
  • there has been a unanimous and far-reaching change of the policy which
  • the Treaty represents, to extract from Germany year after year the
  • maximum sum obtainable. There is a great difference between fixing a
  • definite sum, which though large is within Germany's capacity to pay and
  • yet to retain a little for herself, and fixing a sum far beyond her
  • capacity, which is then to be reduced at the discretion of a foreign
  • Commission acting with the object of obtaining each year the maximum
  • which the circumstances of that year permit. The first still leaves her
  • with some slight incentive for enterprise, energy, and hope. The latter
  • skins her alive year by year in perpetuity, and however skilfully and
  • discreetly the operation is performed, with whatever regard for not
  • killing the patient in the process, it would represent a policy which,
  • if it were really entertained and deliberately practised, the judgment
  • of men would soon pronounce to be one of the most outrageous acts of a
  • cruel victor in civilized history.
  • There are other functions and powers of high significance which the
  • Treaty accords to the Reparation Commission. But these will be most
  • conveniently dealt with in a separate section.
  • III. _Germany's Capacity to pay_
  • The forms in which Germany can discharge the sum which she has engaged
  • herself to pay are three in number--
  • 1. Immediately transferable wealth in the form of gold, ships, and
  • foreign securities;
  • 2. The value of property in ceded territory, or surrendered under the
  • Armistice;
  • 3. Annual payments spread over a term of years, partly in cash and
  • partly in materials such as coal products, potash, and dyes.
  • There is excluded from the above the actual restitution of property
  • removed from territory occupied by the enemy, as, for example, Russian
  • gold, Belgian and French securities, cattle, machinery, and works of
  • art. In so far as the actual goods taken can be identified and restored,
  • they must clearly be returned to their rightful owners, and cannot be
  • brought into the general reparation pool. This is expressly provided for
  • in Article 238 of the Treaty.
  • 1. _Immediately Transferable Wealth_
  • (_a_) _Gold_.--After deduction of the gold to be returned to Russia, the
  • official holding of gold as shown in the Reichsbank's return of the 30th
  • November, 1918, amounted to $577,089,500. This was a very much larger
  • amount than had appeared in the Reichsbank's return prior to the
  • war,[117] and was the result of the vigorous campaign carried on in
  • Germany during the war for the surrender to the Reichsbank not only of
  • gold coin but of gold ornaments of every kind. Private hoards doubtless
  • still exist, but, in view of the great efforts already made, it is
  • unlikely that either the German Government or the Allies will be able to
  • unearth them. The return can therefore be taken as probably representing
  • the maximum amount which the German Government are able to extract from
  • their people. In addition to gold there was in the Reichsbank a sum of
  • about $5,000,000 in silver. There must be, however, a further
  • substantial amount in circulation, for the holdings of the Reichsbank
  • were as high as $45,500,000 on the 31st December, 1917, and stood at
  • about $30,000,000 up to the latter part of October, 1918, when the
  • internal run began on currency of every kind.[118] We may, therefore,
  • take a total of (say) $625,000,000 for gold and silver together at the
  • date of the Armistice.
  • These reserves, however, are no longer intact. During the long period
  • which elapsed between the Armistice and the Peace it became necessary
  • for the Allies to facilitate the provisioning of Germany from abroad.
  • The political condition of Germany at that time and the serious menace
  • of Spartacism rendered this step necessary in the interests of the
  • Allies themselves if they desired the continuance in Germany of a stable
  • Government to treat with. The question of how such provisions were to be
  • paid for presented, however, the gravest difficulties. A series of
  • Conferences was held at Trèves, at Spa, at Brussels, and subsequently at
  • ChĂ¢teau Villette and Versailles, between representatives of the Allies
  • and of Germany, with the object of finding some method of payment as
  • little injurious as possible to the future prospects of Reparation
  • payments. The German representatives maintained from the outset that the
  • financial exhaustion of their country was for the time being so complete
  • that a temporary loan from the Allies was the only possible expedient.
  • This the Allies could hardly admit at a time when they were preparing
  • demands for the immediate payment by Germany of immeasurably larger
  • sums. But, apart from this, the German claim could not be accepted as
  • strictly accurate so long as their gold was still untapped and their
  • remaining foreign securities unmarketed. In any case, it was out of the
  • question to suppose that in the spring of 1919 public opinion in the
  • Allied countries or in America would have allowed the grant of a
  • substantial loan to Germany. On the other hand, the Allies were
  • naturally reluctant to exhaust on the provisioning of Germany the gold
  • which seemed to afford one of the few obvious and certain sources for
  • Reparation. Much time was expended in the exploration of all possible
  • alternatives; but it was evident at last that, even if German exports
  • and saleable foreign securities had been available to a sufficient
  • value, they could not be liquidated in time, and that the financial
  • exhaustion of Germany was so complete that nothing whatever was
  • immediately available in substantial amounts except the gold in the
  • Reichsbank. Accordingly a sum exceeding $250,000,000 in all out of the
  • Reichsbank gold was transferred by Germany to the Allies (chiefly to the
  • United States, Great Britain, however, also receiving a substantial sum)
  • during the first six months of 1919 in payment for foodstuffs.
  • But this was not all. Although Germany agreed, under the first extension
  • of the Armistice, not to export gold without Allied permission, this
  • permission could not be always withheld. There were liabilities of the
  • Reichsbank accruing in the neighboring neutral countries, which could
  • not be met otherwise than in gold. The failure of the Reichsbank to meet
  • its liabilities would have caused a depreciation of the exchange so
  • injurious to Germany's credit as to react on the future prospects of
  • Reparation. In some cases, therefore, permission to export gold was
  • accorded to the Reichsbank by the Supreme Economic Council of the
  • Allies.
  • The net result of these various measures was to reduce the gold reserve
  • of the Reichsbank by more than half, the figures falling from
  • $575,000,000 to $275,000,000 in September, 1919.
  • It would be _possible_ under the Treaty to take the whole of this latter
  • sum for Reparation purposes. It amounts, however, as it is, to less
  • than 4 per cent of the Reichsbank's Note Issue, and the psychological
  • effect of its total confiscation might be expected (having regard to the
  • very large volume of mark notes held abroad) to destroy the exchange
  • value of the mark almost entirely. A sum of $25,000,000, $50,000,000, or
  • even $100,000,000 might be taken for a special purpose. But we may
  • assume that the Reparation Commission will judge it imprudent, having
  • regard to the reaction on their future prospects of securing payment, to
  • ruin the German currency system altogether, more particularly because
  • the French and Belgian Governments, being holders of a very large volume
  • of mark notes formerly circulating in the occupied or ceded territory,
  • have a great interest in maintaining some exchange value for the mark,
  • quite apart from Reparation prospects.
  • It follows, therefore, that no sum worth speaking of can be expected in
  • the form of gold or silver towards the initial payment of $5,000,000,000
  • due by 1921.
  • (_b_) _Shipping_.--Germany has engaged, as we have seen above, to
  • surrender to the Allies virtually the whole of her merchant shipping. A
  • considerable part of it, indeed, was already in the hands of the Allies
  • prior to the conclusion of Peace, either by detention in their ports or
  • by the provisional transfer of tonnage under the Brussels Agreement in
  • connection with the supply of foodstuffs.[119] Estimating the tonnage of
  • German shipping to be taken over under the Treaty at 4,000,000 gross
  • tons, and the average value per ton at $150 per ton, the total money
  • value involved is $600,000,000.[120]
  • (_c_) _Foreign Securities_.--Prior to the census of foreign securities
  • carried out by the German Government in September, 1916,[121] of which
  • the exact results have not been made public, no official return of such
  • investments was ever called for in Germany, and the various unofficial
  • estimates are confessedly based on insufficient data, such as the
  • admission of foreign securities to the German Stock Exchanges, the
  • receipts of the stamp duties, consular reports, etc. The principal
  • German estimates current before the war are given in the appended
  • footnote.[122] This shows a general consensus of opinion among German
  • authorities that their net foreign investments were upwards of
  • $6,250,000,000. I take this figure as the basis of my calculations,
  • although I believe it to be an exaggeration; $5,000,000,000 would
  • probably be a safer figure.
  • Deductions from this aggregate total have to be made under four heads.
  • (i.) Investments in Allied countries and in the United States, which
  • between them constitute a considerable part of the world, have been
  • sequestrated by Public Trustees, Custodians of Enemy Property, and
  • similar officials, and are not available for Reparation except in so far
  • as they show a surplus over various private claims. Under the scheme for
  • dealing with enemy debts outlined in Chapter IV., the first charge on
  • these assets is the private claims of Allied against German nationals.
  • It is unlikely, except in the United States, that there will be any
  • appreciable surplus for any other purpose.
  • (ii.) Germany's most important fields of foreign investment before the
  • war were not, like ours, oversea, but in Russia, Austria-Hungary,
  • Turkey, Roumania, and Bulgaria. A great part of these has now become
  • almost valueless, at any rate for the time being; especially those in
  • Russia and Austria-Hungary. If present market value is to be taken as
  • the test, none of these investments are now saleable above a nominal
  • figure. Unless the Allies are prepared to take over these securities
  • much above their nominal market valuation, and hold them for future
  • realization, there is no substantial source of funds for immediate
  • payment in the form of investments in these countries.
  • (iii.) While Germany was not in a position to realize her foreign
  • investments during the war to the degree that we were, she did so
  • nevertheless in the case of certain countries and to the extent that
  • she was able. Before the United States came into the war, she is
  • believed to have resold a large part of the pick of her investments in
  • American securities, although some current estimates of these sales (a
  • figure of $300,000,000 has been mentioned) are probably exaggerated. But
  • throughout the war and particularly in its later stages, when her
  • exchanges were weak and her credit in the neighboring neutral countries
  • was becoming very low, she was disposing of such securities as Holland,
  • Switzerland, and Scandinavia would buy or would accept as collateral. It
  • is reasonably certain that by June, 1919, her investments in these
  • countries had been reduced to a negligible figure and were far exceeded
  • by her liabilities in them. Germany has also sold certain overseas
  • securities, such as Argentine cedulas, for which a market could be
  • found.
  • (iv.) It is certain that since the Armistice there has been a great
  • flight abroad of the foreign securities still remaining in private
  • hands. This is exceedingly difficult to prevent. German foreign
  • investments are as a rule in the form of bearer securities and are not
  • registered. They are easily smuggled abroad across Germany's extensive
  • land frontiers, and for some months before the conclusion of peace it
  • was certain that their owners would not be allowed to retain them if the
  • Allied Governments could discover any method of getting hold of them.
  • These factors combined to stimulate human ingenuity, and the efforts
  • both of the Allied and of the German Governments to interfere
  • effectively with the outflow are believed to have been largely futile.
  • In face of all these considerations, it will be a miracle if much
  • remains for Reparation. The countries of the Allies and of the United
  • States, the countries of Germany's own allies, and the neutral countries
  • adjacent to Germany exhaust between them almost the whole of the
  • civilized world; and, as we have seen, we cannot expect much to be
  • available for Reparation from investments in any of these quarters.
  • Indeed there remain no countries of importance for investments except
  • those of South America.
  • To convert the significance of these deductions into figures involves
  • much guesswork. I give the reader the best personal estimate I can form
  • after pondering the matter in the light of the available figures and
  • other relevant data.
  • I put the deduction under (i.) at $1,500,000,000, of which $500,000,000
  • may be ultimately available after meeting private debts, etc.
  • As regards (ii.)--according to a census taken by the Austrian Ministry
  • of Finance on the 31st December, 1912, the nominal value of the
  • Austro-Hungarian securities held by Germans was $986,500,000. Germany's
  • pre-war investments in Russia outside Government securities have been
  • estimated at $475,000,000, which is much lower than would be expected,
  • and in 1906 Sartorius v. Waltershausen estimated her investments in
  • Russian Government securities at $750,000,000. This gives a total of
  • $1,225,000,000, which is to some extent borne out by the figure of
  • $1,000,000,000 given in 1911 by Dr. Ischchanian as a deliberately modest
  • estimate. A Roumanian estimate, published at the time of that country's
  • entry in the war, gave the value of Germany's investments in Roumania at
  • $20,000,000 to $22,000,000, of which $14,000,000 to $16,000,000 were in
  • Government securities. An association for the defense of French
  • interests in Turkey, as reported in the _Temps_ (Sept. 8, 1919), has
  • estimated the total amount of German capital invested in Turkey at about
  • $295,000,000, of which, according to the latest Report of the Council of
  • Foreign Bondholders, $162,500,000 was held by German nationals in the
  • Turkish External Debt. No estimates are available to me of Germany's
  • investments in Bulgaria. Altogether I venture a deduction of
  • $2,500,000,000 in respect of this group of countries as a whole.
  • Resales and the pledging as collateral of securities during the war
  • under (iii.) I put at $500,000,000 to $750,000,000, comprising
  • practically all Germany's holding of Scandinavian, Dutch, and Swiss
  • securities, a part of her South American securities, and a substantial
  • proportion of her North American securities sold prior to the entry of
  • the United States into the war.
  • As to the proper deduction under (iv.) there are naturally no available
  • figures. For months past the European press has been full of sensational
  • stories of the expedients adopted. But if we put the value of securities
  • which have already left Germany or have been safely secreted within
  • Germany itself beyond discovery by the most inquisitorial and powerful
  • methods at $500,000,000, we are not likely to overstate it.
  • These various items lead, therefore, in all to a deduction of a round
  • figure of about $5,000,000,000, and leave us with an amount of
  • $1,250,000,000 theoretically still available.[123]
  • To some readers this figure may seem low, but let them remember that it
  • purports to represent the remnant of _saleable_ securities upon which
  • the German Government might be able to lay hands for public purposes. In
  • my own opinion it is much too high, and considering the problem by a
  • different method of attack I arrive at a lower figure. For leaving out
  • of account sequestered Allied securities and investments in Austria,
  • Russia, etc., what blocks of securities, specified by countries and
  • enterprises, can Germany possibly still have which could amount to as
  • much as $1,250,000,000? I cannot answer the question. She has some
  • Chinese Government securities which have not been sequestered, a few
  • Japanese perhaps, and a more substantial value of first-class South
  • American properties. But there are very few enterprises of this class
  • still in German hands, and even _their_ value is measured by one or two
  • tens of millions, not by fifties or hundreds. He would be a rash man, in
  • my judgment, who joined a syndicate to pay $500,000,000 in cash for the
  • unsequestered remnant of Germany's overseas investments. If the
  • Reparation Commission is to realize even this lower figure, it is
  • probable that they will have to nurse, for some years, the assets which
  • they take over, not attempting their disposal at the present time.
  • We have, therefore, a figure of from $500,000,000 to $1,250,000,000 as
  • the maximum contribution from Germany's foreign securities.
  • Her immediately transferable wealth is composed, then, of--
  • (_a_) Gold and silver--say $300,000,000.
  • (_b_) Ships--$600,000,000.
  • (_c_) Foreign securities--$500,000,000 to $1,250,000,000.
  • Of the gold and silver, it is not, in fact, practicable to take any
  • substantial part without consequences to the German currency system
  • injurious to the interests of the Allies themselves. The contribution
  • from all these sources together which the Reparation Commission can hope
  • to secure by May, 1921, may be put, therefore, at from $1,250,000,000 to
  • $1,750,000,000 _as a maximum_.[124]
  • 2. _Property in ceded Territory or surrendered under the Armistice_
  • As the Treaty has been drafted Germany will not receive important
  • credits available towards meeting reparation in respect of her property
  • in ceded territory.
  • _Private_ property in most of the ceded territory is utilized towards
  • discharging private German debts to Allied nationals, and only the
  • surplus, if any, is available towards Reparation. The value of such
  • property in Poland and the other new States is payable direct to the
  • owners.
  • _Government_ property in Alsace-Lorraine, in territory ceded to Belgium,
  • and in Germany's former colonies transferred to a Mandatory, is to be
  • forfeited without credit given. Buildings, forests, and other State
  • property which belonged to the former Kingdom of Poland are also to be
  • surrendered without credit. There remain, therefore, Government
  • properties, other than the above, surrendered to Poland, Government
  • properties in Schleswig surrendered to Denmark,[125] the value of the
  • Saar coalfields, the value of certain river craft, etc., to be
  • surrendered under the Ports, Waterways, and Railways Chapter, and the
  • value of the German submarine cables transferred under Annex VII. of the
  • Reparation Chapter.
  • Whatever the Treaty may say, the Reparation Commission will not secure
  • any cash payments from Poland. I believe that the Saar coalfields have
  • been valued at from $75,000,000 to $100,000,000. A round figure of
  • $150,000,000 for all the above items, excluding any surplus available in
  • respect of private property, is probably a liberal estimate.
  • Then remains the value of material surrendered under the Armistice.
  • Article 250 provides that a credit shall be assessed by the Reparation
  • Commission for rolling-stock surrendered under the Armistice as well as
  • for certain other specified items, and generally for any material so
  • surrendered for which the Reparation Commission think that credit should
  • be given, "as having non-military value." The rolling-stock (150,000
  • wagons and 5,000 locomotives) is the only very valuable item. A round
  • figure of $250,000,000, for all the Armistice surrenders, is probably
  • again a liberal estimate.
  • We have, therefore, $400,000,000 to add in respect of this heading to
  • our figure of $1,250,000,000 to $1,750,000,000 under the previous
  • heading. This figure differs from the preceding in that it does not
  • represent cash capable of benefiting the financial situation of the
  • Allies, but is only a book credit between themselves or between them and
  • Germany.
  • The total of $1,650,000,000 to $2,150,000,000 now reached is not,
  • however, available for Reparation. The _first_ charge upon it, under
  • Article 251 of the Treaty, is the cost of the Armies of Occupation both
  • during the Armistice and after the conclusion of Peace. The aggregate of
  • this figure up to May, 1921, cannot be calculated until the rate of
  • withdrawal is known which is to reduce the _monthly_ cost from the
  • figure exceeding $100,000,000, which prevailed during the first part of
  • 1919, to that of $5,000,000, which is to be the normal figure
  • eventually. I estimate, however, that this aggregate may be about
  • $1,000,000,000. This leaves us with from $500,000,000 to $1,000,000,000
  • still in hand.
  • Out of this, and out of exports of goods, and payments in kind under the
  • Treaty prior to May, 1921 (for which I have not as yet made any
  • allowance), the Allies have held out the hope that they will allow
  • Germany to receive back such sums for the purchase of necessary food and
  • raw materials as the former deem it essential for her to have. It is not
  • possible at the present time to form an accurate judgment either as to
  • the money-value of the goods which Germany will require to purchase from
  • abroad in order to re-establish her economic life, or as to the degree
  • of liberality with which the Allies will exercise their discretion. If
  • her stocks of raw materials and food were to be restored to anything
  • approaching their normal level by May, 1921, Germany would probably
  • require foreign purchasing power of from $500,000,000 to $1,000,000,000
  • at least, in addition to the value of her current exports. While this is
  • not likely to be permitted, I venture to assert as a matter beyond
  • reasonable dispute that the social and economic condition of Germany
  • cannot possibly permit a surplus of exports over imports during the
  • period prior to May, 1921, and that the value of any payments in kind
  • with which she may be able to furnish the Allies under the Treaty in the
  • form of coal, dyes, timber, or other materials will have to be returned
  • to her to enable her to pay for imports essential to her existence.[126]
  • The Reparation Commission can, therefore, expect no addition from other
  • sources to the sum of from $500,000,000 to $1,000,000,000 with which we
  • have hypothetically credited it after the realization of Germany's
  • immediately transferable wealth, the calculation of the credits due to
  • Germany under the Treaty, and the discharge of the cost of the Armies of
  • Occupation. As Belgium has secured a private agreement with France, the
  • United States, and Great Britain, outside the Treaty, by which she is to
  • receive, towards satisfaction of her claims, the _first_ $500,000,000
  • available for Reparation, the upshot of the whole matter is that Belgium
  • may _possibly_ get her $500,000,000 by May, 1921, but none of the other
  • Allies are likely to secure by that date any contribution worth speaking
  • of. At any rate, it would be very imprudent for Finance Ministers to lay
  • their plans on any other hypothesis.
  • 3. _Annual Payments spread over a Term of Years_
  • It is evident that Germany's pre-war capacity to pay an annual foreign
  • tribute has not been unaffected by the almost total loss of her
  • colonies, her overseas connections, her mercantile marine, and her
  • foreign properties, by the cession of ten per cent of her territory and
  • population, of one-third of her coal and of three-quarters of her iron
  • ore, by two million casualties amongst men in the prime of life, by the
  • starvation of her people for four years, by the burden of a vast war
  • debt, by the depreciation of her currency to less than one-seventh its
  • former value, by the disruption of her allies and their territories, by
  • Revolution at home and Bolshevism on her borders, and by all the
  • unmeasured ruin in strength and hope of four years of all-swallowing war
  • and final defeat.
  • All this, one would have supposed, is evident. Yet most estimates of a
  • great indemnity from Germany depend on the assumption that she is in a
  • position to conduct in the future a vastly greater trade than ever she
  • has had in the past.
  • For the purpose of arriving at a figure it is of no great consequence
  • whether payment takes the form of cash (or rather of foreign exchange)
  • or is partly effected in kind (coal, dyes, timber, etc.), as
  • contemplated by the Treaty. In any event, it is only by the export of
  • specific commodities that Germany can pay, and the method of turning the
  • value of these exports to account for Reparation purposes is,
  • comparatively, a matter of detail.
  • We shall lose ourselves in mere hypothesis unless we return in some
  • degree to first principles, and, whenever we can, to such statistics as
  • there are. It is certain that an annual payment can only be made by
  • Germany over a series of years by diminishing her imports and increasing
  • her exports, thus enlarging the balance in her favor which is available
  • for effecting payments abroad. Germany can pay in the long-run in goods,
  • and in goods only, whether these goods are furnished direct to the
  • Allies, or whether they are sold to neutrals and the neutral credits so
  • arising are then made over to the Allies. The most solid basis for
  • estimating the extent to which this process can be carried is to be
  • found, therefore, in an analysis of her trade returns before the war.
  • Only on the basis of such an analysis, supplemented by some general data
  • as to the aggregate wealth-producing capacity of the country, can a
  • rational guess be made as to the maximum degree to which the exports of
  • Germany could be brought to exceed her imports.
  • In the year 1913 Germany's imports amounted to $2,690,000,000, and her
  • exports to $2,525,000,000, exclusive of transit trade and bullion. That
  • is to say, imports exceeded exports by about $165,000,000. On the
  • average of the five years ending 1913, however, her imports exceeded her
  • exports by a substantially larger amount, namely, $370,000,000. It
  • follows, therefore, that more than the whole of Germany's pre-war
  • balance for new foreign investment was derived from the interest on her
  • existing foreign securities, and from the profits of her shipping,
  • foreign banking, etc. As her foreign properties and her mercantile
  • marine are now to be taken from her, and as her foreign banking and
  • other miscellaneous sources of revenue from abroad have been largely
  • destroyed, it appears that, on the pre-war basis of exports and imports,
  • Germany, so far from having a surplus wherewith to make a foreign
  • payment, would be not nearly self-supporting. Her first task, therefore,
  • must be to effect a readjustment of consumption and production to cover
  • this deficit. Any further economy she can effect in the use of imported
  • commodities, and any further stimulation of exports will then be
  • available for Reparation.
  • Two-thirds of Germany's import and export trade is enumerated under
  • separate headings in the following tables. The considerations applying
  • to the enumerated portions may be assumed to apply more or less to the
  • remaining one-third, which is composed of commodities of minor
  • importance individually.
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • | Amount: | Percentage of
  • German Exports, 1913 | Million | Total Exports
  • | Dollars |
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • Iron goods (including tin plates, etc.) | 330.65 | 13.2
  • Machinery and parts (including | |
  • motor-cars) | 187.75 | 7.5
  • Coal, coke, and briquettes | 176.70 | 7.0
  • Woolen goods (including raw and | |
  • combed wool and clothing) | 147.00 | 5.9
  • Cotton goods (including raw cotton, | |
  • yarn, and thread) | 140.75 | 5.6
  • +---------+---------------
  • | 982.85 | 39.2
  • +---------+---------------
  • Cereals, etc. (including rye, oats, | |
  • wheat, hops) | 105.90 | 4.1
  • Leather and leather goods | 77.35 | 3.0
  • Sugar | 66.00 | 2.6
  • Paper, etc. | 65.50 | 2.6
  • Furs | 58.75 | 2.2
  • Electrical goods (installations, | |
  • machinery, lamps, cables) | 54.40 | 2.2
  • Silk goods | 50.50 | 2.0
  • Dyes | 48.80 | 1.9
  • Copper goods | 32.50 | 1.3
  • Toys | 25.75 | 1.0
  • Rubber and rubber goods | 21.35 | 0.9
  • Books, maps, and music | 18.55 | 0.8
  • Potash | 15.90 | 0.6
  • Glass | 15.70 | 0.6
  • Potassium chloride | 14.55 | 0.6
  • Pianos, organs, and parts | 13.85 | 0.6
  • Raw zinc | 13.70 | 0.5
  • Porcelain | 12.65 | 0.5
  • +---------+---------------
  • | 711.70 | 67.2
  • +---------+---------------
  • Other goods, unenumerated | 829.60 | 32.8
  • +---------+---------------
  • Total |2,524.15 | 100.0
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • | Amount: | Percentage of
  • German Imports, 1913 | Million | Total Imports
  • | Dollars |
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • I. Raw materials:-- | |
  • Cotton | 151.75 | 5.6
  • Hides and skins | 124.30 | 4.6
  • Wool | 118.35 | 4.4
  • Copper | 83.75 | 3.1
  • Coal | 68.30 | 2.5
  • Timber | 58.00 | 2.2
  • Iron ore | 56.75 | 2.1
  • Furs | 46.75 | 1.7
  • Flax and flaxseed | 46.65 | 1.7
  • Saltpetre | 42.75 | 1.6
  • Silk | 39.50 | 1.5
  • Rubber | 36.50 | 1.4
  • Jute | 23.50 | 0.9
  • Petroleum | 17.45 | 0.7
  • Tin | 14.55 | 0.5
  • Phosphorus chalk | 11.60 | 0.4
  • Lubricating oil | 11.45 | 0.4
  • +---------+---------------
  • | 951.90 | 35.3
  • +---------+---------------
  • II. Food, tobacco, etc.:-- | |
  • Cereals, etc. (wheat, barley, | |
  • bran, rice, maize, oats, rye, | |
  • clover) | 327.55 | 12.2
  • Oil seeds and cake, etc. | |
  • (including palm kernels, copra,| |
  • cocoa, beans) | 102.65 | 3.8
  • Cattle, lamb fat, bladders | 73.10 | 2.8
  • Coffee | 54.75 | 2.0
  • Eggs | 48.50 | 1.8
  • Tobacco | 33.50 | 1.2
  • Butter | 29.65 | 1.1
  • Horses | 29.05 | 1.1
  • Fruit | 18.25 | 0.7
  • Fish | 14.95 | 0.6
  • Poultry | 14.00 | 0.5
  • Wine | 13.35 | 0.5
  • +---------+---------------
  • | 759.30 | 28.3
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • | Amount: | Percentage of
  • German Imports, 1913 | Million | Total Imports
  • | Dollars |
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • III. Manufactures:-- | |
  • Cotton yarn and thread and | |
  • cotton goods | 47.05 | 1.8
  • Woolen yarn and woolen | |
  • goods | 37.85 | 1.4
  • Machinery | 20.10 | 0.7
  • +---------+---------------
  • | 105.00 | 3.9
  • +---------+---------------
  • IV. Unenumerated | 876.40 | 32.5
  • +---------+---------------
  • Total |2,692.60 | 100.0
  • -----------------------------------------+---------+---------------
  • These tables show that the most important exports consisted of:--
  • (1) Iron goods, including tin plates (13.2 per cent),
  • (2) Machinery, etc. (7.5 per cent),
  • (3) Coal, coke, and briquettes (7 per cent),
  • (4) Woolen goods, including raw and combed wool (5.9 per
  • cent), and
  • (5) Cotton goods, including cotton yarn and thread and raw
  • cotton (5.6 per cent),
  • these five classes between them accounting for 39.2 per cent. of the
  • total exports. It will be observed that all these goods are of a kind in
  • which before the war competition between Germany and the United Kingdom
  • was very severe. If, therefore, the volume of such exports to overseas
  • or European destinations is very largely increased the effect upon
  • British export trade must be correspondingly serious. As regards two of
  • the categories, namely, cotton and woolen goods, the increase of an
  • export trade is dependent upon an increase of the import of the raw
  • material, since Germany produces no cotton and practically no wool.
  • These trades are therefore incapable of expansion unless Germany is
  • given facilities for securing these raw materials (which can only be at
  • the expense of the Allies) in excess of the pre-war standard of
  • consumption, and even then the effective increase is not the gross value
  • of the exports, but only the difference between the value of the
  • manufactured exports and of the imported raw material. As regards the
  • other three categories, namely, machinery, iron goods, and coal,
  • Germany's capacity to increase her exports will have been taken from her
  • by the cessions of territory in Poland, Upper Silesia, and
  • Alsace-Lorraine. As has been pointed out already, these districts
  • accounted for nearly one-third of Germany's production of coal. But they
  • also supplied no less than three-quarters of her iron-ore production, 38
  • per cent of her blast furnaces, and 9.5 per cent of her iron and steel
  • foundries. Unless, therefore, Alsace-Lorraine and Upper Silesia send
  • their iron ore to Germany proper, to be worked up, which will involve an
  • increase in the imports for which she will have to find payment, so far
  • from any increase in export trade being possible, a decrease is
  • inevitable.[127]
  • Next on the list come cereals, leather goods, sugar, paper, furs,
  • electrical goods, silk goods, and dyes. Cereals are not a net export and
  • are far more than balanced by imports of the same commodities. As
  • regards sugar, nearly 90 per cent of Germany's pre-war exports came to
  • the United Kingdom.[128] An increase in this trade might be stimulated
  • by a grant of a preference in this country to German sugar or by an
  • arrangement by which sugar was taken in part payment for the indemnity
  • on the same lines as has been proposed for coal, dyes, etc. Paper
  • exports also might be capable of some increase. Leather goods, furs, and
  • silks depend upon corresponding imports on the other side of the
  • account. Silk goods are largely in competition with the trade of France
  • and Italy. The remaining items are individually very small. I have heard
  • it suggested that the indemnity might be paid to a great extent in
  • potash and the like. But potash before the war represented 0.6 per cent
  • of Germany's export trade, and about $15,000,000 in aggregate value.
  • Besides, France, having secured a potash field in the territory which
  • has been restored to her, will not welcome a great stimulation of the
  • German exports of this material.
  • An examination of the import list shows that 63.6 per cent are raw
  • materials and food. The chief items of the former class, namely, cotton,
  • wool, copper, hides, iron-ore, furs, silk, rubber, and tin, could not be
  • much reduced without reacting on the export trade, and might have to be
  • increased if the export trade was to be increased. Imports of food,
  • namely, wheat, barley, coffee, eggs, rice, maize, and the like, present
  • a different problem. It is unlikely that, apart from certain comforts,
  • the consumption of food by the German laboring classes before the war
  • was in excess of what was required for maximum efficiency; indeed, it
  • probably fell short of that amount. Any substantial decrease in the
  • imports of food would therefore react on the efficiency of the
  • industrial population, and consequently on the volume of surplus exports
  • which they could be forced to produce. It is hardly possible to insist
  • on a greatly increased productivity of German industry if the workmen
  • are to be underfed. But this may not be equally true of barley, coffee,
  • eggs, and tobacco. If it were possible to enforce a rĂ©gime in which for
  • the future no German drank beer or coffee, or smoked any tobacco, a
  • substantial saving could be effected. Otherwise there seems little room
  • for any significant reduction.
  • The following analysis of German exports and imports, according to
  • destination and origin, is also relevant. From this it appears that of
  • Germany's exports in 1913, 18 per cent went to the British Empire, 17
  • per cent to France, Italy, and Belgium, 10 per cent to Russia and
  • Roumania, and 7 per cent to the United States; that is to say, more than
  • half of the exports found their market in the countries of the Entente
  • nations. Of the balance, 12 per cent went to Austria-Hungary, Turkey,
  • and Bulgaria, and 35 per cent elsewhere. Unless, therefore, the present
  • Allies are prepared to encourage the importation of German products, a
  • substantial increase in total volume can only be effected by the
  • wholesale swamping of neutral markets.
  • GERMAN TRADE (1913) ACCORDING TO DESTINATION AND ORIGIN.
  • ----------------------+--------------------+--------------------
  • | Destination of | Origin of
  • | Germany's Exports | Germany's Imports
  • ----------------------+--------------------+--------------------
  • | Million Per cent | Million Per cent
  • | Dollars | Dollars
  • Great Britain | 359.55 14.2 | 219.00 8.1
  • India | 37.65 1.5 | 135.20 5.0
  • Egypt | 10.85 0.4 | 29.60 1.1
  • Canada | 15.10 0.6 | 16.00 0.6
  • Australia | 22.10 0.9 | 74.00 2.8
  • South Africa | 11.70 0.5 | 17.40 0.6
  • | ------ ---- | ------ ----
  • Total: British Empire | 456.95 18.1 | 491.20 18.2
  • | |
  • France | 197.45 7.8 | 146.05 5.4
  • Belgium | 137.75 5.5 | 86.15 3.2
  • Italy | 98.35 3.9 | 79.40 3.0
  • U.S.A. | 178.30 7.1 | 427.80 15.9
  • Russia | 220.00 8.7 | 356.15 13.2
  • Roumania | 35.00 1.4 | 19.95 0.7
  • Austria-Hungary | 276.20 10.9 | 206.80 7.7
  • Turkey | 24.60 1.0 | 18.40 0.7
  • Bulgaria | 7.55 0.3 | 2.00 ...
  • Other countries | 890.20 35.3 | 858.70 32.0
  • | ------ ---- | ------ ----
  • | 2,522.35 100.0 | 2,692.60 100.0
  • ----------------------+--------------------+--------------------
  • The above analysis affords some indication of the possible magnitude of
  • the maximum modification of Germany's export balance under the
  • conditions which will prevail after the Peace. On the assumptions (1)
  • that we do not specially favor Germany over ourselves in supplies of
  • such raw materials as cotton and wool (the world's supply of which is
  • limited), (2) that France, having secured the iron-ore deposits, makes a
  • serious attempt to secure the blast-furnaces and the steel trade also,
  • (3) that Germany is not encouraged and assisted to undercut the iron and
  • other trades of the Allies in overseas market, and (4) that a
  • substantial preference is not given to German goods in the British
  • Empire, it is evident by examination of the specific items that not much
  • is practicable.
  • Let us run over the chief items again: (1) Iron goods. In view of
  • Germany's loss of resources, an increased net export seems impossible
  • and a large decrease probable. (2) Machinery. Some increase is possible.
  • (3) Coal and coke. The value of Germany's net export before the war was
  • $110,000,000; the Allies have agreed that for the time being 20,000,000
  • tons is the maximum possible export with a problematic (and in fact)
  • impossible increase to 40,000,000 tons at some future time; even on the
  • basis of 20,000,000 tons we have virtually no increase of value,
  • measured in pre-war prices;[129] whilst, if this amount is exacted,
  • there must be a decrease of far greater value in the export of
  • manufactured articles requiring coal for their production. (4) Woolen
  • goods. An increase is impossible without the raw wool, and, having
  • regard to the other claims on supplies of raw wool, a decrease is
  • likely. (5) Cotton goods. The same considerations apply as to wool. (6)
  • Cereals. There never was and never can be a net export. (7) Leather
  • goods. The same considerations apply as to wool.
  • We have now covered nearly half of Germany's pre-war exports, and there
  • is no other commodity which formerly represented as much as 3 per cent
  • of her exports. In what commodity is she to pay? Dyes?--their total
  • value in 1913 was $50,000,000. Toys? Potash?--1913 exports were worth
  • $15,000,000. And even if the commodities could be specified, in what
  • markets are they to be sold?--remembering that we have in mind goods to
  • the value not of tens of millions annually, but of hundreds of millions.
  • On the side of imports, rather more is possible. By lowering the
  • standard of life, an appreciable reduction of expenditure on imported
  • commodities may be possible. But, as we have already seen, many large
  • items are incapable of reduction without reacting on the volume of
  • exports.
  • Let us put our guess as high as we can without being foolish, and
  • suppose that after a time Germany will be able, in spite of the
  • reduction of her resources, her facilities, her markets, and her
  • productive power, to increase her exports and diminish her imports so as
  • to improve her trade balance altogether by $500,000,000 annually,
  • measured in pre-war prices. This adjustment is first required to
  • liquidate the adverse trade balance, which in the five years before the
  • war averaged $370,000,000; but we will assume that after allowing for
  • this, she is left with a favorable trade balance of $250,000,000 a year.
  • Doubling this to allow for the rise in pre-war prices, we have a figure
  • of $500,000,000. Having regard to the political, social, and human
  • factors, as well as to the purely economic, I doubt if Germany could be
  • made to pay this sum annually over a period of 30 years; but it would
  • not be foolish to assert or to hope that she could.
  • Such a figure, allowing 5 per cent for interest, and 1 per cent for
  • repayment of capital, represents a capital sum having a present value of
  • about $8,500,000,000.[130]
  • I reach, therefore, the final conclusion that, including all methods of
  • payment--immediately transferable wealth, ceded property, and an annual
  • tribute--$10,000,000,000 is a safe maximum figure of Germany's capacity
  • to pay. In all the actual circumstances, I do not believe that she can
  • pay as much. Let those who consider this a very low figure, bear in mind
  • the following remarkable comparison. The wealth of France in 1871 was
  • estimated at a little less than half that of Germany in 1913. Apart from
  • changes in the value of money, an indemnity from Germany of
  • $2,500,000,000 would, therefore, be about comparable to the sum paid by
  • France in 1871; and as the real burden of an indemnity increases more
  • than in proportion to its amount, the payment of $10,000,000,000 by
  • Germany would have far severer consequences than the $1,000,000,000 paid
  • by France in 1871.
  • There is only one head under which I see a possibility of adding to the
  • figure reached on the line of argument adopted above; that is, if German
  • labor is actually transported to the devastated areas and there engaged
  • in the work of reconstruction. I have heard that a limited scheme of
  • this kind is actually in view. The additional contribution thus
  • obtainable depends on the number of laborers which the German Government
  • could contrive to maintain in this way and also on the number which,
  • over a period of years, the Belgian and French inhabitants would
  • tolerate in their midst. In any case, it would seem very difficult to
  • employ on the actual work of reconstruction, even over a number of
  • years, imported labor having a net present value exceeding (say)
  • $1,250,000,000; and even this would not prove in practice a net addition
  • to the annual contributions obtainable in other ways.
  • A capacity of $40,000,000,000 or even of $25,000,000,000 is, therefore,
  • not within the limits of reasonable possibility. It is for those who
  • believe that Germany can make an annual payment amounting to hundreds of
  • millions sterling to say _in what specific commodities_ they intend this
  • payment to be made and _in what markets_ the goods are to be sold. Until
  • they proceed to some degree of detail, and are able to produce some
  • tangible argument in favor of their conclusions, they do not deserve to
  • be believed.[131]
  • I make three provisos only, none of which affect the force of my
  • argument for immediate practical purposes.
  • _First_: if the Allies were to "nurse" the trade and industry of Germany
  • for a period of five or ten years, supplying her with large loans, and
  • with ample shipping, food, and raw materials during that period,
  • building up markets for her, and deliberately applying all their
  • resources and goodwill to making her the greatest industrial nation in
  • Europe, if not in the world, a substantially larger sum could probably
  • be extracted thereafter; for Germany is capable of very great
  • productivity.
  • _Second_: whilst I estimate in terms of money, I assume that there is no
  • revolutionary change in the purchasing power of our unit of value. If
  • the value of gold were to sink to a half or a tenth of its present
  • value, the real burden of a payment fixed in terms of gold would be
  • reduced proportionately. If a sovereign comes to be worth what a
  • shilling is worth now, then, of course, Germany can pay a larger sum
  • than I have named, measured in gold sovereigns.
  • _Third_: I assume that there is no revolutionary change in the yield of
  • Nature and material to man's labor. It is not _impossible_ that the
  • progress of science should bring within our reach methods and devices by
  • which the whole standard of life would be raised immeasurably, and a
  • given volume of products would represent but a portion of the human
  • effort which it represents now. In this case all standards of "capacity"
  • would be changed everywhere. But the fact that all things are _possible_
  • is no excuse for talking foolishly.
  • It is true that in 1870 no man could have predicted Germany's capacity
  • in 1910. We cannot expect to legislate for a generation or more. The
  • secular changes in man's economic condition and the liability of human
  • forecast to error are as likely to lead to mistake in one direction as
  • in another. We cannot as reasonable men do better than base our policy
  • on the evidence we have and adapt it to the five or ten years over which
  • we may suppose ourselves to have some measure of prevision; and we are
  • not at fault if we leave on one side the extreme chances of human
  • existence and of revolutionary changes in the order of Nature or of
  • man's relations to her. The fact that we have no adequate knowledge of
  • Germany's capacity to pay over a long period of years is no
  • justification (as I have heard some people claim that, it is) for the
  • statement that she can pay $50,000,000,000.
  • Why has the world been so credulous of the unveracities of politicians?
  • If an explanation is needed, I attribute this particular credulity to
  • the following influences in part.
  • In the first place, the vast expenditures of the war, the inflation of
  • prices, and the depreciation of currency, leading up to a complete
  • instability of the unit of value, have made us lose all sense of number
  • and magnitude in matters of finance. What we believed to be the limits
  • of possibility have been so enormously exceeded, and those who founded
  • their expectations on the past have been so often wrong, that the man in
  • the street is now prepared to believe anything which is told him with
  • some show of authority, and the larger the figure the more readily he
  • swallows it.
  • But those who look into the matter more deeply are sometimes misled by a
  • fallacy, much more plausible to reasonableness. Such a one might base
  • his conclusions on Germany's total surplus of annual productivity as
  • distinct from her export surplus. Helfferich's estimate of Germany's
  • annual increment of wealth in 1913 was $2,000,000,000 to $2,125,000,000
  • (exclusive of increased money value of existing land and property).
  • Before the war, Germany spent between $250,000,000 and $500,000,000 on
  • armaments, with which she can now dispense. Why, therefore, should she
  • not pay over to the Allies an annual sum of $2,500,000,000? This puts
  • the crude argument in its strongest and most plausible form.
  • But there are two errors in it. First of all, Germany's annual savings,
  • after what she has suffered in the war and by the Peace, will fall far
  • short of what they were before, and, if they are taken from her year by
  • year in future, they cannot again reach their previous level. The loss
  • of Alsace-Lorraine, Poland, and Upper Silesia could not be assessed in
  • terms of surplus productivity at less than $250,000,000 annually.
  • Germany is supposed to have profited about $500,000,000 per annum from
  • her ships, her foreign investments, and her foreign banking and
  • connections, all of which have now been taken from her. Her saving on
  • armaments is far more than balanced by her annual charge for pensions
  • now estimated at $1,250,000,000,[132] which represents a real loss of
  • productive capacity. And even if we put on one side the burden of the
  • internal debt, which amounts to 24 milliards of marks, as being a
  • question of internal distribution rather than of productivity, we must
  • still allow for the foreign debt incurred by Germany during the war, the
  • exhaustion of her stock of raw materials, the depletion of her
  • live-stock, the impaired productivity of her soil from lack of manures
  • and of labor, and the diminution in her wealth from the failure to keep
  • up many repairs and renewals over a period of nearly five years. Germany
  • is not as rich as she was before the war, and the diminution in her
  • future savings for these reasons, quite apart from the factors
  • previously allowed for, could hardly be put at less than ten per cent,
  • that is $200,000,000 annually.
  • These factors have already reduced Germany's annual surplus to less than
  • the $500,000,000 at which we arrived on other grounds as the maximum of
  • her annual payments. But even if the rejoinder be made, that we have not
  • yet allowed for the lowering of the standard of life and comfort in
  • Germany which may reasonably be imposed on a defeated enemy,[133] there
  • is still a fundamental fallacy in the method of calculation. An annual
  • surplus available for home investment can only be converted into a
  • surplus available for export abroad by a radical change in the kind of
  • work performed. Labor, while it may be available and efficient for
  • domestic services in Germany, may yet be able to find no outlet in
  • foreign trade. We are back on the same question which faced us in our
  • examination of the export trade--in _what_ export trade is German labor
  • going to find a greatly increased outlet? Labor can only he diverted
  • into new channels with loss of efficiency, and a large expenditure of
  • capital. The annual surplus which German labor can produce for capital
  • improvements at home is no measure, either theoretically or practically,
  • of the annual tribute which she can pay abroad.
  • IV. _The Reparation Commission_.
  • This body is so remarkable a construction and may, if it functions at
  • all, exert so wide an influence on the life of Europe, that its
  • attributes deserve a separate examination.
  • There are no precedents for the indemnity imposed on Germany under the
  • present Treaty; for the money exactions which formed part of the
  • settlement after previous wars have differed in two fundamental respects
  • from this one. The sum demanded has been determinate and has been
  • measured in a lump sum of money; and so long as the defeated party was
  • meeting the annual instalments of cash no consequential interference was
  • necessary.
  • But for reasons already elucidated, the exactions in this case are not
  • yet determinate, and the sum when fixed will prove in excess of what can
  • be paid in cash and in excess also of what can be paid at all. It was
  • necessary, therefore, to set up a body to establish the bill of claim,
  • to fix the mode of payment, and to approve necessary abatements and
  • delays. It was only possible to place this body in a position to exact
  • the utmost year by year by giving it wide powers over the internal
  • economic life of the enemy countries, who are to be treated henceforward
  • as bankrupt estates to be administered by and for the benefit of the
  • creditors. In fact, however, its powers and functions have been enlarged
  • even beyond what was required for this purpose, and the Reparation
  • Commission has been established as the final arbiter on numerous
  • economic and financial issues which it was convenient to leave unsettled
  • in the Treaty itself.[134]
  • The powers and constitution of the Reparation Commission are mainly laid
  • down in Articles 233-241 and Annex II. of the Reparation Chapter of the
  • Treaty with Germany. But the same Commission is to exercise authority
  • over Austria and Bulgaria, and possibly over Hungary and Turkey, when
  • Peace is made with these countries. There are, therefore, analogous
  • articles _mutatis mudandis_ in the Austrian Treaty[135] and in the
  • Bulgarian Treaty.[136]
  • The principal Allies are each represented by one chief delegate.
  • The delegates of the United States, Great Britain, France, and
  • Italy take part in all proceedings; the delegate of Belgium in all
  • proceedings except those attended by the delegates of Japan or the
  • Serb-Croat-Slovene State; the delegate of Japan in all proceedings
  • affecting maritime or specifically Japanese questions; and the
  • delegate of the Serb-Croat-Slovene State when questions relating to
  • Austria, Hungary, or Bulgaria are under consideration. Other allies
  • are to be represented by delegates, without the power to vote,
  • whenever their respective claims and interests are under examination.
  • In general the Commission decides by a majority vote, except in certain
  • specific cases where unanimity is required, of which the most important
  • are the cancellation of German indebtedness, long postponement of the
  • instalments, and the sale of German bonds of indebtedness. The
  • Commission is endowed with full executive authority to carry out its
  • decisions. It may set up an executive staff and delegate authority to
  • its officers. The Commission and its staff are to enjoy diplomatic
  • privileges, and its salaries are to be paid by Germany, who will,
  • however, have no voice in fixing them, If the Commission is to discharge
  • adequately its numerous functions, it will be necessary for it to
  • establish a vast polyglot bureaucratic organization, with a staff of
  • hundreds. To this organization, the headquarters of which will be in
  • Paris, the economic destiny of Central Europe is to be entrusted.
  • Its main functions are as follows:--
  • 1. The Commission will determine the precise figure of the claim against
  • the enemy Powers by an examination in detail of the claims of each of
  • the Allies under Annex I. of the Reparation Chapter. This task must be
  • completed by May, 1921. It shall give to the German Government and to
  • Germany's allies "a just opportunity to be heard, but not to take any
  • part whatever in the decisions of the Commission." That is to say, the
  • Commission will act as a party and a judge at the same time.
  • 2. Having determined the claim, it will draw up a schedule of payments
  • providing for the discharge of the whole sum with interest within thirty
  • years. From time to time it shall, with a view to modifying the schedule
  • within the limits of possibility, "consider the resources and capacity
  • of Germany ... giving her representatives a just opportunity to be heard."
  • "In periodically estimating Germany's capacity to pay, the Commission
  • shall examine the German system of taxation, first, to the end that the
  • sums for reparation which Germany is required to pay shall become a
  • charge upon all her revenues prior to that for the service or discharge
  • of any domestic loan, and secondly, so as to satisfy itself that, in
  • general, the German scheme of taxation is fully as heavy proportionately
  • as that of any of the Powers represented on the Commission."
  • 3. Up to May, 1921, the Commission has power, with a view to securing
  • the payment of $5,000,000,000, to demand the surrender of any piece of
  • German property whatever, wherever situated: that is to say, "Germany
  • shall pay in such installments and in such manner, whether in gold,
  • commodities, ships, securities, or otherwise, as the Reparation
  • Commission may fix."
  • 4. The Commission will decide which of the rights and interests of
  • German nationals in public utility undertakings operating in Russia,
  • China, Turkey, Austria, Hungary, and Bulgaria, or in any territory
  • formerly belonging to Germany or her allies, are to be expropriated and
  • transferred to the Commission itself; it will assess the value of the
  • interests so transferred; and it will divide the spoils.
  • 5 The Commission will determine how much of the resources thus stripped
  • from Germany must be returned to her to keep enough life in her economic
  • organization to enable her to continue to make Reparation payments in
  • future.[137]
  • 6. The Commission will assess the value, without appeal or arbitration,
  • of the property and rights ceded under the Armistice, and under the
  • Treaty,--roiling-stock, the mercantile marine, river craft, cattle, the
  • Saar mines, the property in ceded territory for which credit is to be
  • given, and so forth.
  • 7. The Commission will determine the amounts and values (within certain
  • defined limits) of the contributions which Germany is to make in kind
  • year by year under the various Annexes to the Reparation Chapter.
  • 8. The Commission will provide for the restitution by Germany of
  • property which can be identified.
  • 9. The Commission will receive, administer, and distribute all receipts
  • from Germany in cash or in kind. It will also issue and market German
  • bonds of indebtedness.
  • 10. The Commission will assign the share of the pre-war public debt to
  • be taken over by the ceded areas of Schleswig, Poland, Danzig, and Upper
  • Silesia. The Commission will also distribute the public debt of the late
  • Austro-Hungarian Empire between its constituent parts.
  • 11. The Commission will liquidate the Austro-Hungarian Bank, and will
  • supervise the withdrawal and replacement of the currency system of the
  • late Austro-Hungarian Empire.
  • 12. It is for the Commission to report if, in their judgment, Germany is
  • falling short in fulfillment of her obligations, and to advise methods
  • of coercion.
  • 13. In general, the Commission, acting through a subordinate body, will
  • perform the same functions for Austria and Bulgaria as for Germany, and
  • also, presumably, for Hungary and Turkey.[138]
  • There are also many other relatively minor duties assigned to the
  • Commission. The above summary, however, shows sufficiently the scope and
  • significance of its authority. This authority is rendered of far greater
  • significance by the fact that the demands of the Treaty generally exceed
  • Germany's capacity. Consequently the clauses which allow the Commission
  • to make abatements, if in their judgment the economic conditions of
  • Germany require it, will render it in many different particulars the
  • arbiter of Germany's economic life. The Commission is not only to
  • inquire into Germany's general capacity to pay, and to decide (in the
  • early years) what import of foodstuffs and raw materials is necessary;
  • it is authorized to exert pressure on the German system of taxation
  • (Annex II. para. 12(_b_))[139] and on German internal expenditure, with
  • a view to insuring that Reparation payments are a first charge on the
  • country's entire resources; and it is to decide on the effect on German
  • economic life of demands for machinery, cattle, etc., and of the
  • scheduled deliveries of coal.
  • By Article 240 of the Treaty Germany expressly recognizes the Commission
  • and its powers "as the same may be constituted by the Allied and
  • Associated Governments," and "agrees irrevocably to the possession and
  • exercise by such Commission of the power and authority given to it under
  • the present Treaty." She undertakes to furnish the Commission with all
  • relevant information. And finally in Article 241, "Germany undertakes to
  • pass, issue, and maintain in force any legislation, orders, and decrees
  • that may be necessary to give complete effect to these provisions."
  • The comments on this of the German Financial Commission at Versailles
  • were hardly an exaggeration:--"German democracy is thus annihilated at
  • the very moment when the German people was about to build it up after a
  • severe struggle--annihilated by the very persons who throughout the war
  • never tired of maintaining that they sought to bring democracy to us....
  • Germany is no longer a people and a State, but becomes a mere trade
  • concern placed by its creditors in the hands of a receiver, without its
  • being granted so much as the opportunity to prove its willingness to
  • meet its obligations of its own accord. The Commission, which is to have
  • its permanent headquarters outside Germany, will possess in Germany
  • incomparably greater rights than the German Emperor ever possessed, the
  • German people under its rĂ©gime would remain for decades to come shorn
  • of all rights, and deprived, to a far greater extent than any people in
  • the days of absolutism, of any independence of action, of any individual
  • aspiration in its economic or even in its ethical progress."
  • In their reply to these observations the Allies refused to admit that
  • there was any substance, ground, or force in them. "The observations of
  • the German Delegation," they pronounced, "present a view of this
  • Commission so distorted and so inexact that it is difficult to believe
  • that the clauses of the Treaty have been calmly or carefully examined.
  • It is not an engine of oppression or a device for interfering with
  • German sovereignty. It has no forces at its command; it has no executive
  • powers within the territory of Germany; it cannot, as is suggested,
  • direct or control the educational or other systems of the country. Its
  • business is to ask what is to be paid; to satisfy itself that Germany
  • can pay; and to report to the Powers, whose delegation it is, in case
  • Germany makes default. If Germany raises the money required in her own
  • way, the Commission cannot order that it shall be raised in some other
  • way; if Germany offers payment in kind, the Commission may accept such
  • payment, but, except as specified in the Treaty itself, the Commission
  • cannot require such a payment."
  • This is not a candid statement of the scope and authority of the
  • Reparation Commission, as will be seen by a comparison of its terms with
  • the summary given above or with the Treaty itself. Is not, for example,
  • the statement that the Commission "has no forces at its command" a
  • little difficult to justify in view of Article 430 of the Treaty, which
  • runs:--"In case, either during the occupation or after the expiration of
  • the fifteen years referred to above, the Reparation Commission finds
  • that Germany refuses to observe the whole or part of her obligations
  • under the present Treaty with regard to Reparation, the whole or part of
  • the areas specified in Article 429 will be reoccupied immediately by the
  • Allied and Associated Powers"? The decision, as to whether Germany has
  • kept her engagements and whether it is possible for her to keep them, is
  • left, it should be observed, not to the League of Nations, but to the
  • Reparation Commission itself; and an adverse ruling on the part of the
  • Commission is to be followed "immediately" by the use of armed force.
  • Moreover, the depreciation of the powers of the Commission attempted in
  • the Allied reply largely proceeds from the assumption that it is quite
  • open to Germany to "raise the money required in her own way," in which
  • case it is true that many of the powers of the Reparation Commission
  • would not come into practical effect; whereas in truth one of the main
  • reasons for setting up the Commission at all is the expectation that
  • Germany will not be able to carry the burden nominally laid upon her.
  • * * * * *
  • It is reported that the people of Vienna, hearing that a section of the
  • Reparation Commission is about to visit them, have decided
  • characteristically to pin their hopes on it. A financial body can
  • obviously take nothing from them, for they have nothing; therefore this
  • body must be for the purpose of assisting and relieving them. Thus do
  • the Viennese argue, still light-headed in adversity. But perhaps they
  • are right. The Reparation Commission will come into very close contact
  • with the problems of Europe; and it will bear a responsibility
  • proportionate to its powers. It may thus come to fulfil a very different
  • rĂ´le from that which some of its authors intended for it. Transferred to
  • the League of Nations, an appanage of justice and no longer of interest,
  • who knows that by a change of heart and object the Reparation Commission
  • may not yet be transformed from an instrument of oppression and rapine
  • into an economic council of Europe, whose object is the restoration of
  • life and of happiness, even in the enemy countries?
  • _V_. _The German Counter-Proposals_
  • The German counter-proposals were somewhat obscure, and also rather
  • disingenuous. It will be remembered that those clauses of the Reparation
  • Chapter which dealt with the issue of bonds by Germany produced on the
  • public mind the impression that the Indemnity had been fixed at
  • $25,000,000,000, or at any rate at this figure as a minimum. The German
  • Delegation set out, therefore, to construct their reply on the basis of
  • this figure, assuming apparently that public opinion in Allied countries
  • would not be satisfied with less than the appearance of $25,000,000,000;
  • and, as they were not really prepared to offer so large a figure, they
  • exercised their ingenuity to produce a formula which might be
  • represented to Allied opinion as yielding this amount, whilst really
  • representing a much more modest sum. The formula produced was
  • transparent to any one who read it carefully and knew the facts, and it
  • could hardly have been expected by its authors to deceive the Allied
  • negotiators. The German tactic assumed, therefore, that the latter were
  • secretly as anxious as the Germans themselves to arrive at a settlement
  • which bore some relation to the facts, and that they would therefore be
  • willing, in view of the entanglements which they had got themselves into
  • with their own publics, to practise a little collusion in drafting the
  • Treaty,--a supposition which in slightly different circumstances might
  • have had a good deal of foundation. As matters actually were, this
  • subtlety did not benefit them, and they would have done much better with
  • a straightforward and candid estimate of what they believed to be the
  • amount of their liabilities on the one hand, and their capacity to pay
  • on the other.
  • The German offer of an alleged sum of $25,000,000,000 amounted to the
  • following. In the first place it was conditional on concessions in the
  • Treaty insuring that "Germany shall retain the territorial integrity
  • corresponding to the Armistice Convention,[140] that she shall keep her
  • colonial possessions and merchant ships, including those of large
  • tonnage, that in her own country and in the world at large she shall
  • enjoy the same freedom of action as all other peoples, that all war
  • legislation shall be at once annulled, and that all interferences during
  • the war with her economic rights and with German private property, etc.,
  • shall be treated in accordance with the principle of reciprocity";--that
  • is to say, the offer is conditional on the greater part of the rest of
  • the Treaty being abandoned. In the second place, the claims are not to
  • exceed a maximum of $25,000,000,000, of which $5,000,000,000 is to be
  • discharged by May 1, 1926; and no part of this sum is to carry interest
  • pending the payment of it.[141] In the third place, there are to be
  • allowed as credit against it (amongst other things): (_a_) the value of
  • all deliveries under the Armistice, including military material (_e.g._
  • Germany's navy); (_b_) the value of all railways and State property in
  • ceded territory; (_c_) the _pro rata_ share of all ceded territory in
  • the German public debt (including the war debt) and in the Reparation
  • payments which this territory would have had to bear if it had remained
  • part of Germany; and (_d_) the value of the cession of Germany's claims
  • for sums lent by her to her allies in the war.[142]
  • The credits to be deducted under (_a_), (_b_), (_c_), and (_d_) might be
  • in excess of those allowed in the actual Treaty, according to a rough
  • estimate, by a sum of as much as $10,000,000,000, although the sum to be
  • allowed under (_d_) can hardly be calculated.
  • If, therefore, we are to estimate the real value of the German offer of
  • $25,000,000,000 on the basis laid down by the Treaty, we must first of
  • all deduct $10,000,000,000 claimed for offsets which the Treaty does not
  • allow, and then halve the remainder in order to obtain the present value
  • of a deferred payment on which interest is not chargeable. This reduces
  • the offer to $7,500,000,000, as compared with the $40,000,000,000 which,
  • according to my rough estimate, the Treaty demands of her.
  • This in itself was a very substantial offer--indeed it evoked widespread
  • criticism in Germany--though, in view of the fact that it was
  • conditional on the abandonment of the greater part of the rest of the
  • Treaty, it could hardly be regarded as a serious one.[143] But the
  • German Delegation would have done better if they had stated in less
  • equivocal language how far they felt able to go.
  • In the final reply of the Allies to this counter-proposal there is one
  • important provision, which I have not attended to hitherto, but which
  • can be conveniently dealt with in this place. Broadly speaking, no
  • concessions were entertained on the Reparation Chapter as it was
  • originally drafted, but the Allies recognized the inconvenience of the
  • _indeterminacy_ of the burden laid upon Germany and proposed a method by
  • which the final total of claim might be established at an earlier date
  • than May 1, 1921. They promised, therefore, that at any time within four
  • months of the signature of the Treaty (that is to say, up to the end of
  • October, 1919), Germany should be at liberty to submit an offer of a
  • lump sum in settlement of her whole liability as defined in the Treaty,
  • and within two months thereafter (that is to say, before the end of
  • 1919) the Allies "will, so far as may be possible, return their answers
  • to any proposals that may be made."
  • This offer is subject to three conditions. "Firstly, the German
  • authorities will be expected, before making such proposals, to confer
  • with the representatives of the Powers directly concerned. Secondly,
  • such offers must be unambiguous and must be precise and clear. Thirdly,
  • they must accept the categories and the Reparation clauses as matters
  • settled beyond discussion."
  • The offer, as made, does not appear to contemplate any opening up of the
  • problem of Germany's capacity to pay. It is only concerned with the
  • establishment of the total bill of claims as defined in the
  • Treaty--whether (_e.g._) it is $35,000,000,000, $40,000,000,000, or
  • $50,000,000,000. "The questions," the Allies' reply adds, "are bare
  • questions of fact, namely, the amount of the liabilities, and they are
  • susceptible of being treated in this way."
  • If the promised negotiations are really conducted on these lines, they
  • are not likely to be fruitful. It will not be much easier to arrive at
  • an agreed figure before the end of 1919 that it was at the time of the
  • Conference; and it will not help Germany's financial position to know
  • for certain that she is liable for the huge sum which on any computation
  • the Treaty liabilities must amount to. These negotiations do offer,
  • however, an opportunity of reopening the whole question of the
  • Reparation payments, although it is hardly to be hoped that at so very
  • early a date, public opinion in the countries of the Allies has changed
  • its mood sufficiently.[144]
  • * * * * *
  • I cannot leave this subject as though its just treatment wholly depended
  • either on our own pledges or on economic facts. The policy of reducing
  • Germany to servitude for a generation, of degrading the lives of
  • millions of human beings, and of depriving a whole nation of happiness
  • should be abhorrent and detestable,--abhorrent and detestable, even if
  • it were possible, even if it enriched ourselves, even if it did not sow
  • the decay of the whole civilized life of Europe. Some preach it in the
  • name of Justice. In the great events of man's history, in the unwinding
  • of the complex fates of nations Justice is not so simple. And if it
  • were, nations are not authorized, by religion or by natural morals, to
  • visit on the children of their enemies the misdoings of parents or of
  • rulers.
  • FOOTNOTES:
  • [76] "With reservation that any future claims and demands of
  • the Allies and the United States of America remain unaffected, the
  • following financial conditions are required: Reparation for damage done.
  • Whilst Armistice lasts, no public securities shall be removed by the
  • enemy which can serve as a pledge to the Allies for recovery or
  • reparation of war losses. Immediate restitution of cash deposit in
  • National Bank of Belgium, and, in general, immediate return of all
  • documents, of specie, stock, shares, paper money, together with plant
  • for issue thereof, touching public or private interests in invaded
  • countries. Restitution of Russian and Roumanian gold yielded to Germany
  • or taken by that Power. This gold to be delivered in trust to the Allies
  • until signature of peace."
  • [77] It is to be noticed, in passing, that they contain nothing
  • which limits the damage to damage inflicted contrary to the recognized
  • rules of warfare. That is to say, it is permissible to include claims
  • arising out of the legitimate capture of a merchantman at sea, as well
  • as the costs of illegal submarine warfare.
  • [78] Mark-paper or mark-credits owned in ex-occupied territory
  • by Allied nationals should be included, if at all, in the settlement of
  • enemy debts, along with other sums owed to Allied nationals, and not in
  • connection with reparation.
  • [79] A special claim on behalf of Belgium was actually included
  • In the Peace Treaty, and was accepted by the German representatives
  • without demur.
  • [80] To the British observer, one scene, however, stood out
  • distinguished from the rest--the field of Ypres. In that desolate and
  • ghostly spot, the natural color and humors of the landscape and the
  • climate seemed designed to express to the traveler the memories of the
  • ground. A visitor to the salient early in November, 1918, when a few
  • German bodies still added a touch of realism and human horror, and the
  • great struggle was not yet certainly ended, could feel there, as nowhere
  • else, the present outrage of war, and at the same time the tragic and
  • sentimental purification which to the future will in some degree
  • transform its harshness.
  • [81] These notes, estimated to amount to no less than six
  • thousand million marks, are now a source of embarrassment and great
  • potential loss to the Belgian Government, inasmuch as on their recovery
  • of the country they took them over from their nationals in exchange for
  • Belgian notes at the rate of Fr. 120 = Mk. 1. This rate of exchange, being
  • substantially in excess of the value of the mark-notes at the rate of
  • exchange current at the time (and enormously in excess of the rate to
  • which the mark notes have since fallen, the Belgian franc being now
  • worth more than three marks), was the occasion of the smuggling of
  • mark-notes into Belgium on an enormous scale, to take advantage of the
  • profit obtainable. The Belgian Government took this very imprudent step,
  • partly because they hoped to persuade the Peace Conference to make the
  • redemption of these bank-notes, at the par of exchange, a first charge
  • on German assets. The Peace Conference held, however, that Reparation
  • proper must take precedence of the adjustment of improvident banking
  • transactions effected at an excessive rate of exchange. The possession
  • by the Belgian Government of this great mass of German currency, in
  • addition to an amount of nearly two thousand million marks held by the
  • French Government which they similarly exchanged for the benefit of the
  • population of the invaded areas and of Alsace-Lorraine, is a serious
  • aggravation of the exchange position of the mark. It will certainly be
  • desirable for the Belgian and German Governments to come to some
  • arrangement as to its disposal, though this is rendered difficult by the
  • prior lien held by the Reparation Commission over all German assets
  • available for such purposes.
  • [82] It should be added, in fairness, that the very high claims
  • put forward on behalf of Belgium generally include not only devastation
  • proper, but all kinds of other items, as, for example, the profits and
  • earnings which Belgians might reasonably have expected to earn if there
  • had been no war.
  • [83] "The Wealth and Income of the Chief Powers," by J.C. Stamp
  • (_Journal of the Royal Statistical Society_, July, 1919).
  • [84] Other estimates vary from $12,100,000,000 to
  • $13,400,000,000. See Stamp, _loc. cit._
  • [85] This was clearly and courageously pointed out by M.
  • Charles Gide in _L'Emancipation_ for February, 1919.
  • [86] For details of these and other figures, see Stamp, _loc.
  • cit._
  • [87] Even when the extent of the material damage has been
  • established, it will be exceedingly difficult to put a price on it,
  • which must largely depend on the period over which restoration is
  • spread, and the methods adopted. It would be impossible to make the
  • damage good in a year or two at any price, and an attempt to do so at a
  • rate which was excessive in relation to the amount of labor and
  • materials at hand might force prices up to almost any level. We must, I
  • think, assume a cost of labor and materials about equal to that current
  • in the world generally. In point of fact, however, we may safely assume
  • that literal restoration will never be attempted. Indeed, it would be
  • very wasteful to do so. Many of the townships were old and unhealthy,
  • and many of the hamlets miserable. To re-erect the same type of building
  • in the same places would be foolish. As for the land, the wise course
  • may be in some cases to leave long strips of it to Nature for many years
  • to come. An aggregate money sum should be computed as fairly
  • representing the value of the material damage, and France should be left
  • to expend it in the manner she thinks wisest with a view to her economic
  • enrichment as a whole. The first breeze of this controversy has already
  • blown through France. A long and inconclusive debate occupied the
  • Chamber during the spring of 1919, as to whether inhabitants of the
  • devastated area receiving compensation should be compelled to expend it
  • in restoring the identical property, or whether they should be free to
  • use it as they like. There was evidently a great deal to be said on both
  • sides; in the former case there would be much hardship and uncertainty
  • for owners who could not, many of them, expect to recover the effective
  • use of their property perhaps for years to come, and yet would not be
  • free to set themselves up elsewhere; on the other hand, if such persons
  • were allowed to take their compensation and go elsewhere, the
  • countryside of Northern France would never be put right. Nevertheless I
  • believe that the wise course will be to allow great latitude and let
  • economic motives take their own course.
  • [88] _La Richesse de la France devant la Guerre_, published in
  • 1916.
  • [89] _Revue Bleue_, February 3, 1919. This is quoted in a very
  • valuable selection of French estimates and expressions of opinion,
  • forming chapter iv. of _La Liquidation financière de la Guerre_, by H.
  • Charriaut and R. Hacault. The general magnitude of my estimate is
  • further confirmed by the extent of the repairs already effected, as set
  • forth in a speech delivered by M. Tardieu on October 10, 1919, in which
  • he said: "On September 16 last, of 2246 kilomètres of railway track
  • destroyed, 2016 had been repaired; of 1075 kilomètres of canal, 700; of
  • 1160 constructions, such as bridges and tunnels, which had been blown
  • up, 588 had been replaced; of 550,000 houses ruined by bombardment,
  • 60,000 had been rebuilt; and of 1,800,000 hectares of ground rendered
  • useless by battle, 400,000 had been recultivated, 200,000 hectares of
  • which are now ready to be sown. Finally, more than 10,000,000 mètres of
  • barbed wire had been removed."
  • [90] Some of these estimates include allowance for contingent
  • and immaterial damage as well as for direct material injury.
  • [91] A substantial part of this was lost in the service of the
  • Allies; this must not be duplicated by inclusion both in their claims
  • and in ours.
  • [92] The fact that no separate allowance is made in the above
  • for the sinking of 675 fishing vessels of 71,765 tons gross, or for the
  • 1855 vessels of 8,007,967 tons damaged or molested, but not sunk, may be
  • set off against what may be an excessive figure for replacement cost.
  • [93] The losses of the Greek mercantile marine were excessively
  • high, as a result of the dangers of the Mediterranean; but they were
  • largely incurred on the service of the other Allies, who paid for them
  • directly or indirectly. The claims of Greece for maritime losses
  • incurred on the service of her own nationals would not be very
  • considerable.
  • [94] There is a reservation in the Peace Treaty on this
  • question. "The Allied and Associated Powers formally reserve the right
  • of Russia to obtain from Germany restitution and reparation based on the
  • principles of the present Treaty" (Art. 116).
  • [95] Dr. Diouritch in his "Economic and Statistical Survey of
  • the Southern Slav Nations" (_Journal of Royal Statistical Society_, May,
  • 1919), quotes some extraordinary figures of the loss of life: "According
  • to the official returns, the number of those fallen in battle or died in
  • captivity up to the last Serbian offensive, amounted to 320,000, which
  • means that one half of Serbia's male population, from 18 to 60 years of
  • age, perished outright in the European War. In addition, the Serbian
  • Medical Authorities estimate that about 300,000 people have died from
  • typhus among the civil population, and the losses among the population
  • interned in enemy camps are estimated at 50,000. During the two Serbian
  • retreats and during the Albanian retreat the losses among children and
  • young people are estimated at 200,000. Lastly, during over three years
  • of enemy occupation, the losses in lives owing to the lack of proper
  • food and medical attention are estimated at 250,000." Altogether, he
  • puts the losses in life at above 1,000,000, or more than one-third of
  • the population of Old Serbia.
  • [96] _Come si calcola e a quanto ammonta la richezza d'Italia e
  • delle altre principali nazioni_, published in 1919.
  • [97] Very large claims put forward by the Serbian authorities
  • include many hypothetical items of indirect and non-material damage; but
  • these, however real, are not admissible under our present formula.
  • [98] Assuming that in her case $1,250,000,000 are included for
  • the general expenses of the war defrayed out of loans made to Belgium by
  • her allies.
  • [99] It must be said to Mr. Hughes' honor that he apprehended
  • from the first the bearing of the pre-Armistice negotiations on our
  • right to demand an indemnity covering the full costs of the war,
  • protested against our ever having entered into such engagements, and
  • maintained loudly that he had been no party to them and could not
  • consider himself bound by them. His indignation may have been partly due
  • to the fact that Australia, not having been ravaged, would have no
  • claims at all under the more limited interpretation of our rights.
  • [100] The whole cost of the war has been estimated at from
  • $120,000,000,000 upwards. This would mean an annual payment for interest
  • (apart from sinking fund) of $6,000,000,000. Could any expert Committee
  • have reported that Germany can pay this sum?
  • [101] But unhappily they did not go down with their flags
  • flying very gloriously. For one reason or another their leaders
  • maintained substantial silence. What a different position in the
  • country's estimation they might hold now if they had suffered defeat
  • amidst firm protests against the fraud, chicane, and dishonor of the
  • whole proceedings.
  • [102] Only after the most painful consideration have I written
  • these words. The almost complete absence of protest from the leading
  • Statesmen of England makes one feel that one must have made some
  • mistake. But I believe that I know all the facts, and I can discover no
  • such mistake. In any case I have set forth all the relevant engagements
  • in Chapter IV. and at the beginning of this chapter, so that the reader
  • can form his own judgment.
  • [103] In conversation with Frenchmen who were private persons
  • and quite unaffected by political considerations, this aspect became
  • very clear. You might persuade them that some current estimates as to
  • the amount to be got out of Germany were quite fantastic. Yet at the end
  • they would always come back to where they had started: "But Germany
  • _must_ pay; for, otherwise, what is to happen to France?"
  • [104] A further paragraph claims the war costs of Belgium "in
  • accordance with Germany's pledges, already given, as to complete
  • restoration for Belgium."
  • [105] The challenge of the other Allies, as well as the enemy,
  • had to be met; for in view of the limited resources of the latter, the
  • other Allies had perhaps a greater interest than the enemy in seeing
  • that no one of their number established an excessive claim.
  • [106] M. Klotz has estimated the French claims on this head at
  • $15,000,000,000 (75 milliard francs, made up of 13 milliard for
  • allowances, 60 for pensions, and 2 for widows). If this figure is
  • correct, the others should probably be scaled up also.
  • [107] That is to say, I claim for the aggregate figure an
  • accuracy within 25 per cent.
  • [108] In his speech of September 5, 1919, addressed to the
  • French Chamber, M. Klotz estimated the total Allied claims against
  • Germany under the Treaty at $75,000,000,000, which would accumulate at
  • interest until 1921, and be paid off thereafter by 34 annual
  • installments of about $5,000,000,000 each, of which France would receive
  • about $2,750,000,000 annually. "The general effect of the statement
  • (that France would receive from Germany this annual payment) proved," it
  • is reported, "appreciably encouraging to the country as a whole, and was
  • immediately reflected in the improved tone on the Bourse and throughout
  • the business world in France." So long as such statements can be
  • accepted in Paris without protest, there can be no financial or economic
  • future for France, and a catastrophe of disillusion is not far distant.
  • [109] As a matter of subjective judgment, I estimate for this
  • figure an accuracy of 10 per cent in deficiency and 20 per cent in
  • excess, _i.e._ that the result will lie between $32,000,000,000 and
  • $44,000,000,000.
  • [110] Germany is also liable under the Treaty, as an addition
  • to her liabilities for Reparation, to pay all the costs of the Armies of
  • Occupation _after_ Peace is signed for the fifteen subsequent years of
  • occupation. So far as the text of the Treaty goes, there is nothing to
  • limit the size of these armies, and France could, therefore, by
  • quartering the whole of her normal standing army in the occupied area,
  • shift the charge from her own taxpayers to those of Germany,--though in
  • reality any such policy would be at the expense not of Germany, who by
  • hypothesis is already paying for Reparation up to the full limit of her
  • capacity, but of France's Allies, who would receive so much less in
  • respect of Reparation. A White Paper (Cmd. 240) has, however, been
  • issued, in which is published a declaration by the Governments of the
  • United States, Great Britain, and France engaging themselves to limit
  • the sum payable annually by Germany to cover the cost of occupation to
  • $60,000,000 "as soon as the Allied and Associated Powers _concerned_ are
  • convinced that the conditions of disarmament by Germany are being
  • satisfactorily fulfilled." The word which I have italicized is a little
  • significant. The three Powers reserve to themselves the liberty to
  • modify this arrangement at any time if they agree that it is necessary.
  • [111] Art. 235. The force of this Article is somewhat
  • strengthened by Article 251, by virtue of which dispensations may also
  • be granted for "other payments" as well as for food and raw material.
  • [112] This is the effect of Para. 12 (_c_) of Annex II. of the
  • Reparation Chapter, leaving minor complications on one side. The Treaty
  • fixes the payments in terms of _gold marks_, which are converted in the
  • above rate of 20 to $5.
  • [113] If, _per impossibile_, Germany discharged $2,500,000,000
  • in cash or kind by 1921, her annual payments would be at the rate of
  • $312,500,000 from 1921 to 1925 and of $750,000,000 thereafter.
  • [114] Para. 16 of Annex II. of The Reparation Chapter. There is
  • also an obscure provision by which interest may be charged "on sums
  • arising out of _material damage_ as from November 11, 1918, up to May 1,
  • 1921." This seems to differentiate damage to property from damage to the
  • person in favor of the former. It does not affect Pensions and
  • Allowances, the cost of which is capitalized as at the date of the
  • coming into force of the Treaty.
  • [115] On the assumption which no one supports and even the most
  • optimistic fear to be unplausible, that Germany can pay the full charge
  • for interest and sinking fund _from the outset_, the annual payment
  • would amount to $2,400,000,000.
  • [116] Under Para. 13 of Annex II. unanimity is required (i.)
  • for any postponement beyond 1930 of installments due between 1921 and
  • 1926, and (ii.) for any postponement for more than three years of
  • instalments due after 1926. Further, under Art. 234, the Commission may
  • not cancel any part of the indebtedness without the specific authority
  • of _all_ the Governments represented on the Commission.
  • [117] On July 23, 1914, the amount was $339,000,000.
  • [118] Owing to the very high premium which exists on German
  • silver coin, as the combined result of the depreciation of the mark and
  • the appreciation of silver, it is highly improbable that it will be
  • possible to extract such coin out of the pockets of the people. But it
  • may gradually leak over the frontier by the agency of private
  • speculators, and thus indirectly benefit the German exchange position as
  • a whole.
  • [119] The Allies made the supply of foodstuffs to Germany
  • during the Armistice, mentioned above, conditional on the provisional
  • transfer to them of the greater part of the Mercantile Marine, to be
  • operated by them for the purpose of shipping foodstuffs to Europe
  • generally, and to Germany in particular. The reluctance of the Germans
  • to agree to this was productive of long and dangerous delays in the
  • supply of food, but the abortive Conferences of Trèves and Spa (January
  • 16, February 14-16, and March 4-5, 1919) were at last followed by the
  • Agreement of Brussels (March 14, 1919). The unwillingness of the Germans
  • to conclude was mainly due to the lack of any absolute guarantee on the
  • part of the Allies that, if they surrendered the ships, they would get
  • the food. But assuming reasonable good faith on the part of the latter
  • (their behavior in respect of certain other clauses of the Armistice,
  • however, had not been impeccable and gave the enemy some just grounds
  • for suspicion), their demand was not an improper one; for without the
  • German ships the business of transporting the food would have been
  • difficult, if not impossible, and the German ships surrendered or their
  • equivalent were in fact almost wholly employed in transporting food to
  • Germany itself. Up to June 30, 1919, 176 German ships of 1,025,388 gross
  • tonnage had been surrendered, to the Allies in accordance with the
  • Brussels Agreement.
  • [120] The amount of tonnage transferred may be rather greater
  • and the value per ton rather less. The aggregate value involved is not
  • likely, however, to be less than $500,000,000 or greater than
  • $750,000,000.
  • [121] This census was carried out by virtue of a Decree of
  • August 23, 1918. On March 22, 1917, the German Government acquired
  • complete control over the utilization of foreign securities in German
  • possession; and in May, 1917, it began to exercise these powers for the
  • mobilization of certain Swedish, Danish, and Swiss securities.
  • [122] 1892. Schmoller $2,500,000,000
  • 1892. Christians 3,250,000,000
  • 1893-4. Koch 3,000,000,000
  • 1905. v. Halle 4,000,000,000[A]
  • 1913. Helfferich 5,000,000,000[B]
  • 1914. Ballod 6,250,000,000
  • 1914. Pistorius 6,250,000,000
  • 1919. Hans David 5,250,000,000[C]
  • [A] Plus $2,500,000 for investments other than securities.
  • [B] Net investments, _i.e._ after allowance for property in
  • Germany owned abroad. This may also be the case with some of the other
  • estimates.
  • [C] This estimate, given in the _Weltwirtschaftszeitung_ (June
  • 13, 1919), is an estimate of the value of Germany's foreign investments
  • as at the outbreak of war.
  • [123] I have made no deduction for securities in the ownership
  • of Alsace-Lorrainers and others who have now ceased to be German
  • nationals.
  • [124] In all these estimates, I am conscious of being driven by
  • a fear of overstating the case against the Treaty, of giving figures in
  • excess of my own real judgment. There is a great difference between
  • putting down on paper fancy estimates of Germany's resources and
  • actually extracting contributions in the form of cash. I do not myself
  • believe that the Reparation Commission will secure real resources from
  • the above items by May, 1921, even as great as the _lower_ of the two
  • figures given above.
  • [125] The Treaty (see Art. 114) leaves it very dubious how far
  • the Danish Government is under an obligation to make payments to the
  • Reparation Commission in respect of its acquisition of Schleswig. They
  • might, for instance, arrange for various offsets such as the value of
  • the mark notes held by the inhabitants of ceded areas. In any case the
  • amount of money involved is quite small. The Danish Government is
  • raising a loan for $33,000,000 (kr. 120,000,000) for the joint purposes
  • of "taking over Schleswig's share of the German debt, for buying German
  • public property, for helping the Schleswig population, and for settling
  • the currency question."
  • [126] Here again my own judgment would carry me much further
  • and I should doubt the possibility of Germany's exports equaling her
  • imports during this period. But the statement in the text goes far
  • enough for the purpose of my argument.
  • [127] It has been estimated that the cession of territory to
  • France, apart from the loss of Upper Silesia, may reduce Germany's
  • annual pre-war production of steel ingots from 20,000,000 tons to
  • 14,000,000 tons, and increase France's capacity from 5,000,000 tons to
  • 11,000,000 tons.
  • [128] Germany's exports of sugar in 1913 amounted to 1,110,073
  • tons of the value of $65,471,500, of which 838,583 tons were exported to
  • the United Kingdom at a value of $45,254,000. These figures were in
  • excess of the normal, the average total exports for the five years
  • ending 1913 being about $50,000,000.
  • [129] The necessary price adjustment, which is required, on
  • both sides of this account, will be made _en bloc_ later.
  • [130] If the amount of the sinking fund be reduced, and the
  • annual payment is continued over a greater number of years, the present
  • value--so powerful is the operation of compound interest--cannot be
  • materially increased. A payment of $500,000,000 annually _in
  • perpetuity_, assuming interest, as before, at 5 per cent, would only
  • raise the present value to $10,000,000,000.
  • [131] As an example of public misapprehension on economic
  • affairs, the following letter from Sir Sidney Low to _The Times_ of the
  • 3rd December, 1918, deserves quotation: "I have seen authoritative
  • estimates which place the gross value of Germany's mineral and chemical
  • resources as high as $1,250,000,000,000 or even more; and the Ruhr basin
  • mines alone are said to be worth over $225,000,000,000. It is certain,
  • at any rate, that the capital value of these natural supplies is much
  • greater than the total war debts of all the Allied States. Why should
  • not some portion of this wealth be diverted for a sufficient period from
  • its present owners and assigned to the peoples whom Germany has
  • assailed, deported, and injured? The Allied Governments might justly
  • require Germany to surrender to them the use of such of her mines, and
  • mineral deposits as would yield, say, from $500,000,000 to
  • $1,000,000,000 annually for the next 30, 40, or 50 years. By this means
  • we could obtain sufficient compensation from Germany without unduly
  • stimulating her manufactures and export trade to our detriment." It is
  • not clear why, if Germany has wealth exceeding $1,250,000,000,000. Sir
  • Sidney Low is content with the trifling sum of $500,000,000 to
  • $1,000,000,000 annually. But his letter is an admirable _reductio ad
  • absurdum_ of a certain line of thought. While a mode of calculation,
  • which estimates the value of coal miles deep in the bowels of the earth
  • as high as in a coal scuttle, of an annual lease of $5000 for 999 years
  • at $4,995,000 and of a field (presumably) at the value of all the crops
  • it will grow to the end of recorded time, opens up great possibilities,
  • it is also double-edged. If Germany's total resources are worth
  • $1,250,000,000,000, those she will part with in the cession of
  • Alsace-Lorraine and Upper Silesia should be more than sufficient to pay
  • the entire costs of the war and reparation together. In point of fact,
  • the _present_ market value of all the mines in Germany of every kind has
  • been estimated at $1,500,000,000, or a little more than one-thousandth
  • part of Sir Sidney Low's expectations.
  • [132] The conversion at par of 5,000 million marks overstates,
  • by reason of the existing depreciation of the mark, the present money
  • burden of the actual pensions payments, but not, in all probability, the
  • real loss of national productivity as a result of the casualties
  • suffered in the war.
  • [133] It cannot be overlooked, in passing, that in its results
  • on a country's surplus productivity a lowering of the standard of life
  • acts both ways. Moreover, we are without experience of the psychology of
  • a white race under conditions little short of servitude. It is, however,
  • generally supposed that if the whole of a man's surplus production is
  • taken from him, his efficiency and his industry are diminished, The
  • entrepreneur and the inventor will not contrive, the trader and the
  • shopkeeper will not save, the laborer will not toil, if the fruits of
  • their industry are set aside, not for the benefit of their children,
  • their old age, their pride, or their position, but for the enjoyment of
  • a foreign conqueror.
  • [134] In the course of the compromises and delays of the
  • Conference, there were many questions on which, in order to reach any
  • conclusion at all, it was necessary to leave a margin of vagueness and
  • uncertainty. The whole method of the Conference tended towards
  • this,--the Council of Four wanted, not so much a settlement, as a
  • treaty. On political and territorial questions the tendency was to leave
  • the final arbitrament to the League of Nations. But on financial and
  • economic questions, the final decision has generally be a left with the
  • Reparation Commission,--in spite of its being an executive body composed
  • of interested parties.
  • [135] The sum to be paid by Austria for Reparation is left to
  • the absolute discretion of the Reparation Commission, no determinate
  • figure of any kind being mentioned in the text of the Treaty Austrian
  • questions are to be handled by a special section of the Reparation
  • Commission, but the section will have no powers except such as the main
  • Commission may delegate.
  • [136] Bulgaria is to pay an indemnity of $450,000,000 by
  • half-yearly instalments, beginning July 1, 1920. These sums will be
  • collected, on behalf of the Reparation Commission, by an Inter-Ally
  • Commission of Control, with its seat at Sofia. In some respects the
  • Bulgarian Inter-Ally Commission appears to have powers and authority
  • independent of the Reparation Commission, but it is to act,
  • nevertheless, as the agent of the latter, and is authorized to tender
  • advice to the Reparation Commission as to, for example, the reduction of
  • the half-yearly instalments.
  • [137] Under the Treaty this is the function of any body
  • appointed for the purpose by the principal Allied and Associated
  • Governments, and not necessarily of the Reparation Commission. But it
  • may be presumed that no second body will be established for this special
  • purpose.
  • [138] At the date of writing no treaties with these countries
  • have been drafted. It is possible that Turkey might be dealt with by a
  • separate Commission.
  • [139] This appears to me to be in effect the position (if this
  • paragraph means anything at all), in spite of the following disclaimer
  • of such intentions in the Allies' reply:--"Nor does Paragraph 12(b) of
  • Annex II. give the Commission powers to prescribe or enforce taxes or to
  • dictate the character of the German budget."
  • [140] Whatever that may mean.
  • [141] Assuming that the capital sum is discharged evenly over a
  • period as short as thirty-three years, this has the effect of _halving_
  • the burden as compared with the payments required on the basis of 5 per
  • cent interest on the outstanding capital.
  • [142] I forbear to outline the further details of the German
  • offer as the above are the essential points.
  • [143] For this reason it is not strictly comparable with my
  • estimate of Germany's capacity in an earlier section of this chapter,
  • which estimate is on the basis of Germany's condition as it will be when
  • the rest of the Treaty has come into effect.
  • [144] Owing to delays on the part of the Allies in ratifying
  • the Treaty, the Reparation Commission had not yet been formally
  • constituted by the end of October, 1919. So far as I am aware,
  • therefore, nothing has been done to make the above offer effective. But,
  • perhaps in view of the circumstances, there has been an extension of the
  • date.
  • CHAPTER VI
  • EUROPE AFTER THE TREATY
  • This chapter must be one of pessimism. The Treaty includes no provisions
  • for the economic rehabilitation of Europe,--nothing to make the defeated
  • Central Empires into good neighbors, nothing to stabilize the new States
  • of Europe, nothing to reclaim Russia; nor does it promote in any way a
  • compact of economic solidarity amongst the Allies themselves; no
  • arrangement was reached at Paris for restoring the disordered finances
  • of France and Italy, or to adjust the systems of the Old World and the
  • New.
  • The Council of Four paid no attention to these issues, being preoccupied
  • with others,--Clemenceau to crush the economic life of his enemy, Lloyd
  • George to do a deal and bring home something which would pass muster for
  • a week, the President to do nothing that was not just and right. It is
  • an extraordinary fact that the fundamental economic problems of a Europe
  • starving and disintegrating before their eyes, was the one question in
  • which it was impossible to arouse the interest of the Four. Reparation
  • was their main excursion into the economic field, and they settled it
  • as a problem of theology, of polities, of electoral chicane, from every
  • point of view except that of the economic future of the States whose
  • destiny they were handling.
  • I leave, from this point onwards, Paris, the Conference, and the Treaty,
  • briefly to consider the present situation of Europe, as the War and the
  • Peace have made it; and it will no longer be part of my purpose to
  • distinguish between the inevitable fruits of the War and the avoidable
  • misfortunes of the Peace.
  • The essential facts of the situation, as I see them, are expressed
  • simply. Europe consists of the densest aggregation of population in the
  • history of the world. This population is accustomed to a relatively high
  • standard of life, in which, even now, some sections of it anticipate
  • improvement rather than deterioration. In relation to other continents
  • Europe is not self-sufficient; in particular it cannot feed Itself.
  • Internally the population is not evenly distributed, but much of it is
  • crowded into a relatively small number of dense industrial centers. This
  • population secured for itself a livelihood before the war, without much
  • margin of surplus, by means of a delicate and immensely complicated
  • organization, of which the foundations were supported by coal, iron,
  • transport, and an unbroken supply of imported food and raw materials
  • from other continents. By the destruction of this organization and the
  • interruption of the stream of supplies, a part of this population is
  • deprived of its means of livelihood. Emigration is not open to the
  • redundant surplus. For it would take years to transport them overseas,
  • even, which is not the case, if countries could be found which were
  • ready to receive them. The danger confronting us, therefore, is the
  • rapid depression of the standard of life of the European populations to
  • a point which will mean actual starvation for some (a point already
  • reached in Russia and approximately reached in Austria). Men will not
  • always die quietly. For starvation, which brings to some lethargy and a
  • helpless despair, drives other temperaments to the nervous instability
  • of hysteria and to a mad despair. And these in their distress may
  • overturn the remnants of organization, and submerge civilization itself
  • in their attempts to satisfy desperately the overwhelming needs of the
  • individual. This is the danger against which all our resources and
  • courage and idealism must now co-operate.
  • On the 13th May, 1919, Count Brockdorff-Rantzau addressed to the Peace
  • Conference of the Allied and Associated Powers the Report of the German
  • Economic Commission charged with the study of the effect of the
  • conditions of Peace on the situation of the German population. "In the
  • course of the last two generations," they reported, "Germany has become
  • transformed from an agricultural State to an industrial State. So long
  • as she was an agricultural State, Germany could feed forty million
  • inhabitants. As an industrial State she could insure the means of
  • subsistence for a population of sixty-seven millions; and in 1913 the
  • importation of foodstuffs amounted, in round figures, to twelve million
  • tons. Before the war a total of fifteen million persons in Germany
  • provided for their existence by foreign trade, navigation, and the use,
  • directly or indirectly, of foreign raw material." After rehearsing the
  • main relevant provisions of the Peace Treaty the report continues:
  • "After this diminution of her products, after the economic depression
  • resulting from the loss of her colonies, her merchant fleet and her
  • foreign investments, Germany will not be in a position to import from
  • abroad an adequate quantity of raw material. An enormous part of German
  • industry will, therefore, be condemned inevitably to destruction. The
  • need of importing foodstuffs will increase considerably at the same time
  • that the possibility of satisfying this demand is as greatly diminished.
  • In a very short time, therefore, Germany will not be in a position to
  • give bread and work to her numerous millions of inhabitants, who are
  • prevented from earning their livelihood by navigation and trade. These
  • persons should emigrate, but this is a material impossibility, all the
  • more because many countries and the most important ones will oppose any
  • German immigration. To put the Peace conditions into execution would
  • logically involve, therefore, the loss of several millions of persons in
  • Germany. This catastrophe would not be long in coming about, seeing that
  • the health of the population has been broken down during the War by the
  • Blockade, and during the Armistice by the aggravation of the Blockade of
  • famine. No help, however great, or over however long a period it were
  • continued, could prevent those deaths _en masse_." "We do not know, and
  • indeed we doubt," the report concludes, "whether the Delegates of the
  • Allied and Associated Powers realize the inevitable consequences which
  • will take place if Germany, an industrial State, very thickly populated,
  • closely bound up with the economic system of the world, and under the
  • necessity of importing enormous quantities of raw material and
  • foodstuffs, suddenly finds herself pushed back to the phase of her
  • development, which corresponds to her economic condition and the numbers
  • of her population as they were half a century ago. Those who sign this
  • Treaty will sign the death sentence of many millions of German men,
  • women and children."
  • I know of no adequate answer to these words. The indictment is at least
  • as true of the Austrian, as of the German, settlement. This is the
  • fundamental problem in front of us, before which questions of
  • territorial adjustment and the balance of European power are
  • insignificant. Some of the catastrophes of past history, which have
  • thrown back human progress for centuries, have been due to the reactions
  • following on the sudden termination, whether in the course of nature or
  • by the act of man, of temporarily favorable conditions which have
  • permitted the growth of population beyond what could be provided for
  • when the favorable conditions were at an end.
  • The significant features of the immediate situation can be grouped under
  • three heads: first, the absolute falling off, for the time being, in
  • Europe's internal productivity; second, the breakdown of transport and
  • exchange by means of which its products could be conveyed where they
  • were most wanted; and third, the inability of Europe to purchase its
  • usual supplies from overseas.
  • The decrease of productivity cannot be easily estimated, and may be the
  • subject of exaggeration. But the _primĂ¢ facie_ evidence of it is
  • overwhelming, and this factor has been the main burden of Mr. Hoover's
  • well-considered warnings. A variety of causes have produced it;--violent
  • and prolonged internal disorder as in Russia and Hungary; the creation
  • of new governments and their inexperience in the readjustment of
  • economic relations, as in Poland and Czecho-Slovakia; the loss
  • throughout the Continent of efficient labor, through the casualties of
  • war or the continuance of mobilization; the falling-off in efficiency
  • through continued underfeeding in the Central Empires; the exhaustion of
  • the soil from lack of the usual applications of artificial manures
  • throughout the course of the war; the unsettlement of the minds of the
  • laboring classes on the above all (to quote Mr. Hoover), "there is a
  • great fundamental economic issues of their lives. But relaxation of
  • effort as the reflex of physical exhaustion of large sections of the
  • population from privation and the mental and physical strain of the
  • war." Many persons are for one reason or another out of employment
  • altogether. According to Mr. Hoover, a summary of the unemployment
  • bureaus in Europe in July, 1919, showed that 15,000,000 families were
  • receiving unemployment allowances in one form or another, and were being
  • paid in the main by a constant inflation of currency. In Germany there
  • is the added deterrent to labor and to capital (in so far as the
  • Reparation terms are taken literally), that anything, which they may
  • produce beyond the barest level of subsistence, will for years to come
  • be taken away from them.
  • Such definite data as we possess do not add much, perhaps, to the
  • general picture of decay. But I will remind the reader of one or two of
  • them. The coal production of Europe as a whole is estimated to have
  • fallen off by 30 per cent; and upon coal the greater part of the
  • industries of Europe and the whole of her transport system depend.
  • Whereas before the war Germany produced 85 per cent of the total food
  • consumed by her inhabitants, the productivity of the soil is now
  • diminished by 40 per cent and the effective quality of the live-stock by
  • 55 per cent.[145] Of the European countries which formerly possessed a
  • large exportable surplus, Russia, as much by reason of deficient
  • transport as of diminished output, may herself starve. Hungary, apart
  • from her other troubles, has been pillaged by the Romanians immediately
  • after harvest. Austria will have consumed the whole of her own harvest
  • for 1919 before the end of the calendar year. The figures are almost too
  • overwhelming to carry conviction to our minds; if they were not quite so
  • bad, our effective belief in them might be stronger.
  • But even when coal can be got and grain harvested, the breakdown of the
  • European railway system prevents their carriage; and even when goods can
  • be manufactured, the breakdown of the European currency system prevents
  • their sale. I have already described the losses, by war and under the
  • Armistice surrenders, to the transport system of Germany. But even so,
  • Germany's position, taking account of her power of replacement by
  • manufacture, is probably not so serious as that of some of her
  • neighbors. In Russia (about which, however, we have very little exact or
  • accurate information) the condition of the rolling-stock is believed to
  • be altogether desperate, and one of the most fundamental factors in her
  • existing economic disorder. And in Poland, Roumania, and Hungary the
  • position is not much better. Yet modern industrial life essentially
  • depends on efficient transport facilities, and the population which
  • secured its livelihood by these means cannot continue to live without
  • them. The breakdown of currency, and the distrust in its purchasing
  • value, is an aggravation of these evils which must be discussed in a
  • little more detail in connection with foreign trade.
  • What then is our picture of Europe? A country population able to support
  • life on the fruits of its own agricultural production but without the
  • accustomed surplus for the towns, and also (as a result of the lack of
  • imported materials and so of variety and amount in the saleable
  • manufactures of the towns) without the usual incentives to market food
  • in return for other wares; an industrial population unable to keep its
  • strength for lack of food, unable to earn a livelihood for lack of
  • materials, and so unable to make good by imports from abroad the failure
  • of productivity at home. Yet, according to Mr. Hoover, "a rough estimate
  • would indicate that the population of Europe is at least 100,000,000
  • greater than can be supported without imports, and must live by the
  • production and distribution of exports."
  • The problem of the re-inauguration of the perpetual circle of production
  • and exchange in foreign trade leads me to a necessary digression on the
  • currency situation of Europe.
  • Lenin is said to have declared that the best way to destroy the
  • Capitalist System was to debauch the currency. By a continuing process
  • of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an
  • important part of the wealth of their citizens. By this method they not
  • only confiscate, but they confiscate _arbitrarily_; and, while the
  • process impoverishes many, it actually enriches some. The sight of this
  • arbitrary rearrangement of riches strikes not only at security, but at
  • confidence in the equity of the existing distribution of wealth. Those
  • to whom the system brings windfalls, beyond their deserts and even
  • beyond their expectations or desires, become "profiteers,", who are the
  • object of the hatred of the bourgeoisie, whom the inflationism has
  • impoverished, not less than of the proletariat. As the inflation
  • proceeds and the real value of the currency fluctuates wildly from
  • month to month, all permanent relations between debtors and creditors,
  • which form the ultimate foundation of capitalism, become so utterly
  • disordered as to be almost meaningless; and the process of
  • wealth-getting degenerates into a gamble and a lottery.
  • Lenin was certainly right. There is no subtler, no surer means of
  • overturning the existing basis of society than to debauch the currency.
  • The process engages all the hidden forces of economic law on the side of
  • destruction, and does it in a manner which not one man in a million is
  • able to diagnose.
  • In the latter stages of the war all the belligerent governments
  • practised, from necessity or incompetence, what a Bolshevist might have
  • done from design. Even now, when the war is over, most of them continue
  • out of weakness the same malpractices. But further, the Governments of
  • Europe, being many of them at this moment reckless in their methods as
  • well as weak, seek to direct on to a class known as "profiteers" the
  • popular indignation against the more obvious consequences of their
  • vicious methods. These "profiteers" are, broadly speaking, the
  • entrepreneur class of capitalists, that is to say, the active and
  • constructive element in the whole capitalist society, who in a period of
  • rapidly rising prices cannot help but get rich quick whether they wish
  • it or desire it or not. If prices are continually rising, every trader
  • who has purchased for stock or owns property and plant inevitably makes
  • profits. By directing hatred against this class, therefore, the European
  • Governments are carrying a step further the fatal process which the
  • subtle mind of Lenin had consciously conceived. The profiteers are a
  • consequence and not a cause of rising prices. By combining a popular
  • hatred of the class of entrepreneurs with the blow already given to
  • social security by the violent and arbitrary disturbance of contract and
  • of the established equilibrium of wealth which is the inevitable result
  • of inflation, these Governments are fast rendering impossible a
  • continuance of the social and economic order of the nineteenth century.
  • But they have no plan for replacing it.
  • We are thus faced in Europe with the spectacle of an extraordinary
  • weakness on the part of the great capitalist class, which has emerged
  • from the industrial triumphs of the nineteenth century, and seemed a
  • very few years ago our all-powerful master. The terror and personal
  • timidity of the individuals of this class is now so great, their
  • confidence in their place in society and in their necessity to the
  • social organism so diminished, that they are the easy victims of
  • intimidation. This was not so in England twenty-five years ago, any
  • more than it is now in the United States. Then the capitalists believed
  • in themselves, in their value to society, in the propriety of their
  • continued existence in the full enjoyment of their riches and the
  • unlimited exercise of their power. Now they tremble before every
  • insult;--call them pro-Germans, international financiers, or profiteers,
  • and they will give you any ransom you choose to ask not to speak of them
  • so harshly. They allow themselves to be ruined and altogether undone by
  • their own instruments, governments of their own making, and a press of
  • which they are the proprietors. Perhaps it is historically true that no
  • order of society ever perishes save by its own hand. In the complexer
  • world of Western Europe the Immanent Will may achieve its ends more
  • subtly and bring in the revolution no less inevitably through a Klotz or
  • a George than by the intellectualisms, too ruthless and self-conscious
  • for us, of the bloodthirsty philosophers of Russia.
  • The inflationism of the currency systems of Europe has proceeded to
  • extraordinary lengths. The various belligerent Governments, unable, or
  • too timid or too short-sighted to secure from loans or taxes the
  • resources they required, have printed notes for the balance. In Russia
  • and Austria-Hungary this process has reached a point where for the
  • purposes of foreign trade the currency is practically valueless. The
  • Polish mark can be bought for about three cents and the Austrian crown
  • for less than two cents, but they cannot be sold at all. The German mark
  • is worth less than four cents on the exchanges. In most of the other
  • countries of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe the real position is
  • nearly as bad. The currency of Italy has fallen to little more than a
  • half of its nominal value in spite of its being still subject to some
  • degree of regulation; French currency maintains an uncertain market; and
  • even sterling is seriously diminished in present value and impaired in
  • its future prospects.
  • But while these currencies enjoy a precarious value abroad, they have
  • never entirely lost, not even in Russia, their purchasing power at home.
  • A sentiment of trust in the legal money of the State is so deeply
  • implanted in the citizens of all countries that they cannot but believe
  • that some day this money must recover a part at least of its former
  • value. To their minds it appears that value is inherent in money as
  • such, and they do not apprehend that the real wealth, which this money
  • might have stood for, has been dissipated once and for all. This
  • sentiment is supported by the various legal regulations with which the
  • Governments endeavor to control internal prices, and so to preserve some
  • purchasing power for their legal tender. Thus the force of law
  • preserves a measure of immediate purchasing power over some commodities
  • and the force of sentiment and custom maintains, especially amongst
  • peasants, a willingness to hoard paper which is really worthless.
  • The presumption of a spurious value for the currency, by the force of
  • law expressed in the regulation of prices, contains in itself, however,
  • the seeds of final economic decay, and soon dries up the sources of
  • ultimate supply. If a man is compelled to exchange the fruits of his
  • labors for paper which, as experience soon teaches him, he cannot use to
  • purchase what he requires at a price comparable to that which he has
  • received for his own products, he will keep his produce for himself,
  • dispose of it to his friends and neighbors as a favor, or relax his
  • efforts in producing it. A system of compelling the exchange of
  • commodities at what is not their real relative value not only relaxes
  • production, but leads finally to the waste and inefficiency of barter.
  • If, however, a government refrains from regulation and allows matters to
  • take their course, essential commodities soon attain a level of price
  • out of the reach of all but the rich, the worthlessness of the money
  • becomes apparent, and the fraud upon the public can be concealed no
  • longer.
  • The effect on foreign trade of price-regulation and profiteer-hunting
  • as cures for inflation is even worse. Whatever may be the case at home,
  • the currency must soon reach its real level abroad, with the result that
  • prices inside and outside the country lose their normal adjustment. The
  • price of imported commodities, when converted at the current rate of
  • exchange, is far in excess of the local price, so that many essential
  • goods will not be imported at all by private agency, and must be
  • provided by the government, which, in re-selling the goods below cost
  • price, plunges thereby a little further into insolvency. The bread
  • subsidies, now almost universal throughout Europe, are the leading
  • example of this phenomenon.
  • The countries of Europe fall into two distinct groups at the present
  • time as regards their manifestations of what is really the same evil
  • throughout, according as they have been cut off from international
  • intercourse by the Blockade, or have had their imports paid for out of
  • the resources of their allies. I take Germany as typical of the first,
  • and France and Italy of the second.
  • The note circulation of Germany is about ten times[146] what it was
  • before the war. The value of the mark in terms of gold is about
  • one-eighth of its former value. As world-prices in terms of gold are
  • more than double what they were, it follows that mark-prices inside
  • Germany ought to be from sixteen to twenty times their pre-war level if
  • they are to be in adjustment and proper conformity with prices outside
  • Germany.[147] But this is not the case. In spite of a very great rise in
  • German prices, they probably do not yet average much more than five
  • times their former level, so far as staple commodities are concerned;
  • and it is impossible that they should rise further except with a
  • simultaneous and not less violent adjustment of the level of money
  • wages. The existing maladjustment hinders in two ways (apart from other
  • obstacles) that revival of the import trade which is the essential
  • preliminary of the economic reconstruction of the country. In the first
  • place, imported commodities are beyond the purchasing power of the great
  • mass of the population,[148] and the flood of imports which might have
  • been expected to succeed the raising of the blockade was not in fact
  • commercially possible.[149] In the second place, it is a hazardous
  • enterprise for a merchant or a manufacturer to purchase with a foreign
  • credit material for which, when he has imported it or manufactured it,
  • he will receive mark currency of a quite uncertain and possibly
  • unrealizable value. This latter obstacle to the revival of trade is one
  • which easily escapes notice and deserves a little attention. It is
  • impossible at the present time to say what the mark will be worth in
  • terms of foreign currency three or six months or a year hence, and the
  • exchange market can quote no reliable figure. It may be the case,
  • therefore, that a German merchant, careful of his future credit and
  • reputation, who is actually offered a short period credit in terms of
  • sterling or dollars, may be reluctant and doubtful whether to accept it.
  • He will owe sterling or dollars, but he will sell his product for marks,
  • and his power, when the time comes, to turn these marks into the
  • currency in which he has to repay his debt is entirely problematic.
  • Business loses its genuine character and becomes no better than a
  • speculation in the exchanges, the fluctuations in which entirely
  • obliterate the normal profits of commerce.
  • There are therefore three separate obstacles to the revival of trade: a
  • maladjustment between internal prices and international prices, a lack
  • of individual credit abroad wherewith to buy the raw materials needed to
  • secure the working capital and to re-start the circle of exchange, and a
  • disordered currency system which renders credit operations hazardous or
  • impossible quite apart from the ordinary risks of commerce.
  • The note circulation of France is more than six times its pre-war level.
  • The exchange value of the franc in terms of gold is a little less than
  • two-thirds its former value; that is to say, the value of the franc has
  • not fallen in proportion to the increased volume of the currency.[150]
  • This apparently superior situation of France is due to the fact that
  • until recently a very great part of her imports have not been paid for,
  • but have been covered by loans from the Governments of Great Britain and
  • the United States. This has allowed a want of equilibrium between
  • exports and imports to be established, which is becoming a very serious
  • factor, now that the outside assistance is being gradually discontinued.
  • The internal economy of France and its price level in relation to the
  • note circulation and the foreign exchanges is at present based on an
  • excess of imports over exports which cannot possibly continue. Yet it is
  • difficult to see how the position can be readjusted except by a lowering
  • of the standard of consumption in France, which, even if it is only
  • temporary, will provoke a great deal of discontent.[151]
  • The situation of Italy is not very different. There the note circulation
  • is five or six times its pre-war level, and the exchange value of the
  • lira in terms of gold about half its former value. Thus the adjustment
  • of the exchange to the volume of the note circulation has proceeded
  • further in Italy than in France. On the other hand, Italy's "invisible"
  • receipts, from emigrant remittances and the expenditure of tourists,
  • have been very injuriously affected; the disruption of Austria has
  • deprived her of an important market; and her peculiar dependence on
  • foreign shipping and on imported raw materials of every kind has laid
  • her open to special injury from the increase of world prices. For all
  • these reasons her position is grave, and her excess of imports as
  • serious a symptom as in the case of France.[152]
  • The existing inflation and the maladjustment of international trade are
  • aggravated, both in France and in Italy, by the unfortunate budgetary
  • position of the Governments of these countries.
  • In France the failure to impose taxation is notorious. Before the war
  • the aggregate French and British budgets, and also the average taxation
  • per head, were about equal; but in France no substantial effort has been
  • made to cover the increased expenditure. "Taxes increased in Great
  • Britain during the war," it has been estimated, "from 95 francs per head
  • to 265 francs, whereas the increase in France was only from 90 to 103
  • francs." The taxation voted in France for the financial year ending June
  • 30, 1919, was less than half the estimated normal _post-bellum_
  • expenditure. The normal budget for the future cannot be put below
  • $4,400,000,000 (22 milliard francs), and may exceed this figure; but
  • even for the fiscal year 1919-20 the estimated receipts from taxation
  • do not cover much more than half this amount. The French Ministry of
  • Finance have no plan or policy whatever for meeting this prodigious
  • deficit, except the expectation of receipts from Germany on a scale
  • which the French officials themselves know to be baseless. In the
  • meantime they are helped by sales of war material and surplus American
  • stocks and do not scruple, even in the latter half of 1919, to meet the
  • deficit by the yet further expansion of the note issue of the Bank of
  • France.[153]
  • The budgetary position of Italy is perhaps a little superior to that of
  • France. Italian finance throughout the war was more enterprising than
  • the French, and far greater efforts were made to impose taxation and pay
  • for the war. Nevertheless Signor Nitti, the Prime Minister, in a letter
  • addressed to the electorate on the eve of the General Election (Oct.,
  • 1919), thought it necessary to make public the following desperate
  • analysis of the situation:--(1) The State expenditure amounts to about
  • three times the revenue. (2) All the industrial undertakings of the
  • State, including the railways, telegraphs, and telephones, are being run
  • at a loss. Although the public is buying bread at a high price, that
  • price represents a loss to the Government of about a milliard a year.
  • (3) Exports now leaving the country are valued at only one-quarter or
  • one-fifth of the imports from abroad. (4) The National Debt is
  • increasing by about a milliard lire per month. (5) The military
  • expenditure for one month is still larger than that for the first year
  • of the war.
  • But if this is the budgetary position of France and Italy, that of the
  • rest of belligerent Europe is yet more desperate. In Germany the total
  • expenditure of the Empire, the Federal States, and the Communes in
  • 1919-20 is estimated at 25 milliards of marks, of which not above 10
  • milliards are covered by previously existing taxation. This is without
  • allowing anything for the payment of the indemnity. In Russia, Poland,
  • Hungary, or Austria such a thing as a budget cannot be seriously
  • considered to exist at all.[154]
  • Thus the menace of inflationism described above is not merely a product
  • of the war, of which peace begins the cure. It is a continuing
  • phenomenon of which the end is not yet in sight.
  • All these influences combine not merely to prevent Europe from
  • supplying immediately a sufficient stream of exports to pay for the
  • goods she needs to import, but they impair her credit for securing the
  • working capital required to re-start the circle of exchange and also, by
  • swinging the forces of economic law yet further from equilibrium rather
  • than towards it, they favor a continuance of the present conditions
  • instead of a recovery from them. An inefficient, unemployed,
  • disorganized Europe faces us, torn by internal strife and international
  • hate, fighting, starving, pillaging, and lying. What warrant is there
  • for a picture of less somber colors?
  • I have paid little heed in this book to Russia, Hungary, or
  • Austria.[155] There the miseries of life and the disintegration of
  • society are too notorious to require analysis; and these countries are
  • already experiencing the actuality of what for the rest of Europe is
  • still in the realm of prediction. Yet they comprehend a vast territory
  • and a great population, and are an extant example of how much man can
  • suffer and how far society can decay. Above all, they are the signal to
  • us of how in the final catastrophe the malady of the body passes over
  • into malady of the mind. Economic privation proceeds by easy stages, and
  • so long as men suffer it patiently the outside world cares little.
  • Physical efficiency and resistance to disease slowly diminish,[156] but
  • life proceeds somehow, until the limit of human endurance is reached at
  • last and counsels of despair and madness stir the sufferers from the
  • lethargy which precedes the crisis. Then man shakes himself, and the
  • bonds of custom are loosed. The power of ideas is sovereign, and he
  • listens to whatever instruction of hope, illusion, or revenge is carried
  • to him on the air. As I write, the flames of Russian Bolshevism seem,
  • for the moment at least, to have burnt themselves out, and the peoples
  • of Central and Eastern Europe are held in a dreadful torpor. The lately
  • gathered harvest keeps off the worst privations, and Peace has been
  • declared at Paris. But winter approaches. Men will have nothing to look
  • forward to or to nourish hopes on. There will be little fuel to moderate
  • the rigors of the season or to comfort the starved bodies of the
  • town-dwellers.
  • But who can say how much is endurable, or in what direction men will
  • seek at last to escape from their misfortunes?
  • FOOTNOTES:
  • [145] Professor Starling's _Report on Food Conditions in
  • Germany_. (Cmd. 280.)
  • [146] Including the _Darlehenskassenscheine_ somewhat more.
  • [147] Similarly in Austria prices ought to be between twenty
  • and thirty times their former level.
  • [148] One of the moat striking and symptomatic difficulties
  • which faced the Allied authorities in their administration of the
  • occupied areas of Germany during the Armistice arose out of the fact
  • that even when they brought food into the country the inhabitants could
  • not afford to pay its cost price.
  • [149] Theoretically an unduly low level of home prices should
  • stimulate exports and so cure itself. But in Germany, and still more in
  • Poland and Austria, there is little or nothing to export. There must be
  • imports _before_ there can be exports.
  • [150] Allowing for the diminished value of gold, the exchange
  • value of the franc should be less than 40 per cent of its previous
  • value, instead of the actual figure of about 60 per cent, if the fall
  • were proportional to the increase in the volume of the currency.
  • [151] How very far from equilibrium France's international
  • exchange now is can be seen from the following table:
  • Excess of
  • Monthly Imports Exports Imports
  • Average $1,000 $1,000 $1,000
  • 1913 140,355 114,670 25,685
  • 1914 106,705 81,145 25,560
  • 1918 331,915 69,055 262,860
  • Jan.-Mar. 1919 387,140 66,670 320,470
  • Apr.-June 1919 421,410 83,895 337,515
  • July 1919 467,565 123,675 343,890
  • These figures have been converted, at approximately par rates, but this
  • is roughly compensated by the fact that the trade of 1918 and 1919 has
  • been valued at 1917 official rates. French imports cannot possibly
  • continue at anything approaching these figures, and the semblance of
  • prosperity based on such a state of affairs is spurious.
  • [152] The figures for Italy are as follows:
  • Excess of
  • Monthly Imports Exports Imports
  • Average $1,000 $1,000 $1,000
  • 1913 60,760 41,860 18,900
  • 1914 48,720 36,840 11,880
  • 1918 235,025 41,390 193,635
  • Jan.-Mar. 1919 229,240 38,685 191,155
  • Apr.-June 1919 331,035 69,250 261,785
  • July-Aug. 1919 223,535 84,515 139,020
  • [153] In the last two returns of the Bank of France available
  • as I write (Oct. 2 and 9, 1919) the increases in the note issue on the
  • week amounted to $93,750,000 and $94,125,000 respectively.
  • [154] On October 3, 1919, M. Bilinski made his financial
  • statement to the Polish Diet. He estimated his expenditure for the next
  • nine months at rather more than double his expenditure for the past nine
  • months, and while during the first period his revenue had amounted to
  • one-fifth of his expenditure, for the coming months he was budgeting for
  • receipts equal to one-eighth of his outgoings. The _Times_ correspondent
  • at Warsaw reported that "in general M. Bilinski's tone was optimistic
  • and appeared to satisfy his audience."
  • [155] The terms of the Peace Treaty imposed on the Austrian
  • Republic bear no relation to the real facts of that State's desperate
  • situation. The _Arbeiter Zeitung_ of Vienna on June 4, 1919, commented
  • on them as follows: "Never has the substance of a treaty of peace so
  • grossly betrayed the intentions which were said to have guided its
  • construction as is the case with this Treaty ... in which every provision
  • is permeated with ruthlessness and pitilessness, in which no breath of
  • human sympathy can be detected, which flies in the face of everything
  • which binds man to man, which is a crime against humanity itself,
  • against a suffering and tortured people." I am acquainted in detail with
  • the Austrian Treaty and I was present when some of its terms were being
  • drafted, but I do not find it easy to rebut the justice of this
  • outburst.
  • [156] For months past the reports of the health conditions in
  • the Central Empires have been of such a character that the imagination
  • is dulled, and one almost seems guilty of sentimentality in quoting
  • them. But their general veracity is not disputed, and I quote the three
  • following, that the reader may not be unmindful of them: "In the last
  • years of the war, in Austria alone at least 35,000 people died of
  • tuberculosis, in Vienna alone 12,000. Today we have to reckon with a
  • number of at least 350,000 to 400,000 people who require treatment for
  • tuberculosis.... As the result of malnutrition a bloodless generation is
  • growing up with undeveloped muscles, undeveloped joints, and undeveloped
  • brain" (_Neue Freie Presse_, May 31, 1919). The Commission of Doctors
  • appointed by the Medical Faculties of Holland, Sweden, and Norway to
  • examine the conditions in Germany reported as follows in the Swedish
  • Press in April, 1919: "Tuberculosis, especially in children, is
  • increasing in an appalling way, and, generally speaking, is malignant.
  • In the same way rickets is more serious and more widely prevalent. It is
  • impossible to do anything for these diseases; there is no milk for the
  • tuberculous, and no cod-liver oil for those suffering from rickets....
  • Tuberculosis is assuming almost unprecedented aspects, such as have
  • hitherto only been known in exceptional cases. The whole body is
  • attacked simultaneously, and the illness in this form is practically
  • incurable.... Tuberculosis is nearly always fatal now among adults. It
  • is the cause of 90 per cent of the hospital cases. Nothing can be done
  • against it owing to lack of food-stuffs.... It appears in the most
  • terrible forms, such as glandular tuberculosis, which turns into
  • purulent dissolution." The following is by a writer in the _Vossische
  • Zeitung_, June 5, 1919, who accompanied the Hoover Mission to the
  • Erzgebirge: "I visited large country districts where 90 per cent of all
  • the children were ricketty and where children of three years are only
  • beginning to walk.... Accompany me to a school in the Erzgebirge. You
  • think it is a kindergarten for the little ones. No, these are children
  • of seven and eight years. Tiny faces, with large dull eyes, overshadowed
  • by huge puffed, ricketty foreheads, their small arms just skin and bone,
  • and above the crooked legs with their dislocated joints the swollen,
  • pointed stomachs of the hunger oedema.... 'You see this child here,' the
  • physician in charge explained; 'it consumed an incredible amount of
  • bread, and yet did not get any stronger. I found out that it hid all the
  • bread it received underneath its straw mattress. The fear of hunger was
  • so deeply rooted in the child that it collected stores instead of eating
  • the food: a misguided animal instinct made the dread of hunger worse
  • than the actual pangs.'" Yet there are many persons apparently in whose
  • opinion justice requires that such beings should pay tribute until they
  • are forty or fifty years of age in relief of the British taxpayer.
  • CHAPTER VII
  • REMEDIES
  • It is difficult to maintain true perspective in large affairs. I have
  • criticized the work of Paris, and have depicted in somber colors the
  • condition and the prospects of Europe. This is one aspect of the
  • position and, I believe, a true one. But in so complex a phenomenon the
  • prognostics do not all point one way; and we may make the error of
  • expecting consequences to follow too swiftly and too inevitably from
  • what perhaps are not _all_ the relevant causes. The blackness of the
  • prospect itself leads us to doubt its accuracy; our imagination is
  • dulled rather than stimulated by too woeful a narration, and our minds
  • rebound from what is felt "too bad to be true." But before the reader
  • allows himself to be too much swayed by these natural reflections, and
  • before I lead him, as is the intention of this chapter, towards remedies
  • and ameliorations and the discovery of happier tendencies, let him
  • redress the balance of his thought by recalling two contrasts--England
  • and Russia, of which the one may encourage his optimism too much, but
  • the other should remind him that catastrophes can still happen, and
  • that modern society is not immune from the very greatest evils.
  • In the chapters of this book I have not generally had in mind the
  • situation or the problems of England. "Europe" in my narration must
  • generally be interpreted to exclude the British Isles. England is in a
  • state of transition, and her economic problems are serious. We may be on
  • the eve of great changes in her social and industrial structure. Some of
  • us may welcome such prospects and some of us deplore them. But they are
  • of a different kind altogether from those impending on Europe. I do not
  • perceive in England the slightest possibility of catastrophe or any
  • serious likelihood of a general upheaval of society. The war has
  • impoverished us, but not seriously;--I should judge that the real wealth
  • of the country in 1919 is at least equal to what it was in 1900. Our
  • balance of trade is adverse, but not so much so that the readjustment of
  • it need disorder our economic life.[157] The deficit in our Budget is
  • large, but not beyond what firm and prudent statesmanship could bridge.
  • The shortening of the hours of labor may have somewhat diminished our
  • productivity. But it should not be too much to hope that this is a
  • feature of transition, and no one who is acquainted with the British
  • workingman can doubt that, if it suits him, and if he is in sympathy and
  • reasonable contentment with the conditions of his life, he can produce
  • at least as much in a shorter working day as he did in the longer hours
  • which prevailed formerly. The most serious problems for England have
  • been brought to a head by the war, but are in their origins more
  • fundamental. The forces of the nineteenth century have run their course
  • and are exhausted. The economic motives and ideals of that generation no
  • longer satisfy us: we must find a new way and must suffer again the
  • _malaise_, and finally the pangs, of a new industrial birth. This is one
  • element. The other is that on which I have enlarged in Chapter II.;--the
  • increase in the real cost of food and the diminishing response of nature
  • to any further increase in the population of the world, a tendency which
  • must be especially injurious to the greatest of all industrial
  • countries and the most dependent on imported supplies of food.
  • But these secular problems are such as no age is free from. They are of
  • an altogether different order from those which may afflict the peoples
  • of Central Europe. Those readers who, chiefly mindful of the British
  • conditions with which they are familiar, are apt to indulge their
  • optimism, and still more those whose immediate environment is American,
  • must cast their minds to Russia, Turkey, Hungary, or Austria, where the
  • most dreadful material evils which men can suffer--famine, cold,
  • disease, war, murder, and anarchy--are an actual present experience, if
  • they are to apprehend the character of the misfortunes against the
  • further extension of which it must surely be our duty to seek the
  • remedy, if there is one.
  • What then is to be done? The tentative suggestions of this chapter may
  • appear to the reader inadequate. But the opportunity was missed at Paris
  • during the six months which followed the Armistice, and nothing we can
  • do now can repair the mischief wrought at that time. Great privation and
  • great risks to society have become unavoidable. All that is now open to
  • us is to redirect, so far as lies in our power, the fundamental economic
  • tendencies which underlie the events of the hour, so that they promote
  • the re-establishment of prosperity and order, instead of leading us
  • deeper into misfortune.
  • We must first escape from the atmosphere and the methods of Paris. Those
  • who controlled the Conference may bow before the gusts of popular
  • opinion, but they will never lead us out of our troubles. It is hardly
  • to be supposed that the Council of Four can retrace their steps, even if
  • they wished to do so. The replacement of the existing Governments of
  • Europe is, therefore, an almost indispensable preliminary.
  • I propose then to discuss a program, for those who believe that the
  • Peace of Versailles cannot stand, under the following heads:
  • 1. The Revision of the Treaty.
  • 2. The settlement of inter-Ally indebtedness.
  • 3. An international loan and the reform of the currency.
  • 4. The relations of Central Europe to Russia.
  • 1. _The Revision of the Treaty_
  • Are any constitutional means open to us for altering the Treaty?
  • President Wilson and General Smuts, who believe that to have secured the
  • Covenant of the League of Nations outweighs much evil in the rest of the
  • Treaty, have indicated that we must look to the League for the gradual
  • evolution of a more tolerable life for Europe. "There are territorial
  • settlements," General Smuts wrote in his statement on signing the Peace
  • Treaty, "which will need revision. There are guarantees laid down which
  • we all hope will soon be found out of harmony with the new peaceful
  • temper and unarmed state of our former enemies. There are punishments
  • foreshadowed over most of which a calmer mood may yet prefer to pass the
  • sponge of oblivion. There are indemnities stipulated which cannot be
  • enacted without grave injury to the industrial revival of Europe, and
  • which it will be in the interests of all to render more tolerable and
  • moderate.... I am confident that the League of Nations will yet prove
  • the path of escape for Europe out of the ruin brought about by this
  • war." Without the League, President Wilson informed the Senate when he
  • presented the Treaty to them early in July, 1919, "...long-continued
  • supervision of the task of reparation which Germany was to undertake to
  • complete within the next generation might entirely break down;[158] the
  • reconsideration and revision of administrative arrangements and
  • restrictions which the Treaty prescribed, but which it recognized might
  • not provide lasting advantage or be entirely fair if too long enforced,
  • would be impracticable."
  • Can we look forward with fair hopes to securing from the operation of
  • the League those benefits which two of its principal begetters thus
  • encourage us to expect from it? The relevant passage is to be found in
  • Article XIX. of the Covenant, which runs as follows:
  • "The Assembly may from time to time advise the
  • reconsideration by Members of the League of treaties which
  • have become inapplicable and the consideration of
  • international conditions whose continuance might endanger the
  • peace of the world."
  • But alas! Article V. provides that "Except where otherwise expressly
  • provided in this Covenant or by the terms of the present Treaty,
  • decisions at any meeting of the Assembly or of the Council shall require
  • the agreement of all the Members of the League represented at the
  • meeting." Does not this provision reduce the League, so far as concerns
  • an early reconsideration of any of the terms of the Peace Treaty, into a
  • body merely for wasting time? If all the parties to the Treaty are
  • unanimously of opinion that it requires alteration in a particular
  • sense, it does not need a League and a Covenant to put the business
  • through. Even when the Assembly of the League is unanimous it can only
  • "advise" reconsideration by the members specially affected.
  • But the League will operate, say its supporters, by its influence on the
  • public opinion of the world, and the view of the majority will carry
  • decisive weight in practice, even though constitutionally it is of no
  • effect. Let us pray that this be so. Yet the League in the hands of the
  • trained European diplomatist may become an unequaled instrument for
  • obstruction and delay. The revision of Treaties is entrusted primarily,
  • not to the Council, which meets frequently, but to the Assembly, which
  • will meet more rarely and must become, as any one with an experience of
  • large Inter-Ally Conferences must know, an unwieldy polyglot debating
  • society in which the greatest resolution and the best management may
  • fail altogether to bring issues to a head against an opposition in favor
  • of the _status quo_. There are indeed two disastrous blots on the
  • Covenant,--Article V., which prescribes unanimity, and the
  • much-criticized Article X., by which "The Members of the League
  • undertake to respect and preserve as against external aggression the
  • territorial integrity and existing political independence of all Members
  • of the League." These two Articles together go some way to destroy the
  • conception of the League as an instrument of progress, and to equip it
  • from the outset with an almost fatal bias towards the _status quo_. It
  • is these Articles which have reconciled to the League some of its
  • original opponents, who now hope to make of it another Holy Alliance for
  • the perpetuation of the economic ruin of their enemies and the Balance
  • of Power in their own interests which they believe themselves to have
  • established by the Peace.
  • But while it would be wrong and foolish to conceal from ourselves in the
  • interests of "idealism" the real difficulties of the position in the
  • special matter of revising treaties, that is no reason for any of us to
  • decry the League, which the wisdom of the world may yet transform into a
  • powerful instrument of peace, and which in Articles XI.-XVII.[159] has
  • already accomplished a great and beneficent achievement. I agree,
  • therefore, that our first efforts for the Revision of the Treaty must be
  • made through the League rather than in any other way, in the hope that
  • the force of general opinion and, if necessary, the use of financial
  • pressure and financial inducements, may be enough to prevent a
  • recalcitrant minority from exercising their right of veto. We must trust
  • the new Governments, whose existence I premise in the principal Allied
  • countries, to show a profounder wisdom and a greater magnanimity than
  • their predecessors.
  • We have seen in Chapters IV. and V. that there are numerous particulars
  • in which the Treaty is objectionable. I do not intend to enter here into
  • details, or to attempt a revision of the Treaty clause by clause. I
  • limit myself to three great changes which are necessary for the economic
  • life of Europe, relating to Reparation, to Coal and Iron, and to
  • Tariffs.
  • _Reparation_.--If the sum demanded for Reparation is less than what the
  • Allies are entitled to on a strict interpretation of their engagements,
  • it is unnecessary to particularize the items it represents or to hear
  • arguments about its compilation. I suggest, therefore, the following
  • settlement:--
  • (1) The amount of the payment to be made by Germany in respect of
  • Reparation and the costs of the Armies of Occupation might be fixed at
  • $10,000,000,000.
  • (2) The surrender of merchant ships and submarine cables under the
  • Treaty, of war material under the Armistice, of State property in ceded
  • territory, of claims against such territory in respect of public debt,
  • and of Germany's claims against her former Allies, should be reckoned as
  • worth the lump sum of $2,500,000,000, without any attempt being made to
  • evaluate them item by item.
  • (3) The balance of $7,500,000,000 should not carry interest pending its
  • repayment, and should be paid by Germany in thirty annual instalments of
  • $250,000,000, beginning in 1923.
  • (4) The Reparation Commission should be dissolved, or, if any duties
  • remain for it to perform, it should become an appanage of the League of
  • Nations and should include representatives of Germany and of the neutral
  • States.
  • (5) Germany would be left to meet the annual instalments in such manner
  • as she might see fit, any complaint against her for non-fulfilment of
  • her obligations being lodged with the League of Nations. That is to say,
  • there would be no further expropriation of German private property
  • abroad, except so far as is required to meet private German obligations
  • out of the proceeds of such property already liquidated or in the hands
  • of Public Trustees and Enemy Property Custodians in the Allied countries
  • and in the United States; and, in particular, Article 260 (which
  • provides for the expropriation of German interests in public utility
  • enterprises) would be abrogated.
  • (6) No attempt should be made to extract Reparation payments from
  • Austria.
  • _Coal and Iron_.--(1) The Allies' options on coal under Annex V. should
  • be abandoned, but Germany's obligation to make good France's loss of
  • coal through the destruction of her mines should remain. That is to say,
  • Germany should undertake "to deliver to France annually for a period not
  • exceeding ten years an amount of coal equal to the difference between
  • the annual production before the war of the coal mines of the Nord and
  • Pas de Calais, destroyed as a result of the war, and the production of
  • the mines of the same area during the years in question; such delivery
  • not to exceed twenty million tons in any one year of the first five
  • years, and eight million tons in any one year of the succeeding five
  • years." This obligation should lapse, nevertheless, in the event of the
  • coal districts of Upper Silesia being taken from Germany in the final
  • settlement consequent on the plebiscite.
  • (2) The arrangement as to the Saar should hold good, except that, on the
  • one hand, Germany should receive no credit for the mines, and, on the
  • other, should receive back both the mines and the territory without
  • payment and unconditionally after ten years. But this should be
  • conditional on France's entering into an agreement for the same period
  • to supply Germany from Lorraine with at least 50 per cent of the
  • iron-ore which was carried from Lorraine into Germany proper before the
  • war, in return for an undertaking from Germany to supply Lorraine with
  • an amount of coal equal to the whole amount formerly sent to Lorraine
  • from Germany proper, after allowing for the output of the Saar.
  • (3) The arrangement as to Upper Silesia should hold good. That is to
  • say, a plebiscite should be held, and in coming to a final decision
  • "regard will be paid (by the principal Allied and Associated Powers) to
  • the wishes of the inhabitants as shown by the vote, and to the
  • geographical and economic conditions of the locality." But the Allies
  • should declare that in their judgment "economic conditions" require the
  • inclusion of the coal districts in Germany unless the wishes of the
  • inhabitants are decidedly to the contrary.
  • (4) The Coal Commission already established by the Allies should become
  • an appanage of the League of Nations, and should be enlarged to include
  • representatives of Germany and the other States of Central and Eastern
  • Europe, of the Northern Neutrals, and of Switzerland. Its authority
  • should be advisory only, but should extend over the distribution of the
  • coal supplies of Germany, Poland, and the constituent parts of the
  • former Austro-Hungarian Empire, and of the exportable surplus of the
  • United Kingdom. All the States represented on the Commission should
  • undertake to furnish it with the fullest information, and to be guided
  • by its advice so far as their sovereignty and their vital interests
  • permit.
  • _Tariffs_.--A Free Trade Union should be established under the auspices
  • of the League of Nations of countries undertaking to impose no
  • protectionist tariffs[160] whatever against the produce of other members
  • of the Union, Germany, Poland, the new States which formerly composed
  • the Austro-Hungarian and Turkish Empires, and the Mandated States should
  • be compelled to adhere to this Union for ten years, after which time
  • adherence would be voluntary. The adherence of other States would be
  • voluntary from the outset. But it is to be hoped that the United
  • Kingdom, at any rate, would become an original member.
  • * * * * *
  • By fixing the Reparation payments well within Germany's capacity to pay,
  • we make possible the renewal of hope and enterprise within her
  • territory, we avoid the perpetual friction and opportunity of improper
  • pressure arising out of Treaty clauses which are impossible of
  • fulfilment, and we render unnecessary the intolerable powers of the
  • Reparation Commission.
  • By a moderation of the clauses relating directly or indirectly to coal,
  • and by the exchange of iron-ore, we permit the continuance of Germany's
  • industrial life, and put limits on the loss of productivity which would
  • be brought about otherwise by the interference of political frontiers
  • with the natural localization of the iron and steel industry.
  • By the proposed Free Trade Union some part of the loss of organization
  • and economic efficiency may be retrieved, which must otherwise result
  • from the innumerable new political frontiers now created between greedy,
  • jealous, immature, and economically incomplete nationalist States.
  • Economic frontiers were tolerable so long as an immense territory was
  • included in a few great Empires; but they will not be tolerable when the
  • Empires of Germany, Austria-Hungary, Russia, and Turkey have been
  • partitioned between some twenty independent authorities. A Free Trade
  • Union, comprising the whole of Central, Eastern, and South-Eastern
  • Europe, Siberia, Turkey, and (I should hope) the United Kingdom, Egypt,
  • and India, might do as much for the peace and prosperity of the world as
  • the League of Nations itself. Belgium, Holland, Scandinavia, and
  • Switzerland might be expected to adhere to it shortly. And it would be
  • greatly to be desired by their friends that France and Italy also should
  • see their way to adhesion.
  • It would be objected, I suppose, by some critics that such an
  • arrangement might go some way in effect towards realizing the former
  • German dream of Mittel-Europa. If other countries were so foolish as to
  • remain outside the Union and to leave to Germany all its advantages,
  • there might be some truth in this. But an economic system, to which
  • every one had the opportunity of belonging and which gave special
  • privilege to none, is surely absolutely free from the objections of a
  • privileged and avowedly imperialistic scheme of exclusion and
  • discrimination. Our attitude to these criticisms must be determined by
  • our whole moral and emotional reaction to the future of international
  • relations and the Peace of the World. If we take the view that for at
  • least a generation to come Germany cannot be trusted with even a modicum
  • of prosperity, that while all our recent Allies are angels of light, all
  • our recent enemies, Germans, Austrians, Hungarians, and the rest, are
  • children of the devil, that year by year Germany must be kept
  • impoverished and her children starved and crippled, and that she must be
  • ringed round by enemies; then we shall reject all the proposals of this
  • chapter, and particularly those which may assist Germany to regain a
  • part of her former material prosperity and find a means of livelihood
  • for the industrial population of her towns. But if this view of nations
  • and of their relation to one another is adopted by the democracies of
  • Western Europe, and is financed by the United States, heaven help us
  • all. If we aim deliberately at the impoverishment of Central Europe,
  • vengeance, I dare predict, will not limp. Nothing can then delay for
  • very long that final civil war between the forces of Reaction and the
  • despairing convulsions of Revolution, before which the horrors of the
  • late German war will fade into nothing, and which will destroy, whoever
  • is victor, the civilization and the progress of our generation. Even
  • though the result disappoint us, must we not base our actions on better
  • expectations, and believe that the prosperity and happiness of one
  • country promotes that of others, that the solidarity of man is not a
  • fiction, and that nations can still afford to treat other nations as
  • fellow-creatures?
  • Such changes as I have proposed above might do something appreciable to
  • enable the industrial populations of Europe to continue to earn a
  • livelihood. But they would not be enough by themselves. In particular,
  • France would be a loser on paper (on paper only, for she will never
  • secure the actual fulfilment of her present claims), and an escape from
  • her embarrassments must be shown her in some other direction. I proceed,
  • therefore, to proposals, first, for the adjustment of the claims of
  • America and the Allies amongst themselves; and second, for the provision
  • of sufficient credit to enable Europe to re-create her stock of
  • circulating capital.
  • 2. _The Settlement of Inter-Ally Indebtedness_
  • In proposing a modification of the Reparation terms, I have considered
  • them so far only in relation to Germany. But fairness requires that so
  • great a reduction in the amount should be accompanied by a readjustment
  • of its apportionment between the Allies themselves. The professions
  • which our statesmen made on every platform during the war, as well as
  • other considerations, surely require that the areas damaged by the
  • enemy's invasion should receive a priority of compensation. While this
  • was one of the ultimate objects for which we said we were fighting, we
  • never included the recovery of separation allowances amongst our war
  • aims. I suggest, therefore, that we should by our acts prove ourselves
  • sincere and trustworthy, and that accordingly Great Britain should waive
  • altogether her claims for cash payment in favor of Belgium, Serbia, and
  • France. The whole of the payments made by Germany would then be subject
  • to the prior charge of repairing the material injury done to those
  • countries and provinces which suffered actual invasion by the enemy; and
  • I believe that the sum of $7,500,000,000 thus available would be
  • adequate to cover entirely the actual costs of restoration. Further, it
  • is only by a complete subordination of her own claims for cash
  • compensation that Great Britain can ask with clean hands for a revision
  • of the Treaty and clear her honor from the breach of faith for which she
  • bears the main responsibility, as a result of the policy to which the
  • General Election of 1918 pledged her representatives.
  • With the Reparation problem thus cleared up it would be possible to
  • bring forward with a better grace and more hope of success two other
  • financial proposals, each of which involves an appeal to the generosity
  • of the United States.
  • The first is for the entire cancellation of Inter-Ally indebtedness
  • (that is to say, indebtedness between the Governments of the Allied and
  • Associated countries) incurred for the purposes of the war. This
  • proposal, which has been put forward already in certain quarters, is one
  • which I believe to be absolutely essential to the future prosperity of
  • the world. It would be an act of far-seeing statesmanship for the United
  • Kingdom and the United States, the two Powers chiefly concerned, to
  • adopt it. The sums of money which are involved are shown approximately
  • in the following table:--[161]
  • -----------------+------------+------------+-----------+----------
  • Loans to | By United | By United | By France | Total
  • | States | Kingdom | |
  • -----------------+------------+------------+-----------+----------
  • | Million | Million | Million | Million
  • | Dollars | Dollars | Dollars | Dollars
  • | | | |
  • United Kingdom | 4,210 | 0 | 0 | 4,210
  • France | 2,750 | 2,540 | 0 | 5,200
  • Italy | 1,625 | 2,335 | 175 | 4,135
  • Russia | 190 | 2,840[162]| 800 | 3,830
  • Belgium | 400 | 490[163]| 450 | 1,340
  • Serbia and | | | |
  • Jugo-Slavia | 100 | 100[163]| 100 | 300
  • Other Allies | 175 | 395 | 250 | 820
  • | ----- | ----- | ----- | ------
  • Total | 9,450[164]| 8,700 | 1,775 | 19,925
  • | | | |
  • -----------------+------------+------------+-----------+----------
  • Thus the total volume of Inter-Ally indebtedness, assuming that loans
  • from one Ally are not set off against loans to another, is nearly
  • $20,000,000,000. The United States is a lender only. The United Kingdom
  • has lent about twice as much as she has borrowed. France has borrowed
  • about three times as much as she has lent. The other Allies have been
  • borrowers only.
  • If all the above Inter-Ally indebtedness were mutually forgiven, the
  • net result on paper (_i.e._ assuming all the loans to be good) would be
  • a surrender by the United States of about $10,000,000,000 and by the
  • United Kingdom of about $4,500,000,000. France would gain about
  • $3,500,000,000 and Italy about $4,000,000,000. But these figures
  • overstate the loss to the United Kingdom and understate the gain to
  • France; for a large part of the loans made by both these countries has
  • been to Russia and cannot, by any stretch of imagination, be considered
  • good. If the loans which the United Kingdom has made to her Allies are
  • reckoned to be worth 50 per cent of their full value (an arbitrary but
  • convenient assumption which the Chancellor of the Exchequer has adopted
  • on more than one occasion as being as good as any other for the purposes
  • of an approximate national balance sheet), the operation would involve
  • her neither in loss nor in gain. But in whatever way the net result is
  • calculated on paper, the relief in anxiety which such a liquidation of
  • the position would carry with it would be very great. It is from the
  • United States, therefore, that the proposal asks generosity.
  • Speaking with a very intimate knowledge of the relations throughout the
  • war between the British, the American, and the other Allied Treasuries,
  • I believe this to be an act of generosity for which Europe can fairly
  • ask, provided Europe is making an honorable attempt in other
  • directions, not to continue war, economic or otherwise, but to achieve
  • the economic reconstitution of the whole Continent, The financial
  • sacrifices of the United States have been, in proportion to her wealth,
  • immensely less than those of the European States. This could hardly have
  • been otherwise. It was a European quarrel, in which the United States
  • Government could not have justified itself before its citizens in
  • expending the whole national strength, as did the Europeans. After the
  • United States came into the war her financial assistance was lavish and
  • unstinted, and without this assistance the Allies could never have won
  • the war,[165] quite apart from the decisive influence of the arrival of
  • the American troops. Europe, too, should never forget the extraordinary
  • assistance afforded her during the first six months of 1919 through the
  • agency of Mr. Hoover and the American Commission of Relief. Never was a
  • nobler work of disinterested goodwill carried through with more tenacity
  • and sincerity and skill, and with less thanks either asked or given.
  • The ungrateful Governments of Europe owe much more to the statesmanship
  • and insight of Mr. Hoover and his band of American workers than they
  • have yet appreciated or will ever acknowledge. The American Relief
  • Commission, and they only, saw the European position during those months
  • in its true perspective and felt towards it as men should. It was their
  • efforts, their energy, and the American resources placed by the
  • President at their disposal, often acting in the teeth of European
  • obstruction, which not only saved an immense amount of human suffering,
  • but averted a widespread breakdown of the European system.[166]
  • But in speaking thus as we do of American financial assistance, we
  • tacitly assume, and America, I believe, assumed it too when she gave the
  • money, that it was not in the nature of an investment. If Europe is
  • going to repay the $10,000,000,000 worth of financial assistance which
  • she has had from the United States with compound interest at 5 per cent,
  • the matter takes on quite a different complexion. If America's advances
  • are to be regarded in this light, her relative financial sacrifice has
  • been very slight indeed.
  • Controversies as to relative sacrifice are very barren and very foolish
  • also; for there is no reason in the world why relative sacrifice should
  • necessarily be equal,--so many other very relevant considerations being
  • quite different in the two cases. The two or three facts following are
  • put forward, therefore, not to suggest that they provide any compelling
  • argument for Americans, but only to show that from his own selfish point
  • of view an Englishman is not seeking to avoid due sacrifice on his
  • country's part in making the present suggestion. (1) The sums which the
  • British Treasury borrowed from the American Treasury, after the latter
  • came into the war, were approximately offset by the sums which England
  • lent to her other Allies _during the same period_ (i.e. excluding sums
  • lent before the United States came into the war); so that almost the
  • whole of England's indebtedness to the United States was incurred, not
  • on her own account, but to enable her to assist the rest of her Allies,
  • who were for various reasons not in a position to draw their assistance
  • from the United States direct.[167] (2) The United Kingdom has disposed
  • of about $5,000,000,000 worth of her foreign securities, and in addition
  • has incurred foreign debt to the amount of about $6,000,000,000. The
  • United States, so far from selling, has bought back upwards of
  • $5,000,000,000, and has incurred practically no foreign debt. (3) The
  • population of the United Kingdom is about one-half that of the United
  • States, the income about one-third, and the accumulated wealth between
  • one-half and one-third. The financial capacity of the United Kingdom may
  • therefore be put at about two-fifths that of the United States. This
  • figure enables us to make the following comparison:--Excluding loans to
  • Allies in each case (as is right on the assumption that these loans are
  • to be repaid), the war expenditure of the United Kingdom has been about
  • three times that of the United Sates, or in proportion to capacity
  • between seven and eight times.
  • Having cleared this issue out of the way as briefly as possible, I turn
  • to the broader issues of the future relations between the parties to the
  • late war, by which the present proposal must primarily be judged.
  • Failing such a settlement as is now proposed, the war will have ended
  • with a network of heavy tribute payable from one Ally to another. The
  • total amount of this tribute is even likely to exceed the amount
  • obtainable from the enemy; and the war will have ended with the
  • intolerable result of the Allies paying indemnities to one another
  • instead of receiving them from the enemy.
  • For this reason the question of Inter-Allied indebtedness is closely
  • bound up with the intense popular feeling amongst the European Allies on
  • the question of indemnities,--a feeling which is based, not on any
  • reasonable calculation of what Germany can, in fact, pay, but on a
  • well-founded appreciation of the unbearable financial situation in which
  • these countries will find themselves unless she pays. Take Italy as an
  • extreme example. If Italy can reasonably be expected to pay
  • $4,000,000,000, surely Germany can and ought to pay an immeasurably
  • higher figure. Or if it is decided (as it must be) that Austria can pay
  • next to nothing, is it not an intolerable conclusion that Italy should
  • be loaded with a crushing tribute, while Austria escapes? Or, to put it
  • slightly differently, how can Italy be expected to submit to payment of
  • this great sum and see Czecho-Slovakia pay little or nothing? At the
  • other end of the scale there is the United Kingdom. Here the financial
  • position is different, since to ask us to pay $4,000,000,000 is a very
  • different proposition from asking Italy to pay it. But the sentiment is
  • much the same. If we have to be satisfied without full compensation from
  • Germany, how bitter will be the protests against paying it to the
  • United States. We, it will be said, have to be content with a claim
  • against the bankrupt estates of Germany, France, Italy, and Russia,
  • whereas the United States has secured a first mortgage upon us. The case
  • of France is at least as overwhelming. She can barely secure from
  • Germany the full measure of the destruction of her countryside. Yet
  • victorious France must pay her friends and Allies more than four times
  • the indemnity which in the defeat of 1870 she paid Germany. The hand of
  • Bismarck was light compared with that of an Ally or of an Associate. A
  • settlement of Inter-Ally indebtedness is, therefore, an indispensable
  • preliminary to the peoples of the Allied countries facing, with other
  • than a maddened and exasperated heart, the inevitable truth about the
  • prospects of an indemnity from the enemy.
  • It might be an exaggeration to say that it is impossible for the
  • European Allies to pay the capital and interest due from them on these
  • debts, but to make them do so would certainly be to impose a crushing
  • burden. They may be expected, therefore, to make constant attempts to
  • evade or escape payment, and these attempts will be a constant source of
  • international friction and ill-will for many years to come. A debtor
  • nation does not love its creditor, and it is fruitless to expect
  • feelings of goodwill from France, Italy, and Russia towards this
  • country or towards America, if their future development is stifled for
  • many years to come by the annual tribute which they must pay us. There
  • will be a great incentive to them to seek their friends in other
  • directions, and any future rupture of peaceable relations will always
  • carry with it the enormous advantage of escaping the payment of external
  • debts, if, on the other hand, these great debts are forgiven, a stimulus
  • will be given to the solidarity and true friendliness of the nations
  • lately associated.
  • The existence of the great war debts is a menace to financial stability
  • everywhere. There is no European country in which repudiation may not
  • soon become an important political issue. In the case of internal debt,
  • however, there are interested parties on both sides, and the question is
  • one of the internal distribution of wealth. With external debts this is
  • not so, and the creditor nations may soon find their interest
  • inconveniently bound up with the maintenance of a particular type of
  • government or economic organization in the debtor countries. Entangling
  • alliances or entangling leagues are nothing to the entanglements of cash
  • owing.
  • The final consideration influencing the reader's attitude to this
  • proposal must, however, depend on his view as to the future place in the
  • world's progress of the vast paper entanglements which are our legacy
  • from war finance both at home and abroad. The war has ended with every
  • one owing every one else immense sums of money. Germany owes a large sum
  • to the Allies, the Allies owe a large sum to Great Britain, and Great
  • Britain owes a large sum to the United States. The holders of war loan
  • in every country are owed a large sum by the State, and the State in its
  • turn is owed a large sum by these and other taxpayers. The whole
  • position is in the highest degree artificial, misleading, and vexatious.
  • We shall never be able to move again, unless we can free our limbs from
  • these paper shackles. A general bonfire is so great a necessity that
  • unless we can make of it an orderly and good-tempered affair in which no
  • serious injustice is done to any one, it will, when it comes at last,
  • grow into a conflagration that may destroy much else as well. As regards
  • internal debt, I am one of those who believe that a capital levy for the
  • extinction of debt is an absolute prerequisite of sound finance in
  • everyone of the European belligerent countries. But the continuance on a
  • huge scale of indebtedness between Governments has special dangers of
  • its own.
  • Before the middle of the nineteenth century no nation owed payments to a
  • foreign nation on any considerable scale, except such tributes as were
  • exacted under the compulsion of actual occupation in force and, at one
  • time, by absentee princes under the sanctions of feudalism. It is true
  • that the need for European capitalism to find an outlet in the New World
  • has led during the past fifty years, though even now on a relatively
  • modest scale, to such countries as Argentine owing an annual sum to such
  • countries as England. But the system is fragile; and it has only
  • survived because its burden on the paying countries has not so far been
  • oppressive, because this burden is represented by real assets and is
  • bound up with the property system generally, and because the sums
  • already lent are not unduly large in relation to those which it is still
  • hoped to borrow. Bankers are used to this system, and believe it to be a
  • necessary part of the permanent order of society. They are disposed to
  • believe, therefore, by analogy with it, that a comparable system between
  • Governments, on a far vaster and definitely oppressive scale,
  • represented by no real assets, and less closely associated with the
  • property system, is natural and reasonable and in conformity with human
  • nature.
  • I doubt this view of the world. Even capitalism at home, which engages
  • many local sympathies, which plays a real part in the daily process of
  • production, and upon the security of which the present organization of
  • society largely depends, is not very safe. But however this may be, will
  • the discontented peoples of Europe be willing for a generation to come
  • so to order their lives that an appreciable part of their daily produce
  • may be available to meet a foreign payment, the reason of which, whether
  • as between Europe and America, or as between Germany and the rest of
  • Europe, does not spring compellingly from their sense of justice or
  • duty?
  • On the one hand, Europe must depend in the long run on her own daily
  • labor and not on the largesse of America; but, on the other hand, she
  • will not pinch herself in order that the fruit of her daily labor may go
  • elsewhere. In short, I do not believe that any of these tributes will
  • continue to be paid, at the best, for more than a very few years. They
  • do not square with human nature or agree with the spirit of the age.
  • If there is any force in this mode of thought, expediency and generosity
  • agree together, and the policy which will best promote immediate
  • friendship between nations will not conflict with the permanent
  • interests of the benefactor.[168]
  • 3. _An International Loan_
  • I pass to a second financial proposal. The requirements of Europe are
  • _immediate_. The prospect of being relieved of oppressive interest
  • payments to England and America over the whole life of the next two
  • generations (and of receiving from Germany some assistance year by year
  • to the costs of restoration) would free the future from excessive
  • anxiety. But it would not meet the ills of the immediate present,--the
  • excess of Europe's imports over her exports, the adverse exchange, and
  • the disorder of the currency. It will be very difficult for European
  • production to get started again without a temporary measure of external
  • assistance. I am therefore a supporter of an international loan in some
  • shape or form, such as has been advocated in many quarters in France,
  • Germany, and England, and also in the United States. In whatever way the
  • ultimate responsibility for repayment is distributed, the burden of
  • finding the immediate resources must inevitably fall in major part upon
  • the United States.
  • The chief objections to all the varieties of this species of project
  • are, I suppose, the following. The United States is disinclined to
  • entangle herself further (after recent experiences) in the affairs of
  • Europe, and, anyhow, has for the time being no more capital to spare for
  • export on a large scale. There is no guarantee that Europe will put
  • financial assistance to proper use, or that she will not squander it and
  • be in just as bad case two or three years hence as she is in now;--M.
  • Klotz will use the money to put off the day of taxation a little longer,
  • Italy and Jugo-Slavia will fight one another on the proceeds, Poland
  • will devote it to fulfilling towards all her neighbors the military rĂ´le
  • which France has designed for her, the governing classes of Roumania
  • will divide up the booty amongst themselves. In short, America would
  • have postponed her own capital developments and raised her own cost of
  • living in order that Europe might continue for another year or two the
  • practices, the policy, and the men of the past nine months. And as for
  • assistance to Germany, is it reasonable or at all tolerable that the
  • European Allies, having stripped Germany of her last vestige of working
  • capital, in opposition to the arguments and appeals of the American
  • financial representatives at Paris, should then turn to the United
  • States for funds to rehabilitate the victim in sufficient measure to
  • allow the spoliation to recommence in a year or two?
  • There is no answer to these objections as matters are now. If I had
  • influence at the United States Treasury, I would not lend a penny to a
  • single one of the present Governments of Europe. They are not to be
  • trusted with resources which they would devote to the furtherance of
  • policies in repugnance to which, in spite of the President's failure to
  • assert either the might or the ideals of the people of the United
  • States, the Republican and the Democratic parties are probably united.
  • But if, as we must pray they will, the souls of the European peoples
  • turn away this winter from the false idols which have survived the war
  • that created them, and substitute in their hearts for the hatred and the
  • nationalism, which now possess them, thoughts and hopes of the happiness
  • and solidarity of the European family,--then should natural piety and
  • filial love impel the American people to put on one side all the smaller
  • objections of private advantage and to complete the work, that they
  • began in saving Europe from the tyranny of organized force, by saving
  • her from herself. And even if the conversion is not fully accomplished,
  • and some parties only in each of the European countries have espoused a
  • policy of reconciliation, America can still point the way and hold up
  • the hands of the party of peace by having a plan and a condition on
  • which she will give her aid to the work of renewing life.
  • The impulse which, we are told, is now strong in the mind of the United
  • States to be quit of the turmoil, the complication, the violence, the
  • expense, and, above all, the unintelligibility of the European problems,
  • is easily understood. No one can feel more intensely than the writer
  • how natural it is to retort to the folly and impracticability of the
  • European statesmen,--Rot, then, in your own malice, and we will go our
  • way--
  • Remote from Europe; from her blasted hopes;
  • Her fields of carnage, and polluted air.
  • But if America recalls for a moment what Europe has meant to her and
  • still means to her, what Europe, the mother of art and of knowledge, in
  • spite of everything, still is and still will be, will she not reject
  • these counsels of indifference and isolation, and interest herself in
  • what may prove decisive issues for the progress and civilization of all
  • mankind?
  • Assuming then, if only to keep our hopes up, that America will be
  • prepared to contribute to the process of building up the good forces of
  • Europe, and will not, having completed the destruction of an enemy,
  • leave us to our misfortunes,--what form should her aid take?
  • I do not propose to enter on details. But the main outlines of all
  • schemes for an international loan are much the same, The countries in a
  • position to lend assistance, the neutrals, the United Kingdom, and, for
  • the greater portion of the sum required, the United States, must provide
  • foreign purchasing credits for all the belligerent countries of
  • continental Europe, allied and ex-enemy alike. The aggregate sum
  • required might not be so large as is sometimes supposed. Much might be
  • done, perhaps, with a fund of $1,000,000,000 in the first instance. This
  • sum, even if a precedent of a different kind had been established by the
  • cancellation of Inter-Ally War Debt, should be lent and should be
  • borrowed with the unequivocal intention of its being repaid in full.
  • With this object in view, the security for the loan should be the best
  • obtainable, and the arrangements for its ultimate repayment as complete
  • as possible. In particular, it should rank, both for payment of interest
  • and discharge of capital, in front of all Reparation claims, all
  • Inter-Ally War Debt, all internal war loans, and all other Government
  • indebtedness of any other kind. Those borrowing countries who will be
  • entitled to Reparation payments should be required to pledge all such
  • receipts to repayment of the new loan. And all the borrowing countries
  • should be required to place their customs duties on a gold basis and to
  • pledge such receipts to its service.
  • Expenditure out of the loan should be subject to general, but not
  • detailed, supervision by the lending countries.
  • If, in addition to this loan for the purchase of food and materials, a
  • guarantee fund were established up to an equal amount, namely
  • $1,000,000,000 (of which it would probably prove necessary to find only
  • a part in cash), to which all members of the League of Nations would
  • contribute according to their means, it might be practicable to base
  • upon it a general reorganization of the currency.
  • In this manner Europe might be equipped with the minimum amount of
  • liquid resources necessary to revive her hopes, to renew her economic
  • organization, and to enable her great intrinsic wealth to function for
  • the benefit of her workers. It is useless at the present time to
  • elaborate such schemes in further detail. A great change is necessary in
  • public opinion before the proposals of this chapter can enter the region
  • of practical politics, and we must await the progress of events as
  • patiently as we can.
  • 4. _The Relations of Central Europe to Russia_
  • I have said very little of Russia in this book. The broad character of
  • the situation there needs no emphasis, and of the details we know almost
  • nothing authentic. But in a discussion as to how the economic situation
  • of Europe can be restored there are one or two aspects of the Russian
  • question which are vitally important.
  • From the military point of view an ultimate union of forces between
  • Russia and Germany is greatly feared in some quarters. This would be
  • much more likely to take place in the event of reactionary movements
  • being successful in each of the two countries, whereas an effective
  • unity of purpose between Lenin and the present essentially middle-class
  • Government of Germany is unthinkable. On the other hand, the same people
  • who fear such a union are even more afraid of the success of Bolshevism;
  • and yet they have to recognize that the only efficient forces for
  • fighting it are, inside Russia, the reactionaries, and, outside Russia,
  • the established forces of order and authority in Germany. Thus the
  • advocates of intervention in Russia, whether direct or indirect, are at
  • perpetual cross-purposes with themselves. They do not know what they
  • want; or, rather, they want what they cannot help seeing to be
  • incompatibles. This is one of the reasons why their policy is so
  • inconstant and so exceedingly futile.
  • The same conflict of purpose is apparent in the attitude of the Council
  • of the Allies at Paris towards the present Government of Germany. A
  • victory of Spartacism in Germany might well be the prelude to Revolution
  • everywhere: it would renew the forces of Bolshevism in Russia, and
  • precipitate the dreaded union of Germany and Russia; it would certainly
  • put an end to any expectations which have been built on the financial
  • and economic clauses of the Treaty of Peace. Therefore Paris does not
  • love Spartacus. But, on the other hand, a victory of reaction in Germany
  • would be regarded by every one as a threat to the security of Europe,
  • and as endangering the fruits of victory and the basis of the Peace.
  • Besides, a new military power establishing itself in the East, with its
  • spiritual home in Brandenburg, drawing to itself all the military talent
  • and all the military adventurers, all those who regret emperors and hate
  • democracy, in the whole of Eastern and Central and South-Eastern Europe,
  • a power which would be geographically inaccessible to the military
  • forces of the Allies, might well found, at least in the anticipations of
  • the timid, a new Napoleonic domination, rising, as a phoenix, from the
  • ashes of cosmopolitan militarism. So Paris dare not love Brandenburg.
  • The argument points, then, to the sustentation of those moderate forces
  • of order, which, somewhat to the world's surprise, still manage to
  • maintain themselves on the rock of the German character. But the present
  • Government of Germany stands for German unity more perhaps than for
  • anything else; the signature of the Peace was, above all, the price
  • which some Germans thought it worth while to pay for the unity which was
  • all that was left them of 1870. Therefore Paris, with some hopes of
  • disintegration across the Rhine not yet extinguished, can resist no
  • opportunity of insult or indignity, no occasion of lowering the
  • prestige or weakening the influence of a Government, with the continued
  • stability of which all the conservative interests of Europe are
  • nevertheless bound up.
  • The same dilemma affects the future of Poland in the rĂ´le which France
  • has cast for her. She is to be strong, Catholic, militarist, and
  • faithful, the consort, or at least the favorite, of victorious France,
  • prosperous and magnificent between the ashes of Russia and the ruin of
  • Germany. Roumania, if only she could be persuaded to keep up appearances
  • a little more, is a part of the same scatter-brained conception. Yet,
  • unless her great neighbors are prosperous and orderly, Poland is an
  • economic impossibility with no industry but Jew-baiting. And when Poland
  • finds that the seductive policy of France is pure rhodomontade and that
  • there is no money in it whatever, nor glory either, she will fall, as
  • promptly as possible, into the arms of somebody else.
  • The calculations of "diplomacy" lead us, therefore, nowhere. Crazy
  • dreams and childish intrigue in Russia and Poland and thereabouts are
  • the favorite indulgence at present of those Englishmen and Frenchmen who
  • seek excitement in its least innocent form, and believe, or at least
  • behave as if foreign policy was of the same _genre_ as a cheap
  • melodrama.
  • Let us turn, therefore, to something more solid. The German Government
  • has announced (October 30, 1919) its continued adhesion to a policy of
  • non-intervention in the internal affairs of Russia, "not only on
  • principle, but because it believes that this policy is also justified
  • from a practical point of view." Let us assume that at last we also
  • adopt the same standpoint, if not on principle, at least from a
  • practical point of view. What are then the fundamental economic factors
  • in the future relations of Central to Eastern Europe?
  • Before the war Western and Central Europe drew from Russia a substantial
  • part of their imported cereals. Without Russia the importing countries
  • would have had to go short. Since 1914 the loss of the Russian supplies
  • has been made good, partly by drawing on reserves, partly from the
  • bumper harvests of North America called forth by Mr. Hoover's guaranteed
  • price, but largely by economies of consumption and by privation. After
  • 1920 the need of Russian supplies will be even greater than it was
  • before the war; for the guaranteed price in North America will have been
  • discontinued, the normal increase of population there will, as compared
  • with 1914, have swollen the home demand appreciably, and the soil of
  • Europe will not yet have recovered its former productivity. If trade is
  • not resumed with Russia, wheat in 1920-21 (unless the seasons are
  • specially bountiful) must be scarce and very dear. The blockade of
  • Russia, lately proclaimed by the Allies, is therefore a foolish and
  • short-sighted proceeding; we are blockading not so much Russia as
  • ourselves.
  • The process of reviving the Russian export trade is bound in any case to
  • be a slow one. The present productivity of the Russian peasant is not
  • believed to be sufficient to yield an exportable surplus on the pre-war
  • scale. The reasons for this are obviously many, but amongst them are
  • included the insufficiency of agricultural implements and accessories
  • and the absence of incentive to production caused by the lack of
  • commodities in the towns which the peasants can purchase in exchange for
  • their produce. Finally, there is the decay of the transport system,
  • which hinders or renders impossible the collection of local surpluses in
  • the big centers of distribution.
  • I see no possible means of repairing this loss of productivity within
  • any reasonable period of time except through the agency of German
  • enterprise and organization. It is impossible geographically and for
  • many other reasons for Englishmen, Frenchmen, or Americans to undertake
  • it;--we have neither the incentive nor the means for doing the work on a
  • sufficient scale. Germany, on the other hand, has the experience, the
  • incentive, and to a large extent the materials for furnishing the
  • Russian peasant with the goods of which he has been starved for the
  • past five years, for reorganizing the business of transport and
  • collection, and so for bringing into the world's pool, for the common
  • advantage, the supplies from which we are now so disastrously cut off.
  • It is in our interest to hasten the day when German agents and
  • organizers will be in a position to set in train in every Russian
  • village the impulses of ordinary economic motive. This is a process
  • quite independent of the governing authority in Russia; but we may
  • surely predict with some certainty that, whether or not the form of
  • communism represented by Soviet government proves permanently suited to
  • the Russian temperament, the revival of trade, of the comforts of life
  • and of ordinary economic motive are not likely to promote the extreme
  • forms of those doctrines of violence and tyranny which are the children
  • of war and of despair.
  • Let us then in our Russian policy not only applaud and imitate the
  • policy of non-intervention which the Government of Germany has
  • announced, but, desisting from a blockade which is injurious to our own
  • permanent interests, as well as illegal, let us encourage and assist
  • Germany to take up again her place in Europe as a creator and organizer
  • of wealth for her Eastern and Southern neighbors.
  • There are many persons in whom such proposals will raise strong
  • prejudices. I ask them to follow out in thought the result of yielding
  • to these prejudices. If we oppose in detail every means by which Germany
  • or Russia can recover their material well-being, because we feel a
  • national, racial, or political hatred for their populations or their
  • Governments, we must be prepared to face the consequences of such
  • feelings. Even if there is no moral solidarity between the
  • nearly-related races of Europe, there is an economic solidarity which we
  • cannot disregard. Even now, the world markets are one. If we do not
  • allow Germany to exchange products with Russia and so feed herself, she
  • must inevitably compete with us for the produce of the New World. The
  • more successful we are in snapping economic relations between Germany
  • and Russia, the more we shall depress the level of our own economic
  • standards and increase the gravity of our own domestic problems. This is
  • to put the issue on its lowest grounds. There are other arguments, which
  • the most obtuse cannot ignore, against a policy of spreading and
  • encouraging further the economic ruin of great countries.
  • * * * * *
  • I see few signs of sudden or dramatic developments anywhere. Riots and
  • revolutions there may be, but not such, at present, as to have
  • fundamental significance. Against political tyranny and injustice
  • Revolution is a weapon. But what counsels of hope can Revolution offer
  • to sufferers from economic privation, which does not arise out of the
  • injustices of distribution but is general? The only safeguard against
  • Revolution in Central Europe is indeed the fact that, even to the minds
  • of men who are desperate, Revolution offers no prospect of improvement
  • whatever. There may, therefore, be ahead of us a long, silent process of
  • semi-starvation, and of a gradual, steady lowering of the standards of
  • life and comfort. The bankruptcy and decay of Europe, if we allow it to
  • proceed, will affect every one in the long-run, but perhaps not in a way
  • that is striking or immediate.
  • This has one fortunate side. We may still have time to reconsider our
  • courses and to view the world with new eyes. For the immediate future
  • events are taking charge, and the near destiny of Europe is no longer in
  • the hands of any man. The events of the coming year will not be shaped
  • by the deliberate acts of statesmen, but by the hidden currents, flowing
  • continually beneath the surface of political history, of which no one
  • can predict the outcome. In one way only can we influence these hidden
  • currents,--by setting in motion those forces of instruction and
  • imagination which change _opinion_. The assertion of truth, the
  • unveiling of illusion, the dissipation of hate, the enlargement and
  • instruction of men's hearts and minds, must be the means.
  • In this autumn of 1919, in which I write, we are at the dead season of
  • our fortunes. The reaction from the exertions, the fears, and the
  • sufferings of the past five years is at its height. Our power of feeling
  • or caring beyond the immediate questions of our own material well-being
  • is temporarily eclipsed. The greatest events outside our own direct
  • experience and the most dreadful anticipations cannot move us.
  • In each human heart terror survives
  • The ruin it has gorged: the loftiest fear
  • All that they would disdain to think were true:
  • Hypocrisy and custom make their minds
  • The fanes of many a worship, now outworn.
  • They dare not devise good for man's estate,
  • And yet they know not that they do not dare.
  • The good want power but to weep barren tears.
  • The powerful goodness want: worse need for them.
  • The wise want love; and those who love want wisdom;
  • And all best things are thus confused to ill.
  • Many are strong and rich, and would be just,
  • But live among their suffering fellow-men
  • As if none felt: they know not what they do.
  • We have been moved already beyond endurance, and need rest. Never in the
  • lifetime of men now living has the universal element in the soul of man
  • burnt so dimly.
  • For these reasons the true voice of the new generation has not yet
  • spoken, and silent opinion is not yet formed. To the formation of the
  • general opinion of the future I dedicate this book.
  • THE END
  • FOOTNOTES:
  • [157] The figures for the United Kingdom are as follows:
  • Net Excess of
  • Monthly Imports Exports Imports
  • Average $1,000 $1,000 $1,000
  • 1913 274,650 218,850 55,800
  • 1914 250,485 179,465 71,020
  • Jan.-Mar. 1919 547,890 245,610 302,280
  • April-June 1919 557,015 312,315 244,700
  • July-Sept. 1919 679,635 344,315 335,320
  • But this excess is by no means so serious as it looks; for with the
  • present high freight earnings of the mercantile marine the various
  • "invisible" exports of the United Kingdom are probably even higher than
  • they were before the war, and may average at least $225,000,000 monthly.
  • [158] President Wilson was mistaken in suggesting that the
  • supervision of Reparation payments has been entrusted to the League of
  • Nations. As I pointed out in Chapter V., whereas the League is invoked
  • in regard to most of the continuing economic and territorial provisions
  • of the Treaty, this is not the case as regards Reparation, over the
  • problems and modifications of which the Reparation Commission is supreme
  • without appeal of any kind to the League of Nations.
  • [159] These Articles, which provide safeguards against the
  • outbreak of war between members of the League and also between members
  • and non-members, are the solid achievement of the Covenant. These
  • Articles make substantially less probable a war between organized Great
  • Powers such as that of 1914. This alone should commend the League to all
  • men.
  • [160] It would be expedient so to define a "protectionist
  • tariff" as to permit (_a_) the total prohibition of certain imports;
  • (_b_) the imposition of sumptuary or revenue customs duties on
  • commodities not produced at home; (_c_) the imposition of customs duties
  • which did not exceed by more than five per cent a countervailing excise
  • on similar commodities produced at home; (_d_) export duties. Further,
  • special exceptions might be permitted by a majority vote of the
  • countries entering the Union. Duties which had existed for five years
  • prior to a country's entering the Union might be allowed to disappear
  • gradually by equal instalments spread over the five years subsequent to
  • joining the Union.
  • [161] The figures in this table are partly estimated, and are
  • probably not completely accurate in detail; but they show the
  • approximate figures with sufficient accuracy for the purposes of the
  • present argument. The British figures are taken from the White Paper of
  • October 23, 1919 (Cmd. 377). In any actual settlement, adjustments would
  • be required in connection with certain loans of gold and also in other
  • respects, and I am concerned in what follows with the broad principle
  • only. The total excludes loans raised by the United Kingdom on the
  • market in the United States, and loans raised by France on the market in
  • the United Kingdom or the United States, or from the Bank of England.
  • [162] This allows nothing for interest on the debt since the
  • Bolshevik Revolution.
  • [163] No interest has been charged on the advances made to
  • these countries.
  • [164] The actual total of loans by the United States up to date
  • is very nearly $10,000,000,000, but I have not got the latest details.
  • [165] The financial history of the six months from the end of
  • the summer of 1916 up to the entry of the United States into the war in
  • April, 1917, remains to be written. Very few persons, outside the
  • half-dozen officials of the British Treasury who lived in daily contact
  • with the immense anxieties and impossible financial requirements of
  • those days, can fully realize what steadfastness and courage were
  • needed, and how entirely hopeless the task would soon have become
  • without the assistance of the United States Treasury. The financial
  • problems from April, 1917, onwards were of an entirely different order
  • from those of the preceding months.
  • [166] Mr. Hoover was the only man who emerged from the ordeal
  • of Paris with an enhanced reputation. This complex personality, with his
  • habitual air of weary Titan (or, as others might put it, of exhausted
  • prize-fighter), his eyes steadily fixed on the true and essential facts
  • of the European situation, imported into the Councils of Paris, when he
  • took part in them, precisely that atmosphere of reality, knowledge,
  • magnanimity, and disinterestedness which, if they had been found in
  • other quarters also, would have given us the Good Peace.
  • [167] Even after the United States came into the war the bulk
  • of Russian expenditure in the United States, as well as the whole of
  • that Government's other foreign expenditure, had to be paid for by the
  • British Treasury.
  • [168] It is reported that the United States Treasury has agreed
  • to fund (_i.e._ to add to the principal sum) the interest owing them on
  • their loans to the Allied Governments during the next three years. I
  • presume that the British Treasury is likely to follow suit. If the debts
  • are to be paid ultimately, this piling up of the obligations at compound
  • interest makes the position progressively worse. But the arrangement
  • wisely offered by the United States Treasury provides a due interval for
  • the calm consideration of the whole problem in the light of the
  • after-war position as it will soon disclose itself.
  • ***END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF THE
  • PEACE***
  • ******* This file should be named 15776-8.txt or 15776-8.zip *******
  • This and all associated files of various formats will be found in:
  • http://www.gutenberg.org/dirs/1/5/7/7/15776
  • Updated editions will replace the previous one--the old editions
  • will be renamed.
  • Creating the works from public domain print editions means that no
  • one owns a United States copyright in these works, so the Foundation
  • (and you!) can copy and distribute it in the United States without
  • permission and without paying copyright royalties. Special rules,
  • set forth in the General Terms of Use part of this license, apply to
  • copying and distributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works to
  • protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG-tm concept and trademark. Project
  • Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and may not be used if you
  • charge for the eBooks, unless you receive specific permission. If you
  • do not charge anything for copies of this eBook, complying with the
  • rules is very easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose
  • such as creation of derivative works, reports, performances and
  • research. They may be modified and printed and given away--you may do
  • practically ANYTHING with public domain eBooks. Redistribution is
  • subject to the trademark license, especially commercial
  • redistribution.
  • *** START: FULL LICENSE ***
  • THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
  • PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK
  • To protect the Project Gutenberg-tm mission of promoting the free
  • distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work
  • (or any other work associated in any way with the phrase "Project
  • Gutenberg"), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full Project
  • Gutenberg-tm License (available with this file or online at
  • http://gutenberg.net/license).
  • Section 1. General Terms of Use and Redistributing Project Gutenberg-tm
  • electronic works
  • 1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg-tm
  • electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree to
  • and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
  • (trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
  • the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or destroy
  • all copies of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works in your possession.
  • If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic work and you do not agree to be bound by the
  • terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from the person or
  • entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in paragraph 1.E.8.
  • 1.B. "Project Gutenberg" is a registered trademark. It may only be
  • used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people who
  • agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a few
  • things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works
  • even without complying with the full terms of this agreement. See
  • paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic works if you follow the terms of this agreement
  • and help preserve free future access to Project Gutenberg-tm electronic
  • works. See paragraph 1.E below.
  • 1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation ("the Foundation"
  • or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the collection of Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic works. Nearly all the individual works in the
  • collection are in the public domain in the United States. If an
  • individual work is in the public domain in the United States and you are
  • located in the United States, we do not claim a right to prevent you from
  • copying, distributing, performing, displaying or creating derivative
  • works based on the work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg
  • are removed. Of course, we hope that you will support the Project
  • Gutenberg-tm mission of promoting free access to electronic works by
  • freely sharing Project Gutenberg-tm works in compliance with the terms of
  • this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg-tm name associated with
  • the work. You can easily comply with the terms of this agreement by
  • keeping this work in the same format with its attached full Project
  • Gutenberg-tm License when you share it without charge with others.
  • 1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also govern
  • what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most countries are in
  • a constant state of change. If you are outside the United States, check
  • the laws of your country in addition to the terms of this agreement
  • before downloading, copying, displaying, performing, distributing or
  • creating derivative works based on this work or any other Project
  • Gutenberg-tm work. The Foundation makes no representations concerning
  • the copyright status of any work in any country outside the United
  • States.
  • 1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:
  • 1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other immediate
  • access to, the full Project Gutenberg-tm License must appear prominently
  • whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg-tm work (any work on which the
  • phrase "Project Gutenberg" appears, or with which the phrase "Project
  • Gutenberg" is associated) is accessed, displayed, performed, viewed,
  • copied or distributed:
  • This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere at no cost and with
  • almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or
  • re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included
  • with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.net
  • 1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work is derived
  • from the public domain (does not contain a notice indicating that it is
  • posted with permission of the copyright holder), the work can be copied
  • and distributed to anyone in the United States without paying any fees
  • or charges. If you are redistributing or providing access to a work
  • with the phrase "Project Gutenberg" associated with or appearing on the
  • work, you must comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1
  • through 1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the
  • Project Gutenberg-tm trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or
  • 1.E.9.
  • 1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg-tm electronic work is posted
  • with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
  • must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any additional
  • terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms will be linked
  • to the Project Gutenberg-tm License for all works posted with the
  • permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of this work.
  • 1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project Gutenberg-tm
  • License terms from this work, or any files containing a part of this
  • work or any other work associated with Project Gutenberg-tm.
  • 1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this
  • electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
  • prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
  • active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
  • Gutenberg-tm License.
  • 1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
  • compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form, including any
  • word processing or hypertext form. However, if you provide access to or
  • distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg-tm work in a format other than
  • "Plain Vanilla ASCII" or other format used in the official version
  • posted on the official Project Gutenberg-tm web site (www.gutenberg.net),
  • you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense to the user, provide a
  • copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means of obtaining a copy upon
  • request, of the work in its original "Plain Vanilla ASCII" or other
  • form. Any alternate format must include the full Project Gutenberg-tm
  • License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.
  • 1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,
  • performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg-tm works
  • unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.
  • 1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing
  • access to or distributing Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works provided
  • that
  • - You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
  • the use of Project Gutenberg-tm works calculated using the method
  • you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The fee is
  • owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark, but he
  • has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to the
  • Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty payments
  • must be paid within 60 days following each date on which you
  • prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your periodic tax
  • returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked as such and
  • sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation at the
  • address specified in Section 4, "Information about donations to
  • the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation."
  • - You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who notifies
  • you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that s/he
  • does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg-tm
  • License. You must require such a user to return or
  • destroy all copies of the works possessed in a physical medium
  • and discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of
  • Project Gutenberg-tm works.
  • - You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of any
  • money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in the
  • electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90 days
  • of receipt of the work.
  • - You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
  • distribution of Project Gutenberg-tm works.
  • 1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg-tm
  • electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set
  • forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from
  • both the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation and Michael
  • Hart, the owner of the Project Gutenberg-tm trademark. Contact the
  • Foundation as set forth in Section 3 below.
  • 1.F.
  • 1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend considerable
  • effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe and proofread
  • public domain works in creating the Project Gutenberg-tm
  • collection. Despite these efforts, Project Gutenberg-tm electronic
  • works, and the medium on which they may be stored, may contain
  • "Defects," such as, but not limited to, incomplete, inaccurate or
  • corrupt data, transcription errors, a copyright or other intellectual
  • property infringement, a defective or damaged disk or other medium, a
  • computer virus, or computer codes that damage or cannot be read by
  • your equipment.
  • 1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except for the "Right
  • of Replacement or Refund" described in paragraph 1.F.3, the Project
  • Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner of the Project
  • Gutenberg-tm trademark, and any other party distributing a Project
  • Gutenberg-tm electronic work under this agreement, disclaim all
  • liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including legal
  • fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT
  • LIABILITY, BREACH OF WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
  • PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH F3. YOU AGREE THAT THE FOUNDATION, THE
  • TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE
  • LIABLE TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE OR
  • INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH
  • DAMAGE.
  • 1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you discover a
  • defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it, you can
  • receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by sending a
  • written explanation to the person you received the work from. If you
  • received the work on a physical medium, you must return the medium with
  • your written explanation. The person or entity that provided you with
  • the defective work may elect to provide a replacement copy in lieu of a
  • refund. If you received the work electronically, the person or entity
  • providing it to you may choose to give you a second opportunity to
  • receive the work electronically in lieu of a refund. If the second copy
  • is also defective, you may demand a refund in writing without further
  • opportunities to fix the problem.
  • 1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
  • in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you 'AS-IS', WITH NO OTHER
  • WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO
  • WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTIBILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
  • 1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied
  • warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages.
  • If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the
  • law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be
  • interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted by
  • the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any
  • provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions.
  • 1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the Foundation, the
  • trademark owner, any agent or employee of the Foundation, anyone
  • providing copies of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works in accordance
  • with this agreement, and any volunteers associated with the production,
  • promotion and distribution of Project Gutenberg-tm electronic works,
  • harmless from all liability, costs and expenses, including legal fees,
  • that arise directly or indirectly from any of the following which you do
  • or cause to occur: (a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg-tm
  • work, (b) alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any
  • Project Gutenberg-tm work, and (c) any Defect you cause.
  • Section 2. Information about the Mission of Project Gutenberg-tm
  • Project Gutenberg-tm is synonymous with the free distribution of
  • electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of computers
  • including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers. It exists
  • because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and donations from
  • people in all walks of life.
  • Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the
  • assistance they need, is critical to reaching Project Gutenberg-tm's
  • goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg-tm collection will
  • remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
  • Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a secure
  • and permanent future for Project Gutenberg-tm and future generations.
  • To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation
  • and how your efforts and donations can help, see Sections 3 and 4
  • and the Foundation web page at http://www.gutenberg.net/fundraising/pglaf.
  • Section 3. Information about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
  • Foundation
  • The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non profit
  • 501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
  • state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
  • Revenue Service. The Foundation's EIN or federal tax identification
  • number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg
  • Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent
  • permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state's laws.
  • The Foundation's principal office is located at 4557 Melan Dr. S.
  • Fairbanks, AK, 99712., but its volunteers and employees are scattered
  • throughout numerous locations. Its business office is located at
  • 809 North 1500 West, Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887, email
  • business@pglaf.org. Email contact links and up to date contact
  • information can be found at the Foundation's web site and official
  • page at http://www.gutenberg.net/about/contact
  • For additional contact information:
  • Dr. Gregory B. Newby
  • Chief Executive and Director
  • gbnewby@pglaf.org
  • Section 4. Information about Donations to the Project Gutenberg
  • Literary Archive Foundation
  • Project Gutenberg-tm depends upon and cannot survive without wide
  • spread public support and donations to carry out its mission of
  • increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can be
  • freely distributed in machine readable form accessible by the widest
  • array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small donations
  • ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax exempt
  • status with the IRS.
  • The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating
  • charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
  • States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
  • considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and keep up
  • with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in locations
  • where we have not received written confirmation of compliance. To
  • SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of compliance for any
  • particular state visit http://www.gutenberg.net/fundraising/donate
  • While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where we
  • have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no prohibition
  • against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in such states who
  • approach us with offers to donate.
  • International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make
  • any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
  • outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.
  • Please check the Project Gutenberg Web pages for current donation
  • methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of other
  • ways including including checks, online payments and credit card
  • donations. To donate, please visit:
  • http://www.gutenberg.net/fundraising/donate
  • Section 5. General Information About Project Gutenberg-tm electronic
  • works.
  • Professor Michael S. Hart is the originator of the Project Gutenberg-tm
  • concept of a library of electronic works that could be freely shared
  • with anyone. For thirty years, he produced and distributed Project
  • Gutenberg-tm eBooks with only a loose network of volunteer support.
  • Project Gutenberg-tm eBooks are often created from several printed
  • editions, all of which are confirmed as Public Domain in the U.S.
  • unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not necessarily
  • keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper edition.
  • Most people start at our Web site which has the main PG search facility:
  • http://www.gutenberg.net
  • This Web site includes information about Project Gutenberg-tm,
  • including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
  • Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how to
  • subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.